Land, Shops and Kitchens: Technology in the Food Chain in Twentieth-Century Europe 2503517803, 9782503517803

The book discusses the concept of the food chain from a new perspective, emphasizing the historical dimension and confli

162 62 18MB

English Pages 296 Year 2005

Report DMCA / Copyright

DOWNLOAD FILE

Polecaj historie

Land, Shops and Kitchens: Technology in the Food Chain in Twentieth-Century Europe
 2503517803, 9782503517803

Citation preview

CORN Publication Series 7

© 2005 Brepols Publishers n.v., Tumhout, Belgium All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior permission of the publisher.

D/2005/0095/110 ISBN 2-503-51780-3

Land, shops and kitchens Technology and the food chain in twentieth-century Europe

Edited by Carmen Sarasua, Peter Scholliers & Leen Van Molle

@ BREPOLS

CONTENTS List of contributors

7

List of figures

8

List of tables

9

Preface

11

1. The rise of a food market in European history Carmen SARASUA and Peter SCHOLLIERS

13

2. Conflict and environmental tension in the adoption of technological innovation in the agrarian sector Ramon GARRABOU SEGURA

30

3. Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth Josep PUJOL-ANDREU

42

4. The role of EU policies in technological innovation in agriculture Konstandinos MATTAS and Efstratios LOIZOU

68

5. Recent innovations in the horticultural production system in the Southeast of Spain Carmen NAVARRO DELAGUILA, Jose LOPEZ-GALVEZ and Jose SALAZAR MATO

85

6. Nitrogen in modem European agriculture Vaclav SMIL

110

7. Modernisation and the international food system: re-articulation or resistance? David GOODMAN and Michael REDCLIFT

120

8. Kulturkampfin the countryside.Agricultural education, 1800-1940: a multifaceted offensive Leen VAN MOLLE

139

9. Changing tastes. The role of scientific and medical discoveries in changing the modem diet Rayna GAVRILOVA

170

10. The rise of supermarkets in twentieth-century Britain and France Isabelle LESCENT-GILES

188

5

Land, shops and kitchens

11. Milky ways. Dairy, landscape and nation building until 1930 Barbara ORLAND 12. Fast food and slow food. The fastening food chain and recurrent countertrends in Europe and the Netherlands (1890-1990) Anneke H. VAN OTTERLOO 13. Industrialising catering. Technological developments and its effects in the twentieth century Ulrike THOMS

6

212

255 278

LIST OF CONTRIBUTORS RAMON GARRABOU SEGURA RAYNA GAVRILOVA DAVID GOODMAN ISABELLE LESCENT-GILES EFSTRATIOS LOIZOU

JOSE LOPEZ-GALVEZ KONSTANDINOS MATTAS LEEN VAN MOLLE CARMEN NAVARRO DELAGUILA BARBARA ORLAND

ANNEKE H. VAN OTTERLOO JOSEP PUJOL-ANDREU MICHAEL REDCLIFT JOSE SALAZAR MATO CARMEN SARASUA PETER SCHOLLIERS VACLAV SMIL ULRIKE THOMS

Dept. of Economic History Universitat Aut6noma de Barcelona, ES Dept. of Cultural Studies University of Sofia, BG Dept. of Environmental Studies University of California, Santa Cruz, US Dept. of History University of Paris - Sorbonne, FR Dept. of Agricultural Products Marketing and Quality Control Technological Educational Institute of Western Macedonia, Florina, GR Dept. of Economics Universidad de Almeria, ES School of Agriculture Aristotle University ofThessaloniki, GR Dept. of History University of Leuven, BE Dept. of Applied Economics Universidad de Almeria, ES History of Knowledge Center Swiss Federal Institute of Technology Zurich, CH Dept. of Sociology University of Amsterdam, NL Dept. of Economic History Universitat Aut6noma de Barcelona, ES Dept. of Geography Kings College, London, UK Dept. of Applied Economics Universidad de Almeria, ES Dept. of Economic History Universitat Aut6noma de Barcelona, ES Dept. of History Free University of Brussels (VUB), BE Dept. of Geography University of Manitoba, CA Dept. of History of Medicine Freie Universitat Berlin, DE

7

LIST OF FIGURES 3.1 3.2 4.1 5 .1 5 .2 5 .3 5 .4 5 .5 5 .6 5 .7 5 .8. 8 .1 8.2 8.3 11.1 11.2 11.3 11.4 11.5 11.6 12.l 12.2 12.3 12.4 13.1 13.2

8

Main flows of wheat seeds between 1830 and 1914 Price indexes in Barcelona (Spain) in constant pesetas, 1865-1935 Simplified form of the development, transfer and use of technology in agriculture Evolution of production, home market and export in the Almeria agrarian sector Evolution of fruit and horticultural production in Almeria, season 1996/97 Distribution of working hours in the cucumber and green bean season 1987 /88 Estimation of labour force needs in one ha of tomato crop grown in a greenhouse without heating, season 1998/99 Sketch representation of the nursery fertigation system Plant of a seeding tray with irrigation by flooding The NFT system Arrangement of the double-paired lines in the cultivation channels Kilograms of cereals per head and per year The knowledge chain The knowledge network Railmilk-flow to Berlin, 1903 and 1927 Development of the Carl Bolle Dairy Development of producer prices for fresh milk in Switzerland, 1800-1914 Development of the milk production in Switzerland, 1837-1930 Development of export/import of cheese in Switzerland. Export 1851-1939 I Import 1851-1913 Export rates Swiss cattle, 1851-1913 The food chain Private consumption in the Netherlands, 1925-1985 Attributes of 'regional food' from consumers' point of view in 1998-1999 Reasons for acceptance and disapproval of higher prices of regional food in 1998-1999 Expenditure for wages of the kitchen staff per patient's day of stay in the Hospital St. Jacobs, Leipzig 1875-1908 Number of canteens in West-Germany and their turnover per employee, 1959-1999

LIST OF TABLES European Experimental Centres, members of the International Association of Seed Testing, 1931 3 .2 Institutions of wheat improvement in Europe, 1880-1938 3.3 New varieties of wheat between 1880 and 1938 3 .4 Pedigrees of wheat hybrids obtained between 1880 and 1938 3.5 Wheat improvement activities in Spain, 1880-1935 3 .6 Consumption of N, P 20 5 and K2 0 from mineral and chemical fertilizers between 1880-1936 3 .7 Agronomic conditioning factors and technical change 5 .1 Cost and destination of the investment 5.2 Production prices and income from the main cultivation alternatives (1990/91, 1993/94 and 1998/99 seasons) 5.3 Evolution of internal yield taxes 5.4 Work required by cucumber crops in greenhouses in two exploitations, one with family labour and the other with hired labour 5 .5 Residues generated yearly by tomato crops grown on the NFT system and on rockwool substrate 5 .6 Efficiency of the use of water and fertilisers, and contamination relations between tomato crops grown on the NFT system and on rockwool substrate 5 .7 Plant densities within the nursery and in the greenhouse, relation between nursery surface and greenhouse surface for different crop conditions 5 .8 Composition and characteristics of the nutrient solutions used for the different crops grown on NFT 5.9 Main results obtained with tomato, green bean and cucumber crops grown on NFT 8.1 Lectures organised annually by the Belgische Boerenbond, 1905-1939 10 .1 Household consumption of canned and frozen food in France in the early 1970s 10.2 Numbers of supermarket outlets in the UK 10 .3 Supermarket penetration in Europe in January 1972 10.4 Hypermarket penetration in Europe at 1/111972 10.5 Share of top five food retailers in Europe in 2000 10 .6 American acquisitions by European food retailers 1973-1984 10 .7 International network of major European retailers in 1990 12.l The ten leading world-wide food companies in 1997 12.2 Average availability of meat by type (g/person/day) in 1998 13 .1 The composition of cost of meals from the canteen of the Emser Plumb and Silverworks in Ems, Germany, 1875-1891 13 .2 Per capita consumption of potatoes, West-Germany, 1948/49-197 5 13 .3 Increase in the consumption of frozen food in private and collective households in Switzerland, 1964-1970 13 .4 Sales figures of frozen food 1991 and 2001 in Germany 13 .5 Costs per menu in a defrosting and in a normal kitchen in 1964 13.6 Food sold to the catering industry as percentage of total food sales in 1986

3 .1

9

Preface Bringing together historians from chiefly the North Sea countries, the CORN network conducts comparative research into rural developments in the North Sea Area from the Middle Ages to the twentieth century. Particular attention has been given by the research group to such key themes as land productivity, agro-systems, price development, the rural labour market, marriage patterns, common rights, tenure and land ownership. Agriculture and the countryside have no sharply defined geographic or intrinsic boundaries: town and country, agriculture and industry, the land, the cowshed, the market and the kitchen are all closely intertwined. In consequence, agrarian and rural history is not confined to the farm or does not stop at the borders of the village. Historical research follows the logic of increasing connections between agriculture and the surrounding world, as is clearly illustrated by the present CORN book Land, Shops and Kitchens and as will be further demonstrated by the succeeding volume Exploring the Food Chain. Both publications show the extent to which the inclusion of technological innovations has become a crucial factor in the proper understanding of the entire nutritional process. Land, Shops and Kitchens links the nineteenth century with the twenty-first and the North Sea Area with Central Europe and the Atlantic and Mediterranean regions. It traces the line from the land to what comprises our daily nourishment, and in doing so draws on the expertise of historians, economists, sociologists, geographers, natural scientists and engineers - a very enriching combination. Production, retailing and consumption are inextricable parts of the same reality offeeding the people. In this respect, European farmers are producing steadily less food for their own needs, concentrating rather on supplying local, regional, national and international markets. They are producing more and better, according to the demands of the customers in the food chain: the expanding food industry, the powerful wholesale business and the ever more numerous, wealthy and demanding public. Moreover, the development of the means of transport and new preservation techniques signify that there are nearly no limitations on transporting food; food processing indeed is transforming the notion of perishable food. Agriculture is no longer the pivotal and incontestable food supplier it once was, but has become just another of the many elements in the extensive food chain, together with fundamental and applied research, political interference, the industrialisation of food processing, the standardisation of packaging, the commercialisation of food in department stores and shifting eating patterns. The contributions of eighteen authors, coupled - it must be said - with the stimulating efforts of its initiators and editors, Carmen Sarasua and Peter Scholliers, have enabled this book to offer an exploration of numerous facets of the kaleidoscopic food chain. It is thus very gratifying that this publication has been accorded an excellent place in the CORN series. Leuven, June 2005 Leen Van Molle

11

1 The rise of a food market in European history Carmen SARASUA, Universitat Aut6norna de Barcelona Peter ScHOLLIERS, Free University of Brussels (VUB) The history of contemporary Europe is the history of the effort of European peasants and farmers to produce enough food for themselves, and to provide the market. It is the history of technicians, scientists, and individual inventors who, together with the peasants, developed new tools, machines, seeds and breeds in order to produce more wheat and more meat, and to produce a better quality and taste. It is also the history of governments to put an end to starvation crises which fuelled the masses' opposition to the Ancient Regime across Europe in the second half of the 18th century, and to guarantee lower prices for food, so that workers could subsist with very poor wages. Since the 18th century, the ever-growing European populations accounted for an increasing demand for food. Furthermore, an increasing percentage of this population was urban, dependent upon food markets, and of which the middle and higher classes, given their higher incomes and social aspirations, aimed at an increasingly diversified diet. To what extent did these massive changes in the demand for food transform its supply, i.e., agricultural productivity, techniques, and total output? They did transform it in the first place because of the central importance of agriculture in 18th-century economic thought and policies. Growing agricultural output meant the increase of the nation's wealth, to 'perpetuate wealth in the form of corn, drink, wood, livestock, raw materials for manufactured goods', as Quesnay wrote in his 1764 Tableau Economique (1972: i). The strategic importance of agricultural development for European governments explains the central role of agricultural policies and institutions that have regulated European agriculture in the last three centuries, developing a new revolutionary framework of property rights, and investing public money in water and transport infrastructures. The political importance of food was also apparent in the central role of agricultural price policies within economic policy. In the 18th and 19th centuries, when food shortages were common, European governments intervened to guarantee the supply of food at low prices for consumers and, at the same time, the profits of farmers (with protectionist policies). In the second half of the 20th century, with overproduction and increasing pressure from non-European producers, public intervention (EU agricultural policies) has consisted of subsidising agricultural prices in order to maintain farmers' profits. To a large extent, the fact that European governments shifted from keeping low food prices to subsidising agricultural prices, reflects the success of the impressive ensemble of technological innovations known as the agricultural revolution. The pressures from the demand not only stimulated the rapid diffusion of new machines and tools, but what was more important, also the expansion of an international market for food. This in turn was possible because of the major transformation of the transatlantic transport system, achieved thanks to technological innovations such as steam power applied to ships, which allowed for a much cheaper and regular connection between the American highly productive fields and the European markets. The transport revolution meant cheaper food and an increasingly integrated international food market, for wheat in the first place, which was a powerful incentive to further adoption of technological innovations

13

Land, shops and kitchens

by European farmers (a process, nevertheless, delayed or ignored thanks to the protectionist reaction of European agriculture). In this sequence, changes in the demand for food appear as the origin of the transformation of European agricultural production, and particularly of the central role that technological innovations had in the increase of agricultural productivity. But this new, competitive, and capital-intensive agriculture had in turn major impacts on the demand for food, that is, on the Europeans' diet: cheaper and better food, with a more diversified diet, was possible for more people now, particularly in the 20th century. Thus, the impact of technological innovations on relative prices was a key factor of this transformation, with strong consequences on consumption and on the social redistribution of income. To account for this story, this volume brings together three different research traditions: the historiography of agriculture, that of food, and that of retailing, and connects them to the history of technology. Although these fields have undergone distinct developments during the last decade, we strongly believe in their integration when it comes to the explanation of the history of food. Land tenure, soil characteristics, labour organisation, and climate or technical innovations affect directly the type, quality, significance, and quantity of the food. In turn, through consumers' preferences, snob effects, retailers' sales methods, and marketing, the retailers and the consumers have always influenced production. The history of food is, in fact, a perfect example of how the stories of production and consumption must be told together in order to explain the economic growth of the last three centuries. How the complex relationship between food production, distribution, and consumption did operate, and to what views and outcomes this has led and will lead, is a central concern of this volume.

I.

The role of technology in the food chain

Such integral approach is common among food sociologists and food geographers. Particularly the notion of 'chains of provision' or 'food systems' has been applied (Fine and Leopold, 1991; Atkins and Bowler, 2001). So far, historians have hardly considered chains of food provision. One but crucial exception, though: Dutch historians have adapted the 'chain of food products' that includes primary production (agriculture), secondary production (agribusiness), distribution (transport, packaging, wholesale and retail), food preparing (shopping, cooking and serving), actual consumption (eating, conviviality, identification), and waste disposal. Each phase is mirrored by a temporalspatial step, namely the farm, the factory, the market, the kitchen, the table and the garbage can (Van Otterloo, 2000; see also her chapter in this volume). Such approach has great merits with regard to the 20th century, when the so-called middle field is gaining weight (lobby organisations, marketing, household and cooking schools, food regulation by the state, medical counsellors et cetera). However, historians have directed their attention primarily to this middle field, and they neglected the whole chain of production, consumption and their relations. True, historians have not waited for theoretical insights to develop some kind of integrated view. We may refer, for example, to the large literature on past hunger crises, where attention is paid to crop failure, price increases, failing wholesale and retail trade, private and public relief initiatives, nutritional information and cooking advice, shrivelling calorie intake, rising social inequality, emigration, and sharply growing mortality

14

The rise of a food market in European history

(Rotberg and Rabb, 1985). There are of course other examples that advocate a direct link between food production, retailing and consumption (a connection that is not new in economics, that has traditionally analysed markets' supply and demand). But despite this strive for 'integral' consumption history, historians of agriculture, those of food retailing and food consumption seem to live in separate worlds with own journals, conferences, celebrities and bibliographical references. This is linked to different traditions and epistemological developments. Most agricultural historians have a background of economic history, devoting themselves to the study of employment, yield ratios, productivity and output, price developments, market structure, land tenure, technological innovation, labour and wages. Food historians have a very similar background when they study consumed quantities, price developments, institutions' diets, household spending on food, business histories, safety regulations and technological innovations. The 'culturalisation' of historiography, however, has taken many food historians away from the economics toward matters of taste, preference, sociability, representation, gender, identity, classifications, and other issues that became popular in the 1990s (Flandrin, 1999). Historians of retailing have largely followed the same path as food historians. Often, they started with the study of a big corporation (Wilson, 1970), or a spectacular innovation such as the department store (Miller, 1981). The cultural turn is presently shifting the attention to the significance and perception of shopping, fashion, gender, and especially to modernity. So, although the three approaches do have common grounds, they develop largely within own traditions and questions. It takes a very broad outlook to tie together the land, the kitchen, the supermarket, medical counselling, agribusiness, the table, health concerns, and taste. Technology may be saluted as a common ground that brings together the time-spaces of the food chain. We use a functional definition of technology here, as 'the sum of the methods by which a social group provides themselves with the material objects of their civilization' (Long and Post, 2003: viii). Historians of technology have described a multistage process, from invention to information, diffusion, and final adoption, with many factors intervening in it: educational and credit institutions, firms, groups of interest et cetera. Choices made among competing techniques should be taken into account, as well as stories of failure and success. Technology has been and is very present in the study of production, distribution and consumption of food. Agricultural historians have written extensively on innovations in work organisation, crop rotation, tools, fertilisation, machines, new seeds and breeds, in relation particularly to increasing productivity and output (van Zanden, 1991). Food and retailing historiography has focused on technological innovations transforming manufacturing and introduction of new produces, conservation, packaging, health, food distrust, and grocers' rationalisation and reorganisation (den Hartog, 1995). A definition of technology as inducing economic superiority (that can be traced back to Adam Smith and his description of a technologically superior capitalist division of labour) has been uncontested in economic and agricultural history for a long time. In this vision, technological superiority is defined as the method that costs less, with labour-saving technologies (with their massive implications on work organisation) as best indicators of economic efficiency. But technological innovations depend as much on economic and social institutions (that are in control of agricultural production). We think that one of the major contributions of this volume is to show the strength of the critical approaches to the technological box used in the last decades in Western

15

Land, shops and kitchens

agriculture and food industry. Interestingly, these criticisms do not stem from academic circles, but from consumers themselves. The critical reception (or direct refusal) of certain agriculture and food technologies shows the very active role of consumers in shaping and modelling technological production (Oldenziel et al, 2005). In fact, although not a new development, agriculture and food have become more of a battlefield in recent years, with heavy economic but also political interests at stake. And the fact that social scientists are being increasingly critical with the technological models adopted after World War II is only a reflection of consumers' growing discontent and a practical evidence that, in any given market, production cannot be understood without a deep comprehension of how consumption works.

II. Risk society, McDonaldization and other concerns about our food The historical study of technology in relation to the food chain contributes to important, past and present-day societal issues. Two of them, food scares and hyper-rationalisation, have gained large attention in recent years and ought to be put in historical context. Food scares form part of the recent concept of a society of risks, with fears, doubts, mistrust and uncertainties, which may be linked to neo-liberal, post-industrial developments (Beck, 1992). The role of technology is double,here. On the one hand, technology offers possibilities to control the whole chain of food provisioning more than ever, and to reassure consumers by boosting feelings of trust and security. Technological advancements have allowed the improvement of such control in the course oftime. But on the other hand, the same technological innovations which have been the basis of the productivistic model of agricultural growth dominant in the 20th century have had side effects on the world's natural resources and supply of raw materials. Genetic manipulation of plants and animals has contributed highly to the already important distrust of food among an increasing number of people. They (we!) have clear feelings ofjood alienation, which may lead to a loss of identity, tormented social relations, growing anxiety and augmenting tensions, and to the search for food authenticity and food safety (Fischler, 2001). In this process, governments are expected to intervene, and this since far-remote times (Bruegel and Stanziani, 2004). Surely, a society of risk is of all times, and the relation between technology and food insecurity should thus be investigated in a long-term perspective. Feelings offood alienation and food dangers lead to the second important phenomenon that links up with the first one: the so-called McDonaldization of social life, which is considered by sociologists as one of the three trends that affect present-day food consumption (together with social differentiation and self-rationalisation) (Germov and Williams, 1999, 6-8). At the production level, McDonaldization is a model of enduring rationalisation (Ritzer, 1996), fordism applied to the preparation of food. It refers to the ensemble of techniques that have transformed the food sector, seeking lower costs: most prominently the 'assembling line', but also standardisation of the product, ex changeability of components, and dequalification of the 'cooks', workers reduced to the repetition of a pre-fixed and limited number of movements. McDonaldization has transformed as well the consumption of food, implying a totally uniformed offer all over the world: same product, same taste, same process of preparation, same presentation. Again, technology has played a central role with a double effect. The massive success of a globalised model of fast-food eating-places has been possible thanks to technical

16

The rise of a food market in European history

innovations such as frozen foods, diffusion of standard types (in many cases genetically modified) of seeds and breeds (the same meat everywhere), industrial products such as ketchup or mayonnaise based on colouring and preserver chemical products, and transport and marketing innovations such as airlifting, packaging (take-away boxes) and retailing techniques. In this sense, technological developments appear as making possible new business opportunities and low cost food. But on the other hand, McDonaldization involves invariable taste, form and quality of the food, atomisation of meal patterns, disruption of 'traditional' social life, everincreasing distance between producer and consumer, et cetera. It replaces local products, tastes and traditional ways of preparing and consuming food. It ignores culinary culture of both cooks and eaters. The uniformed fast-food system has, thus, consequences that are undesirable for part of the population. The social and political struggle against these effects (and against the very technologies that have made this food system possible, like the demand for fresh, locally grown vs. frozen, imported foods, shows) has taken the form of a defence of 'traditional' or 'authentic' food. This reaction must not only be seen within the broader context of a defence (headed by France) of European food as an essential part of European culture, but also of European firms and markets. In making choices about their food, the new conscious consumers are also acting as protectionist barriers to the EU market as much as tariffs used to do. When Jose Bove and his farmer colleagues boycott a fast-food store, they are doing much more than advocating the return to the 'traditional' cheese, bread and wine diet.

III. Asking questions, seeking integral answers The present volume is based on a workshop organised in Barcelona, March 2003, as part of the European Science Foundation funded project 'Tensions of Europe: Technology and the Making of 20th century Europe' .1 Our main question to the participants was about the economic, social and cultural role of technology in the food chain, with special interest in tensions that came along with the technology. With tensions we meant, for example, the confrontation of different food models (fast food vs. 'slow' food), the distrust with regard to the massive use of chemical fertilisers, the struggle between producers and big retailers about the control over the food chain, or the debate with regard to the role of the state. We proposed to focus on six themes that fit into the broader theoretical concern of the ToE-project (i.e. linking and de-linking of infrastructures, circulation of knowledge, and circulation of artefacts): 1. Models of agricultural technological innovations: the ecological restriction 2. The technical formation of the agricultural labour force 3. The role of EC policies in technological innovations in agriculture 4. Industrial catering, fast food and their rejection 5. Hygiene and technological innovations in food preservation 6. Modem forms of food retailing 1

We would like to thank all the people and institutions that supported the organisation of the colloquium (particularly Johan Schot and Ruth Oldenziel from the Tensions of Europe-project, ToE), and the Universitat Aut6noma de Barcelona for hosting our meeting. More on the ToEproject may be found at http://www.histech.nl/tensions.

17

Land, shops and kitchens

The workshop brought together historians, sociologists, natural scientists, economists, geographers and engineers. This mix turned out to be extremely fruitful. We wished to create for each chapter a close connection between the historiography of food production, food distribution and food consumption around the question of technology. It is far from evident to assemble experts on chemical fertilisers and experts on identity construction through food, or to convince them to consider the whole food system. Yet, we believe that we generally succeeded in doing so: thus, agricultural historians and economists considered the consumers' reactions and resistance, while food historians linked the consumers' hopes and practices to changes in production. We consider this 'integration' of different traditions to be an important contribution to the interpretation of the development of food systems. The volume includes case studies from most of Europe, overcoming the restrictive Anglo-Saxon monopoly of the food system literature (Germany, France, Great Britain, The Netherlands, and Switzerland, but also Spain and Greece). A first outcome of the workshop was the electronic publication of six annotated bibliographies dealing with technology and dairy products (Barbara Orland), fertilisers, and in particular nitrogen (Vaclav Smil), industrial catering (Ulrike Thoms), environment and biological innovations (Josep Pujol), retailing (Isabelle Lescent-Giles), and agricultural education (Leen Van Molle). 2 A second outcome is the publication of the present volume.

IV. The long-term perspective: which technology, how much food? It seems useful to put the chain of food provisioning in a broader historical perspective. For our purpose, this may start in the 18th century. In pre-industrial Europe, the large majority of Europeans ate what the fields produced around them. Their food system and diet depended to a large extent upon the natural conditions of the land, soil, rain and work, that is upon a physical environment little shaped yet by the hands of women and men. European landscapes were modified and transformed, as Sereni (1974) proved when he described the Tuscan territory. Mountains were broken into terraces and cultivated, irrigation systems were developed, and by the 18th century new non-European crops had been adopted. But with the exception of the wealthy people who could afford non-local foods, the population had a diet mostly based upon local production. Yet, the concept of local food was always changing. In Spain, American plants such as potatoes, tomatoes or com were incorporated since the beginning of the 18th century, and by the mid-19th they were regarded as local crops. On the other hand, soil and climate conditions never allowed for the adoption of plants such as coffee, cocoa and spices, which kept being imported and regarded as exotic (in the sense of non-European, not of expensive) food until today (with the exception of sugar cane in parts of Andalucfa and bananas in the Canary Islands). If food consumption was a basic way of class differentiation, the central role of religion in shaping food demand should be remembered as well (for example, the expansion of pork meat as a statement on the condition of the non-Jew consumer). Massive consumption of fish (and an array of techniques to cure, salt, smoke, preserve, or keep it fresh) in 2 http://www.histechnl/tensions/de faultOud.html (theme "Agriculture and Food", see "Publications", and then "Annotated Bibliographies").

18

The rise of a food market in European history

Spain (today the second largest world consumer of fish, only after Japan) was also rooted in the fasting practices of Catholicism (Sarasua, 2001). The 18th-century agricultural revolution meant the development of capital-intensive agricultural techniques, which had rising yields as a consequence. Not only new tools and machines emerged, but also new organisational methods, property rights, practices, and ideas about the land. The incentive to develop, finance and adopt all these novelties, was the increasing population with a growing number of mouths to be fed, but also rising urban incomes. Middle classes and the rise of, what has been called, a consumer society, meant more abundantly supplied urban food markets, more money devoted to food (in absolute terms), and a more diversified diet. This increasing demand for food put new pressure on agricultural production: even if external markets were increasingly able to supply European demand, local farmers wanted of course take advantage and make a profit of it. And so they responded to the rising demand for food. The farmers' strategy was increasing investments, capitalisation, adoption of new techniques, diversification of output, and increasing productivity. After two centuries of capitalist agriculture, as new techniques have developed (agricultural, but also transportation, refrigeration, storage, and transformation techniques), the relation between agriculture (production) and food (consumption) has completely changed. Technology has allowed agriculture to overcome physical restrictions, and thus now we can eat what it pleases us at any moment: cheap tomatoes and strawberries arrive to Central and Northern Europe every day around the year. In the last decades, new functions of food (for example, food as a medicine) and changes in taste (Gavrilova in this volume) are replacing the plain, traditional ones (to merely satisfy a physical need, to perform a ritual as part of being a member of a social group). Thus, the ways we eat, as well as the very nature of our food, are changing. As a result of this deeply changing diet, the demand for food is changing too. And given the increasing international competition, this new demand is deeply conditioning agricultural practices and productive systems (non-refined bread and sugar, replacement of red by white meats, transformation of the greases market, et cetera). Of course, technological change in agriculture, entailing new uses and meanings of food, did not start in the 18th century, but it may be argued that changes then were that huge that the whole process became irreversible. Capital intensive technologies seem to have liberated agricultural production from physical restrictions. Agriculture can produce increasing amounts of any product at any time.

V.

(Agricultural) policies, (ecological) costs, and (food) antagonisms

Which role did policies have? As we mentioned above, agricultural production has had a strategic importance for European governments and institutions since the 18th century. It has been the goal of (particularly EU) agricultural policies after World War II to increase productivity by achieving economies of scale (by favouring large-scale production and concentration) and capitalisation. By the 1980s, however, decades of heavy subsidies had led to a number of serious problems in the EU, such as overproduction, increasing need for tariff protection - and subsequently problems with agricultural producers in the so-called Third World-, increasing regional disparities, heavy reduction in the number of farms and agricultural jobs, and growing political discontent for sub-

19

Land, shops and kitchens

sidies to the agricultural sector (which amounted to half the total EU expenditure). In an attempt to favour more productive units, subsidies have benefited more medium and large-scale units, and more developed regions. As a result, the costly and decades-long subsidies to the agricultural sector have actually increased economic differentiation among farmers and agricultural regions, and are being helpless in fighting the disappearance of agricultural activity. These problems led to the 1992 reform of the EU agricultural policy, analysed in the chapters by Mattas and Loizou, and by Redclift and Goodman. The 1992 reform fostered a new model of 'rural development' to replace the old model of 'agricultural growth', a model that has been 'marketed' and presented to the public opinion as the solution to another problem not yet mentioned here: the damaged environment. Focusing on the environmental problem, some of the chapters in the book put the question: at what cost? Very often, we understand costs in a very short-term way. A vision of long-term costs and externalities allows us to take into account the very high costs of producing while ignoring physical restrictions. In fact, failure or success in the adoption of a given technique also depends upon physical restrictions, as chapters by Pujol, Garrabou, and Navarro, Lopez-Galvez and Salazar show. This is a crucial matter. To what extent recent changes in diet and food consumption are really induced and determined by the consumer? What has been the role of corporations in shaping the demand for food? We know that by using a given technological toolbox, food firms make choices that condition to a large extent agricultural production. Thoms shows in her chapter how the supply of potatoes was heavily conditioned by the technological choices made by canteens and other mass consumers. Furthermore, the rapidity with which agricultural producers are adapting themselves to these new developments (organically-grown agricultural production, et cetera) is explained by the fact that, in a context of increasing competition and 'open' markets, European producers are not competitive via prices. Ecologically produced, traceable, safe and controlled food is more expensive than food imports, and thus it is becoming the best possible strategy to compete in the EU market. Like in the case of the return to local food, the ever growing demand for quality and health controls has replaced (or better, reinforces) tariffs as 'protective' mechanisms. The reaction against the type of standard mass-production that industrial food production entails, is another consequence of increasingly industrialised international food markets. This reaction, that may be labelled as 'slow food' in Van Otterloo's perspective, is taking two forms. One is the re-valuation of the 'traditional' way of producing food (i.e., non-industrial, home made food). This includes the opening of artisan-like shops to make cider, butter or jams 'the old way' (the use of pre-industrial technologies, including the restoration of old machines, tools and devices is an important mark), or the running of farms where hens are raised in open fields (vs. the chain-like industrial production). How food was produced 'traditionally' becomes the subject of a new narrative, as well as the target of food policies trying to preserve these 'traditions'. As Orland points out in her chapter, 'Discourses on old and new( ... ) can be read as a communication strategy which attempts to fill the gap between constant change in an industrialising world and the assumed character of unchanging and invariant peasants traditions'. The second form of this reaction is the definition of locally produced food as quality food. This is entailing the return to old ('local') breeds and seeds, the development of narratives about the 'regional' or 'local' ways of cultivating the soil and breeding ani-

20

The rise of a food market in European history

mals (in France, le terroir), as well as the reshaping of the industrial chains of distribution and marketing, well described in the chapter by Lescent-Gilles. Authenticity is the key word. 'Farmers markets', where farmers sell directly their production to the consumer, belong to this trend, which implies the return to seasonality and the rejection of exotic food. Finally, it seems obvious that one of the functions of these behaviours is to satisfy the need of wealthy consumers to distance themselves from mass consumers. Those who can pay more want to buy different products, and this is the new way to do it. The 'national' definition of technologies has also much to do with the uneven results of their adoption. Every technology is inextricably linked with the place from which it has developed, and this is much truer for agricultural technologies, which aims at modifying the conditions of the soil, and the reproduction of plants and animals. The 19th-century agricultural technology developed mainly in England, the Netherlands, and Central Europe, and was rapidly marketed (in the form of new tools, machines, breeds or seeds) as the recipe for increasing yields. One century later, the results of the a-critical adoption of these new techniques are devastating in regions whose physical conditions differ greatly from the regions where these techniques were originally developed. Chapters by Navarro, Lopez-Galvez and Salazar on the one hand and Pujol on the other, show that the adoption of agricultural technologies developed in Northern European countries had a very negative impact on Mediterranean agriculture, where water scarcity and soil poverty demand a completely different technological set. The questioning of intensive agricultural methods, high returns, high productivity, and industrialised technologies that have characterised the last two centuries, is taking different forms by Garrabou and Smil. The first is in favour of including the hidden costs of environmental destruction in the final balance of these productivistic models. Does it make sense to keep spending on technologies that have such a destructive impact on the environment? Should we abandon the tendency to ever increasing production? If Garrabou proposes to produce less (the abandon of intensive productive technologies), Smil proposes to eat less as the best way to lower the unnecessarily high demand for (and the waste of) food, and thus the non-sustainable pressure on the environment. In other words, to critically analyse consumers' habits and the political creation of needs.

VI. A further survey of the chapters ... It seems worthwhile to present very briefly each chapter separately, although some questions have already been raised. Each chapter shows very distinct points of interest, a specific approach or a particular conclusion, which will allow the emphasising of more questions. Ramon Garrabou's "Conflict and environmental tension in the adoption of technological innovation in the agrarian sector" presents an overview of Europe's agricultural performance since 1800. He reminds of the rapid increase of agricultural productivity since the end of the 19th century, fuelled by technological change, stressing the different development between the Atlantic and the Mediterranean regions, and the growing tension caused by the ever-growing use of non-organic modes of agriculture. In terms of damage to the environment, Garrabou's view is quite pessimistic. He pleads to include fully the environment in the (historical) analysis of agricultural development, and to devote full attention to health, pollution, and destruction of traditional modes of

21

Land, shops and kitchens

production. Vaclav Smil ("Nitrogen in modem European agriculture") picks up arguments developed by Garrabou, to fiercely denounce the ever-growing use of chemical fertilisers, particularly nitrogen that has great difficulties to get totally absorbed. He points at two far-reaching consequences: Europe's changing diet following the American model (particularly, the much too high caloric intake of the average European), and the environmental impact (on soil, water, air, wild life). Smil very explicitly connects agriculture to food, when suggesting that a possible solution for the high nitrogen use would include consumers who eat less, balancing our consumption of food with our real physical needs of food, and avoiding waste and excessive consumption. Such change would require social engineering. In "Modernisation and the international food system: re-articulation and resistance?", Michael Redclift and David Goodman place agricultural technological development in the broader context of the transformations of agri-food systems in 20th-century Western Europe and the region's insertion in global commodity markets. The chapter starts from the transition to capital intensive agriculture in late 19th century, then it discusses European agricultural policies since 1945 (fixing prices, absorbing surpluses ... ), and the problems related to this capital intensive model, such as 'food scares', to arrive to Common Agricultural Policy reform ('a massive decoupling of farm support from production'), and the new paradigm of an alternative agriculture, including new uses of land. This change, they argue, involves consumers' more active (political) role. They introduce a new project of social engineering, the so-called repeasantization (a renewed central role for farmers) and the quality turn in agriculture and food, with increasing importance of alternative agro-food networks. In "Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth", J osep Pujol develops the striking differences between the Atlantic and the Mediterranean regions, stressing the divergent relative cost on the one hand, and environmental conditions on the other since about 1820. He emphasises the way in which technological innovations have been introduced in relation to the environment in both regions. These were developed in northern Europe under particular environmental conditions, and so their adoption in the South has led to unexpected negative consequences (too intensive use of scarce resources). Maria del Carmen Navarro, Jose Lopez-Galvez and .Jose Salazar develop this North - South tension further by concentrating on the adoption of the greenhouse agricultural technology in Southern Spain ("Recent innovations in the horticultural production system in the Southeast of Spain"). Surely, productivity rose manifold, but at the cost of high technological investments and massive environmental damage (in terms of resources, water and soil pollution, and irreversible harm due to irrigation techniques). They stress the urgent need for environmentally aware agricultural policies to reverse this trend. Leen Van Molle's "Kulturkampf in the countryside. Agricultural education, 18001940: a multifaceted offensive" describes the evolution of agricultural education and the spread of technological know-how in Central Europe. In most countries the outcome of agricultural education was paradoxical: on the one hand, a strong discourse on authentic rural values emerged around the notion of the Heimat (homeland), while on the other a market-oriented, modem and scientifically based mode of production was promoted. What made this paradox possible was the 'hidden agenda' of agricultural technical education: not only improving the methods of production, but also maintaining and reinforcing class and gender differences. Education was used as a political instru-

22

The rise of a food market in European history

ment, and the transfer of technical knowledge was not neutral but aimed to maintaining the social, political and religious status quo. In their chapter on "The role of EU policies in technological innovation in agriculture", Konstandinos Mattas and Efstratios Loizou identify six broad categories of technological innovation in agriculture (biotechnology, mechanical and electrical equipment, bioenergy and fossil fuels, environmentally friendly innovations, animal production innovations, and innovations in agro-industries). They discuss to what extent the price-support system characteristic of the UE Common Agricultural Policy induced farmers to adopt technical innovations. They conclude that CAP has led to new problems (pollution, soil mistreatment, water supply problems), which explains the ongoing reform of EU agricultural policy, not longer seeking an increase of productivity, but the supply of healthy food and sustained rural development. These chapters, with an emphasis on the production side of the food system, address questions such as the measurement of the environmental costs, the chronology of innovation, the reaction of farmers to education, the role of mediators, and the responsibility of the state in education, the diffusion of technology and the environment. It appears that cultural elements need to be incorporated into the explanation of how agriculture has been conceived by rural workers, landowners, governments, lobbyists and consumers, and how, in tum, these cultural elements have influenced points of view, strategies and policies. Anneke van Otterloo ("Fast food and slow food. The fastening food chain and recurrent countertrends in Europe and the Netherlands, 1890-1990") historically explores the initiatives countering the industrialisation and rationalisation of food production in Europe since the end of the 19th century. After describing fast food expansion, using as a case study the Netherlands, she analyses Slow Food (born in 1986 in Italy as a movement against fast food), and claims that 'the rise of the modem industrial food chain between 1890 and 1990 has been accompanied by recurrent manifestations of discontent and protest'. The documentation of this discontent allows her to point that the contemporary 'quality tum' described by Goodman and Redclift (in this volume) must be understood not so much as a novelty, but as 'part of a whole century of debates on food qualities'. By focusing on mass consumption of food, Ulrike Thoms' chapter "Industrialising catering. Technological developments and its effects in the twentieth century", indirectly poses the question of defining who is the consumer of food: not only individuals or families but, as eating is increasingly done outside the homes, institutions (be these hospitals, schools, factories, other workplaces ... ). She looks at the cooking technology for 'the masses', considering the factors time, cost, scientific advice, endogenous elements (such as wars), the role of the state, and profit maximisation. Technical innovations, such as freezing and standardisation of the product, appear as preconditions for the increase in eating out. In tum, mass production of food implied the development of suitable (mass) cooking techniques and devices (friers, freezers), and the selection of a few varieties of each product (as the story of the potato shows). For Thoms, the most important innovations in food technology can be traced back to the specific demands of catering. Also, and importantly, the reciprocal influence between producers, scientists, the state and consumers is stressed, as well as the different evolution in East and West Germany. Barbara Orland directly links cattle production and milk consumption to the construction of national identity ("Milky ways. Dairy, landscape and nation building until 1930"). She considers the case of Switzerland (especially between 1880-1930), investi-

23

Land, shops and kitchens

gating the way the milk market operated, how the image of the Swiss nation was built and how and when new, sophisticated technology was applied. She explores the invention of a model (and an image, in casu the 'brown cow'), the way old modes of production changed under the influence of new techniques, market-oriented thinking and nation building. Rayna Gavrilova's chapter "Changing tastes. The role of scientific and medical discoveries in changing the modem diet" explores the influence of scientific and nutritional knowledge on taste and eating. She defines taste as a social construct that influences choices, and gives a survey of the nutritional research. She then considers science's points of interest related to food (energetic value, composition, vitamins, and food-linked diseases as obesity). Finally, she investigates how this knowledge affected the people's minds as well as their everyday eating practice (with health concerns and food scares). Particularly, Gavrilova studies how the scientific and medical knowledge has been diffused by means of texts, education, and policy. Overall, four interrelated phenomena may explain the growing importance of scientific knowledge for the general public: the trust in rational knowledge, the importance of the individual person, the role of the state, and the power of the bourgeoisie and middle-classes. Isabelle Lescent-Giles presents a chronology of modem, large-scale retailing in relation to product, format and business innovation ("The rise of supermarkets in twentieth-century Britain and France"). After an overview of the innovations in food retailing up to the 1920s (advertising, promotions, price strategies, et cetera), she focuses on 20th-century changes, and in particular on the coming of the supermarket in France and the U.K. She deals with product innovation (convenience and healthy foods), sales innovations (self-service, price scanning, differentiation with various trends that include slow food produces), and business innovation (centralisation, efficiency, internationalisation, diversification), which gave birth to a power struggle between the retailer and the manufacturer, won by the big retailers. Lescent-Giles' chapter stresses the technological innovations behind these business developments. These chapters, which emphasise the demand side of the food system (distribution, manufacturing and catering), address the questions of the role of kitchen technology (e.g. microwave) in the transformation of meal patterns (and family life), the reversing links between retailing and agriculture I manufacturing, the role of technology and science in identity formation, and the conflicts in relation to technological development (water and soil pollution, food quality, global markets, North - South and East - West tensions).

VII. .. .leads to new questions Many blank spots need further attention, and among them the use of fertilisers throughout Europe, the diffusion of agricultural know-how or the image of agriculture and agricultural labour in past and present. As for food consumption, the agenda for future research would include the spread of fast-food restaurants, technical innovation on packaging, advertising, conservation techniques or consumer credit; and the changing relation between food consumption, work schedules and the now declining role of housewives as family cooks. Yet, several conclusions may be drawn. The first one relates to a general observation: agriculture and food seem to offer a privileged way of looking at the contradictory

24

The rise of a food market in European history

effects of technology in the twentieth century. The second is a paradox: the technological innovations responsible for the dramatic increase in agricultural production in 20thcentury Europe are now widely rejected by individual consumers and by different social and political groups. The third conclusion refers to persisting (old, new and future) problems in European production, distribution, manufacturing and consumption of food with the widening of markets. There will be at least three main consequences of the 2004 EU enlargement to the East: food markets in the Western countries have to make room for the production of new members; subsidies for agriculture and livestock in the Western countries will be drastically reduced; and agriculture and food industries and distribution in the Eastern countries will have to adapt to the EU stricter health and environmental requirements. Proper insight in these developments and problems require an historical dimension. Soil pollution is one of the most serious environmental problems in Europe. Contaminants deposited in the soil pollute ground waters through leaking, and vice versa, polluted waters affect soil quality. This has obvious consequences for agricultural production, food safety, public health and the perception of food by consumers. The most direct source of water and soil pollution is the chemical products used in excess on agricultural production and lost to the environment. Yet, these agents of pollution were years ago the very sources of productivity increase, both in the West and in the East (ArdillierCarras, forthcoming). We will highlight one example of how technological innovations welcomed in the 20th century for their positive impact on production and productivity have come to be rejected due to their negative side effects on public health and the environment. What Vaclav Smil terms 'the 20th century most important agricultural revolution' was the synthesis of ammonia, the simplest of all stable inorganic nitrogen compounds, in the years around the Great War. It replaced traditional sources of nitrogen fertilisers (organic, such as guano or manure, and inorganic, such as nitrates). Dutch agriculture was the most intensive pre-1940 user of nitrogen fertilisers, with applications averaging above 40 kg N/ha during the late 1930s, and reaching 50-60 kg N/ha in parts of the country (the average US rate was less than 3 kg N/ha). By the early 1980s the Dutch application averaged 250 kg N/ha and was the highest in the world. European usage of nitrogenous fertilisers remained above half of the world's total. It has gone from 1.8 Mt Nin 1950, to 9.6 Mt N two decades later (in 1970), and it has peaked in 1988 at 15.98 Mt N. Europe's intensive fertilisation (even before ammonia) whose post-1950 costs were increasingly supported by rising agricultural subsidies, was reflected in a steady growth of average crop yields. By 1900 wheat harvests were around 2 t/ha in the UK, the Netherlands, Denmark and Germany. Due to other innovations, Dutch, English and French wheat yields rose from 4.3 t/ha during the early 1960s to 7 .3 t/ha two decades later. But unwanted side effects of intensive fertilisation appeared: 'The most acute problems with nitrogen leaking from excessively fertilised agro-ecosystems is the leaching of highly soluble nitrates into surface and ground waters' (Smil, this volume). In 1991 the Council of the European Communities issued its nitrate directive (91/676/EEC) requiring the member states to reduce the nitrate load from the agricultural sector to acceptable levels. This pullback lowered the average European applications to 99 kg N/ha by the year 2000, a nearly 20 percent from the 1988 peak (2057 g). Despite this reduction, 'The price Europe pays for its surplus of food thus goes beyond the staggering cost of

25

Land, shops and kitchens

irrationally high agricultural subsidies and the health effects of changing diets. Environmental costs of excess food output are actually more worrisome as many of these impacts would persevere even if the subsidies were to be miraculously cut' (Smil, this volume). Furthermore, there is a risk of over-production due to a fall in the demand for food. According to FAO's food balance sheets, Europe has by far the highest per capita food availability in the world. The EU mean was about 3,500 kcal/day in the year 2000, while actual daily food requirements are rarely above 2,000 kcal/person (a gap of 1,000 kcal/day). Food waste accounts for a large part of this gap which probably will lead to reduce food consumption (and thus, demand) in the near future. Changing diets and the continent's ageing population will further this tendency. Not only does Europe have the highest per capita food availability, but the dominant model of protein consumption, based mainly on animal proteins, results extremely inefficient and costly. In the first half of the 20th century the 'climbing of the protein ladder' (Goodman and Redclift, this volume) was centered on cattle breeding: cows need to process massive amounts of pasture to produce every kg. of meat. The same process is today taking place with fish breeding in fish factories (after technological innovations have made it possible): to produce 1 kg of salmon, 4 kg of fish flour are needed. Fish flour is industrially produced using as raw material other less demanded (cheaper) types offish, a process which incentives a systematic depredation of the seas. At the same time, consumption of vegetable proteins is falling dramatically. The relation between agriculture and food is twofold, as stated above. Within the current system of the large agribusiness, agricultural production is dependant upon its conveniences and requirements, that have also changed cheap, standardised and industrially processed food in mass consumption, and has to a large extent dictate EU agricultural policies. This transformation has consigned agriculture to a subordinate role in modern food systems, while it shifted control from farmers to oligopolistic trans-national food industry conglomerates and retail multiples. A more efficient use of technological innovations in the food chain implies, in the first place, a redefinition of efficiency: it is not about increasing yields and output at any cost or no matter how, but about sustainability and creating wealth without risking the environment or public health. Farmers must grow their crops without old chemical.friends such as pesticides and fertilisers, and replace them with old traditional inputs such as manure. They must be very careful with, or completely avoid, their use of genetically modified seeds or breeds. They will be required, on the other hand, to produce under most strict hygienic and safety norms, recycling their packaging. Is a realistic option this return to traditional, labour intensive techniques, replacing the capital intensive, productivistic technological model that has been dominant for over two centuries? At least we know that for the first time in their history, current EU environmental and agricultural policies are in the process of convergence, which means that their goals are no longer in contradiction. This also means that institutions and firms involved in the production of technology will have to adapt to this new type of demand for technology, new legal and health requirements, a new vision of what the role of technology must be, a new place for technology in agricultural production, in the food industries, and in consumption in general.

26

The rise of a food market in European history

VIII. Towards a new relationship between food and agriculture? A redefinition of the functions of the agricultural sector is currently taking place in Europe and particularly debated in the European institutions. This has evolved from the exhaustion of the fifty-year old model of EU Common Agricultural Policy, and the new challenges from both the world food market and the European consumers' demands. EU agriculture employs less than four percent of EU workers, but absorbs almost half the EU total budget. The reason for this dramatic unbalance is the old political decision by member states to subsidy a European agricultural sector, including a number of agricultural units of currently six millions (of which only one million would survive without subsidies). Heavy subsidies to agricultural production and exports have also led to other unsatisfactory unbalances. Within Europe, a double burden for the nonagricultural population arose, both in terms of how their taxes are being used and the prices they have to pay for their food. Outside Europe, the unfair competition with nonEU agricultural producers appears most particularly the non-industrialised, and thus the damaging consequences for food world markets. There is also the question of who has benefited from this agricultural policy. Despite the general claims, the main beneficiaries have been by far the largest producers, particularly the multinational firms. Today, eighty percent of total beneficiaries of CAP subsidies receive around twenty percent of the money, whilst twenty percent of the beneficiaries receive the other eighty percent. This has led to serious social and regional inequalities in the distribution of the subsidies. According to the Commission (October 2002), half of all direct payments by CAP go to the largest beneficiaries in the more productive and competitive areas, such as the Paris basin, Low Saxony or East Anglia, most of which contain export-led, multinational firms. Since 1 January 2005 the reformed CAP foresees the dis-entailment of subsidies from production: subsidies will be granted (and progressively reduced) to the agricultural unit, and no longer in connection with (as a percentage of) output. This is intended to end with overproduction and (what has been worst of all) with the fraud consisting in producing only to be granted the subsidy, no matter whether a demand existed for the product, and regardless any quality of environmental requirements. Discussing overproduction does not mean that hunger and malnutrition are not a problem for Europeans anymore, given the growing numbers of poor people among the immigrant population, elder citizens - particularly women, and unemployed. Women and men collecting rejected meat or vegetables at night at the garbage cans, backdoors of supermarkets, are a common view in large cities, as people queuing at the entrance of private and public charity institutions for a simple, hot meal. Yet despite these new (or rather old) hungry poor, European agricultural policy is no longer concerned by food provision, but by increasingly sophisticated consumers' demands, such as quality and safety standards, traceability, protection of local denominations, environmental protection, and animal welfare. These complex and new consumers' demands are shaping agricultural production in a wholly new way. Yet, this is not to say that the productive sector is in the hands of consumers. After a long century of innovations in organisation, marketing and distribution, and increasing vertical integration of firms in the food chain, favoured by CAP subsidies and policies, large agribusiness are able to market in their benefit every type of 'consumer demand', and increasing their profits through it. Not only that, but the

27

Land, shops and kitchens

high standards of quality and safety required by EU food legislation are acting, in practice, as powerful trade barriers to imports from non EU (and non Western) agricultural producers (and as such, defended by EU multinational firms). Yet, even if agribusiness is profiting by the new changes in demands of food, it is not the only one in doing so. The new tendencies in food consumption include a strong flavour of 'back to the local', a re-valorisation of the local, non-industrial cultivation and food production systems. Even if main suppliers of ecological and biologically produced food are large fmns, a small segment of small scale producers coexists with them, mainly distributing through local fairs and markets, or through the farms themselves. Although their dimension is very modest, their existence is significant of a new taste for non-mass, industrialised, food production, and has also interesting political implications. The role played by cow breeding and milk production in the Swiss process of nation building (Orland, this volume) echoes the role played by agriculture and food in the new regionalisms and nationalisms growing within the EU. The construction (and then the defence) oflocal 'traditions' in soil cultivation, animal breeding, and food producing and cooking, explains some of the latest developments in food consumption. Increasingly, the old functions of agriculture are being replaced by a new vision of the rural regions. This implies a vision about what the rural population should devote themselves to, i.e. to protect the environment and landscapes, to receive tourists (and sports lovers, hunters and fishermen), to keep alive the old productive activities, the cultural heritage. Europeans are surely happier to pay for these social goods than for overproduction of unwanted or too costly produced food items, only to be later destroyed to keep a convenient price level. What can be envisioned for the future is a much smaller part of the European soil devoted to agricultural and cattle production (and of this, most outside the intensively technological model today increasingly rejected), together with a large part devoted to alternative, non agricultural production. This evolution means that the close connection made at the beginning of this Introduction between agriculture and food may be less close in a few decades. Not only the old 'agricultural sector' will be less and less connected with food production, and increasingly centered in providing services or alternative -not for food-produc ts (such as wood). Part of our food may have no relation with agriculture anymore! It may come from industries producing at their own laboratories. Is it too shocking for Europeans to imagine ourselves buying our vitamins, minerals and proteins in the parapharmacies, like Americans already do, instead of in our old markets in the form of oranges and milk? A perfectly balanced and perfectly safe diet for the European of the future? Let us simply say that this is, already, technically possible.

28

The rise of a food market in European history

Bibliography Ardillier-Carras, F. (forthcoming), 'La descolectivizaci6n de la agricultura en Armenia o las dificultades de la transici6n post sovietica', Historia Agraria, 36. Atkins, P. and Bowler, I. (2001) Food in society: economy, culture, geography, London. Beck, U. (1992) Risk society. Towards a new modernity, London. Bruegel, M. and Stanziani, A. (2004) 'Pour une histoire de la "securite alimentaire"', Revue d'Histoire Moderne et Contmporaine, 51, 3, pp. 7-16. Fine, B. and Leopold, E. (1991) The world of consumption, London. Fischler, C. (2001) L' Homnivore. Le gout, la cuisine et le corps, Paris. Flandrin, J.-L. (1999) 'Preface', in J.-L. Flandrin and J. Cobbi (eds), Tables d'hier, tables d' ailleurs. Histoire et ethnologie du repas, Paris, pp. 17-36. Germov, J. and Williams, L. (eds) (1999) A sociology offood and nutrition. The social appetite, Oxford. Hartog, A. den (ed.) (1995) Food technology, science and marketing. The European diet in the twentieth century, East Linton. Long, P.O. and Post, R.C. (2003) 'Series Introduction', in R.C. Post (ed), Technology, transport and travel in American history. Historical perspectives on technology, society and culture, Washington, pp. vii-ix. Miller, M.B. (1981) The Bon Marche: bourgeois culture and the department store 18691920, London. Oldenziel, R., Albert de la Bruheze, A. and Wit, 0. de (2005) 'Europe's mediation junction: technology and consumer society in the 20th Century', History and Technology, 21, 1,pp. 107-139. Otterloo,A. van (2000) 'Voeding in verandering', in J.W. Schot, [et al.] (eds), Techniek in Nederland in de twintigste eeuw, Zutphen, pp. 237-247. Ritzer, G. (1996 2) The McDonaldization of society, New York. Rotberg, R. and Rabb, T.K. (eds) (1985) Hunger and history, Cambridge. Quesnay's Tableau Economique (1972), edited and translated by Kuczynski, M. and Meek, R.L, London. Sarasua, C. (2001) 'Upholding status: the diet of a noble family in early 19th-century La Mancha', in P. Scholliers (ed.), Food, drink and identity. Cooking, eating and drinking in Europe since the Middle Ages, Oxford, pp. 37-61. Sereni, E. (1974) Storia de! paesaggio agrario italiano, Milan. Wilson, C. (1970) The history of Unilever: a study in economic growth and social change, London, 1970. Zanden, J.L. van (1991) 'The first green revolution: the growth of production and productivity in European agriculture, 1870-1914', Economic History Review, 44, 2, pp. 215-239.

29

2

Conflict and environmental tension in the adoption of technological innovation in the agrarian sector Ramon GARRABOU SEGURA, Universitat Aut6noma de Barcelona

There is little doubt today about the adverse effects that the technological complex behind the systems of agriculture in the world's industrialised nations had on the environment. Following several decades of use, serious problems of degradation have been observed to the extent that there are now growing doubts as to whether productive capacity can be maintained and food quality and safety be guaranteed in the future. Observation of the food production system of the end of the 20th century reveals the twin phenomenon of spectacular growth in production and productivity and, at the same time, alarming processes of environmental damage and worrying problems of food safety. When we consider how this situation has emerged, there is little doubt about the decisive role technological innovation has had in the whole process. Analysis of technological change is thus evidently a significant factor in order to explain the contradictory nature of the evolution of agriculture and the environmental conflicts it has generated. It is my intention here not to systematically examine technological changes in agriculture but, rather, to show some of the significant differences between the technological innovations before and after the implementation of the technological complex behind the green revolution. Having characterised the innovations of advanced organic agriculture, I will show how a series of factors led, from the end of the 19th century onwards, to an intensification of technological change and how, above all, this moved off in new directions. Finally, I will look at the environmental conflicts that the application of the new technological model generated, concentrating on those caused by the spread of new fertilisation techniques and the emergence of a new stock-raising system.

I. Technological change in the context of advanced organic agriculture Until the beginning of the 20th century, farming systems continued to be organically based. In Atlantic Europe from the 18th century on, the main line of innovation depended essentially on the diffusion of crop rotation that brought in leguminous forage plants and alternated cereals with turnips and beet. 1 Fallow was abandoned, which meant an intensification of land use and greater pressure than under previous systems without, however, destroying the equilibrium that guaranteed the maintenance of its productive capacity. Despite processes of specialisation, the succession of a very diverse series of plants on the land was the norm under these systems of agriculture, and the maintenance of vegetation on field boundaries meant the survival of levels of diversity that were of enormous value in agronomic terms. Farmers had observed that the technique of crop

An excellent analysis of this fundamental aspect of technological change at this time is to be found in Chorley, 1981: 34. 1

30

Conflict and environmental tension in the adoption of technological innovation

alternating produced good results at harvest time and avoided the problem of infesting plants and, at the same time, was an efficient means of preventing or diminishing the effects of plagues and disease. The bringing in of leguminous forage plants, turnips and beet made possible the development of large-scale stock-raising, closely linked to the crops grown on the farms, which produced most of the fodder. Stock raising provided the driving force that accounted for a significant proportion of the energy inputs used on the farm, besides growing quantities of meat and milk supply. As for the fundamental element of any system of agriculture, the question of replacing the nutrients extracted from the soil with the harvest, the innovations brought in with the new rotations were a major improvement, in particular as regarded the nitrogen cycle. With their ability to fix nitrogen from the atmosphere, leguminous forage plants, alfalfa and clover added to the nitrogen drawn from the soil free of charge, to be used for future crops. Besides that, livestock produced a significant proportion of the fertilising material in the form of manure, produced from farmyard waste, which meant the elimination of the waste that was later to cause such problems. Although over the course of the 19th century other fertilising materials began to be used, particularly guano as well as industrial fertilisers, their use was marginal and complementary to a system of fertilisation based on the reuse of waste matter of all kinds from the farms themselves. The variety of animal breeds remained another characteristic of this technological model. Although there was development of the practice of selective stock breeding with a view to improving meat, dairy or work production, the degree of manipulation was moderate and the feeding system continued to be based on natural pasture and forage, and feed from the farms themselves. As for seeds, the process of ecological globalisation that occurred in the 19th century and the first attempts at hybridisation (in that they put species and plant varieties from around the world at the disposal of European farmers) guaranteed high levels of bio-diversity compatible with the growing homogeneousness of plantations. In the context of systems of organically based agriculture in which the use of fossil fuels remained very limited, levels of mechanisation continued to be modest. With the exception of threshing machines, the use of the steam engine was very limited in other farming activities. The use of animal power was dominant, and the type of machinery that could be used with such traction had neither an adverse effect on the maintenance of the fertility of arable land nor caused significant levels of pollution. 2 In the Mediterranean, the spread of this technological model and its principal innovation, the alternation of crops with the incorporation of forage plants in rotations, was less marked than in Atlantic Europe. Low rainfall was often an insurmountable obstacle, and extensive farming with the use of fallow remained the very generalised norm. The persistence of fallow has often been interpreted as proof of a reticence to technological change and of irrational behaviour on the part of Mediterranean farmers in not introducing a form of innovation that had spread throughout Atlantic Europe and that had brought marked improvements in production. Contemporary writers often made assessments of this nature, and historians have often repeated them. I believe this is a good example of the problems involved in the analysis of technological change in

2

An overview of the main lines of innovation in European agriculture in the 18th and the 19th centuries can be found in Mazoyer and Roudart, 1997.

31

Land, shops and kitchens

agriculture when environmental variables are overlooked.3 As some agronomists and technicians began to argue in the early years of the 20th century, the arid conditions typical of much of the Mediterranean impeded the implementation of the type of rotation that had a major role in improvements in production in Atlantic Europe. In the climatic conditions of the Mediterranean it was difficult to replace fallow with leguminous forage plants as water levels and the cycle of rainfall did not guarantee the proper growth of such plants, while fallow served to retain in the soil some of the rain that could be used for cereal crops the following year. It was also an efficient means of eliminating weeds. Given frequent situations of hydraulic stress affecting most of the crops, having a little more water available, albeit in small amounts, was of enormous importance. Despite the persistence of fallow, the alternation of crops was commonplace, on occasion different varieties and species of cereals being planted and, on others, a small proportion of the land lying fallow was planted with leguminous plants. This diversification proved to be an efficient means of maintaining fertility and reducing the incidence of plagues, pests and competing plants. Another aspect to be noted in Mediterranean agriculture was the trend towards specialisation in tree and bush crops more appropriate to the physical environment. Woody plants with lower water requirements adapt better to hydraulic cycles and allow better results than to be obtained with other crops. The expansion of the cultivation of vines, olives, almonds and carob beans, whether alone or in conjunction with herbaceous crops, meant that agricultural production increased, efficient advantage being taken of the particular natural resources the Mediterranean bio-region provided. There was also an expansion of the area under irrigation and, in that water was a major limiting factor, overcoming this obstacle meant significant improvements in the production of cereals and horticultural and fruit products, for which there was growing demand. The type of technology used in the expansion of irrigation was still fundamentally based on gravity, with modest infrastructure and little incidence of major hydraulic works. Nor did the technology available to extract water from the subsoil, given its limited operating capacity, lead to destabilising phenomena like those seen later. The innovations that spread through European agriculture until the end of the 19th century, those to be expected in advanced organic agriculture, brought significant improvements to production and productivity without creating serious tensions with the environment in which they occurred. The degree of artificialisation of agrarian ecosystems was relatively modest, and the ways in which the land was worked depended to a large extent on the natural systems that remained the heart of production. With these systems of agriculture retaining their organic base and the consumption of fossil fuels being low, their adverse effects on the environment as a whole were insignificant. Nor was irreparable damage done by fertilisation techniques as these continued to be based on the reuse of organic materials and the consumption of extraneous fertilisers was limited, despite the incipient use of industrial fertilisers. The practice of recycling avoided problems with residue and waste. Integrated land management, with areas devoted to agriculture, stock raising and forestry, and high levels of variety and diversity, continued to guarantee the land's productive potential. The dependency of the farming

For a review of the limits and characteristics of innovation in Mediterranean farming in the 19th century, see Bevilacqua, 1993; Garrabou, 1994; Gonzalez de Molina, 2001.

3

32

Conflict and environmental tension in the adoption of technological innovation

sector on the environment and the low intensity of the processes of substitution complicated the widespread use of methods of production that had become the norm in industry. This meant that improvements in production and productivity were lower than those in the economy as a whole.

II. The take-off of a new model of technological change following the end-of-century crisis Following the agrarian crisis at the end of the 19th century, new lines of technological change acquired growing importance. These developed separately until in mid-20th century they merged into the new technological complex that became widespread during the second half of the century, and which, unlike the technologies of the advanced organic agriculture that had existed until then, have led to major environmental problems. They are to a large extent responsible for the serious ecological crisis currently facing us. How do we explain the change of direction that occurred at this time? Why was there deviation from the lines of innovation that had made it possible to improve agricultural production without harming the physical bases that are vital to guaranteeing the continuity and reproduction of the productive system? The answers are complex, as a wide range of factors was involved. The existence of an institutional climate based on market values which brought pressure to, above all, increase productivity of labour, while at the same time lessening the importance of the functions of the natural world, is undoubtedly one of them. But there were also other causes. For example, the notions of the economy, production and the conceptualisation of the functions of Nature that inspired the new technological model. We should also consider the new principles of agronomic science that were behind the new technologies and the transformations of the secondary sector linked to the second industrial revolution. Finally, we should not forget the situation created by the globalisation of the food system and the problems created in the agrarian sector by intensification of exchange and competition. We will now look at some of these factors. The development of new technological proposals in the agrarian sector is closely related with the view a given society has of Nature and in particular of the ways in which it conceives its relationship with natural factors. At the end of the 19th century, the answer to both questions is to be found in economic science, constructed from the classical school and its followers, and which had attained great prestige and acceptance, having been recognised as a scientific discipline. What does economic theory have to say about the environment and the economy? J.M. Naredo and H. Immler, who have read the economic theory that dominated at the end of the 19th century from this perspective, raise the follow issues (Naredo, 1996a; Immler, 1993). These authors believe that in conventional economic theory the physical world has in practice been largely left out. The exclusion of Nature from the field of economics was the result of the formulation of a notion of production that became separated from the strictly physical meaning it originally had, and which came to consider labour and capital the only sources of production and wealth. Simultaneously, an economic system was created as a selfsufficient universe of exchange values, where the stabilising elements were of an exclusively financial nature. Production no longer had a material base as consideration was given exclusively to its monetary values. By reducing material wealth to the ab-

33

Land, shops and kitchens

stract notion of value and by attributing it to capital and labour, in practice the fundamental contribution to production of the physical world and of natural resources was overlooked. In this way, a conception of wealth that was completely dematerialised was eventually created, with a supposedly unlimited capacity for growth. In the conception of the economy dominant at the end of the 19th century, nature as a single whole and as a vital resource for the reproduction of social life lost its place, with consideration being given only to those fragments of it that had market value. As a result there was a lack of any concern for managing natural resources according to rules and laws their conservation called for, as they were seen merely as a warehouse of energy and materials to be exploited, as an already built machine, one that was free and which Man could use as he pleased, J.M. Naredo suggests (1996b). Finally, it was all too easy to regard natural resources as being unlimited and inexhaustible, particularly as seen from the neo-classic viewpoint on the principle of replacing factors through technological change, thus opening the way for an exaggerated faith in the possibility of substituting labour and capital for resources. As these ideas on the economy and the relationship between Nature and society took root, there were significant changes in the technologies being proposed. With the physical bases of the production systems not being properly valued, and with the lack of any concern about how they operated, the idea took hold that agricultural production could be increased through an intensification of the 'exploitation' of the environment, which could in fact be ignored, by means of substituting the natural components of systems of agriculture by others from outside the sector. Another factor involved in the shift in technological change that occurred from the early 20th century onwards was the way agronomic sciences viewed environmental issues. Scientific knowledge of the natural world improved substantially over the course of the 19th century but, as J.M. Naredo has shown (1996b), it was much influenced by narrow mercantile views. Post-Liebig, plants and animals were considered little more than mechanical converters, the food requirements of which it was interesting to ascertain in order to boost their productive capacity, with any deficiencies of the natural environment that acted as a limiting factor or brake on production being made up for. A substantial proportion of agronomic research revolved around the subject of plant and animal nutrition. With such a focus, plants came to be considered mere converters, the soil a reservoir, with no consideration being given to that fact that both were much more complex and that the interactions established between them could alter their behaviour. The direction of technological change in the agrarian sector is to some extent determined by the degree of technological development attained by a given society. Until the end of the 19th century, the technologies that had transformed industrial production had barely been seen in the countryside. However, the second wave of technological innovation, known as the second industrial revolution, offered new possibilities, and we should thus regard it as being of major importance in order to understand the new directions taken by technological change from the early years of the 20th century onwards. A few examples will suffice to illustrate this idea. The use of non-organic sources of energy, one of the main lines of innovation in the 20th century, was possible because the internal combustion engine permitted the use of fossil fuels in the form of petrol. The same could be said of the electric engines that opened the way for the use of this new source of energy in agriculture. The substitution of animal and

34

Conflict and environmental tension in the adoption of technological innovation

human labour by machines depended to a large extent on the new sources of energy that were available and on the innovations that had been seen in mechanised industry, which permitted its use in agriculture. A similar thing could be said of other lines of change such as that in systems of fertilisation. The introduction of industrial fertilisers was closely linked to the development of a new chemical industry that opened up the possibility of providing increasing amounts of fertiliser at diminishing prices. Innovations in the pharmaceutical industry were also a decisive element in changes in the stockraising sector, and similar comments could be made regarding the widespread use of pesticides and herbicides, which were unthinkable without the development of a powerful chemical industry. What I wish to show with these examples is that while technological change in agriculture advanced in particular directions, this was only possible because the level of technological development achieved in the second industrial revolution permitted its application in agriculture. To this we might also add the pressure brought by the industrial sectors that were emerging for technological change to occur in particular directions. The new conditions facing European agriculture following the end-of-century crisis was another of the factors involved in the new wave of technological changes that occurred from the beginning of the 20th century onwards. The creation of world markets for agricultural products intensified competition and led to a drop in farm income, creating deep unease in the European countryside. In such circumstances, technological innovation became a necessary instrument for recovering prosperity. The availability of new techniques that cut labour costs and/or raised income was a necessary condition for righting the situation. The growing social demand for technological change led the state to create research centres, experimental farms and schools that were decisive in the generation and diffusion of technological change.

III. Implementation of the new technological model and environmental conflicts As we have just seen, from the early 20th century onwards a series of socio-economic, cultural and scientific factors led to a new wave of technological changes that had a twin objective: to boost to the maximum possible extent the physical production of the different crops and, at the same time, to increase the productivity of labour. The two lines of innovation advanced separately until they fully converged in mid-20th century in a new technological complex structured round the green revolution and that of mechanisation which became widespread in the second half of the century. The potential of the new complex is beyond doubt. Productivity of land and labour has seen spectacular increases, well above those achieved during the previous phase. However, in breaking the equilibrium maintained by advanced organic agricultures, the new technologies have caused serious environmental problems. What has caused these conflicts and how have they manifested themselves? I should like to highlight as a major explanatory factor the ideas underlying the notions of economic systems and the relationship between society and nature that I referred to earlier. According to the principle that it was possible to replace production factors with scientific-technical knowledge, the new cycle of innovations in agriculture was much influenced by the idea that improvements in production and in productivity could be obtained by substituting natural inputs with those that

35

Land, shops and kitchens

could be brought in from outside, with natural ecosystems taking second place. It was a question of developing technologies that, in theory, would bring in production elements that were considered scarce or insufficient or that limited returns. This same principle was then extended to other production factors, with the use of means of production provided by natural ecosystems thus being reduced. In this fashion, the way was opened for substitution to become widespread, with Nature being as far as possible dispensed with. By thus reducing as far as possible the importance the natural environment, the agrarian sector would succeed in increasing production and would operate on lines similar to those of industry, which it had used as its model. The green revolution and other technologies that have become widespread have meant a qualitative leap in forms of human intervention in natural systems and have led to a marked turnaround in the degree of artificialisation of farming systems. But why did that process of artificialisation lead to environmental problems? The problems arose in the first place when the energy flows of essentially organic origin, with which agriculture had operated until then, were replaced by the use of fossil fuel. This meant growing dependence on non-renewable energy, while agriculture was responsible for a variety of serious pollution phenomena. But above all, problems came about because of the lack of awareness that farming continued to depend on natural ecosystems and that these operated according to their own laws. The natural environment, the soil and animals came to be conceived as being subsidiary to human activity, with no consideration being made of the complex biochemical processes involved. As J.M. Naredo has argued (1996b), the soil was seen as a reservoir into which it sufficed to pour the necessary inputs in order to obtain the desired results. In a similar fashion, animals came to be seen merely as food converters, the fact that they were elements in complex natural ecosystems being overlooked. Along with this growing artificialisation often came the under-use of the means of production that Nature provided free. We will now look at two examples of these processes of artificialisation that were instrumental in increasing production and, at the same time, the source of serious ecological problems.

IV. New fertilisation techniques and stock production The question of plant nutrition was one of the major themes of agronomic research. Following the discoveries by Liebig, via the technique of balancing nutrients and his law of minimum, it was established that a series of nutrients had a fundamental role in plant growth and their absence or insufficiency affected levels of return. It was thus believed that increasing the applied doses was one of the most efficient means of increasing farm production. The issue of fertilisation is a good example of the narrow mercantile view that eventually imposed itself in agronomic sciences. A variable in the agrarian system was isolated, in this case plant nutrition, some of its fundamental components were identified, inputs and outputs were quantified and thus the recipe with which to improve yields was obtained. This way of seeing things gave no consideration either to the complex biochemical processes occurring in the soil in order to provide plants with the materials necessary for growth or to the complex network of relationships established with other components of the ecosystem. In fact, the soil was seen as an inert receptacle into which it was sufficient to pour increasing doses of fertilising materials in order to obtain the desired results. Traditionally, agriculture had

36

Conflict and environmental tension in the adoption of technological innovation

used a wide range of procedures to replace these, and in the systems of advanced organic agriculture referred to earlier it had been possible to increase the flow of nutrients, in particular with the introduction of leguminous forage plants and the expansion of stock raising. From the mid-19th century onwards, use of guano, some mineral and the first industrial fertilisers had begun. However, the penetration of these new fertilisation techniques was relatively limited and was complementary in nature, with traditional techniques continuing to dominate. The high cost of such fertilisers limited their consumption. It was in the context of the development of the technological complex of the second industrial revolution that new technologies permitted mass production of industrial fertilisers at low cost. In 1910, Fritz Haber and Carl Bosch discovered how to synthesise atmospheric nitrogen and succeeded after the Second World War in synthesising nitrogen by cracking petroleum and natural gas, permitting the widespread use of synthetic fertilisers, which eventually replaced organic fertilisation techniques. The consumption of industrial fertilisers had seen a certain amount of development in such countries as Germany before the Second World War, but it was after the war that the doses took off spectacularly, reaching 200 kg/ha in some countries. The so-called green revolution, with the spread of new varieties of hybrids, was another of the elements involved in this line of technological change, as their ability to respond to increasing doses of synthetic fertilisers was one of the characteristics of new seeds. The new systems of fertilisation was one form of the new agro-technological complex 's 'denaturalisation' referred to earlier, which became widespread from the mid20th century on, as it eventually implanted a system of fertilisation in which organic consumables were replaced by others of extraneous fossil and mineral origin bought on the market, leading both to high consumption of non-renewable materials and to damage to the natural base sustaining agricultural production. Increasingly widespread use of new fertilisation techniques that were industrial in origin was one source of the environmental conflicts that have been observed in the last few decades. Growing doses of fossil fertilisers, coupled with a loss in efficiency have lead to very serious problems of pollution. Some of the nitrogen introduced, according to some authors as much as half, cannot be assimilated by plants and is lost by run-off and filtration into the subsoil and eventually contaminates subterranean as well as river and sea water, and brings serious problems for human and animal health. Another of the consequences of the application of such fertilisation techniques is that they eventually cause the mineralisation of the soil, which loses basic properties important to the maintenance of fertility due to the disappearance of organic matter. Traditional systems of fertilisation guaranteed continuous replacement that does not occur with the new technology. The scarcity or non-existence of organic material in soil degrades its structure and texture, it retains less moisture and a significant proportion of the biological life that is a necessary condition for the maintenance of fertility is lost. The progressive mineralisation of the soil, together with an intensification of farming with new machinery, has led to the fragmentation of soil particles and with this the aggravation of erosion phenomena. It has been seen that, in soils with high levels of synthetic fertilisers and a lack of humus, the activity of micro-organisms that fix atmospheric nitrogen is inhibited, with the loss of the possibility of being able to use this means of fertilisation that Nature had freely provided. The use of industrial fertilisers has led to greater water consumption with the result that agriculture has become the top water consumer, while at the same time causing a worsening of its quality. Finally, the widespread use of industrial fertilisers

37

Land, shops and kitchens

has subjected agriculture to the buying in of and, above all, to the consumption of nonrenewable materials requiring large amounts of non-renewable energy for their production and transport. One area of the food system where there have been radical changes is undoubtedly the stock-rearing sector. The new technologies that appeared, have permitted spectacular increases in the production of meat and dairy produce, albeit at the cost of intensifying pressure on natural ecosystems, with the rational limits of manipulation and artificialisation having been surpassed. This has created new sources of environmental conflicts, with vital land use having been destabilised and concerns about food safety having been caused. Stock raising, from its origins, in that it involved the domestication of animals, implied a certain degree of human intervention in the natural environment. Although under advanced organic farming, with increasing stabling of stock, the practices of selective breeding and the use of artificial fodder, the degree of artificialisation intensified and the importance of natural elements was reduced, there was still an awareness of the need to maintain the balance between the advantages of stabling and the need to maintain the natural basis that sustained the sector. However, from the early 20th century onwards, the panorama began to change and by mid-century a new model of stock raising, one increasingly far-removed from Nature, had emerged. Bevilacqua (2002) has made a careful analysis of the content and ideas in the new technologies that transformed the stock-raising sector. In a climate much dominated by productivist ideas, the pressure to increase stock production grew, and in a fashion similar to what was happening in the agrarian sector, the idea took hold that the most efficient means of achieving this was bringing farm production into line with industrial production. This implied increasingly less recourse to Nature and the substitution of natural factors. In this way, a system of stock raising was conceived in which the animals were merely machines converting feed. The key to increasing production lay in improving their efficiency at transforming the matter consumed. At this time agricultural research and experimentation focused on establishing what was considered rational or scientific stock feeding. The intention was to determine what form of and how much fodder was best in order to obtain the desired products as well as to ensure the maximum efficiency in transforming the fodder into the meat, dairy produce and eggs. Feeding ceased to be a practice the animals did naturally and became part of a controlled, co-ordinated productive process. While stock raising was increasingly being reduced to the use of herds as converters, the growth of production depended on the availability and quality of fodder for the animals to process. As a result, experiments began with new products that were proposed as being considered more likely to attain the objective of maximising production. Oleaginous seedcakes, the leftovers of distilled products such as the residue from grapes or sugar beet, became fairly commonplace in the early decades of the 20th century. Experiments were also made with dried and powdered meats from Latin America and with fish flours. Although some of these experiments did not always produce the desired results, it is interesting to note that an animal-feed industry emerged that was able to provide diets. These were elaborated according to supposedly scientific principles that had proved to be very efficient. A number of formulae were tried, and to the basic ingredients were added a series of chemical and pharmaceutical products with the objective of accelerating production on a minimum amount of feed. In this fashion, a new model of stock raising emerged that essentially depended on the animal feed industry, and increasingly less on the farm's own production. New

38

Conflict and environmental tension in the adoption of technological innovation

technologies in animal feeding meant another form of substituting nature and they were presented as a means of overcoming its imperfections and rigidities. The new stock raising broke ties with systems of agriculture and was able to operate in a fashion similar to industrial production. Simultaneously with the changes in feeding systems, a new model of stock farming emerged, one that was highly specialised and designed to organise itself in large productive units, taking advantage of the economies of scale that had proved so successful in industry. In this manner, the way was opened for new forms of artificialisation, with natural factors increasing being left out of the equation. Stabilisation had already meant a first step towards 'denaturalisation', in limiting the animals' freedom to feed and move about and the free benefits of such things as sunlight. As the size of the new stock farms increased, these trends were accentuated. In aviculture the attempt was made to replace hen runs by large installations housing thousands of animals, which gave rise to totalitarian stabling, to quote Bevilacqua. The new poultry farms were organised into batteries inside which the animals were practically immobilised, with the objective of reducing the energy losses produced by the animals moving about to a minimum. In this way, all the fodder eaten could be used for growth of the animal. However, industrial aviculture of this nature led to problems of the animals' health. They were affected by a variety of pathologies, on occasions caused by a lack of exposure to sunlight, deficiencies of diet of different sorts (such as the lack of vitamin E which caused the outbreak of chicken disease in 1937-1938) or problems of force-feeding. The response to these problems, rather than a return to 'natural' space, was to accentuate artificialisation even further. New chemical-pharmaceutical knowledge provided the necessary instruments with which to counterbalance the effects of brutal artificialisation. The medicalisation of herds, with extensive use of vitamins, antibiotics and drugs of all kinds, became a necessity that had to be regularly applied in order to maintain a system of stock raising that was increasingly far removed from the laws of nature. Industrialised stock raising also needed to develop another line of technological change, one that would allow it to have a hand in the field of biological material. Scientific advances and in particular those achieved in the field of genetics meant better knowledge of the mechanics of inheritance and allowed selected breeding methods to be perfected. The widespread use of these techniques together with those of artificial insemination and the incubator opened the way for fresh human intervention in natural processes. With intervention in animal breeding dependency on nature was reduced, its imperfections were supposedly limited and stock raising became an increasingly industrial operation. Industrialised stock raising of this nature has generated a number of issues of environmental conflict. Large stock farms coexist in the same space as arable farms but they operate in completely separate fashion. The ties that with advanced organic agriculture linked stock raising and arable farming and which had made possible balanced land use, with crop rotations and levels of great diversity, of vital importance for maintaining soil quality and defences against pests and plagues, have been broken. In addition, with the industrialisation of stock raising and the spread of new systems of fertilisation, one of the main, historical functions disappeared, namely the provision of a significant proportion of nutrients and organic matter which had to be put back into the soil in order to maintain fertility. Animal dung and manure, which under the previous system provided for free vital input in the form of fertilisers have now become instruments

39

Land, shops and kitchens

of widespread pollution, given the difficulty of properly recycling the huge amount of produced waste. The pollution of aquifers, the soil and the atmosphere has been one of the undesired effects of the new forms of management of stock raising. The new technologies that have spread to the stock-raising sector have made possible spectacular increases in the production of meat and dairy products, though the nutritional quality of the products has often been questioned. Under the principle of rational and scientific feeding of stock, experiments have been made with new diets with the aim of obtaining results, without the necessary prudence of observing the effects these might have on the human organism. In addition the growing use of pharmaceutical products of all kinds, in order to prevent certain pathologies, boost growth or obtain certain properties, has led to uncertainty as to the effects this may have on our health. Finally, the new conditions to be found in stock raising today have meant a yawning gap between this and the animals natural life conditions, and reduced them to a precarious physiological state, a veritable hell never previously known. The environmental impact of the technological complex of an industrialised farm system is not limited to those deriving from fertilisation techniques and the system of stock raising. The widespread use of mono-cultivation, with the abandonment of crop rotation and diversified land use, led to processes of impoverishment of the soil, and a major incidence of plagues and pests required systematic use of pest- and herbicides. The abuse of such chemical products has eventually caused problems of intoxication affecting farm workers, and may have harmful effects on consumers. The widespread use of genetically modified seeds has led to a loss of bio-diversity with the subsequent impoverishment of our resources of genetic material for the agriculture of the future. Growing mechanisation has made the sector one that, for its energy, is subsidised from outside and depends on the consumption of non-renewable energy, so that the food system has come to be responsible for the pollution caused by the consumption of such materials. In short, while the present-day system of farming has attained spectacular success in growth of productivity oflabour and physical returns, the negative impact on the environment has reached such a degree of severity that there is good reason to question the likelihood of continuing in this direction. There is sufficient evidence, as has been demonstrated for several decades now, to question the sustainability of this model, as respect for the requirements and laws of natural ecosystems vital for any farming system has been lost. Historical analysis of technological change in systems of agriculture cannot ignore their impact on the environment, as has been the case for too long. Fortunately, there has been a reaction in this sense. Improved know ledge of the genesis of the technological complex of industrialised agriculture and its ecological effects, bringing fresh information on the principles behind it and on other lines of technological change, could provide elements to find alternatives to the dead-end in which the food system finds itself at onset of the 21st century.

40

Conflict and environmental tension in the adoption of technological innovation

Bibliography Bevilacqua, P. (1993) Breve storia dell' Italia meridionale dall 'Ottocento a oggi, Roma. Bevilacqua, P. (2002) La mucca esavia. Ragioni storiche della crisi alimentare europea, Roma. Chorley, G.P.H. (1981) 'The agricultural revolution in Northern Europe, 1750-1880: Nitrogen, legumes, and crops productivity', in Economic History Review, 34, pp. 71-93. Garrabou, R. (1994) 'Revoluci6n y revoluciones agrarias en el siglo XIX: su difusi6n en el mundo meditemineo', in AA.VY., Agriculturas mediterraneas y mundo campesino. Cambia hist6rico y retos actuales, Almeria, pp. 93-110. Gonzalez de Molina, M. (2001) 'Condicionamientos ambientales del crecimiento agrario espafiol (siglos XIX y XX)', in J. Pujol [et al.] (eds), El poza de todos los males. Sohre el atraso en la agricultura espafiola contemporanea, Barcelona, pp. 43-94. Immler,H. (1993) Economia della natura. Produzione e consumo nell' era ecol6gica, Roma. Mazoyer, M. and Roudart L. (1997) Histoire des agricultures du monde, Paris. Naredo, J.M. (l 996a) La economia en evoluci6n. Historia y perspectivas de las categor{as basicas de! pensamiento econ6mico, Madrid. N aredo, J.M. ( l 996b) 'Sobre la reposici6n natural y artificial de agua y de nutrientes en los sistemas agrarios y las dificultades que comporta su medici6n y seguimiento', in R. Garrabou and J.M. Naredo (eds), Lafertilizaci6n en los sistemas agrarios. Una perspectiva hist6rica, Madrid, pp. 17-34.

41

3

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth 1 Josep

PUJOL-ANDREU ,

UniversitatAut6noma de Barcelona

The driving forces behind Europe's economic growth in the nineteenth century are diverse, and not easily prioritised. In economics and economic history, attention has been focused on different institutional and technological variables, and particularly on the dynamic effects of market's expansion (among others Hobsbawm, 1968; Landes, 1969; Pollard, 1981, Maddison, 1995; Mokyr, 2002). In this sense, the middle classes' capacity to foster technological change and the new possibilities of production provided by capitalist institutions have often been underlined. According to some authors, this happened within the framework of intense conflicts around the control of power structures, productive process and/or rent and wealth distribution. But according to others, this happened in contexts in which consensus would have prevailed, given the longterm improvements in standards of living. Nevertheless, it has also been underlined that the evolution of economic activity could not be understood considering only the new production possibilities offered by market economies. As a result, today it is accepted that those processes cannot be explained without considering two additional circumstances: the energy flows that sustained them, and the changes undergone in their transformation (Debeir, Deleage and Hemery, 1986; Wrigley, 1990; Naredo and Valero, 1999; Diamond, 1997; Sieferle, 2001). In this context, a question arises of special importance. Which was the influence of the biological change in the economic growth? A part of the flows of energy must be made into food, and this transformation can only happen with the participation of plants and animals. As Soddy emphasised in 1921, 'The plant world continues to be the only one that can transform the original flow of inanimate energy into vital energy' (Martinez Alier, 1995). In recent years there has been research in this direction, and we should consider the long tradition of biological innovations in the agricultural sector; their important implications; and the final configuration of an important business sector around these processes (Heiser, 1990; Friedland et al., 1991; Goodman, Sorj and Wilkinson, 1987; Goodman and Redclift, 1991; Busch, 1997; Busch, Lacy, Burkhardt and Lacy, 1991; Perkins, 1997). It is also shown that the orientation of this type of innovations and their institutional organisation have become more complex with market expansion, and that their contribution has played a decisive role in the configuration of contemporary economic growth. From this research, in synthesis, an issue can be raised as a working hypothesis. In the study of economic growth, we should consider three processes: 1) the changes undergone in the organisation of society, 2) the flows of energy and materials used and the technical bases of their transformation, and 3) the biological conditions under which the production of food is carried out. This article is part of a research project financed by the DGICYT 'Food, mortality and Standard of living in Spain (19th and 20th centuries)', SEJ2004-00799. The author wishes to acknowledge the helpful comments of J. Martinez-Alier, R. Nicolau, C. Sarastia, P. Scholliers and the other researchers that participated in the meeting of Tensions of Europe in Barcelona (March, 2003). 1

42

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

In this context, some clarification is required with respect to our knowledge about the third issue. On the one hand, we know well the processes undergone after World War II, and this circumstance has propitiated unrealistic perceptions about the true possibilities of agrarian change at different times. On the other hand, the handling of the previous issues has advanced notably since the 1980s, but the studies performed have focused especially on the agriculture of the United States. With respect to this country we have excellent analyses of the importance of biological changes in agrarian growth since the 19th century, about its institutional characteristics, and about its relationships with other aspects of technical change (Kloppenburg, 1988; Dalrymple, 1988; Busch and Lacy, 1983; Danbom, 1986; Huffman and Evenson, 1993; Olmstead and Rhode, 2003). For Europe, these contributions have been less numerous. Various circumstances have been involved in this imbalance, such as the different significance of the biological problems in both areas; the traditional interest of US governments in transforming the biological bases of its agriculture; and the hegemony acquired on an international scale by that country's food and biotechnological industries. In any case, for European agriculture, one must remember the studies that have been performed about the wheat sector and different species of livestock, or, about the relations between biological innovations and agrarian change (Martin, 2000). We also must remember two other issues. In the first place, the non-existence of a general framework in economic history for interpreting biological and economic changes over time. Secondly, the need to dispose of more sectoral studies on a national and regional scale, especially with respect to the impact of those innovations on the levels of productivity. In this chapter I will develop these directions by analysing the biological changes in both the Atlantic and Mediterranean Europe till the 1930s. The first section places those changes in the general framework of the environmental conditions of production. The second section will indicate some of their main characteristics in the wheat and livestock sectors. The third section puts forward some explanations for their differing evolution in different places. The final section relates these changes to other innovations, and underlines their importance in order to understand them better. Just one word of caution. In this chapter, the institutional variables will be considered only indirectly. Not because they are not considered important but rather because I prefer to focus on certain aspects that are still relatively unexplored in economic history. When biological variables and environmental conditions are considered, some characteristics of the processes of change undergone by European agriculture up until the middle of the 20th century may be better understood.

I.

Agrarian systems and environmental conditions

I understand biological innovation to be all the activities performed consciously for increasing the production capacity of the agrarian sector, whether this be by introducing new varieties of plants or animals, or by altering their constitution through different techniques (selection, crossing, etc.). Therefore, from this perspective biological innovations have been one of the main lines of the participation of human societies in the environmental conditions of production, and, more specifically, one of those most used for increasing agrarian production.

43

Land, shops and kitchens

In this sense it is important to underline the development of these innovations from the second half of the eighteenth century, as a result of three circumstances. Firstly, the knowledge accumulated on the physiology of plants and animals, the progressive improvements undergone in selection and crossing techniques and the rediscovery of Mendel's Laws in 1900 (Stubbe, 1972; Corcos,Monaghan and Mendel, 1990). Secondly, the ever-closer contacts fostered by the expansion of trade between areas with different natural resources. Thirdly, especially beginning in the second half of the 19th century, the growing availability of new means of production, both chemical and mechanical, linked to the availability of new biological varieties (Walton, 1999; Grantham, 1984). Another issue to emphasise is more related to the different orientations and possibilities that these innovations could have. As the biological conditions of production depend on the climatic, hydraulic and edaphic characteristics of each area, these innovations were also conditioned by the degree to which these innovations were complementary to the overall environmental circumstances under which the agrarian systems operated. The importance of these circumstances with respect to the two large areas that we will be dealing with, is well known. While in the agriculture of Central and Northern Europe there were high levels of rainfall, deep soils, and mild climatic conditions in the Spring and Summer, in Mediterranean Europe these conditions could be very different. The rainfall was lower, especially when it was needed the most, temperatures tended to be high from the end of the spring on, and agricultural soil was poorer in organic material. These differences are not very dissimilar nowadays, although technical changes have mitigated them (Papadakis, 1966). As a result, when demographic pressure, institutional changes, and the intensification of exchanges accentuated the expansion of cultivated areas and the processes of specialisation, these processes tended to take different forms from one part of the continent to the other. The first area tended towards very intensive growing systems and increasing integration between agricultural and livestock activities (Tracy, 1982; Grigg, 1992; Van Bavel and Thoen, 1999). In the second area, the expansion of crops was combined with the maintenance of very extensive systems in the grain-growing regions, and growing specialisation in vineyards, olive groves, and fruit trees. Where climatic conditions allowed, and the irrigated surface area could be increased, other orientations must also be underlined. The expansion of vegetable crops, rice, and fresh fruit trees took place where there was more intensive irrigation, and new grain rotations were used in the more irregularly irrigated areas. Broadly speaking, the most important thing in Mediterranean systems was the articulation of an agrarian sector, characterised by few resources of fodder, livestock, and fertilisers; the presence of fallow land in grain areas; and a high presence of vineyards, olives and tree crops in most parts of the territory. On the other hand, livestock farming continued with grazing, and the development of livestock producing milk and meat took place later and was more limited (Simpson, 1997; Bevilacqua, 1992; Garrabou and Sanz Fernandez, 1985). But the influence of environmental conditions on both areas is not only reflected in the different productive orientations that accompanied agrarian growth. Their impact also stands out when we consider the different evolution undergone in two important sectors (wheat production and livestock). The evolution of these sectors has often been used to evaluate the ability of European agriculture to adapt to the expansion of markets, and consequently, its study has played an important role in agrarian history research. Wheat, meat, and milk were also three basic foods for the population, although

44

Environment conditions .and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

their importance in this sense tended to vary over the course of time (Teuteberg, 1992; Collins, 1993; Kiple and Ornelas, 2000).

II. Biological innovations during the nineteenth century and the first third of the twentieth century The first issue observed when we consider biological innovations in the wheat sector is its different evolution according to place. Various research projects have emphasised growing importance of such innovations in the British wheat sector since the 1770s, and the quick spread to other countries of Western Atlantic Europe, especially from the second half of the 19th century on (Walton, 1999; Lupton, 1987; Zeven, 1990; Doussinault, 1995). In Mediterranean Europe, however, these kinds of innovations were not begun until the 1880s, their development was slower, and had fewer repercussions. As a result, while wheat seeds were transformed relatively quickly in Atlantic Europe, this process was later and more limited in Mediterranean Europe, particularly where the dry land conditions were more extreme (Pujol, 1998a). At the beginning, these innovations were based on the introduction of new varieties from Eastern Europe, and on the intensification of traditional methods of mass selection. Later in the 19th century, three types of initiatives took on growing importance: the spreading of English and Scottish seeds to the continent, the intensification of biological exchanges inside this area, and the progressive substitution of mass selection with individual, along with the growing use of different types of crossing. 2 Consequently, although the new techniques of improvement were still not very precise and on many occasions were not able to stabilise the desired characteristics in the new seeds, the quick spreading of new types of wheat was also observable in many areas of Atlantic Europe by the middle of the 19th century. Two circumstances favoured this process: the autogamous nature of that grain (which limited spontaneous mutations and hybridisation), and the fact that farmers could continue to obtain the seeds for planting from their own productions, once a new variety was accepted. The fact that the innovations could not be appropriated also meant that improvement activities tended to be very decentralised. Only in special cases were they performed in a new type of company of some size. Even in these cases, it was common that their activities were very diversified, and companies also included the production of other seeds for vegetable or fodder crops among their activities. Two companies of these characteristics were Vilmorin, and Denaiffe, Colle and Sidorot. This situation changed partially between the 1880s and the 1930s. On the one hand, the intensification of competition and exchanges stimulated the demand for seeds that were more productive and resistant to diseases. On the other hand, improvement techniques became more complex and expensive, and their development tended to be concentrated in a new type of institutions, totally or partially financed by the State. 3 In Tables 3.1 and 3.2 of the appendix some of them are listed.

2

Different examples in Lupton, 1987: 53-69; Percival, 1934; Zeven, 1990: 15-99. Sala Roca, 1948; Walton, 1999: 36-37; Grantham, 1984: 195-202; Lupton, 1987: 53-69; Kamps, 1989; Maat, 2001.

3

45

Land, shops and kitchens

In this context, nevertheless, various issues should be emphasised. While British economic policies tended to limit these innovations until the 1920s, protectionism and/ or direct promotion by the state were a driving force behind them in other countries of the continent (Palladino, 1996). The economic and social structures of each area and their different foreign relations probably influenced these options (Offer, 1989, chpt. 5; Tracy, 1989; Koning, 1994). In any case, while these innovations tended to be delayed in British agriculture, in France, Holland, Belgium or Germany they accelerated; and the spread of new wheat and the biological exchange between these countries increased (Simon, 1999; Bonjean and Angus, 2001; Maat, 2001). Additionally, the sources consulted also show that the processes of innovation tended to spread towards the Mediterranean area. Nonetheless, the effects of such processes in this area did not begin to be evident until well into the 20th century: in Italy, particularly in the northern part, towards the end of the 1920s, in Spain, about 20 or 25 years later (Pujol, 2002a). In Figure 3.1 and Tables 3.3 and 3.4 some characteristics of these processes and some of the new types of wheat that tended to be spread, are indicated. With respect to cattle, horses, mules, and pigs, the information and studies show three issues. Firstly, the biological exchanges and different activities of selection and crossing existed already from the end of the eighteenth century. Secondly, these innovations were important results in Western Europe in the middle of the nineteenth century. Finally, the spreading of these activities in Mediterranean Europe had greater repercussions than with respect to wheat, but their impact was again very limited and concentrated in few regions. Let us see some examples. Innovations in cattle are probably best known. Different studies have shown that the owners of Swiss and Dutch livestock had already achieved at the end of the 1800s the consolidation of different milk-giving breeds that were improved (for example, the Friesian and the Holstein in the case of the Dutch, and the Brown Swiss and the Simmental in the case of the Swiss). Soon, with the purpose of reinforcing the uniformity of the new varieties, and focusing their improvement more precisely, they established the Dutch herdbook in 1873 and the Friesian herdbook in 1879. Somewhat later, the Red and White Spotted Simmental Cattle Association were settled in 1890, and the herdbook for the Brown Swiss in 1911. Other varieties that improved for the production of meat were the Charolais and the Limousin from France, and the Hereford from the United Kingdom, for which their respective herdbooks were also established (for example, the Hereford herdbook, published in 1846, two herdbooks for Charolais livestock, in 1864 and 1882, and another one for Limousin in 1886) (Briggs and Briggs, 1980; Felius, 1985; Porter, 1991; Bieleman, 2002). In reference to pigs, two important events are to be mentioned: the successive improvements undergone in different English varieties since the 1770s, and the foundation in 1884 of the National Pig Breeder's Association. As a result of these activities, new herdbooks for the Large White or Yorkshire (1884), the Large Black (1898), and the Berkshire (1884) were established, and the new pigs spread quickly to the continent to give rise to other ones (Hall and Clutton-Brock, 1989; Briggs, 1983). Regarding horses and mules, the changes are more difficult to discern. Despite this problem, the information available also shows that their constitution tended to improve, gaining in height and strength, and that the Percheron, Ardennes, Belgian and Suffolk varieties got notable prestige. Also, in all these cases biological exchanges were very intense, both to directly exploit the new varieties and to generate other ones with successive selections and crossing (Hendricks, 1995; Mason, 1996).

46

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

In clear contrast with these processes, those observed in the Mediterranean areas again show important differences. In fact, leaving out the more northern areas with a greater livestock tradition, the information available again underlines the long survival of traditional varieties. The evaluations and comments of different Spanish agronomists and engineers of the end of the nineteenth century are very illustrative. In the 1880s and the 1890s, these technicians still underline two circumstances: the scarce integration of agricultural activities with livestock farming, and the existence of varieties that were not very productive. With respect to pigs, the hegemony of the varieties with dark skin and long snouts, with scarce aptitude for fattening, and slow growth was remarkable. Cattle were apt for working, but with low productivity for the production of meat and milk. In reference to horse and mule species, these engineers pointed out their short stature and light weight and their limited capacity in the operations of cultivation and transport (Junta Consultiva Agron6mica, 1892; Junta Consultiva Agron6mica, 1920). This situation changed partially during the first third of the 20th century with the introduction of improved European varieties. In Catalonia in the 1930s for example, a new livestock population replaced the traditional one almost completely, and new varieties of mixed breeds from different places tended to predominate in their composition. Particularly, the characteristics of Yorkshire and Craon pigs, the Swiss and Dutch breeds in cattle, and Percheron, Norfolk and Norfolk-breton in horses and mules spread. These processes are also observed in other agricultural areas of the northern half and the Mediterranean coast, but not so much in the central and southern parts of the territory (Dominguez, 1996; Pujol, 2002b; Castell, 2002).

III. Biological innovations: economic, institutional and environmental conditions What circumstances would allow the explanation of these differences? The processes that we have just synthesised cannot be explained without considering economic and institutional changes that occurred on a European scale between the second half of the 18th century and the 1930s. Nonetheless, the geographical differences that we saw in the previous paragraphs cannot be explained solely in terms of that type of variables. The wheat sector, for example, was not only important as a producer of grain but also of straw, and the varieties of wheat had to be long-stalked for this reason. Straw was necessary for the keeping and caring of livestock, especially where fodder was lacking, and also for the preparation of manure prior to its use as fertiliser. Consequently, although greater fertilisation could increase yield in grain and allow more intensive rotations, also facilitated the appearance of lodging. When this happened, it made harvesting operations more expensive, and it could even make mechanical harvesting impossible. With lodging, a part of the production was also lost, and the attack of various diseases was facilitated. In synthesis, to increase grain production and simultaneously mechanise harvesting, it was necessary to have more productive new varieties, resistant to lodging, so that these characteristics became two of the main objectives of biological innovations .4

4

McNeill 2000, 219-225, Walton 1999, 34-39.

47

Land, shops and kitchens

In Nordic countries, increasing the resistance of plants to low temperatures also occupied an important place. In contrast, in Mediterranean countries obtaining of earlier-ripening varieties was necessary (Sala Roca, 1948). The initial interest of European breeders for British wheat is thus not difficult to understand. With the expansion of mixed farming from the middle of the 18th century, British wheat had evolved towards varieties with low gluten content, but which were very productive of grain and straw, and resistant to lodging. This trend accelerated later with the liberalisation of imports and the change to high farming. But, while the institutional framework discouraged new researches in the British case, in Western Europe it encouraged them, and the wheat varieties of Great Britain were used in a wide range of crossings and selections. Three objectives were pursued: to maintain or improve the protein richness of the wheat varieties planted, to increase their yield per seed or surface area unit, and to make their stalks sturdier. In Table 3 .4 of the appendix some of the main hybridisation performed are indicated. Nevertheless, at the end of the nineteenth century the French breeders still indicated the great difficulties when trying to improve wheat seeds in the southern and eastern parts of France, because of climatic conditions. For Spain, the information is even more explicit. Despite various experimental centres created in the 1890s, and the numerous tests performed with the new wheat seeds spread throughout Europe, the results obtained were very poor. The new wheat varieties degenerated quickly if they came from Atlantic Europe, or they did not surpass the results of indigenous ones if they came from other grain-growing areas with similar environmental conditions. Only at times some success was attained, e.g. at the end of the 19th century, with the Italian Rieti and Richella Blanca wheat from Naples, and, already in the 1920s, with some of the new seeds obtained in Italy by N. Strampelli. In reference to these last varieties, we also have to remember two issues. First, those varieties were obtained from a new type of crossing, in which the Japanese variety Akagomushi was used. Second, their dissemination was concentrated in the central and northern parts of the country. In Spain, on the other hand, the improvement of indigenous wheat began in the 1920s, often using new Italian wheat varieties, but their results did not become relevant until after twenty years. It was not until the 1950s that new varieties such as the Aragon 03 spread further, and only again, in the grain-growing provinces of the northern half of the country (Vilmorin and Meunisier, 1918; Nagore, 1935; Pujol, 2002a). In Table 3 .5 are listed the main experimental centres that carried out these activities. In synthesis, two results arise from these experiences: the use of Atlantic wheat was not viable in Mediterranean Europe, because of different environmental conditions in the two areas, and the improvement of the seeds themselves was more difficult to achieve in the Mediterranean areas than in the Atlantic ones. The problems faced by biological improvements in the livestock sector were different. In this sector, the processes of selection and crossing were easier to perform and to evaluate, and hence their early results in Atlantic Europe during the 19th century. This does not mean that environmental conditions lacked importance. High temperatures throughout a large part of the year, and scarce water also limited the processes of improvement in cattle and pigs in many areas. Also, while the resources of meadows and pastures in Central and Northern Europe were great, in many areas of Mediterranean Europe it was the opposite. This circumstance was aggravated in a large part of the territory by the scarce orientation towards livestock production in the agrarian sector.

48

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

This is once again particularly clear in the case of Spain (Santiago Enriquez, 1922; Garcia Bengoa, 1923; Aran, 1933). As we have indicated, both high levels of specialisation in vineyard, olive and other tree crops, and the impossibility of using the crop rotations that were used in the damper parts of Europe, limited the development of livestock in this country. This situation was also fomented by the need to resort to grazing and the scarce resources obtained with this type of farming. With the change of century, various circumstances made the greater development of that sector possible. The changes in agrarian markets, and the expansion of urbanisation were undoubtedly two of them, as they stimulated the expansion of meat and milk consumption in large cities.5 But the development of new sectors can not be entirely understood without considering two other variables. First, the new production possibilities provided by mineral and chemical fertilisers from the end of the 19th century. Second, the great expansion of irrigated areas undergone at the same time. As a consequence of these innovations, grain rotations were made more intensive, and the offer of fodder resources was more abundant. In a more thorough analysis, nevertheless, it also stands out that the impact of those processes tended to be concentrated in the Mediterranean coast and in other regions of the northeastern third of the territory, but much less in the central and southern parts of the country (Gonzalez de Molina, 2001; Fernandez Prieto, 2001).

IV. Biological innovations and agrarian growth The biological changes that I just have synthesised are not the only ones that could be considered. Others affected Mediterranean agriculture very directly, and their impact, in some cases, was also outstanding. The spreading of new seeds is well documented in the rice sector since the end of the 19th century, often in order to tackle lodging and to make more intensive fertilising possible (Calatayud, 2002). Parallel to this, destruction of vineyards by phylloxera led to the transformation of biological bases in this sector, and the spreading of American vines on which the European varieties of Vitis Vinifera were grafted (Pan-Montojo, 1994; Garrier, 1989). With regard to other fruit trees, we also have varied information about the spreading of new varieties of plants with three objectives: to improve the quality of final productions and increase yields; to develop new productions; and to better control harvesting operations (Abad, 1984). Based on these considerations, there are certain questions that should perhaps be raised more clearly in future research. For example, what specific importance did biological innovations have in the different growth processes that took place during the 19th century and the first third of the 20th? Or, what was their role in the expansion of agrarian yields and levels of productivity? These questions are not easily answered. Firstly, because we cannot quantify the biological changes that we have described, and we must limit ourselves to very indirect estimates of their impact and dissemination. And secondly, because biological innovations tended to advance in many cases complementary to other innovations, and it is not easy to isolate their specific effects. Probably we could advance in solving these problems by analysing more carefully the experiments undertaken in the different research centres that were created during those years. Now,

5

Simpson, 1997, 249-261; Langreo, 1995.

49

Land, shops and kitchens

I would only like to stress that the impact of biological innovations may be greater than we usually consider them to be. Recent research has estimated that approximately 50 percent of the increase in US wheat grain productivity between 1839 and 1909 was caused by the spreading of new seeds of that grain (Olmstead and Rhode, 2003). We still do not have studies of these characteristics for European agriculture. On the one hand, we do not have statistical information on the evolution of planted areas, such as those existing for the USA. On the other hand, biological innovations advanced along with the use of more intensive fertilisations and the expansion of irrigated surface area, so it is more difficult to isolate its effects on the levels of productivity. Nevertheless, in recent studies it has also been suggested that environmental conditions might exercise a greater influence over the dissemination of new means of production, and that among these conditions we should consider the initial biological bases, and the possibility of altering them. Various research projects allow us to know a fair amount about the dissemination processes undergone by mineral and chemical fertilisers and harvesters. Three issues stand out: the initial spreading of these means of production in British agriculture, especially in the case of harvesters; the intense spreading of the use of these inputs in Continental Atlantic Europe from about the 1880s; and its later and more limited spreading in Mediterranean Europe. In Table 3 .6 some of these aspects with regard to the spreading of new fertilisers are shown. In reference to the spreading of harvesters, let us remember the following issues. At the end of the 19th century, 80 percent of the British wheat areas were harvested with machines. In France, on the other hand, this percentage dropped to just under 15, and in Germany to little more than 5 percent.6 In the rest of the continent these percentages were even lower, and in the cases of Spain and Italy, they were practically negligible. Soon after, the use of harvesters intensified in Belgium, France and Germany, but in the case of Spain and Italy, they did not begin to be significant until the 1920s (Van Zanden, 1991; Gallego, 1986). Besides, the implementation of harvesters ended up being high in the grain-growing areas of northern Spain, but very little in the central and southern parts, and along the Mediterranean coast. Additionally, the spreading of the new fertilisers ended up being quite remarkable in this last area, and other inner regions in the north. On the contrary, they lacked relevance in the central and southern parts of the country. In fact, the use of those materials in a wide part of this area did not even reach 5 kg/ha in the 1930s, when it was often greater than 30 kg/ha in the coast and in the Ebro basin (see Table 3.7) (Simpson, 1987; Pujol, 1998c; Fernandez Prieto, 2001). How do we explain these processes and differences? The sustained expansion of exchanges and the intensification of the processes of industrialisation tended to favour the spreading of new means of production in two ways. One, by improving the conditions of its offering in terms of price, facility of access, and greater adaptation to local needs. The other, by reinforcing successive salary increases, due to the changes caused in the labour markets by these processes. The sustained reduction in the relative prices of new fertilisers, and the improvements that were introduced into the design of harvesters illustrate the first issue very well (Pezzati, 1994). The tendency of agrarian salaries to rise from the last decades of the 19th century, and especially after World War I, is also 6

Grigg, 1992: 52-55.

50

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

well documented (Scholliers, 1989; Martfnez Carrion, 2002). These processes are also well known for the Spanish case, and they are illustrated in Figure 3 .2. As a consequence of these changes, the threshold of use of these means of production tended to widen over time, and this circumstance reinforced its spreading in a sustained way. But the previous information also shows significant differences in the rhythms and intensity with which the new techniques of production spread, which can not always be explained by the evolution of their offer or by wage pressures. Evidently, another variable that we must consider is the institutional framework, due to their great influence on the farmers' demand for new production techniques. Numerous studies have analysed these issues and have dealt with the influence of three groups of variables on those processes: 1) the structure of land owning and its changes over time, 2) the size of the farm and the social systems of production, and 3) the agrarian and tax policies. Thanks to this research, today we can better explain, for example, the early spreading of new production techniques in the British agricultural sector during the 19th century, or its intense spreading in France, Belgium, Holland or Germany between the 1880s and the 1930s. Interesting explanations have also been provided for the decline of British agriculture since the 1880s, and for the different orientation of biological innovations in the wheat sector in Atlantic Western Europe (Koning, 1994; Van Zanden, 1994; Offer, 1989, Chpt. 5; Walton, 1999). But even if we also consider institutional variables, the processes observed in Mediterranean agriculture are not easy to explain, especially considering the intense regional differences between the middle of the 19th century and the 1930s. For this reason, the need to include environmental factors in the analysis has been mentioned on various occasions, and these proposals have often favoured controversial findings. In the case of Spanish historiography they are still being hotly debated. 7 Recent research on this country sustains what follows. The environmental conditions defined distinct constellations of available techniques in Mediterranean and Atlantic agriculture, and the demand for new means of production also was for this reason, very different. This consideration does not minimise the importance of other variables. The institutional framework undoubtedly delayed the beginning of agrarian changes and contributed to slowing them down, as it realised late and slowly the transformations that the sector needed (irrigation, experimental stations). At the same time, the late development of a new industrial sector, producing fertilisers and mechanical means of production, was another factor that we should not forget. From our perspective, nonetheless, these circumstances cannot satisfactorily explain two issues: the low use of the new agrarian inputs during the 1930s, and their unequal spreading in different places. Moreover, when those agrarian innovations are analysed more carefully, different relations are perceived that should be investigated more precisely. In Table 3 .7 the clearest cases are indicated. Firstly, the close relationship existing between the spreading of new fertilisers and the availability of water. These relationships are shown, for example, in two situations observed in the 1930s: the high consumption of fertilisers in the irrigated areas of the territory and in various northern provinces; and the negligible consumption of these

7

The debate in Historia Agraria, 28, 2002: 179-230. See also, O'Brien and Toniolo, 1991 and Pujol et al. (eds), 2001.

51

Land, shops and kitchens

same products in wide areas of the centre and southern parts of the country, where precipitation was very little and irrigation was not significant. Secondly, although the surface areas to harvest could be very large, mechanised harvesting tended to be not very significant where the surface areas of vineyards and olive groves were also great, or where the three types of surface areas were relatively near each other. There are certainly exceptions, but the relationship between the spreading of harvesters and cultivation structures is difficult to question and must not be ignored. One of the reasons that has been suggested to explain this relationship is the discontinuity that could be generated by grape and olive-growing specialisation in grain-growing lands. Other reasons are the different problems that the work processes of those crops could generate in the different grain-growing areas. Let us recall that the harvesting of grains had to be performed during a short period of time, between June and July, also coinciding with the reaping of the alfalfa fields and the like, and that the gathering of grapes and olives was done later and successively (grape gathering in September, and olives from November till February or March). These operations also required a great deal of work and could not be mechanised. Therefore, it is not risky to suggest that the pressures to mechanise the harvesting of grains had to be very different according to the structures of crops, and lower in the Mediterranean coast, and in the central and southern parts of the country. Finally, both with respect to new fertilisers and harvesters, in this analytical framework there is another issue: its lesser spread in many areas was also conditioned by the existing varieties of seeds and the difficulty to improve them (Gonzalez de Molina, 2001; Fernandez Prieto, 2001).

V.

Conclusions

In synthesis, the transformation of European agriculture during the 19th century and the first third of the 20th should be explained as a result of two large groups of variables. On the one hand, the successive pressures generated by economic and institutional changes undergone during that period, promoted the development of new types of activities, new means of production, and higher levels of productivity. On the other hand, the environmental and biological environments of the different areas, conditioned the productive orientations that could be developed and the available techniques. In this chapter I have tried to show that the biological characteristics of plants and animals occupied a strategic place in the development of the processes of production, hence the interest in transforming them. In some cases, to mitigate the impact of certain diseases or accidents; in others, to improve the quality of the final production, but broadly to increase the levels of productivity and improve agrarian incomes. Analysing the case of wheat and different livestock species, nevertheless, we have also seen another issue. Biological and environmental conditions influenced the spreading of other innovations, such as those related to the fertilisation of the soil and the harvesting of grains, and consequently the different patterns of technical change. Therefore, these circumstances should also be taken into consideration to explain the different courses followed by those sectors in the different areas of the continent. Finally, based on the previous considerations, two working hypotheses could be maintained. First, that the possibilities of agrarian growth until World War II were always fewer in Mediterranean agriculture than in the Atlantic one, although the new offers of

52

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

means of production and the expansion of irrigation tended to increase them. Second, that these differences did not begin to decrease significantly until the 1960s, and then as a consequence of two groups of innovations: those related to the use of fossil fuel in cultivation, harvesting and threshing, and those related to the use of new seeds and chemical products for the fertilisation of the land and the treatment of plants. That is, when a whole group of new technical possibilities allowed the mitigation of the impact of environmental variables and increased the dependence of agriculture with respect to the industrial sector.

Bibliography Abad, V. (1984) Historia de la naranja, 1871-1939, Valencia. Aran, S. (1933) Explotaci6n e industrializaci6n del cerdo, Madrid. Bavel, B.J.P. van and Thoen, E. (eds) (1999) Land productivity and agro-systems in the North Sea area. Middle Ages-20th century, Tumhout (CORN Publication Series; 2). Bevilacqua, P. (1992) Storia dell'agricoltura italiana in eta contemporanea. Spazi e Paesaggi, Venezia. Bieleman, J. (2002) 'Dutch cattle breeding and dairy farming in transition, 1850-2000', unpublished paper presented at the X Congreso de Historia Agraria, Sitges. Bonjean,A. and Angus, WJ. (eds) (2001) The world wheat book: A history ofwheat breeding, Andover-Secaucus. Briggs, H.M. (1983) International pig breed encyclopedia, Greenfield (IN). Briggs, H.M. and Briggs, D.N. (1980) Modern breeds of livestock, New York. Busch, L. (1997) 'Biotechnology and agricultural productivity: changing the rules of the game?', in A. Bhaduri and R. Skarstein (eds), Economic development and agricultural productivity, Chaltenham, pp. 241-254. Busch,L. and Lacy, W. (1983) Science, agriculture and the politics of research,Colorado. Busch, L., Lacy, W., Burkhardt, J. and Lacy, L. (1991) Plants, power and profit, Oxford. Cartana, J. (2000) 'Las estaciones agron6micas y las granjas experimentales como factor de innovaci6n en la agricultura espanola contemporanea (1875-2000)', Scripta Nova. Revista Electr6nica de Geografia y Ciencias Sociales, 69, 16, pp. 1-14. Castell, P. (2002) 'La ganaderfa porcina en Espana antes de la Guerra Civil. Una aproximaci6n a la evoluci6n del sector', unpublished paper presented at the X Congreso de Historia Agraria, Sitges. Calatayud, S. (2002) 'Tierras inundadas. El cultivo del arroz en la Espana contemporanea (1800-1936)', Revista de Historia Econ6mica, 30, pp. 39-80. Cipolla, C.M. (1972/76) The Fontana economic history of Europe, London, vols 5-6. Collins, E.J.T. (1993) 'Why wheat? Choice of food grains in Europe in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries', Journal of European Economic History, 22, 1, pp. 7-38. Coreas, A .F., Monaghan, F.V. and Mendel, G. (1990) 'Mendel's work and its rediscovery: A new perspective', Critical Reviews in Plant Science, 9, 3, pp. 197-212.

53

Land, shops and kitchens

Dalrymple,D. (1988) 'Changes in wheat varieties and yields in the United States, 19191984', Agricultural History, 62, 4, pp. 20-35. Danbom, D. (1986) 'The agricultural experiment station and professionalization: Scientists' goals for agriculture', Agricultural History, 60, 2, pp. 246-255. Debeir, J.C., Deleage, J.-P. and Hemery, D. (1986) Les servitudes de la puissance. Une his to ire de l 'energie, Paris. Denaiffe & Colle and Sidorot, (c.1920) Les btes cultives, Paris. Diamond, J. (1997) Guns, germs and steel: the fates of human societies, New York-London. Dominguez, R. (1996) La vocaci6n ganadera del norte de Espana: del mode lo tradicional a las desaffos del mercado mundial, Madrid. Doussinault, G. (1995) 'Cent ans de selection du ble en France eten Belgique', in J. Dubois (ed.) (Reseau Biotechnologies Vegetales. Joumees scientifiques 4es, Namur, 1993), Que! avenir pour !'amelioration des plantes? Paris, vol. I, pp. 3-8. Felius, M. (1985) Genus bas: Cattle breeds of the world, Rahway. Fernandez Prieto, L. (2001) 'Caminos del cambio tecnol6gico en las agriculturas espafiolas contemporaneas', in J. Pujol [et al.] (eds), El poza de todos las males. Sob re el atraso de la agricultura espanola contempordnea, Barcelona, pp. 95-146. Friedland, W.H. [et al.] (1991) Towards a new political economy of agriculture, Oxford. Gallego, D. (1986) 'Transformaciones tecnicas de la agricultura espafiola en el primer tercio del siglo XX' ,in R. Garrabou and C. Barciela y J.I. Jimenez Blanco (eds),Historia agraria de la Espana contempordnea. 3. El fin de la agricultura tradicional (19001960). Barcelona, pp. 171-229. Garcia Bengoa, J. (1923) Producci6n de carne de cebo, Madrid. Garrabou, R., Pujol, J. and Colome, J. (1991) 'Salaris, us i explotaci6 de la for;;a de treball agrfcola (Catalunya, 1818-1936)', Recerques, 24, pp. 23-51. Garrabou, R. and Sanz Fernandez, J. (eds) (1985) Historia agraria de la Espana contempordnea. 2. Expansion y crisis (1850-1900), Barcelona. Garrier, G. (1989) Le Phylloxera. Une guerre de trente ans, 1870-1900, Paris. Gonzalez de Molina, M. (2001) 'Condicionamientos ambientales del crecimiento agrario espafiol', in J. Pujol [et al.] (eds), El poza de todos las males. Sabre el atraso de la agricultura espanola contempordnea, Barcelona, pp. 43-94. Goodman, D. and Redclift, M. (1991) Refashioning nature,food, ecology & culture, London-New York. Goodman, D., Sorj, B. and Wilkinson, J. ( 1987) From farming to biotechnology. A theory of agro-industrial development, Oxford. Grantham, G. (1984) 'The shifting locus of agricultural innovation in nineteenth-century Europe', Research in Economic History, 3, pp. 191-214. Grigg, D. (1992) The transformation of agriculture in the West, Oxford. Hall, S.J.G. and Clurron-Brick, J. (1989) Two hundred years of British farm livestock, London. Heiser, Ch. (1990) Seed to civilization. The story offood, Cambridge (Mss).

54

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

Hendricks, B.L. (1995) International encyclopedia of horse breeds, Norman. Hobsbawm, E.J. (1968) Industry and empire. An economic history ofBritain since I 750, London. Huffman, W.E. and Evenson, R.E. (1993) Science for agriculture. A long term perspective, Iowa. Institut International d' Agriculture (1933) Les institutions d' experimentation agricole dans les pays temperes, Rome. Junta Consultiva Agron6mica (1892), La ganaderia en Espana, Madrid. Junta Consultiva Agron6mica (1920), Estudio de la ganaderia en Espana, Madrid. Kamps, M. (1989) 'Plant Breeding and Seed Production of Agricultural Crops in the Netherlands', Prophyta, 6, 8, pp. 4-19. Kiple, K.F. and Ornelas, K .C. (2000) The Cambridge world history offood, Cambridge. Kloppenburg, J.R. (1988) First the seed. The political economy ofplant biotechnology, 1492-2000, Cambridge. Koning, N. (1994) The failure of agrarian capitalism, London-New York. Landes, D.S. (1969) The unbound Prometheus. Technological change and industrial development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present, Cambridge. Langreo,A. (1995) Historia de la industria ldctea espanola: una aplicaci6n a Asturias, Madrid. Lupton, F.G.H. (1987) Wheat breeding. Its scientific basis, London-New York. Maat, H. (2001) Science cultivating practice. A history ofagricultural science in the Netherlands and its colonies 1863-1986, Dordrecht-Boston-London. McNeill, J .R. (2000) Something new under the sun. An enviromental history of the twentieth-century world, London-New York. Maddison, A. (1995) Monitoring the world economy, 1820-1992, Paris. Martin, J. (2000) The development ofmodern agriculture. British farming since 1931, London. Martinez Alier, J. (1995) Los principios de la economia ecol6gica. Textos de P. Geddes, SA. Podolinsky y F. Soddy, Madrid. Martinez Carrion, J.M. (ed.) (2002) El nivel de vida en la Espana rural, siglos XVIII-XX, Alicante. Mason, l.L. (1996) A World dictionary of livestock breeds, Types and varieties, Wallingford. Mokyr, J. (2002) The lever of riches: technological creativity and economic progress, Cambridge. Nagore, D. (1934) El trigo y su selecci6n, Barcelona. Naredo, J.M. and Valero, A. (eds) (1999) Desarrollo econ6mico y deterioro ecol6gico, Madrid. O'Brien, P. and Toniolo, G. (1991) 'The poverty of Italy and the backwardness of its agriculture before 1914', in B.M.S. Campbell and M. Overton, M. (eds), Land, labour and livestock. Historical studies in European agricultural productivity, Manchester, pp. 385-409.

55

Land, shops and kitchens

Offer, A. (1989) The First World War. An agrarian interpretation, Oxford. Olmstead, A.L. and Rhode, P.W. (2003) 'The red queen and the hard reds: Productivity growth in American wheat, 1800-1940', Cambridge: NBER Working Paper, No. 8863. Palladino, P. (1996) 'Science, technology and the economy: plant breeding in Great Britain, 1920-1970', Economic History Review, 49, I, pp. 116-136. Pan-Montojo, J. (1994) La bodega del mundo. La vid y el vino en Espana (1800-1936), Madrid. Papadakis, J. (1966) Climates of the world and their agricultural potentialities, Buenos Aires. Percival, J. (1934) Wheat in Great Britain, London. Perkins, J.H. (1997) Geopolitics and the green revolution: wheat, genes and the Cold War, Oxford. Pezzati, M. (1994) 'Industria e agricoltura: i concimi chimici', in Annales. Fondazione Giangiacomo Feltrinelli, Milan, pp. 373-401. Pimentel, D. and Pimentel, M. (eds) (1996) Food, energy and society, Colorado. Pollard, S. (1981) The peaceful conquest, Oxford. Porter, V. (1991) Cattle: A handbook to the breeds of the world, London. Pujol, J. (1998a) 'Las innovaciones biotecnol6gicas en la agricultura espafiola antes de 1936: el caso del trigo', Agricultura y Sociedad, 86, pp. 163-182. Pujol, J. (1998b) 'La difusi6n de los abonos minerales y qufmicos entre 1890 y 1936: el caso espafiol en el contexto europeo', Historia Agraria, 15, pp. 143-182. Pujol, J. (1998c) 'Los lfmites ecol6gicos del crecimiento agrario espafiol entre 1850 y 1935: nuevos elementos para un debate', Revista de Historia Econ6mica, 16, 3, pp. 645-675. Pujol, J. (2002a) 'Agricultura y crecimiento econ6mico: las innovaciones biol6gicas en la cerealicultura europea: 1820-1940', Revista de Historia Industrial, 21, pp. 63-88. Pujol, J. (2002b) 'Especializaci6n ganadera, industrias agroalimentarias y castes de transacci6n: Catalufia, 1880-1926', Historia Agraria, 27, pp. 191-219. Pujol,J., Gonzalez de Molina, M., Fernandez Prieto, L., Gallego, D. and Garrabou,R. (eds) (2001) El poza de todos los males. Sohre el atraso de la agricultura espanola contemporanea, Barcelona. Sala Roca, E. (1948) El problema mundial del trigo y el problema del trigo en Espana, Barcelona. Santiago Enrfquez, C. (1922) Las vacas suizas y holandesas en Espana, Madrid. Scholliers, P. (ed.) (1989) Real wages in 19th and 20th centruy Europe. Historical and comparative perspectives, New York-Oxford-Munich. Sieferle, R.P. (2001) The subterranean forest: Energy systems and the industrial revolution, Cambridge. Simon, M. (1999) 'Les varietes de ble tendre cultivees en France au cours du vingtieme siecle et leurs origines genetiques', in CR. Academie Agricole de France, 85, 8, pp. 5-26.

56

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

Simpson, J. (1987) 'La elecci6n tecnica en el cultivo triguero y el atraso de la agricultura espafiola a finales del siglo XIX', Revista de Historia Econ6mica, 5, 2, pp. 271-299. Simpson, J. (1997) La agricultura espanola (1765-1965): la larga siesta, Madrid. Stubbe, H. ( 1972) History of genetics: From prehistoric times to the rediscovery ofMendel's laws, Cambridge (Mss). Teuteberg, H.-J. (ed.) (1992) European food history. A research overview, Leicester. Tracy, M. (1982) Agriculture in Western Europe: Challenge and response, 1889-1980, London. Tracy, M. (1989) Goverment and agriculture in Western Europe, 1880-1988, London. Vilmorin-Andrieux [et al.] (1880) Les Meilleurs bles. Description et culture des principales varietes de froments d 'hiver et de printemps, 2 vols, Paris. Vilmorin, J. and Meunisier, A. (1918) 'Le ble et sa culture en France', Revue Generate des Sciences pures et appliquees, 30-dec., pp. 694-706. Walton, J.R. (1999) 'Varietal innovation and the competitiveness of the British cereals sector, 17 60-1930', Agricultural History Review, 47, 1, pp. 29-57. Wrigley,A. (1990) Continuity, chance and change. The character ofthe industrial revolution. Cambridge. Zanden, J.L. van (1991) 'The first green revolution: the growth of production and productivity in European agriculture, 1870-1914' ,Economic History Review, 44, pp. 215239. Zanden, J.L. van (1994) The transformation of European agriculture in the 19th Century. The case of Netherlands, Amsterdam. Zeven, A.C. (1990) Landraces and improved cultivars of bread wheat and other wheat t}pes grown in the Netherlands up to 1944, Wageningen.

57

Land, shops and kitchens

Annexe Table 3.1

European Experimental Centres, members of the International Association of Seed Testing, 1931 1

Germany Sweden Italy Poland Czechoslovakia Ukraine Norway 1

No 19 8

5 5 4 4 3

United Kingdom Spain Latvia Switzerland Belgium Bulgaria Ireland

No 3 2 2 2 1 1 1

Finland France Hungary Rumania Netherlands Denmark Estonia

No 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

All seeds, not only wheat.

Source: Instituto Internacional deAgricultura, Bolet{n Mensual de lnformaci6n Tecnica, 1933: 114.

58

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

Table 3.2

Institutions of wheat improvement in Europe, 1880-1938 1

(3)

(1)2

(2)

Maison Vilmorin-Andrieux (Verrieres) Institut de Recherches Agronomiques C. de Recherches Agronomiques (Versailles) Plant Breeding Station at Gembloux Station de Selection du Boerenbond (Heverlee) Plant Breeding Institute at Wageningen Station de Recherches Agro (Groningen) Plant Breeding Institut (Munich) Plant Breeding Institut (Breslau) Plant Breeding Institut (Halle) Plant Breeding Institut (Hohenheim) Plant Breeding Institut (Magyarovar) Plant Breeding Station (Vienna) Plant Breeding Station (Svalof) Plant Breeding Station (Landskrona) Plant Breeding Institut (Cambridge) Ins. di Genetica per la Cerealicoltura (Roma) Stazione Sperimentale di Granicoltura (Rieti) Ins. di Allevamento per la Cereal (Bologna)

(II) FR (I) FR (I) (I)

(4)

(5)3

1815 M.H. and Ph. Vilmorin 1921

1923 FR BEL 1872

(II) BEL (I) NL

1925 A.G. Dumont 1886 L. Broekema

(I) (I) (I) (I)

NL GER GER GER (I) GER (I) HUN (I) AUS (III) SWE (III) SWE (I) UK

1889 1872 1872 1863 1905 1909 1903 E.Von Tschermak 1886 N.H. Nilsson-Ehle 1904 1912 R.H. Biffen, F. Engledow

(I)

ITA

1919 N. Strampelli

(I)

ITA

1907 N. Strampelli

(III) ITA

1920 F. Todaro

(1) Institution

(2) Type of financing: public (I), private (II), and mixed (III) (3) Country (4) Breeder Institutions and breeders most cited in the source Other institutions were: Plant Breeding Station at Krizevci (SER), Kaiser Wilhelm Institut of Breeding (GER). 3 Other breeders were: M. Blondeau (FR), C. Benoist (FR), R. Carsten (GER), C. Krafft (GER), F. Vettel (GER), F. Heine (GER), W. Rimpau (GER), F. Strube (GER) and P.J. Hylkema (NL). 1

2

Source: Based on data from Lupton, 1987: 53-61/164-168; Zeven, 1990: 17-99; Institut International d' Agriculture, 1933.

59

Land, shops and kitchens

Table 33

New varieties of wheat between 1880 and 1938

United Kingdom

Western Continental Europe

Sh. Squarehead, Orice Prilific, Ambrose Stand up, Starting II, Little Joss

Lamed, Datte!, Bordier, Carlota Strampelli, Undici Strubes, Spijk, Rimpau Fruth, Wilhelmina, Japhet, Champlan, Duivendaal, Bon Fermier, Fletum, Hatif Inversable, Briquet Jaune, De Massy, Grosse Tete, Grenadier, Montilleul, Krafft's, Cuiras I, II, Emma, Algebra, Juliana, Concurrent, Jacobs, Geant Rouge, Geant Blanc, Cartens V, Travenant, Milion I, Hylkema, Ceres, Robusta, Kronen

Italy

1880-1914

1915-1938 Yeoman I and II, Holdfast, Al, Premier, Wilma, Steadfast, Quota, Redman, Redman, Warden

Prins Hendrik, Blanka, Des Aliees, Addens, Van Hoek, Extra Kolben II, Van Mansholt, Invicta, Skandia II, Carma, Ideal, Vilmorin 23, 27, 29, Wilobo, Bersee, H. 40, Crown, Jubilee, Mendel, Alba, Astra, Staring, Lovink, Strube 56, Elisabeth, Atle

Senatore Capelli, Ardito, Mentana, Villa Glori, Sestini, Damiano, Fandulla

Sources: Based on data from Vilmorin-Andrieux, 1880; Denaiffe & Colle and Sidorot, c.1920; Percival, 1934, 15-90; Lupton, 1987, 53-61, 164-168; Zeven, 1990, 17-99; Bonjean and Angus,2001, 103-192; Maat, 2001, 126-137.

60

Table 3.4

0\

Pedigrees of wheat hybrids obtained between 1880 and 1938

France Chiddam epi rouge Chiddam epi blanc Gros Tete Massy Bordier Gros Bleu Bon Fermier Tresor Dattel Allies H. Inversable Vilmorin 23 Vilmorin 27 Belgium Jubilee Netherlands Spijk Wilhelmina Emma Juliana Hylkema Staring Germany Carstens V Model Rimpau Frtih

(1)

(2)

Chiddam Chiddam Bro wick Shirreff Prince Albert Shirreff Ble Siegle Shirreff Prince Albert

Noe Noe Noe

(3)

(4)

Chiddam Epi Blanc gi

" ~;::,

s

Gros Bleu Gros Bleu Chiddam Epi Rouge Massy, Gross Tete Gros Bleu/Siegle (?) Allies, Persel, Grosse Tete Dattel, Allies, H. Inversable, B. Fermier

Noe Chiddam Noe

"'~ ";::, ('.)

S: .,,"';::, ('.)

;::,

\::>.

-

?-

"';::.

Schonen Grenadier, Kotte Iron, Shonnen

Squarehead Saumur (FR), Wilhelmina (NL)

Essex

~

"' !:)

;> !:)..

""'

~;::.

"';>

"'

White Fife (CAN)

Squarehead Bro wick Little Joss, Victor, Squarehead Yeoman

Akagomughi Akagomughi Akagomughi Akagomughi

Rieti Rieti Rieti Rieti

Ghirka Red Fife (CAN) 1

(JAP), Wilhelmina (NL) (JAP), Wilhelmina (NL) (JAP), Wilhelmina (NL) (JAP), Wilhelmina (NL)

From UK (Squarehead also include its selections); From East Europe (Noe was a selection and include other selections of it); From other countries; From the same country.

Originally from Danzig (Poland).

Sources: Based on data from Vilmorin-Andrieux, 1880; Denaiffe & Colle and Sidorot, c.1920; Percival, 1934, 15-90; Lupton, 1987, 53-61, 164-168; Zeven, 1990, 17-99; Bonjean and Angus,2001, 103-192; Maat, 2001, 126-137.

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

Table 3.5

Wheat improvement activities in Spain, 1880-1935

Public experimentation centers i

Date of constitution

Granja Experimental del Jardfn del Real de Valencia Granja Escuela Experimental de Valencia Granja Experimental de Barcelona Granja Experimental de Zaragoza Granja Experimental de La Corufia Granja Escuela Practica de Agricultura de Palencia Campos de Demostracion y Experiencias de Segovia Estacion Agronomica del Instituto Agrfcola de Alfonso XII Estacion de Ensayo de Semillas de La Moncloa Escuela Practica de Agricultura de Jerez de la Frontera Granja Escuela Practica de Agricultura de Navarra Granja Agricola de Pamplona Granja Experimental. Badajoz Granja Experimental. Jaen Granja Agrfcola de Palencia Estacion de Agricultura de Zamora Granja Regional de Castilla la Vieja Granja Experimental de Zalla Seccion Agronomica de Aiava Servei de Terra Campa (Catalufia)

1885 1888 1894 1885 1896 1908 1898 1905 1908 1906 1908 1908 1906 1906 1909 1919 1923 ? ?

1923/1932

1

The activities of the Sindicato Agricola de Guissona beginning in 1932 must also be emphasized.

Source: Based on data from J. Cartafia, 2000; Pujol, 2002a: 77.

63

Land, shops and kitchens

Table 3 .6

Consumption of N, P20 5 and K20 from mineral and chemical fertilizers between 1880-1936 (Kg/ha)

Netherlands Belgium Germany

UK Denmark France Italy Spain Mediterranean Coast Northeast Northwest 2 Center and South 1 2

1911-1913 1

1931-1937 1

163.7 68.4 49.9 28.2 17.9 10.7 13.3 5.8

299.2 160.9 143.9 60.1 54.8 40.6 26.0 16.8 32.3 28.8 12.9 9.49

Different years Without Cantabrian coast and Galicia.

Source: Based on data from Pezzati, 1994: 398; Gallego, 1986: 195; Pujol, 1998b: 143-182.

64

Environment conditions and biological innovations in European agrarian growth

Table 3.7

Agronomic conditioning factors and technical change

Mineral and Chemical Fertilizers (2) (1) Provinces 1

Grain Harvesters Provinces 2

(3)

(4)

Areas of Widespred Use Valencia 32.3 Alicante 24.5 23.0 Almeria Lfaida 29.2 Zaragoza 21.1 Castellon 17.3 Tarragona 15.1

75.9 28.2 27,7 22.0 34.2 33.8 39.5

Burgos Palencia Leon Huesca Teruel Zaragoza Gerona

8.7 5.6 15.9 16.6 24.1 24.6 26.4

35 to 40 30 to 35 60 to 70 30 to 35 30 to 40 20 to 25 25 to 30

Areas with Little Use Jaen 5.5 Ciudad Real 3.8 Guadalajara 3.0 Caceres 1.6 Badajoz 0.2 Cordoba 0.7 Cuenca 0.9

1.4 4.8 7.5 7.2 7.2 7.1 7.9

Badajoz Toledo Ciudad Real Malaga Cordoba Barcelona Tarragona

23.6 27.7 37.7 43.7 53.1 64.3 67.9

240 to 260 >1000 800 to 850 200 to 240 350 to 370 620 to 640 565 to 580

(1) Relative importance of irrigated surface areas in 1922.

(2) Kg/ha of mineral and chemical fertilizers around 1933. (3) Relative importance of surface areas of vineyards and olive groves in the total occupied by these crops, the surface areas sown with grains, and the surface areas of artificial pastures, around 1932. (4) Hectares sown with grains by harvester, around 1932. 1 2

Provinces with little precipitation and high temperatures in spring and summer. Provinces with different climate conditions.

Source: Based on data from Pujol, 1998b: 160-169; Pujol, 1998c: 657-669.

65

Land, shops and kitchens

Figure 3.1 Main flows of wheat seeds between 1830 and 1914

(1)

Eastern Europe

(1)

United Kingdom

l

I (5) (5)

Western Continental Europe

--------+

~

So :::I ;> z.s Germany France UK Sweden Netherlands Belgium

14 24 30 16 8 5

0 ....

VJ

:::I µ.:i

5"d

~~ ,..., 0 (.)

VJ

;:; 0

v

.- 0.. . ....; 0

o:s .... .... :::I ~µ.:i

ci....

e v

....

VJ

:::I µ.:i

~

.... v VJ .... 0

0..

....

e"d

2 ~ ~ ~

VJ

]....

:::I 0

~

v

~~ ........ v

:::I

µ.:i ,...,

(.)

~µ.:i

0

VJ

0:::::

0

..0 ....

:::I ::l

z8

s~

~E ..0 VJ

z .. . ;

::l:::::

:::I ::l

z8

::l µ.:i

z.s

9 11 11 11 8 7

670 2,336 1,335 337 423 2,911

5

64

.... v V·.-