Routledge Handbook of Modern Korean History 9780415739313, 9781315816722, 1951972112, 0415739314

Beginning in the mid-nineteenth century when Korea became entangled in the world of modern imperialism and the old socia

1,761 216 3MB

English Pages 408 [409] Year 2016

Report DMCA / Copyright

DOWNLOAD FILE

Polecaj historie

Routledge Handbook of Modern Korean History
 9780415739313, 9781315816722, 1951972112, 0415739314

Table of contents :
Cover......Page 1
Title......Page 4
Copyright......Page 5
Contents......Page 6
List of illustrations......Page 9
Notes on contributors......Page 10
1 Introduction: understanding modern Korean history......Page 14
PART I Late Chosŏn......Page 26
2 Korea by 1860......Page 28
3 Competing imperialisms in Korea......Page 40
4 The nation, the people, and the possibilities of the post-national: Historiographies of late nineteenth-century Korean reform movements......Page 56
5 Religion 1876–1910......Page 75
6 The transformation of the Chosŏn economy in the Open Port Period, 1876–1910......Page 94
7 The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion......Page 108
PART II The colonial period......Page 122
8 The politics of assimilation: Koreans into Japanese......Page 124
9 Colonial modernity......Page 137
10 Women, gender, and social change in colonial Korea......Page 154
11 Nationalist movements before 1945......Page 166
PART III Division and war......Page 182
12 The division of Korea and the rise of two Koreas, 1945–1948......Page 184
13 The Korean War and its politics......Page 193
PART IV North Korea......Page 208
14 North Korean state-making: process and characteristics......Page 210
15 North Korea’s chuch’e philosophy......Page 224
16 A dynastic polity in economic stagnation and decline......Page 234
17 The North Korean famine......Page 247
18 North Korea under Kim Jong II......Page 259
19 Marriage, family, and sexuality in North Korea......Page 275
PART V South Korea......Page 288
20 Trade union movements in South Korea since 1945......Page 290
21 Economic miracle: from post-war reconstruction to post-crisis affluence......Page 308
22 Democratization in South Korea......Page 327
23 Women, gender, and social change in South Korea since 1945......Page 339
24 The post-developmental state: economic and social changes since 1997......Page 356
25 Global Korea......Page 370
26 Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013......Page 381
Index......Page 404

Citation preview

Routledge Handbook of Modern Korean History

Beginning in the mid-nineteenth century when Korea became entangled in the world of modern imperialism and the old social, economic and political order began to change, this handbook brings together cutting-edge scholarship on major themes in Korean history. Contributions by experts in the field cover the late Chŏson and colonial periods, Korea’s partition and the diverging paths of North and South Korea. Topics covered include: • • • • • • • • •

The division of Korea Religion Competing imperialisms Economic change War and rebellions Nationalism Gender North Korea under Kim Jong Il Global Korea

The Handbook provides a stimulating introduction to the most important themes within the subject area and is an invaluable reference work for any student and researcher of Korean history. Michael J. Seth is Professor of History at James Madison University, USA.

This page intentionally left blank

Routledge Handbook of Modern Korean History

Edited by Michael J. Seth

First published 2016 by Routledge 2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN and by Routledge 711 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10017 Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business © 2016 selection and editorial material, Michael J. Seth; individual chapters, the contributors The right of Michael J. Seth to be identified as the author of the editorial material, and of the authors for their individual chapters, has been asserted in accordance with sections 77 and 78 of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilised in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publishers. Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or registered trademarks, and are used only for identification and explanation without intent to infringe. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Title: Routledge handbook of modern Korean history / edited by Michael J. Seth. Other titles: Handbook of modern Korean history Description: Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon : Routledge, 2017. Identifiers: LCCN 2015026654| ISBN 9780415739313 (hardback) | ISBN 9781315816722 (ebook) Subjects: LCSH: Korea—History—1864–1910. | Korea—History—20th century. | Korea—History—1945– | BISAC: HISTORY / Asia / Korea. | SOCIAL SCIENCE / Ethnic Studies / General. Classification: LCC DS907.18 .R68 2017 | DDC 951.9--dc23 LC record available at http://lccn.loc.gov/2015026654 ISBN: 978-0-415-73931-3 (hbk) ISBN: 978-1-315-81672-2 (ebk) Typeset in Bembo and Stone Sans by Florence Production Ltd, Stoodleigh, Devon, UK

iv

Contents

List of illustrations Notes on contributors 1 Introduction: understanding modern Korean history Michael J. Seth

viii ix 1

PART I

Late Choso ˘n

13

2 Korea by 1860 James B. Lewis

15

3 Competing imperialisms in Korea Kirk W. Larsen

27

4 The nation, the people, and the possibilities of the post-national: Historiographies of late nineteenth-century Korean reform movements Joshua Van Lieu 5 Religion 1876–1910 Albert L. Park 6 The transformation of the Chosŏn economy in the Open Port Period, 1876–1910 Owen Miller 7 The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion Carl Young

43 62

81 95

PART II

The colonial period 8 The politics of assimilation: Koreans into Japanese Mark E. Caprio

109 111

v

Contents

9 Colonial modernity E. Taylor Atkins

124

10 Women, gender, and social change in colonial Korea Sonja M. Kim

141

11 Nationalist movements before 1945 Franklin Rausch

153

PART III

Division and war

169

12 The division of Korea and the rise of two Koreas, 1945–1948 Jongsoo Lee

171

13 The Korean War and its politics Grace J. Chae

180

PART IV

North Korea

195

14 North Korean state-making: process and characteristics Shin Jongdae

197

15 North Korea’s chuch’e philosophy James F. Person

211

16 A dynastic polity in economic stagnation and decline Andrei Lankov

221

17 The North Korean famine Marcus Noland

234

18 North Korea under Kim Jong II Adrian Buzo

246

19 Marriage, family, and sexuality in North Korea Suzy Kim

262

PART V

South Korea

275

20 Trade union movements in South Korea since 1945 Jooyeon Jeong

277

21 Economic miracle: from post-war reconstruction to post-crisis affluence Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

295

vi

Contents

22 Democratization in South Korea Gregg Andrew Brazinsky

314

23 Women, gender, and social change in South Korea since 1945 Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

326

24 The post-developmental state: economic and social changes since 1997 Jamie Doucette

343

25 Global Korea John Lie

357

26 Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013 Avram Agov

368

Index

391

vii

Illustrations

Figures 17.1 17.2 17.3 17.4

Food imports and aid, 1990–2010 Total imports and commercial food imports, 1993–2010 Scenarios of food supply and minimum human need, 1990–2004 Estimates of daily per capita PDS rations

237 237 238 238

Tables 14.1 14.2 14.3 16.1 19.1 20.1 20.2 20.3 20.4 20.5 20.6 20.7 21.1 21.2

viii

Dates of KWP meetings and main topics of discussion Establishment of the NKPC Establishment of the KWP Alternative estimates of the North Korean per capita GNP Comparison of features in patriarchal family and socialist family Annual shifts in the number and proportions of employees in various sectors in Korea Numbers of union members of Korean industrial union federations Annual sizes of union membership and numbers of enterprise unions in Chemical Union and its major industrial branches Annual wage growth rates bargained for in the chemical industries Union membership in the Auto Transport Union and its city bus branch Sizes of union membership in five enterprise unions Annual wage growth rates achieved in firm K during the period of its declining bargaining capacities Korean miracle: GDP growth Changes of top five chaebŏls

201 204 206 222 267 280 282 286 287 289 290 292 296 297

Contributors

Avram Agov is a faculty at the Asian Studies Department of Langora College in Vancouver. He received his BA in philosophy and history at Sofia University and completed his PhD at the University of British Columbia. He was a visiting scholar at Columbia University on a Fulbright Fellowship. He received his MA in Regional Studies-East Asia at Harvard University. He is currently working on a manuscript entitled ‘North Korea in the Socialist World: Integration and Divergence, 1945–1991’. E. Taylor Atkins is Presidential Teaching Professor at the Department of History, Northern Illinois University. He is the author of Blue Nippon: Authenticating Jazz in Japan (2001) and Primitive Selves: Koreana in the Japanese Colonial Gaze, 1910–1945 (2010). Gregg Andrew Brazinsky is Associate Professor of History and International Affairs at George Washington University. He is the author of Nation Building in South Korea: Koreans, Americans and the Making of a Democracy. His works have appeared in numerous edited volumes and academic journals, as well as the Chicago Tribune and CNN.com. Adrian Buzo is currently Lecturer in Korean at Macquarie University. He holds a doctorate in Asian Studies from Monash University, where he was also Senior Lecturer in Korean Studies. He has also served on a number of Australian government bodies, including the Australia Korea Foundation and has published widely in the field of Korean language and studies. His The Guerilla Dynasty was published in 1999, and the second edition of his The Making of Modern Korea was published by Routledge in 2007. Mark E. Caprio, the author of Japanese Assimilation Policies in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945, lectures on Japan and Korea relations at Rikkyo University in Tokyo, Japan. He is currently writing a manuscript tentatively titled ‘The dregs of Japanese colonialism in liberated Korea’. Grace J. Chae is a Research Fellow with the project ‘Beyond the Korean War’, sponsored by the University of Cambridge and the Academy of Korean Studies. She received her PhD in modern Korean history from the University of Chicago (2010) and is working on a book manuscript entitled Captive Minds: Race, War and the Education of Korean War POWs in US Custody, 1950–1953.

ix

Contributors

Jamie Doucette is Lecturer in Human Geography in the School of Environment, Education and Development at the University of Manchester. His research interests include the political economy of Korean democratization and development; the transformation of Korean labour relations; and the nexus between sovereignty, territory and economy in East Asia. His articles have appeared in such publications as Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, Critical Asian Studies and the Journal of Contemporary Asia, among others. Cho Haejoang is a cultural anthropologist and has been teaching at Yonsei University since 1979. Her early research focused on gender studies in modern Korean history; her current interests are in the areas of youth, informal life-politics and research methodology in the global/local and postcolonial context of modern-day Korea. She is the founding director of Haja Center, a creative commons/cultural studio for teenagers. Shin Jongdae is Professor of History at Kyungnam University in Masan, South Korea. His field is modern Korean history. He has done research and published in Korean on the history of North Korea. Jooyeon Jeong, Professor in the Department of Economics at Korea University, mainly examines enterprise unions and bargaining and industrial relations in Korea from a comparative perspective. He has published several articles in major international journals, including British Journal of Industrial Relations (1995), Economic and Industrial Democracy (1995), International Journal of Human Resource Management (1999), Industrial Relations Journal (2001), Journal of Industrial Relations (2003, 2005, 2011), and the book Industrial Relations in Korea: Diversity and Dynamism of Korean Enterprise Unions from a Comparative Perspective (Routledge 2007). Hannah Jun is Assistant Professor of the School of Business Administration, Hankuk University of Foreign Studies. Her current research interests include business ethics, corporate social responsibility, and socially responsible investing. Her recent publications include ‘Beneath the Surface: A Discussion of Prominent Ideologies and Philosophical Influences on Anglo-American Business Ethics’ (2014) and ‘Varieties of Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR): An Analysis of Prominent Definitions of CSR in Korea’ (2014). Sonja M. Kim is Associate Professor of Asian and Asian American Studies at Binghamton University (SUNY) where she teaches courses on Korean history and East Asia. Her main research interests and publications focus on gender, medicine and public health in early twentieth-century Korea in edited volumes and journals such as the Korean Journal of Medical History (Ŭisahak) and EASTS. Her book provisionally titled Caring for their Own: Women and the Making of Modern Care in Korea is under final contract with the University of Hawai’i Press. She is also co-editing a volume on science, medicine, and technology in Korea. Suzy Kim is Associate Professor of Korean History in the Department of Asian Languages and Cultures at Rutgers University. Her publications include a special guest-edited volume Cross-Currents: East Asian History and Culture Review on “(De)Memorializing the Korean War” (March 2015) and Everyday Life in the North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950 was published by Cornell University Press in 2013. Her teaching and research interests focus on modern Korean history with particular attention to social and cultural history, gender studies and critical theory. x

Contributors

Andrei Lankov was born in 1963 in Leningrad (now Petersburg), Russia. He graduated from Leningrad State University and taught Korean history at Australian National University. Since 2004, he teaches at Kookmin University in Seoul. His major research interest is North Korean history and society. Kirk W. Larsen is Associate Professor of History at Brigham Young University. His research focuses on East Asian international relations in the early modern and modern periods. His publications include Tradition, Treaties, and Trade: Qing Imperialism and Chosôn Korea, 1850–1910 (Harvard University Press, 2008). Jongsoo Lee is Center Associate at the Davis Center for Russian and Eurasian Studies, Harvard University. Lee has served as Senior Research Fellow at the Asan Institute for Policy Studies in Seoul and as Associate in Research at the Korea Institute, Harvard University. A graduate of Harvard University (MA and PhD) and Williams College (BA), Lee is the author of The Partition of Korea after World War II: A Global History (2005), among other publications. James B. Lewis has studied in the United States, Korea and Japan. He is currently the University Lecturer in Korean History and Oriental Studies, University of Oxford. He specialises in KoreanJapanese relations and the economic history of Chosŏn Korea. He is a member of the Council of the Association for Korean Studies in Europe and is President of the British Association for Korean Studies. John Lie is Professor of Sociology at the University of California, Berkeley. His recent books include Zainichi (Koreans in Japan): Diasporic Nationalism and Postcolonial Identity (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2008); and K-pop: Popular Music, Cultural Amnesia, and Economic Innovation in South Korea (Berkeley: University of California Press, 2015). Owen Miller is Lecturer in Korean Studies at the School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London, where he teaches modern Korean history. He was previously a research fellow at Robinson College, University of Cambridge. Owen received his PhD from SOAS in 2007 for a thesis on merchant-government relations in late nineteenth-century Korea. More broadly, his research interests include the social and economic history of nineteenth- and twentieth-century Korea; the social history of North Korea; and Korean nationalist and Marxist historiographies. Laura C. Nelson is an anthropologist interested in the mutual engagements of public policies and society/culture. Her three current South Korea-based projects examine breast cancer as a personal experience and a political issue; the invisibility of older women without children; and the future generation of new Koreans born to immigrant brides. Her book Measured Excess: Status, Gender, and Consumer Nationalism in South Korea (2000) examined South Korea’s consumer culture. Marcus Noland is Executive Vice President and Director of Studies at the Peterson Institute of International Economics in Washington, DC, and a senior fellow at the East-West Center in Honolulu, Hawaii. He has written extensively on food security in North Korea, including Famine in North Korea: Markets, Aid and Reform. Ingyu Oh is Professor and Director of the Centre for Hallyu Studies, RIKS, Korea University. His research interests include economic sociology, musicology and East Asian political economy. xi

Contributors

Recent publications include ‘Comparing State Economic Ideologies and Business Ethics in East Asia’ (2014), ‘A League of their Own: Female Hallyu Fans and Korea-Japan Relations’ (2014), ‘Intuition and Consilience: the Creation of Clinical and Symptomatic Knowledge in Entertainment Industries’ (2013) and ‘Rent-sharing: Organizational and Technological Innovations under the Military Regimes in South Korea and Turkey’ (2010). Albert L. Park teaches at Claremont McKenna College. A historian of Korea who studies the intersection between political economy and culture, he is the co-editor of Encountering Modernity: Christianity in East Asia and Asian America and the author of Building a Heaven on Earth: Religion, Activism and Protest in Japanese Occupied Korea. James F. Person is Director of the Hyundai Motor-Korea Foundation Center for Korean History and Public Policy and Deputy Director of the History and Public Policy Program (HAPP) at the Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. Person holds a PhD in modern Korean history from the George Washington University, Washington, DC, with a dissertation examining the evolution of North Korea’s political and ideological systems from 1953 to 1967. Person teaches courses on North Korean history at George Washington University. Franklin Rausch earned his doctoral degree from the University of British Columbia in 2011 and is currently Assistant Professor in the Department of History and Philosophy at Lander University in Greenwood, South Carolina. He is the author of multiple articles on the connections between nationalism and religion. Michael J. Seth is Professor of History at James Madison University where he teaches world and Korean history. His publications include Education Fever: Society, Politics and the Pursuit of Schooling in South Korea (2002) and A History of Korea: From Antiquity to the Present (2011). Joshua Van Lieu is Assistant Professor of History and Curriculum Director for the Asian Studies minor at LaGrange College. His research interests include the intellectual, political and diplomatic histories of nineteenth-century East Asia, with a particular focus in the politics and historiography of Chosŏn-Qing relations. Carl Young is Associate Professor at the Department of History of the University of Western Ontario. His main research interests focus on the history of Korean religions and their involvement in social and political movements. He has written a book and several articles on the Tonghak and Ch’ŏndogyo movements.

xii

1 Introduction Understanding modern Korean history Michael J. Seth

Modern Korean history, much like Korea itself, has emerged in recent years out of the shadows of its larger and better known neighbors China and Japan. Several decades ago it was possible to place almost all the scholarly literature on Korean history in English on a single shelf of books. Indeed, Korea was so little understood that when it appeared at all in Western textbooks, it often was restricted to developments related to the Korean War and the Cold War. But in recent years the historical scholarship available to non-Koreans has grown enormously. A tributary of China, a colony of Japan, it failed to emerge in Western consciousness as a distinctive variant of East Asian culture with its own long historical tradition. The study of Korean history was also hampered by the formidable linguistic challenges, generally requiring at minimum the knowledge of the difficult Korean language, and in most cases the ability to read Japanese as well as classical Chinese. Furthermore, there were few institutions in the West that had Korean studies programs or the staff and facilities to train scholars and few positions for academics who had Korea as their specialty. And for those interested in North Korea, the near impossibility of gaining access to its archives or even entering the country was a serious impediment. As a result Korean history was a neglected area of study. In recent years this neglect of Korean history has been replaced by a rapidly developing interest by Western academics. Partly this reflects the general expansion of East Asian studies, but it is also due to South Korea’s emergence as a major economic, cultural and political presence in the world. In 2008, South Korea became a member of the G-20, major economic powers whose leaders meet annually. South Korean products have penetrated almost every market and have given the country a degree of recognition it previously lacked. South Korean popular culture, what is called the “Korean Wave,” has made the country a major exporter of TV dramas, movies, pop music and videos, and Seoul has become the pop culture capital of the Pacific Rim of Asia. Furthermore, South Korea’s “economic miracle” has drawn the interest of economists, historians, and social scientists as well as policymakers. Many aspects of its economic development have become models for countries from China to Chile. The country’s transition from authoritarianism to a vibrant democracy has also been the subject of many scholarly studies. Then of course, there is the interest in North Korea. The country’s truculent posture, its isolationism, the security threats it poses and more recently its human rights record have drawn international attention. 1

Michael J. Seth

And there is a popular fascination with the seemingly bizarre behavior of its leadership and its overall “strangeness.” The essays in this volume both reflect this growing interest in Korea and represent the trends in the study of modern Korean history by South Korean and Western scholars. The modern period for Korean history has been defined in different ways. South Korean historians often regard “modern history” (hyŏndaesa) as beginning with the establishment of the Chosŏn period (also referred to as the Yi Dynasty) in 1392. This handbook defines modern more narrowly as starting from the 1860s, when the old Sino-centric political order in East Asia began to crumble and Korea entered the world of late nineteenth-century imperialism. Although somewhat arbitrary, the essays are then divided into several groupings. The first is the late Chosŏn period, that is, from the start of the modern era to the Japanese annexation in 1910 and the end of the dynastic state. This is followed by the colonial period from 1910 to 1945, the division of Korea in 1945, North Korea since 1945 and South Korea since 1945. Although a significant body of Western scholarship on modern Korean history has appeared only in the past several decades, it was preceded by earlier work in Korea. Korean intellectuals began to study their modern history in the first decade of the twentieth century. They already had a long, sophisticated tradition of historical scholarship in the Chinese-style Confucian mode, but the nature of historical literature changed when scholars began to examine their past, employing Western concepts and analytical tools. These often came via Japanese translations of Western works that students read while studying in Japan or that circulated in Korea. Meanwhile, the Japanese scholars carried out historical and archaeological research mainly focused on the early period of Korean history, and in doing so, introduced more modern methods of historical scholarship to Koreans. Historians and political thinkers such as Pak Ŭn-sik (1859–1923) and Sin Ch’ae-ho (1880–1936) began reexamining Korea’s place in the world and what it meant to be Korean. In 1908, the young Sin published an especially important essay, “A New Reading of History” (“Toksa Sillon”), in which he borrowed the concept of “Volk” (Korean: minjok) from Japanese and Chinese writers and placed it at the center of history. Sin sought to replace the older narratives that reinforced loyalty to the king with one based on a new ethnic-national identity. The history of Korea became a history of a Korean nation and its unique cultural tradition. Korean historical scholarship soon became preoccupied with understanding the loss of their country’s sovereignty in 1910 and the humiliation of Japanese rule. Many Korean intellectuals sought to counter the work of state-sponsored Japanese scholars that found Korean history characterized by stagnation in contrast to the progressive societies of Japan and the West. Writers such as Ch’oe Nam-sŏn (1890–1957) sought to create national histories that pointed to the unique and dynamic nature of their nation’s past. Ch’oe looked for Korea’s “soul” or ǒl, its unique Volkgeist that he traced from ancient times. Korean history became a story of the struggle of Koreans to develop their society and maintain their political and cultural autonomy while threatened by outsiders. Historians such as Yi Pyǒng-do began to take a more academic approach to history, attempting to produce objective scholarship. They established the Chindan Hakhoe (Chindan Society) in 1934 to publish historical scholarship. The same period saw an emergence of Marxist historical scholarship pioneered by Paek Nam-un (1894–1979). This focused on class struggle, with peasant masses struggling against their feudal, landowning exploiters. Marxists also sought to place Korean history within the context of universal historical processes. All basic schools were similar in their linear, progressive view of history and their incorporation of Western concepts and categories for understanding their past. They also saw themselves as guardians and promoters of the nationalist spirit. Historical scholarship during colonial times, however, was hampered by Japanese restrictions, and historians were frequently arrested. 2

Understanding modern Korean history

After 1945, with the division of the country, Paek and many other leftist historians went to North Korea. There, history had to conform to ideological purposes to such an extent that little real scholarship could flourish. In South Korea, scholarship on modern Korean history was hindered by a series of anti-communist authoritarian governments which feared that the examination of the messy origins of the South Korean state in the years since 1945 could undermine its legitimacy. Twentieth-century history, as a result, was often avoided by scholars. In the late 1970s and 1980s, however, historians such as Song Kǒn-ho, Kang Man-gil and Choi Jang-jip began a refocus on more recent history. Among the issues to emerge was the origins of modernization. Yi Ki-baek, in his major work Kuksa Sillon (A New History of Korea), incorporated American ideas of modernization theory to trace its origins back to the emergence of modern science and the political ideas in eighteenth century Europe. Modernization began in Korea toward the end of the eighteenth century, he argued, when Koreans began to adopt these Western concepts and practices. Others such as Kang Man-gil held to the “sprouts of modernization” concept that saw an autonomous Korean path to the modern world that began in the late Chosŏn. These scholars, rather than seeing Korea as a stagnant society, saw it as having its own dynamic nature. They pointed to writers, thinkers and reformers in the seventeenth and eighteenth century, a group they labeled Sirak, who were critical of their own society and proposed progressive changes. They saw the development of commerce, the growth of a more monetized economy and improvements in agriculture and technology as signs that Korea was developing its own parallel modernization. It was not initiated by Western and Japanese imperialist interventions in their country but hijacked by it. Many of these writers came from or were influenced by the leftist nationalist tradition; modernization, they often argued, came not from the top but emanated from the common people: peasants rebelling against the feudal landlord class, low-caste merchants seeking economic opportunities, and “middle people” (chungin), sub-elites of talented professionals who were open to new ideas resisted by the aristocratic class. In the past two decades, an increasing number of South Korean historians have focused on their often troubled recent past, including the social and political costs of South Korea’s “economic miracle.” The lack of translations into Western languages and the nationalist preoccupation of Korean scholars have limited the influence of these works outside Korea. Nonetheless, most non-Korean historians have remained indebted to their efforts. And in recent years, free from political restraints, historical scholarship is flourishing.

Late Choso ˘n One issue examined by Western as well as Korean historians is whether Korea, just prior to its “opening” in the late nineteenth century, was a society in political, economic and social decline. Historians have often seen Korea as going through a period of political stability, effective governance, economic prosperity, cultural creativity and even technological innovation in the eighteenth century and then falling into a period of political corruption, factionalism, weak and ineffective rulers, economic stagnation or decline, social unrest and less cultural creativity in the nineteenth century. James B. Lewis along with Jun Seong Ho and Kang Han-Rog (2009) have argued that the country went into economic decline after 1830. Lewis in this volume states that imperialism came at a time when internal political and economic crises were coming into “conjunction.” Japanese and Western imperialism arrived, many historians believe, at a time when the government was weakened by fiscal problems, a subject touched upon in Owen Miller’s essay in this volume. 3

Michael J. Seth

Historians have attempted to understand the collapse of the old order in Korea and the country’s loss of independence by studying the international and regional diplomacy that country became enmeshed in. An important early work still valuable on this was Eugene Kim and Hankyo Kim’s Korea and the Politics of Imperialism (1967). In later works, Kim Key-Hiuk examined the international politics surrounding the “opening of Korea” and the collapse of the Chinese tributary system (1980). Swiss historian Martina Deuchler documented the efforts to adjust to the new diplomatic order (1977). Japanese specialists such as Hilary Conroy (1960) and Peter Duus (1995) focused on Tokyo’s involvement in Korea, while Kirk Larsen in Tradition, Treaties, and Trade: Qing Imperialism and Chosŏn Korea, 1850–1910 (2008) has looked at the role played by China during this period, arguing that Qing was an imperial power using modern diplomacy, international law, telegraphs and steamboats to aggressively assert itself in Korea. More recently, Yumi Moon in Populist Collaborators: The Ilchinhoe and the Japanese Colonization of Korea, 1896–1910 (2013) has looked at the active participation of Koreans in the annexation. Much of our understanding of the international politics from this period is summarized in Larsen’s essay in this volume. Korea during this period was undergoing dynamic internal change that historians are still exploring. Albert L. Park in this volume looks at religious ferment and change during this period, and Carl Young (2014) in a recent work and in this volume examines the Tonghak Rebellion in 1894 and its legacy. A number of reform movements emerged in the late nineteenth century, which are examined along with the historiography on them in Joshua Van Lieu’s essay. Historians have debated over both the effectiveness of these late reforms and the reasons why they failed to save the country’s independence. Rather than viewing Koreans as hapless victims, and late Chosŏn internal politics as the tug and pull of various factions by the Japanese, Chinese, Russian or other foreign patrons, some historians studying domestic developments have found that the state was proceeding along with reforms that were effective in some areas. But the country’s precarious geopolitical position made reform difficult. Owen Miller in his essay points out the inability of late-Chosŏn Korea to develop an independent path to economic modernization as a result of Chinese and to a greater extent Japanese economic interference. Others scholars have searched for the beginnings of modernity and national consciousness. Koreans, because of their ethnic-linguistic homogeneity, their geographic isolation and their country’s long political unity, appeared to have a sense of identity as a folk or culture that went beyond dynastic loyalty. However, most historians have argued that nationalism is a modern identity. Andre Schmid (2002) argues for the beginnings of modern Korean nationalism in the emergence of a community of educated readers of journals and newspapers. Gi-Wook Shin (2006) similarly traces the emergence of national identity as beginning at the end of the nineteenth century.

The colonial period Historians have tried to understand to what extent Korea’s modernization was a product of colonial rule. Related to this issue is the puzzle of how the foundations of the two very different societies in North and South Korea can be traced to the same colonial legacy. As a result, historians have given considerable attention to the Japanese colonial period, 1910–1945. Arguments have been made that colonialism in Korea did not resemble that of other colonies. It differed in that Koreans were colonized by a neighboring people with whom they shared many cultural traditions. Japan’s attempt at coerced assimilation gave it a unique character, as did the intense nature of its occupation with several hundred thousand soldiers, police and officials from the metropolitan state penetrating deep into Korean society. And Korea underwent a greater degree 4

Understanding modern Korean history

of industrialization than was the usual case for colonies. All of this made the colonial experience of Koreans, it has been suggested, both unusual and deeply traumatic. Scholars are increasing our understanding of this period by placing it in the broader context of modern colonialism. An early example of the first trend is The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895–1945 edited by Ramon Myers and Mark Peattie (1984), which examines colonial Korea as part of an expanding Japanese colonial empire. Two recent works by Mark Caprio (2009) and E. Taylor Atkins (2010) look at the colonial rule from a broader perspective informed by recent studies of colonialism. Caprio places colonial Korea in the larger context of colonialism, finding that the Japanese carried out policies drawn from German and French cultural assimilationist practices that were almost doomed to failure. In his essay in this volume he points to the gap between the rhetoric of assimilation and integration of Koreans into Japanese culture and society and the reality of practices that separated the two peoples and categorized Koreans as a distinctive, subordinate race of imperial subjects. The Koreans who accepted a larger Japanese imperial identity were almost always disillusioned by the failure of the Japanese to accept them. Atkins, who relies on official Japanese documents, pays attention to metropolitan Japan, viewing Korea and Japan as a “unitary field of study.” Drawing from the concept of Orientalism, he finds that the Japanese needed to exaggerate the primitivism of Korea in order to elevate their own civilizing mission. His work, much of it summarized in his essay, is revisionist in that rather than erasing Korean culture, Japanese policy intended to “orientalize” and market it. Some historians have examined the economic and social legacy of Japan’s colonial rule in Korea. Carter Eckert in Offspring of Empire (1991), a study of the small Korean entrepreneurial class and its connections with the colonial administration, looks at how the landowning elite and the business class prospered under Japanese rule, providing a more complex picture of Korea during this period. Eckert’s work is important because it provides not only insights into the colonial period but into the post-liberation period as well, since the South Korean entrepreneurial class has its origins in and exhibits patterns from that earlier period. Dennis McNamara (1990), Chong-soon Kim (1998) and Soon-won Park (1999) have also studied the entrepreneurial class. Park, in her study of the Onoda Cement factory, also sees in colonial business and labor practices much that presages later South Korean economic patterns. Edwin Gragert (1994) has furthered our understanding of socio-economic history during this period with his study of land ownership. While the attention of these studies has been more on the economic elite, Gi-Wook Shin (1996) in Peasant Protest and Social Change in Colonial Korea has looked at the peasantry. Historians have looked at colonial origins of modern Korean nationalism, a topic examined by Franklin Rausch in his essay in this book. Michael Robinson’s examination of nationalist movements in colonial Korea, Cultural Nationalism in Colonial Korea, 1920–1925 (1988), was influential in shaping our understanding of the origins of the ideological divisions of post-liberation Korea. This important work focuses on the split during the 1920s between radical and moderate nationalists, the latter Robinson calls “cultural nationalists,” a term that has now been widely adopted. The religious response to colonial modernity has been studied by Albert L. Park (2015) and the important role of Christianity in shaping nationalism by New Zealand scholar Kenneth Wells (1990). A major concern of colonial studies has been to challenge the dominant narrative of colonial repression and Korean resistance for a more complex understanding of the period. In recent years there has been an explosion of literature reexamining the colonial experience. This includes understanding the relationship between colonialism, modernity and nationalism, and providing a more inclusive approach that incorporates issues of gender. This is reflected in a collection of essays edited by Gi-Wook Shin and Michael Robinson, Colonial Modernity in Korea (2001). Theodore Jun Yoo has looked at gender in the colonial period. In The Politics of Gender in 5

Michael J. Seth

Colonial Korea: Education, Labor, and Health, 1910–1945 (2008), Yoo examines how the “Korean woman” underwent a radical transformation during the Japanese colonial period. Many women moved out of their traditional spheres to take jobs in schools, factories, hospitals and elsewhere. The experience of these women was complex because they faced two forms of modernity: Western and Japanese. Some conformed to the Japanese conventions of dress and social behavior, while others identified with and sought to follow more radical Western models, which are issues examined by Sonja Kim in her essay in this volume. While some of these studies looked at elite women, Janice Kim in To Live to Work: Factory Women in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945 (2009) examined what modernization meant to factory women. Another topic that has drawn considerable attention is the “comfort women.” George Hicks (1995) was one of the earliest scholars to examine this topic, while Sarah Soh (2008) has also made a notable recent contribution. The best of these studies deals not only with the victimization of the Koreans by Japanese but also with the discrimination Korean women faced within their own society. In these studies we see an extremely complex picture of modernization, not only Robinson’s different views of the national agenda, but two different models of modernity. While some Korean nationalist historians see the colonial experience as purely exploitative and a setback in the country’s modern trajectory, much recent scholarship has emphasized the more progressive nature of its development. As Atkins points out in his essay in this volume, this can be exaggerated; modernization that took place under the Japanese was a “colonial modernity,” modernization in a colonial context. The benefits of that modernization, as others have shown, accrued to the colonizer more than the colonized. Another perspective is provided by Donald Clark (2003) in his account of the foreign missionary community in Korea, providing an interesting window into colonial life. In the early 2010s, there was a number of new studies that presented a more complex picture of the colonial rule, including Todd A. Henry’s study of public space in colonial Seoul (2014), Jun Uchida’s work on Japanese settlers (2011), an examination of Koreans who fought for Japan during World War II by Brandon Palmer (2013), the collection of essays edited by Hong Yung Lee and Clark W. Sorenson, Colonial Rule and Social Change in Korea 1910–1945 (2013) and another collection edited by Christopher P. Hanscom and Walter K. Lew, Imperatives of Culture: Selected Essays on Korean History, Literature, and Society from the Japanese Colonial Era (2013). Our picture of the colonial era through these works has thus become more complex and nuanced.

Division and war The division of Korea in 1945 and the Korean War that soon followed the creation of two separate and rival Korean states was to many its great modern tragedy. How can we account for the creation of two Koreas? How exactly did this happened? S. S. Cho (1967) provided an early study of the division by placing it within the geopolitics of the Cold War. Jongsoo Lee’s The Partition of Korea after World War II: A Global History (2005) is a recent study of the diplomacy around the division of Korea that makes use of Soviet archival material. He argues that there is no clear evidence that the Soviet Union immediately after the war had a set plan to create a separate state in the north. His essay in this volume summarizes his argument and addresses some of the historiography on this issue. While the thirty-eighth parallel was an arbitrarily drawn line imposed on the Peninsula by the United States and the Soviet Union, historians have often traced the foundations of the two regimes to the ideological divisions during the colonial period, a topic touched upon in Rausch’s essay. A long debate over the origins of the Korean War has shifted from viewing it as an international conflict within the context of the Cold War to understanding it within the context of a domestic 6

Understanding modern Korean history

revolution. The most comprehensive treatment is by Bruce Cumings (1981, 1990), whose twovolume Origins of the Korean War is an important study of Korea in the five years before the Korean War. Some of the author’s arguments have been undermined by more recent evidence, but this is still valuable as a source of information on Korean political developments prior to the war. The first volume includes an especially valuable, detailed study of South Korean politics immediately after liberation. Recent studies of the Korean War itself have emphasized the brutality on both sides, the civil war nature of the conflict and its continuation since 1953. Some have focused on the internal conflict; others, such as Japanese historian Wada Haruki (2014), have attempted to place the conflict within its international context without losing sight of its dimension as a civil war. Grace Chae’s essay in this volume points to the deep ideological division before 1945 as a contributing factor and addresses some of the issues on the war itself.

North Korea since 1945 Despite the lack access to sources, a number of historical studies on North Korea have appeared in recent years. Pioneering works in English were Chong-sik Lee’s History of the Korean Workers’ Party (1978) and Dae-sook Suh’s biography of Kim Il Sung (1988), the latter still a standard work. More recently, several historians have focused on the establishment of the North Korean state. An especially significant work on this topic is Charles K. Armstrong’s North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950 (2003). By examining North Korean documents captured in the Korean War, he was able to draw insights into the founding of the regime. He sees the Koreans in the North as full participants in carrying out a revolution, a revolution sponsored by the Soviet Union but also one that was a product of the kind of radical nationalist vision that Robinson has traced. The author persuasively argues that the North Korean government developed into a nationalist regime from its early days. Rather than simply a creation of the Soviet Union, the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea was a product of internal Korean historical forces with Koreans as active agents. This theme has been further explored in Suzy Kim’s Everyday Life in the North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950 (2013). Suzy Kim in her essay in this volume further traces the revolutionary impact the North Korean regime had on women and family as well as the limits of that revolution. Others historians such as Andrei Lankov (2002), while acknowledging the revolutionary nature of the regime and its nationalist elements, have placed more emphasis on Moscow’s role in the creation of the regime. An Australian scholar of North Korea, Adrian Buzo has followed Japanese historian Wada in arguing that North Korea developed as a “guerilla state” (1999) shaped by the experience of the youthful Kim Il Sung and his partisans fighting the Japanese in Manchuria. The history of North Korea since the Korean War has been the object of study of several historians. Andrei Lankov’s The Real North Korea (2013) presents a highly accessible study. James Person of the North Korea International Documentation Project at the Wilson Center in Washington, D.C. has overseen the largest collection of materials on North Korea in America, collecting documents from around the world. Person himself has reevaluated some of the standard beliefs about its history, for example, finding the role of factionalism to be much less important than is given in most accounts (2006). Stephen Kotlin and Charles Armstrong (2006) have looked at the role foreign aid has played in North Korea’s economic development in the early years. Other scholars have tried to examine the ideology and national identity of North Korea, again, grounding their studies within the context of Korean history. Armstrong (2005) and Brian Myers (2010) have traced a distinctive indigenous path of ideological evolution that draws upon the country’s Confucian and Japanese imperial heritages as well as the Stalinist model. James Person’s essay in this volume focuses on the importance of the development of the official ideology 7

Michael J. Seth

of Juche for understanding North Korea. Sheila Miyoshi Jager (2013) has examined both North and South Korea’s development within the context of an ongoing Korean War, while Charles Armstrong (2013) has examined North Korea’s relations with the rest of the world in Tyranny of the Weak: North Korea and the World, 1950–1992. South Korean scholar Lim Jae-cheon (2009) has provided a systematic look at Kim Jong Il’s rise to power using available information to present a lucid analysis of how that political system has evolved. The catastrophic economic decline of North Korea and the regime’s ability to survive has drawn the attention of scholars, three of whom are represented in this volume. Andrei Lankov’s essay examines the roots of the economic disasters of the 1990s in policies implemented in the 1950s and 1960s. Marcus Noland’s research on North Korea’s famine in the 1990s and that of others is summarized in his essay in this book. Adrian Buzo’s essay looks at the ability of Kim Jong Il during his seventeen-year reign to maintain a disciplined political system which, while widely despised abroad, is nonetheless durable.

South Korea since 1945 As one of the postcolonial “success stories,” scholars have produced a large body of literature on South Korea that focuses on its economic and social modernization as well as its democratization. Much of the literature on South Korea’s “economic miracle” has been influenced by Joel Migdal’s theory of a strong state (1988) able to override vested and parochial interests to push through a national development agenda and by Chalmers Johnson’s concept of a developmental state (1987) that gave primacy to economic development over all other goals. These models have been adopted, modified and challenged. Eun Mee Kim (1997) has examined how the state-directed model of economic development needs to be seen more as an interplay between chaebŏls and the state. Other studies looking at the complex factors that account for development include Jung-en Woo’s Race to the Swift: State and Finance in the Industrialization of Korea (1991) and John Lie’s Han Unbound: The Political Economy of South Korea (1998). Hagen Koo (2001) and others have looked at the roles various sectors of society have played in economic development as well as the social cost of economic modernization. Michael Seth (2002) has looked at the historical factors that contributed to educational development and its impact on the country’s social and economic development. His study and those by Doh C. Shin (1999), Geir Helgesen (1998) and Denise Lett (1998) have found the persistence of Confucian values important in shaping South Korea’s recent modernization. Laura Nelson has examined how economic development targeted and impacted women (2000). In recent years, North American scholars have contributed to several collections of essays on the Park Chung Hee era. Many of these essays argue that any examination of South Korea as a model of how a poor country can climb out of poverty needs to factor in the personality of Park Chung Hee and the domestic and international politics of the time. Chung-shik Lee (2012) has added to our understanding of this period by tracing the personal background of Park in his Park Chung-Hee: From Poverty to Power. Other historians such as Oh Ingyu (2000) have pointed to the thuggish and oppressive nature of the Park regime, the collusion of government and big business, the suppression of workers as well as other social costs, criticisms presented by Oh and Hannah Jun in their essay for this volume. South Korea’s turbulent political history and its transition to democracy have also attracted the attention of historians. An early study by Gregory Henderson, Korea: The Politics of the Vortex (1968), although now somewhat dated, is still a provocative and insightful history of South Korea in the first two decades after World War II. Sung-joo Han in The Failure of Democracy in South Korea (1974) and Alexander Joungwon Kim in Divided Korea: The Politics of Development 8

Understanding modern Korean history

1945–1972 (1975) looked at the pre-democratic era. South Korea’s democratization has been examined by historian Gregg Brazinsky in Nation Building in South Korea: Koreans, Americans, and the Making of Democracy (2007), and in his essay in this volume he highlights the U.S. role in democratization. Namhee Lee has examined the place of the minjung movement in the country’s transformation from an authoritarian to a more open society in The Making of Minjung: Democracy and the Politics of Representation in South Korea (2007). Hwasook Nam in Building Ships, Building a Nation (2009), a case study of shipyard labor unionism in the 1960s, places the 1980s democratization within the context of earlier labor activism. Some scholars have moved from tracing economic development and democratization to examining how citizenship has been defined, the nature of ethnic and national identity and changing gender roles. All three issues are examined in Seungsook Moon’s Militarized Modernity and Gendered Citizenship in South Korea (2005) and in Sheila Miyoshi Jager’s Narratives of Nation Building in Korea: A Genealogy of Patriotism (2003), while Hyung Il Pai (2000) has looked at the role of archaeology in constructing a national identity. The essay for this book by Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang surveys the many issues and large body of literature on women and gender in recent South Korea. Today South Korea, once poor, isolated and little known, has become a major player in the increasingly globalized world. Jamie Doucette’s essay in this volume examines the changes in South Korea’s economic and social development in a post-development state since 1997. The embracing of neoliberalism has resulted in greater inequality while at the same time it has become a society of greater personal freedom. John Lie in his essay looks at the society undergoing a radical change from a xenophobic society with a strong isolationist tendency to one that is increasingly embracing globalization. The contrast between the two Koreas provides one of the most fascinating puzzles that modern history can present to historians. How could two societies that are so different emerge among such a homogeneous peoples? Nowhere in the world do two sovereign states with such a wide gap in living standards, such radically different economic and political systems and radically different ideological orientations border each other. And yet within living memory they were the same state, the same society. Both Koreas share the same historical heritage yet in two generations have evolved so contrastingly that they provide a unique case study of how the decisions leaders make and the paths states take in their quest for modernization can produce widely divergent outcomes. Modern Korean history suggests that contingency and human agency do matter in history, matter greatly. Then there is the question of reunification. A large body of literature has studied the relations between the two Koreas and their prospects for unification, a topic summed up in this volume in Avram Agov’s essay. As he points out, the tasks of reconciliation between the two Koreas are “daunting” but not inconceivable. More studies are needed to understand just to what extent the two Koreas have become not just two states but two nations.

References Armstrong, C. K. (2003) The North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Armstrong, C. K. (2005) ‘Familism, Socialism and Political Religion in North Korea,’ Totalitarian Movements and Political Religions, 6.3 (December 2005): 383–94. Armstrong, C. K. (2013) Tyranny of the Weak: North Korea and the World, 1950–1992, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Atkins, E. T. (2010) Primitive Selves: Koreana in the Japanese Colonial Gaze, 1910–1945, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Brazinsky, G. (2007) Nation Building in South Korea: Koreans, Americans, and the Making of Democracy, Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press. 9

Michael J. Seth

Buzo, A. (1999) The Guerilla Dynasty: Politics and Leadership in the DPRK, 1945–1994, Sydney: Allen & Unwin. Caprio, M. (2009) Japanese Assimilation Policies in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Cho, S. S. (1967) Korea in World Politics, 1940–1950: An Evaluation of American Responsibility, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Clark, D. N. (2003) Living Dangerously in Korea: The Western Experience, 1900–1950, Norwalk, CT: Eastbridge. Conroy, H. (1960) The Japanese Seizure of Korea, 1868–1910, Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press. Cumings, B. (1981) The Origins of the Korean War, Vol. 1: Liberation and the Emergence of Separate Regimes, 1945–1947, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Cumings, B. (1990) The Origins of the Korean War, Vol. 2: The Roaring of the Cataract, 1947–1950, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Deuchler, M. (1977) Confucian Gentlemen and Barbarian Envoys: The Opening of Korea, 1875–1885, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Duus, P. (1995) The Abacus and the Sword: The Japanese Penetration of Korea, 1895–1910, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Eckert, C. J. (1991) Offspring of Empire: The Koch’ang Kims and the Origins of Korean Capitalism, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Gragert, E. H. (1994) Landownership under Colonial Rule: Korea’s Japanese Experience, 1900–1935, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Han, S. J. (1974) The Failure of Democracy in South Korea, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Hanscom, C. P. and W. K. Lew, editors (2013) Imperatives of Culture: Selected Essays on Korean History, Literature, and Society from the Japanese Colonial Era, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Helgesen, G. (1998) Democracy and Authority in Korea: The Cultural Dimension in Korean Politics, New York, NY: St Martin’s Press. Henderson, G. (1968) Korea: The Politics of the Vortex, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Henry, T. A. (1914) Assimilating Seoul: Japanese Rule and the Politics of Public Space in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Hicks, G. (1995) The Comfort Women: Japan’s Brutal Regime of Enforced Prostitution in the Second World War, New York, NY: W.W. Norton. Jager, S. M. (2003) Narratives of Nation Building in Korea: A Genealogy of Patriotism, Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Jager, S. M. (2013) Brothers at War: The Unending Conflict in Korea, New York, NY: W.W. Norton. Johnson, C. (1987) “Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan,” in F. C. Deyo, editor, The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, pp. 136–64. Jun, S. H., J. B. Lewis and H. R. Kang (2009) “Stability or Decline? Demand or Supply?” The Journal of Economic History, 69:4 (December 2009): 1144–51. Kim, A. J. (1975) Divided Korea: The Politics of Development, 1945–1972, Cambridge, MA: East Asian Research Center, Harvard University Press. Kim, C. I. and H. K. Kim (1967) Korea and the Politics of Imperialism: 1876–1910, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Kim, C. S. (1998) A Nationalist Korean Entrepreneur: A Life History of Kim Song-su, Albany, NY: State University of New York Press. Kim, E. M. (1997) Big Business, Strong State: Collusion and Conflict in South Korean Development, 1960–1990, Albany, NY: State University of New York Press. Kim, J. (2009) To Live to Work: Factory Women in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Kim, K. H. (1980) The Last Phase of the East Asian World Order, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Kim, S. (2013) Everyday Life in the North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Koo, H. (2001) Korean Workers: The Culture and Pattern of Class Formation, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. 10

Understanding modern Korean history

Kotlin, S. and C. K. Armstrong (2006) “A Socialist Regional Order in Northeast Asia After World War II,” in C. K. Armstrong, G. Rozman, S. S. Kim, and S. Kotlin, editors, Korea at the Center: Dynamics of Regionalism in Northeast Asia, Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, pp. 110–25. Lankov, A. (2002) From Stalin to Kim Il Sung: The Formation of North Korea, 1945–1960, New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press. Lankov, A. (2013) The Real North Korea: Politics and Society in a Failed Socialist Utopia, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Larsen, K. W. (2008) Tradition, Treaties, and Trade: Qing Imperialism and Chosŏn Korea, 1850–1910, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Lee, C. S. (1978) The Korean Workers’ Party: A Short History, Stanford, CA: Stanford University, Hoover Institution Press. Lee, C. S. (2012) Park Chung-Hee: From Poverty to Power, Palos Verde, CA: KHU Press. Lee, H. Y. and C. W. Sorenson, editors (2013) Colonial Rule and Social Change in Korea, 1910–1945, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Lee, J. S. (2005) The Partition of Korea after World War II: A Global History, New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. Lee, N. (2007) The Making of Minjung: Democracy and the Politics of Representation in South Korea, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Lett, D. P. (1998) In Pursuit of Status: The Making of South Korea’s “New” Urban Middle Class, Cambridge, MA: East Asian Research Center, Harvard University Press. Lie, J. (1998) Han Unbound: The Political Economy of South Korea, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Lim, J. C. (2009) Kim Jong Il’s Leadership of North Korea, London: Routledge. McNamara. D. L. (1990) The Colonial Origins of Korean Enterprise, 1910–1945, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Migdal, J. S. (1988) Strong Societies and Weak States: State-Society Relations and State Capabilities in the Third World, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Moon, K. H. (1997) Sex among Allies: Military Prostitution in U.S.-Korea Relations, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Moon, S. (2005) Militarized Modernity and Gendered Citizenship in South Korea, Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Moon, Y. (2013) Populist Collaborators: The Ilchinhoe and the Japanese Colonization of Korea, 1896–1910, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Myers, B. R. (2010) The Cleanest Race: How North Korean See Themselves––And Why It Matters, Brooklyn, NY: Melville House. Myers, R. H. and M. R. Peattie, editors (1984) The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895–1945, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Nam, H. S. (2009) Building Ships, Building a Nation: Korea’s Democratic Unionism under Park Chung Hee, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Nelson, L. C. (2000) Measured Excess: Status, Gender, and Consumer Nationalism in South Korea, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Oh, I. G. (2000) Mafioso, Big Business and the Financial Crisis: The State-Business Relations in South Korea and Japan, Aldershot, England: Ashgate. Pai, H. I. (2000) Constructing Korean Origins: A Critical Review of Archaeology, Historiography, and Racial Myth in Korean State-Formation Theories, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Palmer, B. (2013) Fighting for the Enemy: Koreans in Japan’s War, 1937–1945, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Park, A. L. (2015) Building Heaven on Earth: Religion, Activism and Protest in Japanese Occupied Korea, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Park, S. (1999) Colonial Industrialization and Labor in Korea: The Onoda Cement Factory, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Person, J. F. (2006) “‘We Need Help from Outside:’ The North Korean Opposition Movement of 1956,” Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center, Cold War History Project. Robinson, M. E. (1988) Cultural Nationalism in Colonial Korea, 1920–1925, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Schmid, A. (2002) Korea Between Empires, 1895–1919, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Seth, M. J. (2002) Education Fever: Politics Society and the Pursuit of Schooling in South Korea, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. 11

Michael J. Seth

Shin, D. C. (1999) Mass Politics and Culture in Democratizing Korea, New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Shin, G. W. (1996) Peasant Protest and Social Change in Colonial Korea, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Shin, G. W. (2006) Ethnic Nationalism in Korea: Genealogy, Politics, and Legacy, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Shin, G. W. and M. Robinson, editors (2001) Colonial Modernity in Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. Soh, C. S. (2008) The Comfort Women: Sexual Violence and Postcolonial Memory in Korea and Japan, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Suh, D. (1988) Kim Il Sung: A Biography, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Uchida, J. (2011) Brokers of Empire: Japanese Settler Colonialism in Korea, 1876–1945, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Wada, H. (2014) The Korean War: An International History, Lantham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield. Wells, K. M. (1990) New God, New Nation: Protestants and Self-Reconstruction Nationalism in Korea, 1896–1937, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Woo, J. (1991) Race to the Swift: State and Finance in the Industrialization of Korea, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Yoo, T. J. (2008) The Politics of Gender in Colonial Korea: Education, Labor, and Health, 1910–1945, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Young, C. F. (2014) Eastern Learning and the Heavenly Way: The Tonghak and Ch’ŏndogyo Movements and the Twilight of Korean Independence. Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press.

12

Part I

Late Choso ˘n

This page intentionally left blank

2 Korea by 1860 James B. Lewis

Introduction Starting a Handbook of Modern Korean History with the late nineteenth century will naturally fail to plumb the depths of the rich tapestry that contributes to Korean notions of kingship, state, society, culture, foreign affairs, and a host of other things that populated the minds of nineteenthcentury Koreans. It is impossible to attempt a summation at the outset and not commit further violations against historical sensibilities, so the best I can do is to warn the reader that this essay can only suggest a few arguments, warnings, and suggestions about where we are beginning and how ignorant we really are. The first warning is already well known. We must resist ‘presentism’ and ‘futurism’. It is tempting to view the potential of the late Chosŏn period (from ca. 1600 onwards), and especially the nineteenth century before the Treaty of Kanghwa in 1876, as nothing more than a prelude to the storms that were to engulf Koreans in the latter half of the nineteenth century. After all, modern times are different from pre-modern times, and the discontinuities clearly overwhelm the continuities. By beginning with the late nineteenth century, we are announcing our concern with the creation of the modern world and only looking back for the origins of things that we know will come; why should we pause, even briefly, to survey the death throes of things that we know will not survive? Or, the reverse of that coin: if we must, let us identify who were the villains and who were the heroes who misread or who clearly read the future; where and when were the lost opportunities? Because we know that the Chosŏn state and society failed to resist Japanese imperialism and Koreans lost their sovereignty, we therefore run a significant risk towards engaging in a kind of perverse Whig history: ransacking the archives for the origins of later disasters or for wishful instances of potential salvation. Rather, we should take the nineteenth century in its own right and see it through the eyes of the people who knew their own past but, like most of us, could only dimly see their own future. Concern with the problems of ‘what went wrong’ or ‘who is to blame’ is common to later ages, like our own, when peace and security offer the luxury of hindsight. Just as Southern Song intellectuals pondered why the Northern Song was routed by barbarians, many of us in the twentieth and twenty-first centuries have long considered questions surrounding a failed ‘modernity’ in nineteenth-century Korea: How and why did the society and state that King 15

James B. Lewis

Sejong (r. 1418–1450) envisioned fail to cope with the challenges of the nineteenth century? What happened to the promise of the alleged golden age of Kings Yŏngjo (r. 1724–1776) and Chŏngjo (r. 1776–1800)? The Chosŏn state produced a general peace and prosperity for over five centuries and even survived a horrible invasion from Japan in the 1590s and further humiliations in 1627 and 1636 at the hands of the rising Manchus. What became of that peace, prosperity, and resilience by the nineteenth century? These are not bad questions if handled carefully. In drawing a sharp discontinuity between the pre-modern and the modern, scholars have developed a standard litany of explanations for why late Chosŏn state and society failed to meet the various problems of the nineteenth century: unresponsive and corrupt politics, the irrational and feudal nature of Korean-style Confucianism, and seriously worsening economic conditions. I argue that the internal crises met in a conjunction sometime between the 1830s and the 1860s, and then, from 1876, they were augmented by external threats beyond the control of Koreans. The problem for us is that we have often focused solely on the crises with judgemental hindsight, or sometimes wishful views, and in so doing we have overlooked the rationality and ‘modernity’ that had held state and society together. This essay is highly selective and attempts to raise only a few questions and point to a handful of departures for research. It is not comprehensive of the rich and extensive secondary literature that is developing, and I would encourage the reader to follow the growing body of literature in English and to tap the sea of outstanding work in the Korean and Japanese languages. My overarching argument is very simple: we would benefit by rejecting the notion of a disjuncture between the ‘modern’ and the ‘pre-modern’, which was originally designed to explain European scientific and technological prowess and came to generalise the European political and social transition from feudal, ascriptive societies to post-feudal, meritocratic societies.1 Korean society was not technologically advanced but neither was it backward; it was post-feudal and meritocratic, however imperfectly achieved, and had been meritocratic or at least meritocratically oriented stretching back into the Koryŏ period. Chosŏn political and social, and in some ways even economic, ‘modernities’ pre-dated European modernities. Therefore, if we wish to gain a comparative understanding of Chosŏn state and society in their twilight decades, I would argue that we should approach them in search of their strengths as well as their weaknesses and consider aspects of ‘modern rationality’2 in pre-1876 Korea.

The inherent weaknesses of meritocratic bureaucracies and corruption King Chŏngjo was nearly ten years old when his father was starved to death by his grandfather, King Yŏngjo. His father, Prince Sado, never became king, and that sad tale is related in the outstanding contribution offered by Jahyun Kim Haboush’s translation of the writings by Prince Sado’s widow, Lady Hyegyŏng (Haboush 1996). There we can glimpse the monstrous ideological and political pressures on the royal family and the monstrous results they produced in driving Prince Sado to become a psychopathic murderer. The ten-year-old boy, who was to become King Chŏngjo, was favoured by his grandfather and succeeded King Yŏngjo at age twenty-three. He carried on the attention to good governance established by his grandfather, and his accomplishments were extensive. He established the Kyujanggak, the Royal Library, in 1776 to function as a focus for creative statecraft, bringing to mind the Chiphyŏnjŏn of King Sejong’s time. He built the Hwasŏng Fortress in Suwŏn between 1794 and 1796 to commemorate his father and created a satellite city for the capital. He carried forward his grandfather’s vision of reforming the Chosŏn state and updating the fundamental charters of the state to meet the 16

Korea by 1860

needs of their times. He carried on King Yŏngjo’s t’angp’yŏng ch’aek or the policy of rotating factional appointments to placate court factions and dampen their rivalry. Revised or new publications were continued or originated for state ritual (Sok oryeŭi 1744), diplomacy (Tongmun hwigo 1788), history (Kukcho pogam 1782), legal codes (Taejŏn t’ongp’yŏn 1785), literature (Munwŏn pobul 1787 and Hongjae chŏnsŏ 1799), language (Kyujang chŏn’un 1796), reference works (Chŭngbo tongguk munhŏn pigo, begun in 1770), and didactic literature (Oryun haengsil[-to] 1797). He knew and sponsored the leading intellectuals of the time: Pak Chiwŏn (1737–1805), Chŏng Yagyong (1762–1836), Yu Tŭkkong (1749–1807), and Pak Chega (1750–1815). Just a few months before turning forty-eight in 1800, King Chŏngjo died. His sudden death engendered suspicions that have yet to be settled. Although we have an excellent study by Jahyun Kim Haboush of King Yŏngjo’s reign and the motivations of the king (Haboush 1988, 2001), we lack a good study of King Chŏngjo’s reign and of the man and his world. Politics took a turn for the worse with the enthronement in the seventh lunar month of 1800 of King Chŏngjo’s successor, King Sunjo (r. 1800–1834), who ascended the throne in the same month he became ten years old. Until 1804, Chosŏn was governed by a regent (Queen Chŏngsun, 1745–1805), a Kyŏngju Kim woman, who authorised a Catholic persecution in 1801 and allowed the Noron (‘Old Doctrine’ faction or ‘Patriarch’s Faction’) to come to the fore. King Sunjo married an Andong Kim woman (Queen Sunwŏn, 1789–1857), died at age fortyfour, and his queen later served as regent for two kings: 1834–1841 and again in 1849–1852, firmly placing the Andong Kim clan in a position to exploit power to drain the state fiscally. The first regency was for King Hŏnjong (r. 1834–1849), a grandson who took the throne at seven and died at age twenty-one. A second Catholic persecution was launched in 1839, and in 1840, King Hŏnjong’s mother’s clan, the P’ungyang Cho, briefly took power until 1849, when Queen Sunwŏn (and the Andong Kim clan) returned to power as regent. The second regency was for King Ch’ŏljong (r. 1849–1863). Although he ascended the throne at age eighteen, he may have been illiterate, thus allowing the Andong Kim to continue their in-law rule of the state. King Ch’ŏljong was succeeded by King Kojong (r. 1863–1907), who also rose to the throne as a minor, age eleven. His father was thought malleable by the Cho and Kim clans, and the father was made regent with the title Hŭngsŏn Taewŏn’gun. He is commonly known as the Taewŏn’gun (1820–1898, regency 1863–1873). In other words, from 1800 to the 1860s, control of the Chosŏn state shifted from the court to the in-law clan councils with the result that the machinery of state lost its apical arbiter, reflexive action became very difficult, and corruption spread downwards even to local administration. If the Chosŏn state had not persecuted Christians (i.e., Catholics) from 1801 to 1873, then a Christian connection may have opened an opportunity from the late eighteenth century for Chosŏn society to gain access to the wider world. This argument would have us consider that such access may have contributed to ‘modernization’ in Korea and prevented colonization by 1905, but this argument is trapped in the pathology of a single locus of modernity. The persecution of 1801 was triggered by a perceived threat to the state (high treason as embodied by a letter from a Korean Christian to the Bishop of Beijing requesting support from the French Far East Fleet) and also by the ideological and social threats lurking within the displacement of loyalty to a ‘transcendent object’, the shift to subjectivity (Torrey 2012: 129), and the insinuation of egalitarianism. High treason was entirely adequate to launch a persecution, but the wider significance of the persecution was that it marked the end of a period of tolerance at the court for diverse ideas and allowed a conservative faction (Noron) to police orthodoxy, giving it the power to turn on its rival factions (particularly the Nam’in or ‘Southerner’ faction) with charges of entertaining heterodoxy. Koreans were not ignorant of Christianity. Fr. Gregorio de Cespedes probably converted captured Koreans in Japan in the 1590s. Korean intellectuals had known 17

James B. Lewis

of Christianity from the early seventeenth century via Beijing (Baker 2012: 2), and Koreans influenced by their experiences in Beijing had begun professing Christianity by the 1780s. There was an official persecution in 1785; and by the end of 1794, a Chinese-ordained priest arrived (Cawley 2013: 24 ff.). Leading, experimental intellectuals such as Chŏng Yagyong, who had been close to King Chŏngjo, were implicated in the persecution, as were a number of others associated with the Nam’in faction. Scholars debate the impact of Christianity from the late eighteenth century. Perhaps intellectuals re-fashioned their epistemology after exposure to Catholicism (Torrey 2012: 129), or, perhaps Christian individualism and a greater respect for women were inserted into society and had some effect (Choi 2012).3 But, did a reactionary Confucian mandarinate close off the opportunity to profit from contact with Europeans and Americans and modernise their society? The problem is again ‘modernity’. The mandarinate and the yangban very likely considered themselves to be ‘modern’, if we take that to indicate developed forms of rationality not entirely bounded by feudal claims to authority. Catholicism had long ago alienated itself from Chosŏn and probably most East Asian societies by the 1715 Papal Bull declaring that converts could not practice ancestral rites or attend Confucian temples. Kwŏn Kŭn (1352–1409), as early as the fourteenth century, had clarified that ancestral ritual was not religious, that its practice was not a worship of some ‘subtle animating principle that coheres and does not die, but . . . remains in some boundless realm’ (Lee, Vol. 1, 1993: 606). Although the Papal authority had no access to Kwŏn Kŭn’s arguments, they did reject Jesuit and Chinese arguments that ancestral rites were a civil rite and so failed to appreciate the ‘modern’ nature of the societies in which the rites took place. How could Pope Clement XI (r. 1700–1721) have even understood their arguments? European society had not yet rejected the feudal legitimation of authority in which religion, politics, and inheritance were indistinguishable. No European state had yet to establish a meritocratic bureaucracy. The Pope could not be expected to understand that filial piety was the centrepiece of the construction of loyalty to king and state in a post-feudal, meritocratic society. Even the construction of political loyalty most commonly used in East Asia for millennia has still never been seen in Europe. Whereas Europe and Japan used feudal inheritance or patronclient relations and later mass nationalism to create loyalty to king and state, the post-feudal mandarinates of East Asia (China, Korea, and Vietnam) had, at least from the Song Dynasty, called on Confucian ethics to overcome the self-esteem deficit among mandarins. The mandarins’ ‘self-esteem deficit’ (Woodside 2006: 46–55) derived from the nature of meritocratic bureaucracy: if they were lucky enough to have an appointment, the mandarins had been objectively qualified to staff a bureaucracy by preparing for examinations (at the most prestigious level) that did not test practical knowledge, and after appointment they had to endure humiliating performance-based accountability exercises that eroded their self-image as moral leaders. Korean mandarins were often driven to be focused more on their own careers than on public service. This problem now increasingly confronts most contemporary governments and corporations, but it is not new. The problem is how to counter careerism and obtain loyalty and dedication. Ironically, they drew on feudal virtues of hierarchy and duty to give themselves greater purpose within a ‘modern’, impersonal institution. Filial piety (with its associate virtues in ‘chaste women’ and ‘loyal ministers’) ameliorated the mandarins’ alienation by offering them a noble vision of themselves and their actions.4 UK Whitehall mandarins draw on a sense of clientage to the British monarch to satisfy similar needs, but while Whitehall mandarins might compose position papers on care for the aged, they will never enthuse on the virtues of filial piety or link that to loyalty to the state. Confucian ethics also ameliorated the ‘solidarity deficit’ (Woodside 2006: 70–74) between the mandarins and most of the people. The mandarins obtained their positions by demonstrating 18

Korea by 1860

a mastery of texts and were prone to suffer from bureaucratic subjectivity or a preference for the mastery of texts, what we might call models concocted by inter-agency policy councils and external consultants, over direct experience. The mandarins solipsistically and self-righteously created visions of society that local people either could not comprehend or could not feel any reason to act on and so met the mandarins’ initiatives with apathy and non-compliance. Public and private rituals that celebrated filial piety (with their ‘archery rituals’ and ‘wine-drinking rituals’) as well as quasi-legal community compacts were attempts at artificially creating corporate communities that would help enact the bureaucracy’s visions. In these connections, to reject filial piety was not a religious matter at all. Rejecting the continuity of lineage was political. It was a threat to the virtues that supported the fundamental management principles of the state, to say nothing of the personal and social problems attendant on the implied rejection of identity, status, and patronage. All this is not to say that politics did not narrow from the public space of factional debate to the kitchen governments of in-law clans or that corruption did not grow. That did happen from King Chŏngjo’s death onwards. But even factional struggle itself was much more than the pursuit of self-interest. Widespread debates that involved yangban in and out of government and occasionally crossed factional lines usually displayed sincere motivations at work in the consideration of subjects as profound as Korean identity (Haboush 1999). Again, the intensity and depth of such debates reflected the strength of the meritocratic order, where most yangban had passed even more stringent examinations than most Western universities now conduct and considered themselves informed and meritorious. Such confidence, however, can easily spill over into self-righteousness. Over the seventeenth century and certainly by the eighteenth century, Korean mandarins and the wider yangban ‘public’ (Haboush 2009) were accustomed to extensive and widespread debate on Confucian ethics and their political applications. The number of Chosŏn academies (sŏwŏn) per capita may have far eclipsed the number of Chinese academies per capita (Woodside 2006: 22–23), and the academies certainly took their role as sites of Confucian cultivation very seriously (Ch’oe 1999). The yangban may have been ‘too publicspirited, with an individual and group moral zealousness that could not be harmonized enough with that of others to permit the empire’s governance’ (Woodside 2006: 42–43) and therein we see factional struggle. The problem in nineteenth-century Korea was that Korean kingship in the Chosŏn period (and even earlier) had rarely been strong, much less autocratic. Strong leadership should not be confused with autocracy. Strong leadership makes decisions when government is divided. When King Chŏngjo passed from the scene in 1800 and boys were placed on the throne over the course of the nineteenth century, the state possessed even weaker authority to mediate who was most meritorious and deserving and to impose discipline on the corrupt and criminal. Although we know the political fortunes of those decades and some of the results of misrule, we still lack extensive studies on the politics of the court, the involvement of the clans, and the actual conduct of governance. We are fortunate to have very good studies that focus on the time from the early 1860s when state mechanisms were being refurbished so that central negligence could be overcome and state efficacy could be strengthened. When the Taewŏn’gun became regent from early 1864, he consciously set about trying to establish a clear mediating authority by amalgamating power and resources around the throne (Choe 1972 and Palais 1975). He had mixed results, but before the project could be carried forward, imperialistic pressures came to bear on the kingdom from the outside. The main problem was (and is today still) that meritocratic bureaucracies are inherently weaker at creating loyalty than loyalties based on feudalistic patron-client relations or on massbased nationalisms or on religious sectarianism, and the pressures on that Korean state weakness after 1876 became overwhelming (Woodside 2006: 10). In short, Chosŏn Korea was quite ‘modern’ already. 19

James B. Lewis

Response from the ruled and the strength of Confucianism While the ruled are always unruly, the nineteenth century was a century marked by many rebellions (seventy tax revolts in 1862 alone) (Kim 2007b: 993). Studies of rebellions in earlier centuries offer comparative benchmarks, and fortunately, we now have good studies of the major rebellions of 1728, 1812, and 1862 that allow us to catch a view of the quality of Chosŏn governance over quite a long period. These studies offer glimpses of local society as well. Rebellions generate reports, statements, manifestoes, and other documents, and these documents offer historians a window on locality. We need more such windows. In short, we need more micro-history and not just of trying times but of ordinary times, as well. In these important micro-studies of rebellions, we can also see the inadequacies of higher officials’ bureaucratic subjectivity, the breakdown of practical application of governance, and the complexities of local societies. Consistently, the studies reveal attempts by local (and sometimes even central) elites to mobilise ordinary people to participate in rebellion, belying analyses that rely on class warfare. For example, the Musillan Rebellion of 1728 (named after the year) was an affair of high politics and was focused on a possible coup d’état (Jackson forthcoming). The Hong Kyŏngnae Rebellion of 1812 (named after its putative leader) grew from a conflict between central and local elites over dwindling resources that was complicated by the peculiarities of the northern region (more mercantile than agricultural and often the object of discrimination) (Karlsson 2000 and Kim 2007a). The Chinju Rebellion of 1862 (named after the place) sprang from a tax-resistance movement among local elites and indicted arbitrary taxation and extreme corruption among local officials and clerks (Kim 2007b). Additionally, both the 1812 Hong Kyŏngnae Rebellion in the north and the 1862 Chinju Rebellion in the south had complex economic circumstances behind them: increasing monetization of the economy and increasing competition between centre and locality over control of resources. Although prophecies and messianic messages appeared in 1811–12, a focus on these can obscure the essential ‘modern’ characteristics of the nineteenth-century rebellions: competition over control of the instruments of state, competition over resources in changing economic circumstances, and calls for an end to corruption. It also appears that the assumed rationality of the state structure was so strong that, despite increasing class polarization and social stratification, the 1812 rebels were engaged in a ‘defensive’ exercise and did not seek to create a new state (Karlsson 2000: 275). Belief in the dominant ideology was still so strong in the 1860s that Confucian ideals of justice could be construed to condone violent resistance in the 1862 Chinju Rebellion without calling for the overthrow of the state (Kim 2007b: 1018). Although feudal in origin, Confucian ideology had been appropriated as long ago as the Han Dynasty to shore up a post-feudal, rational bureaucratic vision that was clearly still strong in nineteenth-century Korea. Problems inevitably occurred, however, when the centre received incomplete or false data, and in the course of imposing its vision, the situation worsened when difficulties, such as local rebellions, appeared that required clear mediation. Hence, in the course of the centre depriving the provinces of resources or seeking to extend central control over local resources, the administrators on the ground were forced to invent new taxes to fill the deficits opening up in their accounts. In 1862, the central government took notice of this problem and devised reforms of land, military, and the grain loan tax structures that would have reformed local administration up and down the country, but the reforms lapsed and were abandoned in the midst of royal succession in the capital (Kim 2007b: 1017–1018). Although modern bureaucracies such as the Chosŏn state engaged reflexively in knowledge acquisition and analysis, the weakness of bureaucratic subjectivity was never far away. The mandarins had acquired their positions from the mastery of classical texts and recruitment through 20

Korea by 1860

exams that tested their knowledge of classical texts. Their accomplishments were powerfully self-reinforcing and imparted a feeling of ‘book-based omniscience’, which mirrored the Enlightenment belief ‘that the rationalist use of mathematical and scientific thinking procedures could make the entire world calculable’ (Woodside 2006: 82). Administrators in the centre operating from bad or incomplete data and captive to their subjectivity not only risked devising inappropriate policies, but also commonly ‘mythologize[d] the desired future in such a textbound way that the future became an intellectually closed domain whose definition was controlled almost entirely by bureaucratic elites’ (Woodside 2006: 94). Note that this problem applies to any post-feudal bureaucracy, not just to those dominated by Confucian ethics. Although Confucian ethics apotheosis the Zhou, it does not mean that nineteenth-century Korean mandarins wanted to return to the sixth or fifth century BCE. They could be just as self-reflective and future-oriented as twenty-first century bureaucracies, but the mandarins monopolised the language needed to discuss the future, and from that monopoly they derived their power. Herein lies the strength of the firebrand conservative Yi Hang-no (1792–1868) (Chung 1995), who railed against compromise with the West and Japan. Foreign ideologies were not just alternative views of society, politics, and just about everything else; they were rejections of the basis of the Korean post-feudal, rational bureaucratic order.

Macroeconomic models and capitalist rationality Controversy surrounds the economy of the late Chosŏn period. Some (Jun and Lewis 2006; Jun et al. 2008, 2009) argue that from the late seventeenth century, over the eighteenth century, and into the early decades of the nineteenth century was a period of prosperity and stability. This could be called an ‘efflorescence’ or a time in which economic expansion and creative innovation expanded rather rapidly only to be followed by a collapse (Goldstone 2002: 333–334), and in Korea’s case that collapse came in the nineteenth century. The ‘efflorescence’ of the late seventeenth and eighteenth centuries was a case of Smithian growth or total economic growth in which the land market expanded because it was protected by legally recognised property rights that were strengthened after the Imjin Waeran of 1592–1598 to encourage farming.5 Although land rents and land prices were declining, which suggest declining productivity, land conversion from dry fields to paddy was expanding, resulting in an expansion of available paddy land. More available land, in part spurred by speculation, contributed to declining land rents and land prices: the quantity of paddy land was expanding but its quality was declining from the early nineteenth century. There was an increase in prosperity in agricultural production over the eighteenth century because surpluses were sufficient to buoy up skilled wages and support high prices for manufactured goods, which were traded in expanded and integrated markets. Rice prices stabilised and rice price volatility fell over the eighteenth century as production expanded and markets integrated, but prices and volatility then began rising again from the middle of the nineteenth century as systemic collapse began. General grain prices had been stable over the eighteenth century and lower than the prices of manufactured goods, but that relationship reversed itself from the 1830s when food prices began to rise and the prices of manufactures began to fall, indicating that the structures of food production were decaying and surpluses that had supported the prices of manufactures were disappearing. Government had supplied infrastructure for irrigation and social welfare as grain storage and tax exemptions for bad harvests, but from the early nineteenth century, government investment in irrigation fell off considerably, grain storage became a target for corrupt officials, and tax exemptions ceased to be related to agricultural production from around 1860. Heavier rains over the nineteenth century washed over progressively deforested (Totman 2004) hillsides and 21

James B. Lewis

silted up rivers and irrigation infrastructure, which were no longer being maintained. Imperial pressures after 1876 opened up new economic dynamics and distracted government, thereby considerably worsening matters. Others dispute this depiction and argue that recovery from the Imjin War did occur in the seventeenth century only to be followed by long, slow decline from around 1700 to a nadir that was reached in the late nineteenth century. From 1700 until the late nineteenth century, declining real government wages, the declining price of labour, and declining land rent indicate a decline in productivity, not a rise (Cha 2009). Declining land rents are mirrored by declining land prices, and both reflect declining land productivity as a result of advancing deforestation. The decline in land productivity was somewhat offset by the state dedication to storage that offered greater food security and encouraged the production of cash crops and domestic manufactures. Nevertheless, markets contracted after the mid-eighteenth century as trade with Japan was considerably curtailed from 1745 and trade with China went into deficit. Confucian ideology was ‘dogmatic’ and ‘destroyed incentives to work hard and stifled savings and investment. Instead, the Confucian ideology encouraged people to improve their social and political status by means of rent-seeking activities’ (Rhee 2014: 10). The ‘stagnation, recession, and crisis’ of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries ‘were so deep and serious as to cause Korea eventually to be occupied by Japan’ (Rhee 2014: 2). The overall macroeconomic situation for the eighteenth century is debatable, but there is a general consensus that the nineteenth century, especially from around the 1830s onwards, saw serious decline. There is a lot of work that needs to be done to test these models and devise alternatives. Unlike literary studies or political history, economic history relies on quantitative data-gathering and analysis and is difficult for individuals. Partnerships with Korean and Japanese scholars can be very fruitful. We need to reach a finer-grained resolution on regional economies for the distribution of products and land use. We need more work on demographic and population history and to come to terms with very difficult questions related to biased reporting and small data samples. Research into quality of life indicators (e.g., height) has just begun and is still fraught with difficulties (Lewis et al. 2013). Work needs to be done on the prevalence of endemic disease, water quality, hygiene, and other determinants of the quality of life. If we return to the theme of ‘modern’ rationalities lurking in what was supposedly a ‘premodern’ and ‘pre-rational’ world, we can find multiple examples of ‘modern’ rationality at work in the pre-1876 Korean economy. For example, we know that a full-blown, apparently indigenous, double-entry accounting method was practiced by Kaesŏng merchants from at least as far back as the 1780s and probably earlier (Jun et al. 2013), and we can find its echo in the accounts of non-profit agricultural cooperatives from the 1740s (Jun and Lewis 2006) as well as in the accounts of eighteenth-century Confucian academies. The extraordinary sophistication of these accounts is remarkable enough, but the contents reveal capitalistic activities. Vast sums were being deployed as investments in ginseng with its six-year term of maturity. There were significant merchant groups in Kaesŏng (Kang 1978), Seoul (Kang 1979), and Tongnae (Kim 2004), aside from those merchants who possessed retail monopolies in the centre of Seoul, which will be discussed in a later essay in this volume, but we still know very little about the lives and commercial activities of Korean merchants.

Conclusion Our greatest challenge is to overcome assumptions about what constitutes our world and not confuse technological intensification with institutional sophistication. In short, we have to come to doubt the following definition of modernity: 22

Korea by 1860

When we speak of modernity, however, we refer to institutional transformations that have their origins in the West. . . . In terms of institutional clustering, two distinct organisational complexes are of particular significance in the development of modernity: the nation-state and systematic capitalist production. Both have their roots in specific characteristics of European history and have few parallels in prior periods or in other cultural settings. . . . Is modernity distinctively a Western project in terms of the ways of life fostered by these two great transformative agencies? To this query, the blunt answer must be “yes.” (Giddens 1990: 174–175) If we think that our capitalist nation-states are the height of rationality and that there is a clear disjuncture between pre-modern irrational behaviour and rational modern behaviour, then we risk reducing human history before the railroad to a timeless, agricultural idyll or a dark, oppressive purgatory, depending on your preference. What is worse, we risk dismissing the rest of the world outside Europe to a place where people simply waited to be given what Europeans had made in their workshop and finally we risk ignoring lessons to be learned from the deep experiences Koreans have had with post-feudal, rational structures.

Glossary Chiphyŏnjŏn (集賢殿) Hall of Worthies Chŏljong (哲宗) King Chŏng Yagyong (丁若鏞, 1762–1836) personal name Chŏngjo (正祖) King Chŏngsun wanghu (貞純王后, 1745–1805) Queen Chŭngbo tongguk munhŏn pigo (增補東國文獻備考, begun in 1770) Supplemented Reference Compilation of Documents on Korea Hongjae chŏnsŏ (弘齋全書, 1799) Collected Poems Hŏnjong (憲宗) King Hong Kyŏngnae (洪景來, 1780–1812) personal name Hŭngsŏn Taewŏn'gun (興宣大院君, 1820–1898, regency 1863–1873) Hwasŏng (華城) place name Imjin Waeran (壬辰倭亂) Imjin War or Hideyoshi’s Invasion of Korea Kaesŏng (開城) place name Kojong (高宗) King Kukcho pogam (國朝寶鑑, 1782) Precious Mirror for Succeeding Reigns Kwŏn Kŭn (權近, 1352–1409) personal name Kyujang chŏn’un (奎章全韻, 1796) A Complete Rhyming Dictionary Munwŏn pobul (文苑黼黻, 1787) Beautiful Literature Musillan (戊申亂) name of rebellion Nam’in (南人) Southerners’ faction nobi (奴婢) un-free labour Noron (老論) Old Doctrine Faction or Patriarch’s Faction Oryun haengsil[-to] (五倫行實[-圖], 1797) The [Illustrated] Five Moral Rules Pak Chega (朴齊家, 1750–1815) personal name Pak Chiwŏn (朴趾源, 1737–1805) personal name P’ungyang Cho (豊壤趙氏) Cho clan of P’ungyang Sok oryeŭi ([國朝]續五禮儀, 1744) Extended Five Rites of State sŏwŏn (書院) private academy 23

James B. Lewis

Sunjo (純祖) King Sunwŏn wanghu (純元王后, 1789–1857) Queen Suwŏn (水原市) place name Taejŏn t’ongp’yŏn (大典通編, 1785) Comprehensive National Code t’angp’yŏng ch’aek (蕩平策) Policy of Impartiality Tongmun hwigo (同文彙考, 1788) Diplomatic Letters Tongnae (東萊) place name yangban (兩班) civil and military officials Yi Hang-no (李恒老, 1792–1868) personal name Yŏngjo (英祖) King Yu Tŭkkong (柳得恭, 1749–1807) personal name Zhou (周) Chinese dynasty

Notes 1

2 3

4

5

24

Looking for societies dominated by capitalism or organised as nation-states as universal markers of modernity is probably a dead end because these characteristics seem too peculiar to Europe. Setting aside capitalism and the nation-state, we should consider the constitution of the ‘modern’ mind. Although Anthony Giddens clings to the nation-state and occasionally capitalism, he also offers us a summation of ‘modernity’ as a project to develop impersonal patterns of thinking (Giddens 1990: 53–54). His ideas rest on ‘disembedding’ and the ‘reflexive appropriation of knowledge’. Disembedding begins with the separation of time and space from place, so that time and space can be ‘emptied’ and standardised without regard to locality. Further disembedding is achieved through ‘symbolic tokens’ and ‘expert systems’ that require trust (with a sense of risk), not confidence. Therefore, the transition from premodern to modern is the reorientation of perspectives from who and where people are to what functions, almost entirely impersonal, that people perform. Finally, knowledge is reflexively acquired and applied: ‘social practices are constantly examined and reformed in the light of incoming information about those very practices, thus constitutively altering their character’ (Giddens 1990: 38). The constant alteration means that knowledge does not produce certainty. The paradigmatic example of this is the perspective of the natural sciences where certainty only lasts until the next laboratory test. Any appeal to prior custom or practice carries no value, and change is normal and expected. ‘Disembedding’ and the ‘reflexive appropriation of knowledge’ were part of the scaffolding of pre-modern East Asian bureaucracies. Capitalism (Marx) and industrialism (Durkheim) did not come to dominate Chosŏn society, but rationality (Weber) did (Giddens 1990: 11–12). The question of Christian conversion among Chosŏn intellectuals is an excellent entry point to examine fundamental questions of ontology, cosmology, metaphysics, belief, and the self and the state and still has yet to be extensively explored in a self-conscious comparative framework that relativises assumptions about modernity. We might compare Korean individualism in a post-feudal society with European individualism in feudal societies and examine the significance of the hierarchical nature of Catholicism in comparison with Confucianism. Yi Saek (1328–1396) equates filial piety with loyalty. See 伯中說贈李狀元別 (‘On the courtesy name of Paekchung: Presented to the First Place Laureate Yi at parting’) in the fifteenth-century literary compilation, the Tongmunsŏn (東文選), book 97: ‘When you serve your parents well, it is called filial piety. When it is shifted to the lord, it is called loyalty. The terms (filial piety and loyalty) may be different, but the principle is the same’. In Korea (and possibly in China), the land market was a larger part of economic activity than labour markets or capital markets; the land market was highly liquid and property rights probably more protected than in Europe, but European labour and capital markets were more extensive, better protected, and more elaborated.

Korea by 1860

References Baker, Don. (2012) ‘The Korean Catholic Church’s First Hundred Years: Guest Editor’s Introduction’, Acta Koreana 15:1 (2012): 1–14. Cawley, Kevin. (2012) ‘Deconstructing Hegemony: Catholic Texts in Chosŏn’s Neo-Confucian Context’, Acta Koreana 15:1 (2012): 15–42. Cha, Myung Soo. (2009) ‘Productivity Trend in Korea from the Seventeenth to Nineteenth Century: A Comment on Jun, Lewis, and Kang’, The Journal of Economic History 69:4 (December 2009): 1138–1143. Choe, Ching Young. (1972) The Rule of the Taewŏn’gun, 1864–1873: Restoration in Yi Korea, Cambridge, MA: East Asian Research Center, Harvard University Press. Ch’oe, Yŏng-ho. (1999) ‘Private Academies and the State in Late Chosŏn Korea’ in JaHyun Kim Haboush and Martina Deuchler (eds.) Culture and the State in Late Chosŏn Korea, Cambridge, MA: HarvardHallym Series on Korean Studies, pp. 15–45. Choi, Seon-hye. (2012) ‘The Holy Mother and the Son of God: A Sonte Cast at Patriarchal Society in Late Chosŏn Korea’, Acta Koreana 15:1 (2012): 107–126. Chung, Chai-sik. (1995) A Korean Confucian Encounter with the Modern World: Yi Hang-no and the West, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Giddens, Anthony. (1990) The Consequences of Modernity, London: Polity Press. Goldstone, Jack A. (2002) ‘Efflorescences and Economic Growth in World History: Rethinking the “Rise of the West” and the Industrial Revolution’, Journal of World History 13:2 (2002): 323–389. Haboush, JaHyun Kim, trans. (1996) The Memoirs of Lady Hyegyong: The Autobiographical Writings of a Crown Princess of Eighteenth-Century Korea, Berkeley, CA; London: University of California Press. Haboush, JaHyun Kim. (1999) ‘Constructing the Center: The Ritual Controversy and the Search for a New Identity in Seventeenth-Century Korea’ in JaHyun Kim Haboush and Martina Deuchler (eds.) Culture and the State in Late Chosŏn Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard-Hallym Series on Korean Studies, pp. 46–90. Haboush, JaHyun Kim. (2001) A Heritage of Kings: One Man’s Monarchy in the Confucian World, New York, NY: Columbia University Press, 1988; reprinted with a new preface as The Confucian Kingship in Korea: Yŏngjo and the Politics of Sagacity, New York: Columbia University Press. Haboush, JaHyun Kim, ed. (2009) Epistolary Korea: Letters in the Communicative Space of the Chosŏn, 1392–1910, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Jackson, Andrew. (2011) ‘The Musillan rebellion of 1728, resources and the fifth-columnists’, unpublished PhD dissertation, SOAS, University of London. Jun, Seong-Ho and James B. Lewis. (2006) ‘Accounting Techniques in Korea: Eighteenth-Century Archival Samples from a Non-Profit Association in the Sinitic World’. Second author (corresponding) with S. H. Jun. Accounting Historians Journal, 33:1 (June 2006): 53–87. Jun, Seong-Ho and James B. Lewis. (2006) ‘Wages, Rents, and Interest Rates in Southern Korea, 1700 to 1900’, in Field, Alexander J., Gregory Clark, and William A. Sundstrom, eds., Research in Economic History, University of California, Vol. 24 (2006): 221–281. Jun, Seong-Ho, James B. Lewis, and Han-Rog Kang. (2008) ‘Korean Expansion and Decline from the Seventeenth to the Nineteenth Century: A View Suggested by Adam Smith’, The Journal of Economic History, 68:1 (March 2008): 244–282. Jun, Seong-Ho, James B. Lewis, and Han-Rog Kang. (2009) ‘Stability or Decline? Demand or Supply?’, The Journal of Economic History, 69:4 (December 2009): 1143–1150. Jun, Seong-Ho, James B. Lewis, and Sung-Kwan Huh. (2013) ‘Korean Double-Entry Merchant Accounts from Kaesŏng City (1786–1892)’, Sungkyun Journal of East Asian Studies, 13:2 (October 2013): 105–148. Kang, Man-gil. (1978) ‘Merchants of Kaesong’ in International Cultural Foundation, ed. Economic Life in Korea, Seoul: The Si-sa-yong-o-sa Publishers, Inc. Kang, Man-gil. (1979) ‘Research on the Han River Merchants’, Korea Journal, 19:3 (March 1979): 21–32. Karlsson, Anders. (2000) The Hong Kyŏngnae Rebellion 1811–1812: Conflict between Central Power and Local Society in Nineteenth-Century Korea, Stockholm: University of Stockholm. Kim, Dongchul. (2004) ‘The Waegwan Open Market Trade and Merchants in the Late Chosŏn Period’, Acta Koreana, 7:1 (2004): 9–46. Kim, Sun Joo. (2007a) Marginality and Subversion in Korea: The Hong Kyŏngnae Rebellion of 1812, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. 25

James B. Lewis

Kim, Sun Joo. (2007b) ‘Taxes, the Local Elite, and the Rural Populace in the Chinju Uprising of 1862’, The Journal of Asian Studies, 66:4 (2007): 993–1027b. Lee, Peter H. with Donald Baker (eds.). (1993–1996) Sourcebook of Korean Civilization, Vol.1: From Early Times to the Sixteenth Century and Vol. 2: From the Seventeenth Century to the Modern Period, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Lewis, James B., Jun Seong Ho, and Daniel Schwenkendiek. (2013) ‘Toward an Anthropometric History of Chosŏn Dynasty Korea, Sixteenth to Eighteenth Century’, The Journal of the Historical Society, 13:3 (September 2013): 239–270. Palais, James B. (1975) Politics and Policy in Traditional Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Rausch, Franklin. (2012) ‘Like Birds and Beasts: Justifying Violence Against Catholics in Late Chosŏn Korea’, Acta Koreana, 15:1 (2012): 43–71. Rhee, Young Hoon. (2014) ‘Economic stagnation and crisis in Korea during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries’, Australian Economic History Review: An Asia-Pacific Journal of Economic, Business and Social History, 54:1 (March 2014): 1–13. Roux, Pierre-Emmanuel. (2012) ‘The Great Ming Code and the Repression of Catholics in Chosŏn Korea’, Acta Koreana, 15:1 (2012): 73–106. Tongmunsŏn ((東文選). Han’guk kojŏn chonghap DB (한국고전종합 DB), established and maintained by the Han’guk kojŏn pŏn’yŏgwŏn (한 국 고 전 번 역 원 ). Available online at http://db.itkc.or.kr/index. jsp?bizName=KO&url=/itkcdb/text/bookListIframe.jsp?bizName=KO&seojiId=kc_ko_c006&gunchaId =&NodeId=&setid=242365 (accessed 26 March 2015). Torrey, Deberniere Janet. (2012) ‘Separating from the Confucian World: The Shift Away from Syncretism in Early Korean Catholic Texts’, Acta Koreana, 15:1 (2012): 127–145. Totman, Conrad. (2004) Pre-industrial Korea and Japan in Environmental Perspective, Leiden: Brill. Woodside, Alexander. (2006) Lost Modernities: China, Vietnam, Korea, and the Hazards of World History, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

26

3 Competing imperialisms in Korea Kirk W. Larsen

The story of nineteenth- and early twentieth-century Korea is, in many ways, a story of competing imperialisms. For many Koreans, this story is a straightforward and tragic account of increasing Japanese power and domination on the peninsula, culminating in Meiji Japan’s formal annexation of Korea in 1910. This quest had political, military, and economic dimensions. The Japanese imperialists had to contend with an often-defiant Korean populace as well as foreign competitors, chief among them the Qing Empire (China) and Czarist Russia. But as Japan overcame these obstacles, its annexation of Korea seemed inevitable. Some of the scholarship on this period has focused on the question of who or what is to blame for Korea’s inability to defend itself against the Japanese advances—was it the feckless King Kojong; his father, the “Grand Prince” Taewŏn’gun; the yangban aristocratic elite; the unwanted meddling of Qing China; the negligence or betrayal of the United States; or some other factor?1 However, most appear to assume that Japan’s ultimate domination of Korea was more or less inevitable. While scholarly research has demonstrated that the actual process of Japanese imperialism in Korea was filled with far more contingencies and setbacks than the simple narrative of a Japanese “plot” to conquer Korea would indicate, there remains a great deal of validity to the conventional narrative.2 In addition, it is also illuminating to view the course of imperialism in Korea in the nineteenth century as one of a series of competing (and often overlapping) imperial structures and practices. These reflected a much greater diversity of origins and influences than simply the aims and whims of Tokyo. Korea successfully defended its position and participation in a Sino-centric regional order until at least 1876 when the Chosŏn Kingdom signed its first modern treaty with Japan. While rhetoric of the day emphasized modern, Western-style treaties as the key to entering the “family” of sovereign and independent nations, the reality of the day was one of stronger imperialist powers imposing their will upon weaker victims. The only real question was what type of imperialism would predominate. In the case of Korea, Meiji Japan initiated the introduction of informal, unilateral imperialism to Korea during the period 1876–1882. The subsequent period, 1882–1905, is characterized primarily by Sino-Japanese and Russo-Japanese competition in and over Korea but all within the framework of informal, multilateral imperial structures, most notably the treaty port system. After 1905, with its major competitors removed from the scene, Japan, in keeping with global trends, shifted toward a more formal imperialism in Korea, ultimately annexing and absorbing the peninsula in 1910. 27

Kirk W. Larsen

Opening the “hermit nation” Foreigners who approached the Chosŏn Kingdom in the nineteenth century found a Korea that appeared to be more or less content with the then-dominant imperial structure in the region. This structure was predicated on the centrality and superiority of China, both Ming China (1368–1644) and the subsequent Qing Empire (1644–1912). While both sides of this relationship insisted that it lacked coercion and was based on mutually acceptable Confucian morality, the reality was often that the stronger Ming and Qing made onerous and difficult demands of its Korean vassal—military assistance, human tribute, and the like—that are difficult to fully describe if one uses only the language of the “tribute system.” Nevertheless, by the nineteenth century, the most disagreeably coercive aspects of the relationship had subsided and China and Korea enjoyed a comfortable distance and a minimum of interaction. Relations between Chosŏn Korea and its other East Asian neighbor, Japan, usually are not labeled as imperialism of either country. Japan did attempt the conquest of Korea with the late sixteenth-century invasions of Hideyoshi Toyotomi, but after their failure, both Japan and Korea appear to have accepted restricting their relations to a bare minimum. Foreign encounters with Korea in the nineteenth century generally confirmed the oft-repeated notion that the Chosŏn Kingdom was content with its limited relations with China and Japan and wished to be more or less left alone. But the Korean desire to maintain its status as a “hermit” would come under increasing challenge as the nineteenth century wore on. Western ships which were plying the waters around China and Japan in ever-increasing numbers began to appear on Korea’s coasts as well. And while shipwrecked crews were reasonably well treated by the Koreans (and quickly hustled off to China for repatriation), some Western governments longed for the greater security offered by a treaty with Korea that would at minimum guarantee good treatment of shipwrecked sailors and allow for ships in distress to be able to acquire food and supplies from Korean ports. In addition to the need for a “wood and water” treaty, some in the West harbored the more ambitious desire to fully open Korea to diplomatic and commercial relations with the outside world as had been accomplished previously with China and Japan. A British newspaper confidently predicted that “Korea will no doubt soon figure as a place of trade, through the enterprise of Englishmen.” Other Westerners, particularly Americans, made similar predictions for their countrymen. A third issue was the desire to propagate Christianity in Korea. Roman Catholics had taken the lead in seeking contacts and converts in Korea with a small but influential number of French priests illegally entering Korea (the first arriving in 1836) and organizing congregations of Catholic believers, some of who had converted by reading Catholic materials brought back from China. The typical Korean response to these foreign forays was resistance and exclusion. Foreign explorers, merchants, and other adventurers who happened upon Korea’s shores almost uniformly reported being informed by local officials that their presence in Korea was illegal and unwanted. In addition, Korean Catholic believers were subjected to periodic purges with hundreds and sometimes thousands being executed in 1801, 1839, and 1866. Chosŏn officials sometimes pointed to the then prevailing structure of Chinese imperialism in Korea as a pretext for avoiding unwanted relations with outsiders. The supposed rule that “vassals cannot conduct diplomacy” had been utilized by Korean officials at least as early as the seventeenth century and was often deployed in the nineteenth century (even as late as 1871) in order to convince visiting foreigners to leave Korea alone.3 However, when the inquiring foreigners subsequently approached Korea’s putative suzerain, the Qing Empire, they were often informed that Chinese non-interference in Korean affairs was a bedrock principle of the longstanding suzerain-vassal relationship, leaving the foreigners with no one with which to negotiate on Korean matters. 28

Competing imperialisms in Korea

The year 1866 was pivotal in the history of imperialism in Korea. The Korean persecution of Catholics (including the execution of nine French priests) resulted in a French military mission led by Admiral Pierre-Gustave Roze that attacked Kanghwa Island but retreated after encountering stiff Korean resistance. Weeks before the French assault, the General Sherman, a British-chartered American sailing ship, sailed up the Taedong River to the outskirts of P’yŏngyang. Conflicts with local Koreans ensued (perhaps spurred on by the relentless proselytizing of the Welsh Protestant missionary Robert Jermain Thomas who was on board the General Sherman) with the end result being the destruction of the ship and the murder of all who were on board. This incident led to several American attempts to obtain an explanation and apology for the destruction of the General Sherman, which culminated in the 1871 American attack on Kanghwa Island. Much like the French punitive mission of five years earlier, the 1871 Low-Rodgers Expedition engaged in a series of violent conflicts with Koreans on the island (more than three hundred Koreans died) but then withdrew, having failed to either obtain more information about the General Sherman or progress toward a treaty. In short, Chosŏn Korea had proved able to resist the encroachment of foreign imperialism and to maintain control over the terms of how it engaged with the outside world for decades longer than its East Asian neighbors. While military force (or merely the threat of military force) was sufficient to force China (1842) and Japan (1854) to open, Korean resistance, albeit sometimes with high causalities, was able to keep foreign forces at bay. However, changes both outside and within Korea would combine to begin in earnest the process of opening the “hermit nation” in 1876. Internally, there remained a strong segment of Korean officials and elites who advocated a resistance-at-all-costs approach to foreign imperialism. The Grand Prince T’aewŏn’gun, who ruled as regent in the place of his young son (King Kojong) from 1864 to 1873, is thought to have embodied this type of unflinching resistance. The T’aewŏn’gun advocated fighting back against the French in 1866 and the Americans in 1871 as well as repelling unofficial attempts by outsiders to seek trade or plunder on the peninsula as was the case of the repeated efforts of the German adventurer Ernst Oppert to either convince Korea to open its doors to the outside world or, lacking this, ransack the tombs of Korean royalty (1866, 1867). But the T’aewŏn’gun was hardly alone in his determination that the foreigners could and should be resisted with force. Neo-Confucian stalwarts such as Yi Hang-no, Ch’oe Ik-hyŏn, Yi Man-sŏn, and Hong Chae-hak repeatedly and publicly called for violent resistance to the “wild beasts” that were appearing on Korea’s shores with troubling frequency. In 1873 the T’aewŏn’gun’s son, King Kojong, felt old and strong enough to push his father aside and begin ruling in actuality as well as in name. He proved to be more willing to entertain the notion of negotiating with foreigners rather than simply fighting them. In doing so, Kojong was supported by some among the Chosŏn elite such as Pak Kyu-su, the scion of a “practical learning” (silhak) clan. Their flexibility and pragmatism was needed in an era of growing change. In general, the nineteenth century saw an increasing number of polities and peoples beginning to adhere to Westphalian norms of national identity and sovereignty and to Western modes of treaty-based diplomatic and commercial interactions. As such, Korea increasingly stood out as a recalcitrant outlier. “Corea cannot hope to exclude foreigners much longer,” wrote an American diplomat in 1868.4 Korea’s neighbors had agreed to intensified relations with the West in accordance with Western diplomatic principles. China and Japan had even gone so far as to sign a Western-style treaty between themselves in 1871. But it bears noting that the norm of the time was for Western powers to impose new treaties upon recalcitrant would-be colonies at gunpoint (or by gunboat). 29

Kirk W. Larsen

However, it was not a Western nation but rather Japan that finally successfully opened Korea in 1876. In the years leading up to the 1876 Treaty of Kanghwa, Japan had begun a process of rapid modernization and Westernization often associated with the Meiji Restoration of 1868. Japan’s insistence on approaching Chosŏn Korea as an empire led by an emperor caused no small amount of Korean resentment and resistance. But Japan’s abolition of its system of feudal domains (han) and their daimyo leaders meant that Korea had little choice. Previously, most official Korean-Japanese relations were conducted between Chosŏn officials and representatives of the Tsushima-based Sō clan. The abolition of the Tsushima domain meant that there was literally no one other than Meiji officials with which to conduct diplomacy. Korea continued to resist Japanese overtures (with said resistance prompting some Japanese to call for an attack on Korea in the “Seikanron” debates of 1873) until yet another conflict off of the coast of Kanghwa Island prompted a Japanese threat of forceful retaliation. The 1875 Unyō incident (in which Korean shore batteries fired on a Japanese ship) gave Japan the opportunity to exercise the same sort of gunboat diplomacy that had opened up Japan some two decades earlier. But rather than fight, King Kojong—urged to compromise by an increasingly concerned Qing Empire—agreed to a treaty that contained some of the same types of provisions that had been used to open China and Japan. This ushered in a new era of imperialism in Korea. The 1876 Treaty of Kanghwa is often hailed as a milestone in Korea’s diplomatic history and is usually regarded as Korea’s first “modern” or at least Western-style treaty. As was often the case, actual implementation of the treaty’s provisions would take much time and labor to secure. While Pusan, the only allowed locale for Korean-Japanese trade for centuries, was immediately the first port to be designated as an open treaty port, other ports such as Wŏnsan (1880) and Chemulp’o/Inch’ŏn (1883) took years to open. It also took years before Japan was able to establish a permanent diplomatic presence in the Korean capital. But once these gains were achieved, Japanese merchants and adventurers moved to Korea to pursue their fortunes in trade. There they found a ready market for manufactured goods (mostly Western in the early years) with markups of as much as 1000 percent being recorded. They also sought to obtain Korean agricultural (rice, soybeans, and cowhides) and marine products for export. This commercial activity took place under almost entirely unregulated conditions. Chosŏn Korea had no maritime customs service, and the first few Korean attempts to pursue tariff negotiations with Japan were rebuffed by Tokyo (in the name of waiting until trade got on a better footing). In short, the system that Japan implemented and enjoyed during the period 1876–1882 bore many resemblances to the treaty port system that had been established and was developing in China and Japan save that there were no other foreign competitors in Korea. Japan enjoyed monopolistic but informal imperialism in Korea.

1882: multilateral imperialism comes to Korea This system of informal unilateral imperialism was challenged and ended by a series of events that took place in 1882. Korean officials and leaders and their Qing Chinese counterparts were increasingly concerned about the implications of a Japanese monopoly over access to Korean diplomacy and markets. Some Koreans were persuaded by the essay written by the Qing official Huang Zunxian, A Strategy for Korea, which argued that perilous times required a pragmatic differentiation among various powers and called for Korea’s cultivation of closer ties with the Qing Empire, the United States, and Japan in order to deal with the growing threat of Czarist Russia and other foreign powers. Others, including Pak Kyu-su, reached similar conclusions (this despite Pak’s personal experience of, as governor of P’yŏngan Province, having ordered the destruction of the General Sherman and the killing of its crew in 1866). Their motivation 30

Competing imperialisms in Korea

often did not include any real admiration or respect for the foreigners but rather was a pragmatic acknowledgment of contemporary power relations. Fearing strong domestic resistance to more relations with Western nations, King Kojong proved reluctant to take the first step toward treaty negotiations. As a result, the Qing statesman Li Hongzhang, decided to take matters into his own hands by offering to negotiate Chosŏn Korea’s first treaties with Western powers. He hoped that by involving a number of foreign powers in Korea, no single power would emerge predominant (he used the phrases “using one poison to counter another” and “using one barbarian to control another” to describe his strategy; a present-day description might use the term “balance of power”). Therefore, he invited the American Commodore Robert Shufeldt, who had previously made several unsuccessful attempts to approach Korea directly to negotiate a treaty, to Tianjin to negotiate on behalf of Korea. The resultant Treaty of Amity and Commerce was used as a model for treaties negotiated by Li with the British (1882, 1883) and the Germans (1883). Once the precedent was set, Chosŏn Korea would proceed to negotiate treaties with other major powers in ensuing years, including Russia (1884), Italy (1884), France (1886), and the Austro-Hungarian Empire (1892) among others. A second development in 1882 was also initiated by the Qing Empire, albeit in response to events on the ground in Korea. In July of 1882, Korean soldiers mutinied to protest unequal (or absent) pay and unequal treatment. Their mutiny soon took on political overtones as they enlisted the T’aewŏn’gun to their cause. The rioting soldiers proceeded to attack foreigners (which at the time meant only Japanese) and their businesses and residences in the Korean capital, and the T’aewŏn’gun announced his intention to repudiate all of the recently negotiated treaties. Fearing both the loss of the diplomatic gains secured by the treaties and also the possibility of a forceful Japanese military response to the mutiny, the Qing Empire dispatched three thousand troops from Shandong to Korea to put down the rebellion. The dispatch of troops to assist the Qing-invested monarch of Korea had precedent in the history of Sino-Korean relations. Ming troops had played a critical role in the halting of the Japanese invasions of Korea in the late sixteenth century (1592–1598). However, in something of a break from tradition, the Chinese troops in 1882 remained in the Korean capital even after the crisis was ended. They constituted a powerful political force aimed at least in part on furthering Qing interests in Korea. Still later in 1882, the Qing Empire negotiated its own set of commercial regulations with Chosŏn Korea. The resulting Regulations for Maritime and Overland Trade between Chinese and Korean Subjects put in writing both Qing claims to traditional Chinese suzerainty over Korea and the Qing assertion of commercial access and privilege in Korea. Taken together, these 1882 developments transformed the treaty port system in Korea from one of unilateral Japanese privilege to one in which a number of powers and peoples—but most notably the Chinese and Japanese—competed for power and markets in Korea. This competition within the structure of still informal but now multilateral imperialism would be one of the main features of imperialism in Korea for the next two decades. The post-1882 system also more fully resembled the treaty port system that had been implemented in China and Japan previously. Under this system, designated cities or towns (treaty ports) were set aside for foreign residence and commercial activity. Within these treaty ports, foreigners generally enjoyed the privilege of having any legal dispute being adjudicated according to foreign law and in foreign courts (extra-territoriality or “extrality”). In addition, many treaty ports had certain areas designated in which foreigners administered most if not all affairs (concessions or settlements). In the case of Chosŏn Korea, these settlements sometimes were demarcated by nationality with (usually) a Japanese and a Chinese settlement existing side by 31

Kirk W. Larsen

side sometimes accompanied by an “international settlement” set aside for Westerners. In China and Japan, foreign merchants enjoyed the benefits of generally low tariff rates (often via “unequal treaties” which were imposed under considerable duress) and (in China) a Customs Service managed by foreigners. Both of these features were also implemented in Korea. The post-1882 system of multilateral treaty-port-style imperialism proved resistant to the attempts of individual nations to assert exclusive privileges. This was discovered by Japanese merchants in Pusan who sought in 1883 to exclude newly arrived Chinese competitors from participation in commercial activities in what was previously an exclusively Japanese domain. Chinese diplomatic officials were able to point to treaty-guaranteed rights to force the Japanese to back down. Chinese merchants, too, found that their efforts to take advantage of the presence of aggressive Qing officials such as Yuan Shikai to facilitate the evasion of customs duties (if not outright smuggling of ginseng) were stymied by Korean customs officials, despite the fact that said officials were actually employees of the Chinese Imperial Maritime Customs Service. The period 1882–1894 was characterized by increasingly intense competition, particularly between China and Japan for markets and power in Korea. By all accounts, Chinese merchants swiftly proved to be worthy competitors to their Japanese counterparts as they poured into Korean treaty ports (particularly Inch’ŏn and Seoul, the Korean capital) and eagerly acquired as much ginseng and gold dust as they could, often exchanging them for British and Chinese textiles. A growing Japanese demand for Korean rice meant that Japan always had a larger share of Korea’s export market, but by the early 1890s, imports into Korea were nearly equally divided between Chinese and Japanese merchants (with merchants of other nationalities playing a negligible role in Korea’s foreign trade). At the same time that Chinese merchants were challenging Japan’s dominance in the commercial realm, Qing officials were seeking to enhance China’s political power on the peninsula. They reveled in the Chosŏn Kingdom’s continued dispatch of tribute missions to Beijing and sought to demonstrate Qing suzerainty in a variety of symbolic ways at official diplomatic functions, special occasions, banquets, and the like. But they also sought to promote and project Qing power using an assortment of newer tactics. These included setting up and managing Korea’s first overland telegraph lines, establishing and operating Korea’s maritime customs service (although as noted above, not always with expected results), and taking an active role in Korea’s attempts to borrow money from abroad (stymying Korea’s attempts to secure loans from nonChinese sources in some cases and actively supporting and even subsidizing Chinese loans to the Chosŏn government in others). In all of these areas, the Qing Empire appears to have been far more adept at innovating and adopting the latest imperialist techniques from across the globe than has often been recognized. While the Qing Empire and Imperial Japan were directly competing for power and privilege on the Korean peninsula, other imperialist powers were often present but usually only peripherally involved in the Sino-Japanese competition or its outcome. Despite its significant imperial presence in South (India, Burma, etc.) and East (Singapore, Hong Kong, etc.) Asia, Great Britain never demonstrated much official interest in Korea and its merchants tended to follow suit. The British were more than happy to follow the precedent set by the Korean-American Treaty of 1882 and negotiated with the Qing Empire for a BritishKorean Treaty but soon followed up with a re-negotiated treaty that was deemed more amenable to British interests (the so-called Parkes Treaty of 1883). Subsequently, British interest in Korea flared up periodically, usually in response to perceived Russian designs or advances on the peninsula. Such was the case in 1885 when the British occupied Kŏmun-do (which they had christened Port Hamilton), a small group of islands off of the southern coast of the peninsula. 32

Competing imperialisms in Korea

The official British justification for this act was the need to forestall Russian seizure of a Korean port (perhaps near the treaty port of Wŏnsan). Once the Russian threat diminished, the British withdrew in 1887. British merchants initially displayed considerable interest in Korea, with the famed firm Jardine and Matheson setting up shop in Inch’ŏn soon after the port was opened. However, few found lasting success (one British observer quipped that “There is no abundance of anything in the country except magpies”5), and Britain as a whole seemed content to allow Chinese merchants to market and distribute British goods in Korea. The reports of British consuls stationed in Korea are filled with lamentations concerning the lack of British attention to or interest in Korean markets. After its military setback of 1866, France appears to have lost interest in Korea for the next two decades, concluding a treaty with Korea only in 1886. French Catholics were subsequently permitted to live and preach in Korea without the persecution of earlier decades; some were instrumental in the construction of the still-famous Myŏng-dong Cathedral in Seoul. And while Germany was one of the first Western powers to negotiate and sign a treaty with Korea, its presence in Korea was negligible. The German firm Myer and Company did an often-successful import/export and transportation business in Korea and even loaned money to the cash-strapped Korean government at times. But few other German companies followed its lead in Korea. Although the United States played a significant role in the opening of Korea to the Western world with Commodore Shufeldt’s negotiation of the 1882 Korean-American treaty, the United States, too, seemed lukewarm at best in its interest in Korea. American diplomats and advisors sought to push the Chosŏn Kingdom toward what they regarded as progress and modernity. American missionaries (mostly Protestant) set up schools and hospitals and sought Korean converts. A few American firms, the most famous being Morse, Townsend, and Company, set up shop in Korea, facilitating, among other things, the electrification of Kyŏngbok Palace. Besides Japan and China, the most significant power with abiding interests and presence in Korea was Czarist Russia. Concerned by growing Japanese power on the peninsula and chafing under an increasingly interventionist Qing presence in Korea, King Kojong sought Russian assistance, going so far as to pursue a secret alliance in 1885 and again in 1886. In both cases, once the news became public, outcry from Great Britain, the Qing Empire, and other powers forced both the Koreans and the Russians to back down and disavow the plans. Nevertheless, Russia remained an interested party in Korea and emerged as the major non-Japanese power on the peninsula following the Sino-Japanese War (1894–1895). While many Western powers often used the rhetoric of Westphalian equality and the “family of nations” to describe the ideal system of international relations, actual practice diverged, often dramatically, from the ideal. Some, most prominently the British and the Americans, tacitly and even overtly acquiesced to Qing claims to suzerainty over Korea. While the American Commodore Shufeldt concluded that the treaty he had negotiated in 1882 clearly established Korean sovereignty and independence, American diplomats in Korea were later instructed that “the agitation of the subject of Corea’s complete independence of China, by representatives of the United States, is neither desirable nor beneficial.”6 The British, too, had negotiated a treaty with Korea whose wording seemed to verify Korean independence. But when the British occupied Kŏmun-do (an obvious abridgment of Korean sovereignty in its own right), British diplomats negotiated directly with the Qing Empire (rather than the Korean government) to resolve the issue. More generally, most foreign powers in Korea during this period of multilateral informal imperialism proved less interested in protecting Korean sovereignty and more interested in securing the same unequal access to and privilege in Korea that other powers enjoyed.

33

Kirk W. Larsen

1894: turning point? When rebels initially associated with the Tonghak (Eastern Learning) Movement gathered momentum in the early 1890s, and marched north toward the Korean capital in 1894, King Kojong turned to the Qing Empire, asking for Qing troops to come to Korea to help quell the rebellion. Invoking the terms of the 1885 Convention of Tianjin, Japan followed suit and also sent troops to Korea. A tense standoff was followed by the outbreak of the 1894–1895 SinoJapanese War. To the surprise of many, Japan won a series of victories on both land and sea. With boots on the ground in Korea, Meiji Japan decided not only to directly challenge Qing power in Korea but also to push the Korean government to move in ways more amenable to Japanese interests. Japanese soldiers surrounded the palace of King Kojong and elicited a Korean declaration of independence from China, including the announcement of cessation of tribute missions to Beijing. Although echoes of the customary relationship and the principles that underlay them would still be occasionally visible in the years to come, this move (and the subsequent dramatic series of Qing defeats in the war) effectively ended the Qing-Chosŏn suzerain-vassal relationship. For better or for worse, Chosŏn Korea was now firmly within the world of Westernstyle international relations. Japanese pressure also led to the creation of a new cabinet that called for a series of wideranging reforms (often referred to as the kabo and ŭlmi reforms). Many of these were aimed at modernizing Korean politics and society along Western lines. Others were more narrowly aimed at enhancing Japanese commercial prospects on the peninsula. Resistance to these reforms coalesced around defiance of the so-called top-knot edict, which required Korean males to cut off their customary top-knot and wear their hair Western (or recent Japanese) style, and the vocal opposition of Queen Min. Japanese displeasure at the Queen’s defiance was manifested when a group of Japanese thugs, most likely at the behest of Japanese official Miura Gorō, assassinated the Queen on October 8, 1895, but most of the kabo and ŭlmi reforms were not implemented. Japan also sought to use its suddenly increased power in Korea to engage in a series of moves aimed at enhancing Japanese commercial prospects in Korea and sharply curtailing those of Japan’s Chinese competitors. These included pushing for unilateral exemption from various tariff duties (as well as attempting to seize control of the Korean Customs Service), attempting to seize Chinese property (particularly in Inch’ŏn), and calling for the abolition of extra-territorial privileges for Chinese in Korea. In some respects, Japan appeared to be pushing for the return of the informal but unilateral privileges it had enjoyed during the period 1876–1882. In the words of one observer, “Japan has abolished the impalpable suzerainty of China only to replace it by a palpable and selfish domination of her own.”7 However, the norms of multilateral imperialism were vigorously defended, most prominently by Great Britain. British officials went to considerable lengths to protect the interests of Chinese merchants in Korea, usually pointing to treaty provisions to do so. In most cases, the British efforts to “restore [the Chinese] to equal rights with those subjects of other Powers” were successful.8 Japan might have pushed more vigorously for an expansion of its power and prerogatives in Korea but for the strong Korean domestic opposition as well as the international resistance to its moves. In addition to Great Britain, Russia spearheaded the so-called Triple Intervention, which forced Japan to relinquish its claims to parts of the Liaodong Peninsula in China in the face of Russian, French, and German opposition. Fearing increased Japanese encroachment on the peninsula, Chosŏn Korea sought aid and support from Russia. This extended so far as Russian protection of the Korean King Kojong in the aftermath of Queen Min’s assassination. The beleaguered Korean monarch actually resided in the Russian legation in the Korean capital from February of 1896 to February of 1897. 34

Competing imperialisms in Korea

Once Kojong felt secure enough to leave the protection of the Russian legation, he took the unusual step of formally declaring that Korea was no longer merely a kingdom (wangguk) but rather an empire (cheguk). The accompanying appropriation of imperial symbols, rituals, and practices makes it clear that at least some of the underlying motivation for this shift was the desire to reinforce Korea’s separation and independence from China. The construction of the “Independence Gate” (tongnimmun) by the Independence Club had similar aims. However, at the same time that Korea was asserting equality vis-à-vis China with symbols and language that would have been familiar to both Koreans and Chinese for centuries, the establishment of the Empire of the Great Han (Tae Han Cheguk) also highlighted the reality of late-nineteenth century power politics. Treaties and international law might speak of sovereign equality among the “family of nations,” but more often than not, empires violated the sovereignty of and, in an age of “high imperialism,” colonized, absorbed, annexed, and otherwise eliminated what were previously sovereign nations. Only empires had a chance of survival in such a world. Whatever the formal status of Korea and its ruler, the treaty port system in Korea continued to expand following the Sino-Japanese War. In addition to the three ports—Pusan, Wŏnsan, and Inch’ŏn—opened earlier, six additional ports were opened during the period 1895–1905: Chinnamp’o (1897), Mokp’o (1897), Kunsan (1899), Masan (1899), P’yŏngyang (1899), and Sŏngjin (1899). Merchants flocked to many of these ports seeking to buy Korean products and sell foreign ones. And while the general tendency of observers and historians is to describe commercial relations in an age of imperialism as ones with imperialist winners and colonized losers, the reality on the ground in Korea was more mixed. For example, many Koreans were able to utilize gold—which surprisingly did not function as a medium of exchange for most of Chosŏn Korea’s history—to purchase desired goods such as kerosene, matches, and machinewoven textiles. All of these foreign imports could arguably be seen to have significantly influenced if not improved the quality of life of many Koreans. Moreover, while the conventional narrative of nineteenth-century imperialism focuses on the ways in which the manufactured goods of the industrial revolution often disrupted if not destroyed local handicraft industries in the colony, in the case of Korea, evidence indicates that imports of machine-woven cotton thread actually enhanced the efficiency and profitability of some Korean hand-woven textiles. On the other hand, the growing integration of Korean agriculture into regional and even global markets meant that events far from home could have a profound effect, often a deleterious one, on local production and prices. And few would dispute the fact that all of the imperialists in Korea, but perhaps particularly the Japanese, engaged in their extractive enterprises not with Korean needs or interests in mind. The Russo-Japanese standoff in Korea opened up the peninsula for many powers and companies seeking lucrative concessions. American firms won contracts to build streetcars and the first electrical grid in the Korean capital. Another firm, the Oriental Consolidated Mining Company, secured the rights to a very productive and profitable gold mine in Unsan. Japanese firms constructed an ever-expanding railroad network and, one by one, sought to buy out or otherwise marginalize and eliminate competing concessions on the peninsula.

1905: the beginning of the end In its quest for sole possession of concessions in Korea, Japan’s most formidable opponent was Russia. A series of consortia sought and sometimes won timber concessions for logging along the Yalu River, but most faltered due to financial difficulties. However, in 1903 the Yalu River Timber Company, backed by the Czarist government, began to move forcefully not only to extract lumber from Korea but also to solidify Russian power in the northern part of the 35

Kirk W. Larsen

Korean peninsula. Russian soldiers and Chinese bandits were brought into Korea under the guise of being lumberjacks. Russia established a virtually independent enclave in the port city of Yongamp’o. Japan’s fear of Russia’s expansionistic intentions and capabilities (which would be all the more easily supported by the impeding completion of the Trans-Siberian Railroad) led Japan to initiate the Russo-Japanese War in 1904. Japan’s victories, particularly on sea, led to the Treaty of Portsmouth and a significant weakening of Russian power in the region. As a result, few were able or willing to protest Japan’s announcement that Korea would be a Japanese protectorate, with Japanese officials making all of the key foreign policy and diplomatic decisions on behalf of Korea. This announcement was resented and resisted by many Koreans. Some of them took to the hills and fought against the growing Japanese presence as “righteous armies” (ŭibyŏng). This type of popular resistance to foreign, particularly Japanese, presence in Korea had a long lineage. Violent anti-Japanese outbursts accompanied both the 1882 soldiers’ mutiny and an 1884 coup attempt led by pro-Japanese Korean officials. In addition, the movement that coalesced into the Tonghak Rebellion in the early 1890s had among its diverse ideological and practical motivations the desire to “expel the arrogant enemies from abroad.”9 Tonghak rebels agreed to disband if both the Qing and Japanese armies would leave Korean soil. When the SinoJapanese War and the increased presence and activities of Japanese troops in Korea ensued instead, many Tonghak rebels took up their arms again to fight against the Japanese and were hunted down and killed. After 1905, many more righteous armies formed. But they, too, were hunted down and killed by the thousands by the better-equipped and -supplied Japanese army. King Kojong (by then the Kwangmu Emperor of the Empire of the Great Han) made a last ditch effort to appeal for international support by dispatching a delegation to the 1907 Hague Conference. Due to Japanese pressure, the delegation was not received or recognized. In the words of one scholar, “in the summer of 1907, the world declared Korea illegal.”10 In retaliation for Kojong’s efforts, the Japanese forced him to abdicate in favor of his son, Sunjong (or the Yunghŭi Emperor). But few believed that Sunjong wielded any real power. The Japanese were able to use their enhanced power in Korea to slowly but inexorably crowd out competitors. Growing Japanese control of finance and banking, of transportation infrastructure, of the Customs Service, and of various levers of political power left little room for Chinese, American, or other competitors. The forms of the treaty port system—ports, concessions, extraterritoriality, etc.—remained in place until 1910 (or even beyond), but Korea increasingly became a place of Japanese dominance if not monopoly. The Japanese commercial ascent in Korea was also enhanced by a growing industrial base in Japan which, utilizing all the advantages of late industrialization, was increasingly able to directly challenge Western—especially British—manufactured goods on their own terms, at least in the East Asian region. Thus, the decline of Chinese commercial fortunes in Korea was also a decline, at one remove, of British fortunes as well. The Japanese statesman Itō Hirobumi was sent to Korea as the first Resident-General in 1905. Itō was not afraid to be firm and demanding in his administration of Korea. He expressed little to no opposition to the hunting down and killing of righteous army guerrillas. He also was instrumental in forcing Kojong to abdicate in 1907 as well as in the negotiation of the 1907 Japan-Korea Treaty, which gave Japan even more power to interfere in Korean domestic affairs. On the other hand, he steadfastly resisted the idea of full and formal annexation of Korea, preferring the continuation of the protectorate. However, Itō’s 1909 assassination in Harbin, China, at the hands of the Korean An Chung-gŭn gave momentum to those in Japan calling for annexation. On August 22, 1910, Korea disappeared as a sovereign nation and was formally annexed by Japan. Annexation also signaled the beginning of the end of the treaty port system 36

Competing imperialisms in Korea

in Korea (which would be dismantled in the years to come) and the effective end of competing empires in Korea (at least until the Pacific War in the 1940s). At the end of the day, the story of Japanese dominance and ultimate annexation of Korea was a story that had been repeated in many places across the world. In the age of high imperialism, nearly all of Africa (Liberia and Ethiopia excepted) and much of South and Southeast Asia were formally colonized by one power or another. Less formal and interventionist forms of imperialism like the treaty port system gave way to formal annexation and absorption. For many Koreans, 1910 would usher in an era of turmoil and suffering that in many ways would not end for at least 35 years. While the pre-1910 period of Korea’s history has receded further and further into the mists of the past, there remain areas that warrant additional scholarly attention. Promising areas of ongoing and potential future research regarding competing imperialisms in Korea and their impact on the peninsula include a strong strand of revisionist explorations of areas of unexpected reform, resiliency, and innovation in late-Chosŏn Korea. These include the aforementioned arguably positive impacts that foreign trade had on Korea and Koreans as well as the surprisingly diverse array of reform efforts of the Kwangmu Emperor (King Kojong’s formal title after 1897).11 In addition, explorations of this period that better situate the various imperialist activities in Korea within regional and even global trends and patterns will surely enhance our understanding of this critically formative period of Korean history. As some see early twenty-first-century patterns and developments that closely resemble the pre-1914 world of national (if not imperial) competition and conflict, understanding the Korean peninsula in an age of competing imperialisms may become more relevant than ever.

Notes 1 Examples of scholarship that grapples with these questions include Yi Tôk-ju, Chosônûn wae Ilbon ûi sikminji ga doeônûnga?; Yur-bok Lee, West Goes East; Young-ick Lew, “Yuan Shih-k’ai’s Residency . . .”; and Yung-hwan Jo, ed., Korea’s Response to the West. 2 Notable explorations of the contingencies and nuances of Japanese imperialism in Korea include Hilary Conroy, The Japanese Seizure of Korea, 1868–1910 and Peter Duus, The Abacus and the Sword, The Japanese Penetration of Korea, 1895–1910. 3 See, for example, Kojong sillok, June 4, 1871 (Kojong 8.4.17). 4 George F. Seward to William H. Seward, October 14, 1868. In Park, ed., Anglo-American Diplomatic Materials Relating to Korea, 835. 5 J.C. Hall to Parkes, December 11, 1882. In Ian Nish, ed., British Documents on Foreign Affairs, Part I. Series E, Asia 18601914, 118. 6 Swartout, Robert R., Mandarins, Gunboats, and Power Politics: Owen Nickerson Denny and the International Rivalries in Korea, 93. 7 Hillier to O’Conor, December 4, 1894. In Park, ed., Anglo-American and Chinese Diplomatic Materials Relating to Korea, 1887–1897, 484. 8 Hillier to O’Conor, February 11, 1895. In Park, ed., Anglo-American and Chinese Diplomatic Materials Relating to Korea, 1887–1897, 515. 9 “A Call to Arms Issued at Paeksan” in Peter H. Lee, ed., Sourcebook of Korean Civilization. Volume 2: From the Seventeenth Century to the Modern Period. New York: Columbia University Press, 1996, 364. Among the diverse and sometimes contradictory motivations of the Tonghak rebels was a clear antiforeign (particularly anti-Japanese) animus. However, Tonghak manifestos also mentioned specific aspects of foreign imperialist practice, including telegraph lines, treaty port rice merchants, and taxes on fish and salt collected in port cities. See “Thirty Demands of the Tonghak Peasant Army” in ibid., 367–368. 10 Dudden, Japan’s Colonization of Korea, 7. 11 See, for example, Tae-jin Yi, Kojong sidae ŭi chaejomyŏng. 37

Kirk W. Larsen

References ALLEN, H.N. (1908) Things Korean: A Collection of Sketches and Anecdotes Missionary and Diplomatic. New York, NY: Fleming Revell. BEASLEY, W.G. (1987) Japanese Imperialism 1894–1945. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. BISHOP, D.M. (1983) “Shared Failure: American Military Advisors in Korea, 1888–1896.” Transactions of the Korea Branch of the Royal Asiatic Society, 58: 53–76. BISHOP, I.B. (1985) Korea and Her Neighbours. London, Boston: KPI. BRITISH FOREIGN OFFICE (1884–1910) Diplomatic and Consular Reports on Trade and Finance (Later Diplomatic and Consular Reports) 1884–1910. London: British Foreign Office. CADY, J.F. (1954) The Roots of French Imperialism in Eastern Asia. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. CAIN, P.J., and JOPKINS, A.G. (1993) British Imperialism, Innovation and Expansion, 1688–1914. London: Longman. CARLES, W.R. (1888) Life in Corea. London and New York: Macmillan and Co. CASSEL, P. (2012) Grounds of Judgment. Extraterritoriality and Imperial Power in Nineteenth-century China and Japan. Oxford: Oxford University Press. CHANDRA, V. (1988) Imperialism, Resistance, and Reform in Late Nineteenth-Century Korea: Enlightenment and the Independence Club. Berkeley: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, Berkeley, Center for Korean Studies. CHAY, J. (1990) Diplomacy of Asymmetry: Korean-American Relations to 1910. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. CH’EN, J. (1972) Yuan Shih-K’ai. 2nd ed. Stanford: Stanford University Press. CHIEN, F.F. (1967) The Opening of Korea: A Study of Chinese Diplomacy, 1876–1885. [Hamden]: Shoe String Press. CHINA, IMPERIAL CHINESE MISSION TO KOREA. (1892) Notes on the Imperial Chinese mission to Corea, 1890. Shanghai. CHINA, IMPERIAL MARITIME CUSTOMS. (1885–1894) Returns of Trade and Trade Reports. Shanghai: Inspector General of Customs. –––– (1891) Treaties, Regulations, Etc. Between Corea and Other Powers, Miscellaneous Series, 19. Shanghai: Inspectorate General of Customs. –––– (1917) Treaties, Conventions, Etc., between China and Foreign States. Shanghai: Inspector General of Customs. CHO, K.J. (1976) “The Impact of the Opening of Korea on Its Commerce and Industry.” Korea Journal 16:2, 27–44. CHOE, C.Y. (1972). The Rule of the Taewŏn’gun 1864–1873: Restoration in Yi Korea. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. CH’OE, Y.H. (1982) “The Kapsin Coup of 1884: A Reassessment.” Korean Studies 6: 105–24. CHOI, M.H. (1984) “Korean-British Amity and Its Historical Significance.” Korea Journal 24:4, 9–22. CHU, S.C., AND LIU, K.C. (eds.) (1994) Li Hung-Chang and China’s Early Modernization. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. CHUN, H.J. (1968) “Sino-Korean Tributary Relations in the Ch’ing Period.” In FAIRBANK, J.K. (ed.), The Chinese World Order. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. CHUNG, C.S. (1995) A Korean Confucian Encounter with the Modern World: Yi Hang-No and the West. Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies. CHUNG, H. (1919) Korean Treaties. New York: H.S. Nichols Inc. CLARK, D. (1983) “The Ming Connection: Notes on Korea’s Experience in the Chinese Tributary System.” Transactions of the Korea Branch of the Royal Asiatic Society 58: 77–89. –––– . “Sino-Korean Tributary Relations under the Ming.” In TWITCHETT, D., and MOTE, F. (eds.), The Cambridge History of China. Volume 8, Part 2: The Ming Dynasty, 1368–1644. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 272–300. COHEN, W.I. (2000) East Asia at the Center: Four Thousand Years of Engagement with the World. New York: Columbia University Press. CONROY, F.H. (1960) The Japanese Seizure of Korea, 1868–1910: A Study of Realism and Idealism in International Relations. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press. COOK, H.F. (1972) Korea’s 1884 Incident: Its Background and Kim Ok-Kyun’s Elusive Dream. Seoul: Royal Asiatic Society, Korea Branch, and Taewon Publishing Company. 38

Competing imperialisms in Korea

DENNETT, T. (1941). Americans in Eastern Asia: A Critical Study of the Policy of the United States with Reference to China, Japan and Korea in the 19th Century. New York: Barnes & Noble. DENNY, O.N. (1888) China and Korea. Shanghai. DEUCHLER, M. (1977) Confucian Gentlemen and Barbarian Envoys: The Opening of Korea, 1875–1885. Seattle and London: University of Washington Press. DRAKE, F.C. (1984) The Empire of the Seas: A Biography of Rear Admiral Robert Wilson Shufeldt, USN. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. DUDDEN, A. (2005) Japan’s Colonization of Korea: Discourse and Power. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. DUUS, P. (1995) The Abacus and the Sword: The Japanese Penetration of Korea, 1859–1910. Berkeley: University of California Press. ELKINS, C. and PEDERSEN, S. (eds.) (2005) Settler Colonialism in the Twentieth Century: Projects, Practices, Legacies. New York: Routledge. FAIRBANK, J.K. (1951) Trade and Diplomacy on the China Coast, 1842–1854. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. FAIRBANK, J.K. (ed.) (1968) The Chinese World Order: Traditional China’s Foreign Relations. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. FIELDHOUSE, D.K. (1973) Economics and Empire, 1830–1914. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. –––– (1981) Colonialism 1870–1945: An Introduction. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson. FUNG, A. (1996) “Testing the Self-Strengthening: The Chinese Army in the Sino-Japanese War of 1894–1895.” Modern Asian Studies, 30:4, 1007–1031. FURUTA, K. (2001) “Inchon Trade: Japanese and Chinese Merchants and the Shanghai Network.” In GROVE, L. and SUGIYAMA, S. (eds.), Commercial Networks in Modern Asia. Richmond, Surrey: Curzon. GALE, J.S. and RUTT, R. (1972) James Scarth Gale and His History of the Korean People: A New Edition of the History Together with a Biography and Annotated Bibliographies by Richard Rutt. Seoul: Royal Asiatic Society. GALLAGHER, J. and ROBINSON, R. (1953) “The Imperialism of Free Trade.” Economic History Review I:1, 1–15. GILMORE, G.W. (1892) Korea from Its Capital: With a Chapter on Missions. Philadelphia: Presbyterian Board of Publication and Sabbath-School Work. GRIFFIS, W.E. (1911) Corea, the Hermit Nation. 9th ed. New York: C. Scribner’s Sons. HAMASHITA, T. (2003) “Tribute and treaties: Maritime Asia and treaty port networks in the era of negotiation, 1800–1900.” In ARRIGHI, G., HAMASHITA, T., and SELDEN, M. (eds.), The Resurgence of East Asia. 500, 150, and 50 Year Perspectives. London: Routledge. HAMILTON, A. (1904) Korea: Its History, its People, and its Commerce. London: William Heinemann. HAN, W.K. (1974) The History of Korea. Seoul: Eul-yoo Publishing Co. HARA, T. (1998) “Korea, China, and Western Barbarians: Diplomacy in Early Nineteenth-Century Korea.” Modern Asian Studies 32:2, 389–430. HARRINGTON, F.H. (1961) God, Mammon and the Japanese: Dr. Horace N. Allen and Korean-American Relations, 1884–1905. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press. HOARE, J.E. (1999) Embassies in the East. Richmond, Surrey: Curzon. HOWE, S. (2002) Empire: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press. HULBERT, H.B. (1999) History of Korea. Richmond: Curzon. IRIYE, A. (1970) “Imperialism in East Asia.” In CROWLEY, J.B. (ed.) Modern East Asia: Essays in Interpretation. New York: Harcourt. JO, Y.H. (1971) Korea’s Response to the West. Kalamazoo, MI: Korea Research and Publications. JUNG, W. (1998) Nation Building: The Geopolitical History of Korea. Lanham, MD: University Press of America. KANG, D. (2003) “Getting Asia Wrong: The Need for New Analytical Frameworks.” International Security 27:4, 57–85. –––– (2003/2004). “Hierarchy, Balancing, and Empirical Puzzles in Asian International Relations.” International Security 28:3, 165–180. KANG, E.H.J. (1997) Diplomacy and Ideology in Japanese-Korean Relations: From the Fifteenth to the Eighteenth Century. New York: St. Martin’s. KANG, W.J. (1997) Christ and Caesar in Modern Korea. A History of Christianity and Politics. Albany: State University of New York Press. 39

Kirk W. Larsen

–––– (2005) The Korean Struggle for International Identity in the Foreground of the Shufeldt Negotiation, 1866–1882. Lanham, MD: University Press of America. KIERNAN, V.G. (1939) British Diplomacy in China 1880–1885. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. –––– (1995) Imperialism and its Contradictions. New York: Routledge, 1995. KIM, C.I.E. and KIM, H.K. (1967) Korea and the Politics of Imperialism, 1876–1910. Berkeley: University of California Press. KIM, D. (1976) “Chinese Imperialism in Korea: With Special Reference to Sino-Korean Trade Regulations in 1882 and 1883.” Journal of East-West Studies 2: 97–110. KIM, H.C. (1993) Korea’s Relations with Her Neighbors in a Changing World. Elizabeth, NJ: Hollym. KIM, K.H. (1980) The Last Phase of the East Asian World Order: Korea, Japan, and the Chinese Empire, 1860–1882. Berkeley: University of California Press. –––– (1994) “The Aims of Li Hung-Chang’s Policies toward Japan and Korea, 1870–1882.” In CHU S. and LIU, K.C. (eds.), Li Hung-Chang and China’s Early Modernization. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. KIM, K.S. (2006) “Emperor Gwangmu’s Diplomatic Struggles to Protect His Sovereignty before and after 1905.” Korea Journal 46:2, 233–257. KIM, Y. (2001) The Five Years’ Crisis, 1866–1871. Seoul: Circle. KUKSA PYŎNCH’AN WIWŏNHOE (ed.) (1971) Yun Ch’i-Ho’s Diary. Seoul: Kuksa p’yŏnch’an wiwŏnhoe. –––– (1980) The Collected Letters of Yun Tchi Ho. Seoul: Kuksa p’yŏnch’an wiwŏnhoe. –––– (ed.) Kojong Sillok. Accessed at http://sillok.history.go.kr. LARSEN, K. (2008) Tradition, Treaties, and Trade: Qing Imperialism and Chosŏn Korea, 1850–1910. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. –––– (2009) “Competition in absentia: China, Japan, and British cotton textiles in Korea: 1876–1910” in POMERANZ, K. (ed.), The Pacific in the Age of Early Industrialization. Surrey, U.K.: Ashgate. LEE, K.B. (1983). A New History of Korea. Cambridge, MA: Harvard-Yenching Institute, Harvard University Press. LEE, P. (ed.) (1996) Sourcebook of Korean Civilization. Volume 2: From the Seventeenth Century to the Modern Period. New York: Columbia University Press. LEE, Y.B. (1982) “Politics over Economics: China’s Domination of Korea through Extension of Financial Loans, 1882–1894.” In SUCH’ŏN PAK YONGSŏK KYOSU HWAGAP KINYŏM NONCH’ONG KANHEANG WIWŏNHOE (ed.) Han’guk Sahak Nonch’ong. Seoul: Sudun Pak Yongsôk kyosu hwagap kinyôm nonch’ong kanhaeng wiwônhoe. –––– (1983) “Establishment of a Korean Legation in the United States, 1887–1890: A Study of Conflict Between Confucian World Order and Modern International Relations” Illinois Papers in Asian Studies 3. –––– (1988). West Goes East: Paul Georg Von Mollendorff and Great Power Imperialism in Late Yi Korea. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. –––– (1994) “The Sino-Japanese economic warfare over Korea, 1876–1894.” Russia and the Pacific 1:5, 122–132. LENSEN, G.A. (1982) Balance of Intrigue: International Rivalry in Korea and Manchuria, 1884–1899. 2 vols. Tallahassee: University Presses of Florida. LEW, Y.I. (1984) “Yuan Shih-K’ai’s Residency and the Korean Enlightenment Movement, 1885–94.” Journal of Korean Studies 5: 63–107. LIN, M.D. (1994) “Li Hung-Chang’s Suzerain Policy toward Korea, 1882–1894.” In CHU, S. and LIU, K.C. (eds.), Li Hung-Chang and China’s Early Modernization. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. LIN, T.C. (1935) “Li Hung-Chang: His Korea Policies, 1870–1885.” Chinese Social and Political Science Review 19: 202–23. LONGFORD, J.H. (1911). The Story of Korea. London: T. Fisher Unwin. LOWELL, P. (1886) Choson: Land of Morning Calm. A Sketch of Korea. Boston: Ticknor. LYNN, M. (1999) “British Policy, Trade, and Informal Empire in the Mid-Nineteenth Century” in PORTER, A. (ed.), The Oxford History of the British Empire, Volume III: The Nineteenth Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 101–121. MANCALL, M. (1984) China at the Center: 300 Years of Foreign Relations. New York: The Free Press. MORSE, H.B. (1910) The International Relations of the Chinese Empire. 3 vols. London: Longmans, Green and Co. MUTSU, M. (1982) Kenkenroku. A Diplomatic Record of the Sino-Japanese War, 1894–1895. Tokyo: The Japan Foundation. 40

Competing imperialisms in Korea

MYERS, R. and PEATTIE, M. (eds.) The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895–1945. Princeton: Princeton University Press. NELSON, M.F. (1945) Korea and the Old Orders in Eastern Asia. Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press. NISH, I. (ed.) (1989–1994) Korea, the Ryukyu Islands, and North-East Asia, 1875–1888, In British Documents on Foreign Affairs: Reports and Papers from the Foreign Office Confidential Print. Frederick, MD: University Publications of America. NISH, I. (1992) “John McLeavy Brown in Korea” Papers of the British Association for Korean Studies 2: 29–50. OSTERHAMMEL, J. (1986) “Semi-Colonialism and Informal Empire in Twentieth-Century China: Towards a Framework of Analysis.” In MOMMSEN, W.J. and OSTERHAMMEL, J. (eds.), Imperialism and After: Continuities and Discontinuities. London: Allen and Unwin. –––– (1999) “Britain and China, 1842–1914.” In PORTER, A. (ed.), The Oxford History of the British Empire: The Nineteenth Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 146–169. PAIK, L.G. (1980) The History of Protestant Missions in Korea, 1832–1910. Seoul: Yonsei University Press. PAINE, S.C.M. (2003) The Sino-Japanese War of 1894–1895: Perceptions, Power, and Primacy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. PALAIS, J.B. (1975) Politics and Policy in Traditional Korea. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. PARK E.K. (1989) “Ethnic Network among Chinese Small Business in Korea During the Colonial Period (1910–1945).” Journal of Social Sciences and Humanities 67: 67–89. PARK, I.K. (1981) “China’s Policy toward Korea: 1880–1884.” Journal of Social Sciences and Humanities 53: 45–78. PARK, I.K. (ed.) (1982) Anglo-American Materials Relating to Korea (1866–1886). Seoul: Shin Mun Dang. –––– (ed.) (1984) Anglo-American and Chinese Diplomatic Materials Relating to Korea, 1887–1897. Pusan: Institute of Chinese Studies, Pusan National University. PARK, Y.I. and ANDERSON, K. (1992) “The Experience of Japan in Historical and International Perspective.” In ANDERSON, K. (ed.), New Silk Roads: East Asia and World Textile Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. REYNOLDS, B.L. (1986) “The East Asian ‘Textile Cluster” Trade, 1868–1973: A Comparative Advantage Interpretation.” In FAIRBANK, J.K. and MAY, E. (eds.), America’s China Trade in Historical Perspective. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. SANDS, W.F. (1904) Undiplomatic Memories: The Far East, 1896–1904. London: John Hamilton. SCHMID, A. (2002) Korea between Empires, 1895–1919. New York: Columbia University Press. SEUNG, K.S. (1981) The Russo-Japanese Rivalry over Korea, 1876–1904. Seoul: Yuk Phub Sa. SIGEL, L.T. (1976) “Ch’ing Foreign Policy and the Modern Commercial Community: T’ang Shao-Yi in Korea.” Papers on Far Eastern History [Canberra], no. 13: 77–106. –––– (1976) “Foreign Policy Interests and Activities of the Treaty-Port Chinese Community,” in SCHRECKER, J.E. and COHEN, P. (eds.) Reform in Nineteenth-Century China. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. –––– (1980) “The Role of Korea in Late Qing Foreign Policy.” Papers on Far Eastern History [Canberra], no. 21: 75–98. –––– (1992) “Business-Government Cooperation in Late Qing Korean Policy.” In LEONARD, J.K. and WATT, J.R. (eds.), To Achieve Security and Wealth: The Qing Imperial State and the Economy, 1644–1911. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University East Asia Program. –––– (1992) “The Sino-Japanese Quest for Korean Markets, 1885–1891.” Essays in Economic and Business History 10: 104–16. SUGIYAMA, S. (1988) “Textile Marketing in East Asia, 1860–1914.” Textile History 19:2. SWARTOUT, R.R. (1980) Mandarins, Gunboats, and Power Politics: Owen Nickerson Denny and the International Rivalries in Korea. Honolulu, HI: Asian Studies Program. TSIANG, T.F. (1933/34) “Sino-Japanese Diplomatic Relations, 1870–1894.” Chinese Social and Political Science Review 17: 1–106. UNDERWOOD, L.H. (1904) Fifteen Years among the Top-Knots. Or, Life in Korea. Boston, New York: American Tract Society. –––– (1983) Underwood of Korea: Being an Intimate Record of the Life and Work of the Rev. H.G. Underwood, D.D., LL.D., for Thirty-one Years a Missionary of the Presbyterian Board in Korea. Seoul: Yonsei University Press. WEALE, P. (1905) The Re-Shaping of the Far East. London: Macmillan. 41

Kirk W. Larsen

WRIGHT, M.C. (1958) “The Adaptability of Ch’ing Diplomacy: The Case of Korea.” Journal of Asian Studies 17: 363–81. YEN, C.H. (1985) Ching-hwang. Coolies and Mandarins: China’s Protection of Overseas Chinese during the Late Ching Period (1851–1911). Singapore: Singapore University Press. YI, T.J. (2000) Kojong sidae ŭi chaejomyŏng. Seoul: Taehaksa. ZABROVSKAIA, L.V. (1991) “1899 Treaty and Its Impact on the Development of the Chinese-Korean Trade (1895–1905).” Korea Journal 31:4, 29–39.

42

4 The nation, the people, and the possibilities of the post-national Historiographies of late nineteenthcentury Korean reform movements Joshua Van Lieu

Now in the second decade of the twenty-first century, South Korea is a global presence. South Korean corporations operate around the world as their products and technologies are produced and consumed across the continents while people of multiple languages and nationalities have immersed themselves in the pop-culture artefacts of the “Korean Wave.” Considering the widespread grinding poverty of the first decades after the Korean War, it is not hard to conceive of the current place of Korea in the world as an emergence, as a rise of an almost Aristotelian spontaneity. Indeed, this trope is common in academic and popular writings alike, but it is also possible to consider the place of South Korea in the world not as a rise but as a return. For the more than 500 years prior to the Japanese annexation in 1910, Chosŏn state, society, and culture were deep within the mainstreams of the philosophies, statecraft, literatures, and arts of the East Asian world. By the end of the nineteenth century, however, decades of internal socio-political instability coupled with an increasing chafing against the expansion of the global capitalist economy and the associated machinations of competing imperia provoked Chosŏn intellectuals and officials to engage in increasingly urgent interrogations of received bodies of political and intellectual practice. These critical engagements led to a number of social and political reform movements seeking a rehabilitation of state and society that would shepherd a strong, prosperous, and independent Chosŏn in the twentieth century. The late nineteenth century thus marked the beginning of more than 100 years of both material and epistemic violence through which the Koreas north and south have come to dramatically reposition themselves in the modern world. This initial period of critique and exploration has provided the frame and foundations for Korean encounters with and shaping of the global modernities in which we now live.

Crises of the nineteenth century The reform movements of the late nineteenth century emerged in a society that had already undergone considerable political and economic stresses in the preceding decades, stresses that 43

Joshua Van Lieu

touched the whole of the society from the yangban elite to the common peasantry. Growing numbers of yangban, particularly those in rural areas outside the capital, found themselves alienated from political and economic privilege. This is in part attributable to the weakness of Chosŏn monarchy after 1800. Chosŏn kings of the nineteenth century all came to the throne in compromised circumstances. King Sunjo ascended the throne in 1800 at the age of eleven and within a year the royal in-laws, the Andong Kim clan, came to dominate the court. Upon Sunjo’s death in 1834, King Hŏnjong ascended the throne at the age of eight and his court too was controlled by the consort clan, the P’ungyang Cho. Hŏnjong died in 1849 without issue and was succeeded by a distant member of the royal family living in poverty and alleged illiteracy on Kanghwa Island. The Andong Kim managed to install one of their daughters as the royal consort Queen Ch’ŏrin and then again reign supreme in the Chosŏn court. When Ch’ŏlchong died in 1863 without issue, Queen Dowager Sinjŏng and Yi Ha-ŭng brought Yi’s twelve-yearold son to the throne as King Kojong in 1864. Kojong married a daughter of the Yŏhŭng Min clan, which came to dominate the Chosŏn government into the 1890s and remained central to Chosŏn politics until the end of the dynasty in 1910. This dominance of the consort clans (sedo chŏngch’i) had implications far beyond the machinations of court intrigue in the high politics of the capital. They secured their hegemony through the control of government appointments, limiting access to real political power to the scions of their houses and affiliated families. The result was a growing body of yangban who had passed the highest of the civil service exams but were excluded from positions in the government. The frustration of this marginalized elite was particularly acute in P’yŏngan Province, where successful civil service examinees suffered not only from the grim prospects for official appointment under the restrictions of consort clan rule but also from the regional biases of the capital bureaucracy. In the winter of 1812, Hong Kyŏngnae and his associates, members of this thwarted regional elite, took it upon themselves to bring the end of the dynasty. They attacked the Kasan magistracy, killed its staff, and took over the town. Within two weeks the rebellion had grown to seize a significant portion of the northwest of P’yŏngan Province north of the Ch’ungch’ŏng River with little resistance as many of their fellow elites and local officials were sympathetic to his cause. Several defeats at the hands of government forces in the early spring forced Hong and his rebels into a defensive posture. By the end of that summer, government forces laid siege to the rebels at Chŏngju and eventually broke through the defences and crushed the rebellion after four months. The Chosŏn state succeeded in subduing Hong and his forces, but it entered into its final century facing a fundamental challenge to its authority and legitimacy that it had not seen for generations (Kim, Sun Joo 2007a). While the exclusive political practices of the central government limited the prospects for political participation and advancement for an increasingly marginalized yangban elite, the peasants who comprised the overwhelming majority of the Chosŏn population were facing far greater existential threats in the face of official usury under the auspices of state granaries. The state granary system had originally been tasked with maintaining grain stores for the purposes of providing famine relief, ensuring adequate military provisions, maintaining price stability in grain markets by purchasing surpluses or releasing reserves, and providing seed and working capital in the form of grain loans to enable peasants to survive the spring and summer seasons when food stores were low and harvests were yet to be brought in. Ideally these were to be interestfree loans, but early in the dynasty the state began to charge interest and wastage fees. Over the duration of the Chosŏn state, the system that was originally envisioned as a service to impoverished peasants came to constitute a revenue stream for both central and local governments; the grain loan system became a permanent tax. By the nineteenth century it was common practice for magistrates to charge interest and miscellaneous fees not only to supplement official budgets 44

Historiographies of Korean reform movements

but also to enrich themselves. By mid-century some peasants even found themselves coerced into taking out loans at usurious rates as official corruption forced many to navigate a precarious course between subsistence, destitution, and outright starvation (Yang Chin-sŏk 2003a). In the spring of 1862, peasants in Kyŏngsang Province could take no more and rose in rebellion in Chinju. The uprising spread rapidly through Chŏlla and Ch’ungch’ŏng Provinces to eventually include more than seventy different locations. The geographic scope of the rebellions, however, did not translate into a broad unified assault on the Chosŏn state itself. While the grain loan system was one of the main reasons for the uprisings, it was not the only one (Kim, Sun Joo 2007b). Grievances varied with local circumstances, and the targets of peasant ire were often distinctly proximate. The rebellions did prompt the state to institute limited reforms, but the underlying structural causes of unrest remained largely unaddressed (Han’guk Yŏksa Yŏn’guhoe, ed., 1993; Yang 2003b; Kim 2007b). In addition to the domestic problems the Chosŏn state faced, the decade from 1866 to 1876 saw a series of international incidents that radically and irrevocably altered the place of Chosŏn in the world. During the summer of 1866, the General Sherman, an American-owned and piloted merchant ship with a crew of Malays and Chinese, sailed up the Taedong River to P’yŏngyang seeking trade. The General Sherman refused to comply with Chosŏn instructions to await word from Seoul and there were violent exchanges. After the death of several Koreans, the governor of P’yŏngan Province ordered the ship destroyed; there were no survivors. In the fall of the same year, the French launched a punitive expedition to avenge the Chosŏn execution of a French priest. Seven ships and 600 men under the command of Admiral Roze raided shore installations, but Chosŏn forces repelled them. Two years later, the German adventurer launched a peculiar expedition to disinter the Chosŏn regent’s father’s bones and hold them hostage in order to exact a trade agreement with the Chosŏn court. Chosŏn forces quickly dispatched Oppert and his men. In 1871, Frederick Low, United States minister to China, and Admiral John Rodgers lead an expedition of five US naval vessels and 1,200 men to investigate the fate of the General Sherman. Initial inquiries with Chosŏn officials produced no results. The Americans sailed closer to the mouth of the Han River, some thirty miles from Seoul, where Chosŏn shore batteries fired upon them. Low and Rodgers later launched a punitive attack on shore installations on Kanghwa Island. US casualties were insignificant, but hundreds of Koreans were killed in the ensuing combat before the Americans withdrew. The Chosŏn government under the leadership of the Taewŏn’gun, father and de facto regent of King Kojong, mistakenly understood themselves to have successfully fended off the Americans, the French, and even the Germans without taking into consideration that none of these predations was undertaken with the intent or even authority to execute further military action. The Chosŏn government felt these skirmishes demonstrated its ability to adequately manage its own defence against hostile enemies and thus made little attempt to commence the extensive technological and institutional reforms then underway in Meiji Japan (Palais 1975). Chosŏn ignored developments in Japan at its own risk, however. In 1875, the Japanese sent the ship Unyō to survey waters near the mouth of the Han River. The voyage provoked fire from Chosŏn shore batteries, providing the Japanese with the justification for returning the following year to demand and ultimately conclude an unequal treaty with the Chosŏn government closely reminiscent of the United States treaties imposed upon Japan in the 1850s. Although this agreement, now known as the Kanghwa Treaty, was not fully implemented until the 1880s, it was the first of a series of treaties the Chosŏn state would conclude through the 1880s and 1890s with other states and marked the beginning of a fundamental repositioning of the Chosŏn state within the global geopolitics of the nineteenth century. 45

Joshua Van Lieu

By the close of the 1870s, Chosŏn had passed through decades of political, economic, social, and finally geopolitical transformations that signalled to some that the existing socio-political order was incapable of responding to rapidly changing domestic and international environments. The Qing Empire had embarked upon a path of so-called self-strengthening in the early 1860s, and the Japanese followed in the late 1860s with even more radical reforms under the new Meiji order. By 1880, Chosŏn was already fifteen to twenty years behind its neighbours, but with a younger king open to reform and a newer generation of officials following the developments in Japan and the Qing Empire, it was indeed plausible that Chosŏn too might mobilize to reform its social and political institutions to meet the challenges and fully engage in the global modernities of the late nineteenth century.

Moderates and radicals: enlightenment thought in the 1880s By the early 1880s, there was a small group of reformist officials in the Chosŏn court who sought social and institutional change to meet the merging domestic and international challenges of the nineteenth century. While most of them had come into contact with earlier forms of reformist thought during the 1870s through figures such as Pak Kyu-su, who himself came from reformist intellectual lineages dating back to the eighteenth century, the so-called enlightenment party (kaehwap’a) was generally divided between two factions: the moderates (on’gŏn kaehwap’a) and the radicals (kŭpchin kaehwap’a). The moderates looked to the Qing model of technological transformation with limited institutional and cultural change, while the radicals took inspiration from the more revolutionary approach of the Meiji reforms still underway in Japan. In 1880, Chosŏn envoy Kim Hong-jip travelled to Japan where he met with the Qing diplomat Huang Zunxian. Huang presented him with an outline policy for the reform of Chosŏn diplomatic and trade relations entitled Chaoxian celue or “A Strategy for Korea.” While Huang drafted the text, it largely represented the consensus of Li Hongzhang, Qing Commissioner for Northern Ports and chief creator of Qing policy toward Chosŏn, and his staff. The text famously identified Russia as the chief threat to the security of Qing, Chosŏn, and Japan and recommended that King Kojong enter into close relations with Qing, Japan, and the United States in order to build a matrix of overlapping treaty obligations that would guarantee Chosŏn territorial integrity and sovereignty in the face of possible Russian aggression. The document was also a call for Chosŏn to adopt the self-strengthening paradigm of the Qing Empire by adopting western military, transportation, and communications technologies. King Kojong and his inner circle accepted the proposals with enthusiasm and after dispatching considerable domestic opposition among conservative rural scholars in particular, he set about implementing the proposals (Van Lieu 2010). To this end, the Chosŏn government created a new office, the T’ongni Kimu Amun, based on the Qing Zongli Yamen, as something of a foreign office responsible for international relations, commercial affairs, foreign language education, military affairs, and armaments production. Kojong also sent a mission to negotiate new protocols for Chosŏn-Qing relations and a group of Chosŏn artisans under the leadership of Kim Yun-sik to Tianjin to train in the most current methods and armament and ship production in Qing armouries and students to study foreign languages. The Chosŏn government also looked to Japan as a model of reform, sending observers to Japan in 1881–1882 and hiring a Japanese drill instructor to train a new unit of the Chosŏn army in modern tactics and weaponry. The resources and pay this so-called Special Skills Unit (pyŏlkigun) received became the cause of no small amount of resentment among the existing capital units, who by 1882 had not been paid in months. When the quartermaster finally did distribute their pay in rice during the summer of 1882, the soldiers found that the rice was 46

Historiographies of Korean reform movements

mixed with sand and stones to increase the weight while reducing the actual amount of rice distributed. They exploded in revolt, killing the Japanese drill instructor and the Japanese legation and burning down the houses of Chosŏn officials associated with the Special Skills Unit and other reforms. The Taewŏn’gun took advantage of the ensuing mayhem to reinstate himself as regent and systematically undo the military and institutional reforms of the previous two years (Cho Sŏng-yun 2003). Concerned with the possibility of Japanese military intervention in Chosŏn, the Qing court rapidly deployed a force of some 4,500 to Seoul. Upon their arrival, they abducted the Taewŏn’gun and detained him in Tianjin, dispatched the Chosŏn troops who had revolted, and reinstated Kojong to the throne. This was the beginning of a deep and direct Qing involvement in Chosŏn affairs that was to last until the Japanese victory in the Sino-Japanese War of 1894–1895. For the next two years, the Qing military presence also served to enforce Qing interests in further reforms of the Chosŏn state. During this period, Qing representatives oversaw the creation of the Chosŏn customs service and telegraph lines while Qing diplomats concluded treaties securing Qing political and commercial interests. Moderate officials like Kim Yun-sik and Ŏ Yun-jung, among others, saw no need to fundamentally change Chosŏn society or institutions; all that was truly needed to meet the challenges of the age was to embrace the technologies of the west and simply insert them into the existing socio-political milieu (Chang In-sŏng 2002; No Tae-hwan 2005; Kim Sŏng-bae 2009). In 1968, the historian Han U-gŭn famously characterized this stance with the phrase he coined, “eastern ways, western means” (tongdo sŏgi) (Han U-gŭn 1968; No Tae-hwan 2005). This interest in maintaining the socio-cultural as well as institutional status quo often led these men to maintain a pro-Qing stance. Much like the Northern Learning (pukhak) scholars of the turn of the end of the eighteenth century, the moderates at the end of the nineteenth century saw the Qing Empire as the locus of practical reform and placed trust in the integrity of the 250-year peaceful relationship between the Qing and Chosŏn states. The typically younger, radical reform-minded officials, however, had no interest in or patience for piecemeal reform that did not engage in socio-political transformation as well as technological change. Deeply suspicious of the moderates’ dependence on both the Qing model and the Qing state, this alternative group looked not to the north but to the east for their inspiration. In 1882–1883, several young Chosŏn officials, Kim Ok-kyun chief among them, studied in Japan, then deep in the throes of the Meiji reforms, and came to develop close relationships with educator and reformer Fukuzawa Yukichi. These students returned to Chosŏn wholly unable to accept the existing order into which the moderates sought to import their new technologies; they wanted nothing less than revolution. With the encouragement and the material aid of the Japanese legation in Seoul, Kim Okkyun and his associates executed a coup d’état in December of 1884 (Cook 1972; Ch’ŏnga P’yŏnjippu 1983; Sin Yong-ha 2000, 2003a, 2003b; Yun Pyŏng-hŭi 2003a, 2003b). The coup was initially a success as Kim and his party seized control of the government and announced a fourteen-point plan to reform Chosŏn state and society. The planned reforms included ending the tributary relationship with the Qing Empire, which they deemed naught but “empty ritual” (hŏrye), abolishing all formal status distinctions and adopting the principle of equal rights for all, abolishing the grain loan system, rooting out corruption and instituting aid for the indigent, and centralizing all fiscal affairs under the purview of the ministry of revenue (hojo). These and other institutional reforms were to be the beginning of transformation of Chosŏn modelled after the Meiji reforms then still underway in Japan. As radical and potentially transformative as these reforms would have been, the new government lasted only three days before it collapsed under the military might of the combined Qing and Chosŏn military units under the command 47

Joshua Van Lieu

of Yuan Shikai, a young Qing officer tasked with the training and command of new units of the Chosŏn army. Aside from a handful of armed guards from the Japanese legation, Kim and his party had no real arms to speak of and soon fled. Kim and other made it to exile in Japan while many more were killed on the spot or later executed for treason. The failure of the Coup of 1884 effectively put an end to meaningful reform in Chosŏn for the next ten years (Lew 1984). The Qing Empire installed Yuan Shikai as a de facto imperial resident in Seoul the following year and secured unparalleled influence in Chosŏn, with little enthusiasm for the kinds of self-strengthening reforms it had once encouraged King Kojong to pursue only two years previously (Larsen 2008; Van Lieu 2009, 2010). The Japanese remained largely passive, unable to challenge Qing supremacy in Chosŏn. Those Chosŏn reformers who remained both alive and within the country maintained a low profile, while those who fled were trapped in a helpless exile in Japan for the better part of a decade. Kim Ok-kyun himself fled to Japan, where he largely refrained from political activity. Chosŏn agents eventually tracked him down while he travelled in Shanghai and assassinated him. They brought his corpse back to Chosŏn, where the government had it cut into pieces and put on public display in different locations throughout the country as a warning to others who might consider another revolution.

The Tonghak Rebellion and the Kabo Reforms, 1894–1895 The remainder of the 1880s remained largely without serious unrest, but by the early 1890s there were increasing tensions in the southwest of the country as merchants from Qing and Japan scoured the countryside for rice and bean harvests, bringing distortions to local markets and causing tensions in rural areas where foreigners were generally not welcome. The pressures of Chosŏn’s integration into the global capitalist system coupled with local officials leveeing taxes and corvée for their own enrichment made for a politically fragile situation that in 1894 erupted into violence and a rebellion of such scale that for a time it threatened the viability of the Chosŏn state. The moving force behind this rebellion were members of the Tonghak faith, a syncretic religion incorporating elements of Confucianism, Daoism, and Catholicism. The founder of the faith, Ch’oe Che-u, had been executed by the state in 1864, and by the early 1890s the faithful petitioned the government for his exoneration without significant result. The Tonghak finally took up arms in the summer of 1894, but by that time the aggrieved were no longer limited to Tonghak believers but also tens of thousands of peasants suffering under official abuse and the burdens of socio-economic inequality. The uprising met with considerable early success and established what amounted to a proto-state that administered large swaths of the southwest of the country and enacted reforms that deposed corrupt officials, abolished status distinctions, rectified systems of taxation, and curtailed foreign commercial activity in an effort to correct local and regional market distortions (Weems 1964; Han’guk Yŏksa Yŏn’guhoe, 1991, 1993, 1995, 1997; Kallander 2013; Moon 2013b; Young 2014). The Chosŏn government initially found itself unable to stop the Tonghak advance toward Seoul and called upon the Qing Empire to intervene military. The Qing military escalation prompted the Japanese to send an expeditionary force as well. By this time the Chosŏn government has managed to stop the Tonghak advance through negotiation, but the close proximity of Qing and Japanese forces soon led to combat and the opening of the Sino-Japanese War of 1894–1895 (Cho Chae-gon 2003; Pak Yŏng-jae 2003). The Japanese quickly took Seoul and surrounded the palace. Under these circumstances King Kojong readily agreed to a Japanese proposal to form a “deliberative council” (kun’guk kimuch’ŏ) under the leadership of Kim Hongjip. In the nearly six months that it was active, from July through December of 1894, the council enacted more than 200 laws, collectively known as the Kabo Reforms, named for the kabo year 48

Historiographies of Korean reform movements

of the lunar calendar (1894–1895) in which they began. The reforms, based in no small part on the Meiji reforms enacted in Japan in late 1860s and through the 1870s, restricted the Chosŏn government by establishing the post of prime minister, creating a cabinet, and completely reorganizing the old ministries. The new government stripped away much of the authority of the throne and placed it in the new office of the prime minister and his cabinet, concentrated all fiscal authority in the newly created ministry of finance, and abolished the civil service examination system. The reforms also brought an end to slavery, yangban legal privilege, stategranted merchant monopolies, torture, and guilt by association while embracing the principle of the rule of law, creating a hierarchical system of courts and a new police system, adopting the Gregorian calendar, and implementing a Western-style education system with an emphasis on training in the technology and the sciences (Son In-su 1980; Yu Yŏng-ik 1990; Yi Haemyŏng 1991; Yu Yŏng-ik 1998, 2003). The scope of the political and social change embodied in these reforms was enormous and thus, unsurprisingly, they did not meet with the unanimous support of the court. The king had been side-lined in the process and there were more than a few officials, and even the politically powerful Queen Min herself, who approved neither of the pace and content of the reforms nor of the central role played by the officials of the Japanese legation. By 1895 the Japanese had won a decisive victory against the Qing Empire and appeared unassailable, but before they were able to consolidate their position, Russia, Germany, and France, in what has come to be known as the Triple Intervention, pressured Japan into forfeiting its lease on the Liaodong Peninsula that it had recently won in the peace negotiations with the Qing Empire (Kang Ch’angil 2003). Sensing weakness, anti-Japanese and pro-Russian elements in the Chosŏn court deposed key pro-Japanese officials and threatened continued Japanese influence. In October of 1895, believing her to be the locus of the anti-Japanese faction, Japanese minister Miura Gorō sent assassins armed with swords into the queen’s quarters where they murdered her and her ladies-in-waiting and then burned her body on the courtyard. The assassination served only to ignite a nationwide outrage and stir anti-Japanese sentiment into a storm of unprecedented apoplexy. By February of 1896, the king had fled his own palace to take refuge in the Russian legation, where he, his inner circle, and a coterie of pro-Russian officials conducted the affairs of the Chosŏn state without consultation with the Japanese or their now dwindled supporters at court (Yi Min-wŏn 2003a). The new government and most of the hundreds of reforms it decreed were effectively finished.

The Independence Club Over the three-year period from 1894 to 1896, various factions of the Chosŏn court had depended on direct Qing military intervention, direct Japanese military intervention, and finally on the Triple Intervention and the provision of the haven of the Russian legation. Sŏ Chae-p’il, Yun Ch’i-ho, and others did not see any long-term advantage in the Chosŏn government constantly allying itself with more powerful foreign states and instead sought to define a path of true independence in which a viable Chosŏn state would have sufficient political, economic, military, and diplomatic resources to stand on its own in the international community. To this end, they established the Independence Club in 1896. The club first devoted its energies to the construction of the Independence Gate (tongnimmun) at the site of the old Gate of Welcoming Imperial Grace (yŏngŭnmun) where Chosŏn officials once welcomed Ming and Qing imperial envoys, the acquisition of the former official guest house for Qing envoys and renaming it “Independence Hall,” and the creating of an Independence Park (Chandra 1988). The club also organized a variety of educational activities, including lectures and debates on the issues of the day pertaining 49

Joshua Van Lieu

to the question of Chosŏn independence. Among the more lasting of the club’s projects was the publication of a newspaper in both Korean (Tongnip sinmun) and English (The Independent). The Tongnip sinmun is remarkable not only for its extensive exploration of liberal political ideals but also for its having been published entirely in the Korean vernacular script, now known as Han’gŭl. The club saw independence not only as a political state of being also a cultural condition. Rather than employ the Classical Chinese more common in formal publications of the day, the club employed the vernacular script as a bold statement of Chosŏn political and cultural selfreliance (Yu Yŏng-nyŏl 2003). When the club formed in 1896, the king was still residing in the Russian legation. There is little about that arrangement that could be construed as independent, so the club vociferously called for the king to return to the palace and, moreover, declare the Kingdom of Chosŏn an empire and declare himself an emperor rather than a king. This would place Chosŏn on the same level as the Japanese, Qing, and Russian empires on its borders and move the Chosŏn state that much further to safeguarding its independence in a maelstrom of global imperial rivalries. When the king left the Russian legation and return to his palace, he did indeed declare himself an emperor with his own reign era, “kwangmu,” and he renamed the state “the Great Han Empire” (Yi Min-wŏn 2003b). It was not hard for the newly enthroned Kwangmu Emperor to find the Independence Club both acceptable and useful in this period as their work of securing Korean independence and calling for the creation of an imperial institution was seamlessly flush with his own intent to become an absolute monarch in both name in reality. As he moved to relocate executive and fiscal authority in the throne, however, the Kwangmu Emperor was to clash with the more liberal strands of the Independence Club of which he was not yet particularly aware (Kim To-hyŏng 1994; Sŏ Yŏng-hŭi 2003; Yi Yun-sang 2003; Hwang, 2006; Kim Dohyung 2006; Chang Yŏng-suk 2010). By the spring of 1898, the Independence Club was publishing editorials and holding public discussions on representative government, popular political participation, and the creation of a deliberative assembly to participate in the creation and implementation of imperial policy. The club proposed the transformation of the Privy Council (ch’ungch’uwŏn) from a body largely without substantive role in deliberation or decision making into something of a national assembly with a central role in policy (Chandra 1988; Wang Hyŏn-jong 2003). Increasingly suspicious of the club’s intentions, the emperor was reluctant to accept the idea. As the throne and its conservative allies either ignored or obstructed the move to create the assembly, the Independence Club organized massive street demonstrations in Seoul calling not only for the creation of the assembly but also for the full implementation of the body of reforms decreed during the Kabo Reforms three years previously. After some waffling in negotiations with the club, the emperor finally ordered the demonstrations forcibly broken up and the leadership of the Independence Club arrested by the end of 1898. The club soon collapsed, and much of its membership dropped out of political activism. By 1899, the emperor stripped the Privy Council of all semblance of deliberative function, utterly extinguishing the vision of a national assembly.

The Patriotic Enlightenment Movement The demise of the Independence Club did not signal the end of its concerns and causes. Indeed, the opening years of the twentieth century saw a growing concern across the country for the very issue that first animated the club: the defence of Korean sovereignty in an increasingly hostile world. The imperial government sold mining, communications, and transportation concessions to foreign interests and throughout the late 1890s and early 1900s as it grew ever more dependent upon Russian guidance and sponsorship. With the Russian defeat in the Russo50

Historiographies of Korean reform movements

Japanese War of 1904–1905, however, the Korean government was left bereft of protection, and by the end of 1905, Japan had coerced the Korean imperial government into a protectorate treaty that stripped it of the right to conduct its own foreign affairs (Ku Tae-yŏl 2003). With this fundamental assault on the sovereignty of the Korean state, the hypothetical fall to foreign imperial powers was rapidly becoming a reality. It was during these final ten years of the Han Empire, from approximately 1900 to 1910, that a nationwide discourse on the nature and defence of Korean identity and sovereignty arose that has come to be known collectively as the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement (aeguk kyemong undong). The Patriotic Enlightenment Movement was coeval in Korea with the flowering of a vibrant public sphere facilitated by multiple newspapers, magazines, and newsletters. Newspapers like the Hwangsŏng sinmun, Cheguk sinmun, Maeil sinmun, Taehan maeil sinmun, and Kyŏnghyang sinmun, among others, ran essays and editorials on an enormous variety of topics (Kim Min-hwan 1988, 1996; Ch’oe Chun 1997; Han Wŏn-yŏng 2002; Robinson 1988; Schmid 2002; Kim Dongno 2006). This newly emerging patriotic enlightenment discourse largely followed two courses: explorations of the western political, cultural, and institutional practices worthy of study and adoption in the struggle to fend off the existential threat to the Korean state and re-examinations of Korean history as part of a project to reimagine a Korean national identity that could serve as the foundation of a strong and thriving independent nation-state (Robinson 1988; Cho Hangnae 1993; Ch’oe Ki-yŏng 1997, 2003; Chŏng Yong-hwa 2004). Many of these discussions delved into a Spencerian Darwinism in which superior peoples and states rose to dominate the world while inferior peoples, saddled with backwardness and ignorance, were doomed to colonization and cultural extinction (Pak Sŏng-jin 2003; Tikhonov 2010). There was an emerging consensus that if Koreans did not refashion themselves into an educated modern people fully cognizant of their national identity and civic duties, Korea would soon vanish, absorbed into the empires of peoples who were fully conscious and committed to the love, defence, and advancement of their own nations. Historians such as Sin Ch’ae-ho (1908) and Pak Ŭn-sik (1915) attributed the purported absence of a Korean national consciousness to centuries of historiographic practice that emphasized participation in a universal Confucian civilization that revolved around China while denigrating Korean language, culture, and history collectively as a primitive vernacular that functioned to obstruct and cloud true human civilization. For Sin in particular, Confucianism was at the very root of Korean weakness. It was Confucianism that encouraged a fetishization of the ancient Chinese past, the erasure of the Korean nation from the historical consciousness of his compatriots, and the weakening of the nation through an emphasis on scholarship and the arts at the expense of the martial skills and values that he deemed so desperately necessary to maintain the Korean state and people before the incoming tides of foreign aggression. While the kinds of socio-cultural transformations for which the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement campaigned may well have been central to the construction of a robust nation-state capable of mobilizing in defence of its sovereignty, the newspapers, organizations, and schools created to foster these changes were too little too late. Indeed, it is arguable that by the conclusion of the protectorate treaty in 1905, the struggle was already lost. Over the five years following the end of the Russo-Japanese War, the Japanese Residency-General systematically dismantled the Korean state until the summer of 1910 when Japan annexed the Great Han Empire outright (Yun Pyŏng-sŏk 2003). Despite the annexation, however, these movements continued to shape much of the future discourses of the nation, development, and independence throughout the colonial period and beyond (Robinson 1988; Schmid 2002; Miyoshi-Jaeger 2003; Duncan 2006). Indeed Korean incorporation into the Japanese Empire may seem to render thirty years of reform movements an interesting yet ultimately futile exercise in failure, but to understand these 51

Joshua Van Lieu

intellectual and political labours in such terms is to turn away from the very real engagement with the modern these movements represented. This realignment of perspective is central to the development of the historiographies of late nineteenth-century reform during the last fifty years.

Post-war historiographies of reform Being the twilight of the Korean dynastic state, the time of some of the earliest Korean encounters with global modernities, and the prelude to the experience of colonization, the late nineteenth century has been the subject of extensive scholarly inquiry. While it is beyond the scope of the present work to cover the entirety of the literatures on the reforms of this period, the remainder of this chapter will discuss primarily the developments in South Korean historiography along with a sampling of some of the more recent works in English. South Korean historians began to look in earnest at the late nineteenth-century reform movements in the 1960s and 1970s. These works were committed to rectifying perceived distortions of Japanese colonial historiography and deeply informed by modernization theory. For these historians, the reform movements represented a pre-colonial proto-modernity that failed to mature due to Japanese colonial intervention. The reformers were ultimately unable to modernize the nation and therefore failed to save it from colonization. With the spread of the democracy and mass movements of the 1980s and early 1990s, many South Korean historians turned to uncovering a Korean history in which the masses, or the people (minjung), were the only authentic subjects of historical change rather than the nation unmediated by class. People’s histories written in this period still identified the failed modernization of the nineteenth century as the prime cause for the loss of nation sovereignty, but they located this in the movements’ refusal to engage the masses. Without popular support, the reformers were doomed to seek foreign sponsorship and ultimately to sacrifice the nation for the sake of their own class interests. During the last fifteen years, research on the period in both Korean and English has made a conscious effort to reconsider both the nation and modernity in the late nineteenth century. Rather than judge the reform movements by their perceived failure to modernize and rescue national sovereignty, these works move beyond these conceptual categories to explore both the movements’ contemporary cultural and intellectual accomplishments and their legacy in the twentieth and twenty-first centuries (Duncan 2006). A sustained and systematic critique of colonial historiography did not fully emerge in South Korea until the 1960s. During the fifteen years following liberation from colonial rule in 1945, national division, the imposition of United States military rule, the Korean War, the flight of left-wing historians to the north, and the continued institutional prominence of historians trained during the colonial period made such a critique difficult to undertake. By the early 1960s, however, a newer generation of historians motivated by the progressive impulses of the April 19 Revolution of 1960 and the public discord over normalization negotiations with Japan opened a discursive space wherein the historiographical legacy of the colonial experience was subject to direct interrogation (Ch’oe Ki-yŏng 2003; Kim In-gŏl, 1994; Kim To-hyŏng 1997; Em 2013). Although intended largely as a general survey of Korean history, Yi Ki-baek’s Han’guksa sillon (A new theory of Korean history), first published in 1961, provides a succinct summary of the emerging critique of colonial histories of Korea. Indeed, the text opens with this declaration: There are many tasks we must take on for the correct understanding of Korean history but the most important work among these is the liquidation (ch’ŏngsan) of the colonial historical perspective (singminjijuŭi sagwan). (Yi Ki-baek 1961) 52

Historiographies of Korean reform movements

This perspective was defined first by what Yi identified as a geographical determinism (chirijŏk kyŏlchŏngnon) in which the fact of Korea’s peninsular geomorphology relegated it to something of a geographical and historical footnote to the dynamic time and space of the continent. This stance precluded the recognition of Korean historical autochthony (chayulsŏng), rendering change attributably only to the heteronomy (t’ayulsŏng) originating from the continent. This alleged peninsular nature of Korea ensured that no significant socio-historical change was possible without some kind of intervention by outside forces. A second claim closely related to the heteronomy thesis is stagnation (chŏngch’esŏng). Unable to produce socio-historical change on its own, Korean peoples remained largely unchanged across the millennia as they maintained agricultural societies that never developed from feudalism to modern capitalism. Finally, Yi pointed to Japanese colonial historians’ invocation of a debilitating factionalism as a Korean national trait (tangp’asŏng). The culmination of this line of scholarship, Yi maintains, is the legitimation of Japanese rule; a society that is unable to change on its own, mired in stagnation, and incapable of self-governance due to endless factional infighting naturally comes to be ruled by other states and, moreover, cannot but benefit from the experience (Ch’oe Ki-yŏng 2003; Em 2013). This was the intellectual legacy that historians of the early 1960s had to negotiate in order to establish a new history free from the politics inherent in the production of colonial knowledge. They adopted an explicit agenda to write histories of Korea that would engage in a continuous assault on colonial perspectives by uncovering Korean historical autochthony. Often uncritically accepting the modernization theory that undergirded the very intellectual regimes they sought to overturn, these historians looked to produce histories foregrounding the development of a proto-capitalism in the late Chosŏn period, anti-colonial struggles of the independence movement, and the emergence of enlightenment thought (kaehwa sasang) in the nineteenth century (Ch’oe Ki-yŏng 2003). Studies of the Korean enlightenment in particular provided opportunities to show that Korean intellectuals were well aware of the internal and external problems facing the Chosŏn state and society in the nineteenth century and were actively and strategically engaged in the very reforms of thought and policy that evinced an internal dynamism to Korean intellectual and political history. One of the most prolific historians of the 1960s and 1970s writing on Korean enlightenment thought was Yi Kwang-nin. Yi wrote dozens of field-defining articles on the figures, texts, and projects of the 1870 and 1880s reform movements. Tracing the beginnings of Korean enlightenment thought to the 1870s, Yi saw reformist impulses born largely of an intellectual curiosity about western technologies. By the 1880s, however, this impulse was to change, Yi maintained, to a more urgent dynamic of selective importation of modern technologies, described by Han U-gŭn’s (1968) notion of “eastern ways, western means.” Korean enlightenment thought changed again from the late 1890s with the Independence Club’s interest in republicanism and sovereignty and the development of nationalist identity politics in the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement prior to annexation. For Yi, Korean enlightenment was a domestic phenomenon born of an intellectual history internal to Chosŏn that over the course of the late nineteenth century came into contact with western enlightenment ideals to produce dialectically a phase of social development capable of transporting Chosŏn from the pre-modern to the modern. Ultimately, however, Yi saw the enlightenment intellectuals of the late nineteenth century as failed conservative reformers unable to enact the systemic changes needed to build a viable Chosŏn independence capable of withstanding the vicissitudes of nineteenthcentury imperialism (Yi Kwang-nin 1969, 1973, 1994; Yi Wan-jae, 1989, 1999). Working from a similar theoretical stance, Kim Yŏng-ho rejected the understanding of Korean enlightenment thought as a reaction to foreign pressures or even as the exogenous introduction 53

Joshua Van Lieu

of a global capitalist modernity. He maintained that kaehwa was itself a part of modernity. Modernity then became for Kim not something external to the Korean historical experience but a phenomenon arising internally as an integral part of the Korean historical experience. The nineteenth century represented a sprouting of the modern akin to the “sprouts of capitalism” of modern Chinese historiography. Kim called for a historical practice that investigated the results of the clash between this indigenous modernity and foreign political, commercial, and intellectual pressure (Yi Wan-jae 1989). Building on the notion of a modernity arising within Chosŏn, the work of Kang Chae-ŏn is of particular interest in this period. He examined the roots of kaehwa thought and linked them back to Pak Che-ga and the Practical Learning and Northern Learning scholars of late eighteenth- and early nineteenth-century Chosŏn (Kyō Zaigen 1973; Kang Chae-ŏn 1982). Kang’s work was a pioneering illustration of the kind of scholarship that could highlight the intellectual vibrancy internal to Chosŏn without dependence on a heteronomous understanding of historical change. There was some question as to how close the relationship really was and whether future work should seek to clarify the connections or look for the disjunctures, but even with these issues, Kang’s work was an early model for scholarship on Korean enlightenment that did not begin from an assumption that Korean intellectual transformation had to be the result of external influences (Yi Wan-jae 1989). Kang’s work was an important step in positing a connection between the kaehwa reform movements and earlier Chosŏn intellectual currents, but the precise points of contact and deviation remained unclear. One strand of kaehwa research in the 1970s thus turned in earnest to the question of origins. Yi Kwang-nin and Sin Yong-ha, among others, suggested that the reformers of the 1880s had been influenced by Chosŏn interpreters who brought Qing texts on Western thought and technology back to Chosŏn and by their interactions with Pak Kyu-su and his intellectual lineage as represented by his grandfather and Practical Learning scholar Pak Chiwŏn (Yi Kwang-nin 1973; Yi Wan-Jae 1989, 1999; Son Hyŏng-bu 1997). It was through this body of scholarship that the intellectual connections between the Practical Learning and Northern Learning schools of the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries and the various enlightenment movements in the final decades before colonization became established in the field of Korean history. There was something of a consensus in the 1970s concerning the nature of the kaehwa movements. First, kaehwa thought was not just a matter of reformist thought imported from Japan or Qing but rather an intellectual practice born of older Chosŏn scholarly lineages that came into contact with foreign practices and ideas. Second, kaehwa thought arose in the midnineteenth century, twenty to thirty years before the radical reformers of the 1880s turned to the Japanese model, and set its roots in the scholarship of eighteenth-century Chosŏn intellectuals like Pak Che-ga and Pak Chi-wŏn. Third, kaehwa thought was at its base a body of conservative reform thought seeking to eliminate the weaknesses of the existing order by adopting the technologies of the west. Finally, kaehwa was bourgeois. The enlightenment thinkers across the movements from the 1880s through to the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement of the 1900s were all of the elite, educated classes. Their intellectual world was limited by their bourgeois class interests and thus their reform proposals were ultimately limited. They were incapable of contradicting their class interests and as a result failed to implement the systemic reforms necessary to preserve the independence of the Chosŏn state (Yi Wan-jae 1989). Although the question of class was not at the forefront of the research on the enlightenment movement during the 1960s and 1970s, political conflict in South Korea from the late 1970s and into the 1980s brought a dramatic change in perspective (Yi Se-yŏng 1997). Among the 54

Historiographies of Korean reform movements

most widely recognized people’s history scholars, Kang Man-gil (1978, 1984) was an active opponent to the authoritarian military government under Chŏn Tu-hwan. In January of 1981, two months after the 1980 Kwangju Massacre, Kang found himself “unemployed,” as he put it, after having been forced to resign from the history department of Korea University for his political activities (Kang 1994). It was during this time that he began work on his two volumes, Han’guk kŭndae sa (Modern Korean history) and Han’guk hyŏndae sa (Contemporary Korean history), both first published in 1984. Kang identified the masses, or the people (minjung) as the only authentic revolutionary subject capable of instituting substantive historical change. It is from this perspective that he provided an alternate reading of the history of nineteenth-century Korean reform movements. Kang located the cause of the failure of the reform movements to save Chosŏn from colonization in the social class of the reformers themselves. From the 1880s to the 1900s, leaders of the various reform movements looked to one another and to foreign sponsors rather than to the Korean people for support. The result, Kang maintained, could only be failure and the inevitable loss of national sovereignty (Kang Man-gil 1984; Kang Man-gil 1994; Em 2013). In his analysis of the Coup of 1884, Kang cited an interview with Sŏ Chae-p’il, one of the central figures of the coup conspirators, in which Sŏ identified their failure to secure the support of the people as the greatest miscalculation, an error that fundamentally undermined the movement. This was an important admission to Kang but not because it indicated a failure on the part of the masses to support a potentially progressive political cause. He noted that the Korean masses had clearly demonstrated their taste and skill for direct political action throughout the nineteenth century both before and after the Coup of 1884. The problem was that the radical reformers of the 1880s themselves did not arise from the masses. The class origins of the men and their ideas was enough to ensure their failure. Kang also noted, in absence of popular support, that the radical reformers had to look to Japan for sponsorship, further eroding their support among the people. It was their rejection of the Korean masses and their embrace of a foreign power that ensured the failure of the movement. Although there have been more recent attempts to reveal popular participation in the Coup of 1884 (Pak Ŭn-suk 2005), Kang’s analysis remains representative of what is still a broadly accepted understanding of the nature of the coup and the root of its failure. The questions of autochthony and heteronomy are Kang’s central concerns in his analysis of the Kabo Reforms. With the central role of the Japanese in creating a political space in which the reforms could move forward, to what degree was the reform program a Korean project and to what degree was it a Japanese imposition? During the first two months in which the deliberative council was active and, Kang notes, the period in which the council decreed the most important reforms, the Japanese were distracted by on-going combat operations against the Qing Empire, leaving Kim Hong-jip, Kim Yun-sik, and Yu Kil-chun. It was not until the autumn when Pak Yŏng-hyo and Sŏ Kwang-bŏm returned from exile in Japan to join the cabinet that Japanese influence overshadowed the reforms. And yet Kang was unwilling to celebrate Kim Hong-jip and his colleagues as exemplars of an authentic national sovereignty for they were among the old gradualist reformers from the 1880s and had no desire to challenge the institution of absolute monarchy; they too actively rejected the Korean masses in favour of foreign favour as they refused to support the Tonghak rebels in their mission to end the abuses of the state and exonerate the founder of their faith. Kang refused to refer to the uprising of 1894 as the Tonghak Rebellion (Tonghangnan), preferring to call it the Peasant War of 1894 (Kabo nongmin chŏnjaeng). There was broad peasant participation in the uprising that went beyond the community of the faithful and the objectives 55

Joshua Van Lieu

of the uprising exceeded matters of faith to include overthrowing what Kang called the “feudal system” in order to execute an authentic socio-political transformation. He saw the uprising as an authentic mass movement for the creation of a new society and as such was the moment at which the Korean people came the closest to realizing their role as the sole true subject of history. In this respect the uprising carried a historical significance greater than any of the other reform movements of the late nineteenth century. This movement too, in Kang’s evaluation, was to fail for the Chosŏn state, ever willing to reject the people for the political sponsorship of foreign powers, facilitated peasant defeat at the hands of the Japanese military. The fate of the Independence Club was somewhat different in Kang’s estimation for it did not meet its end through dependence on foreign powers. He instead identified two factors that lead to its demise. The first was that the club’s demands were too radical and too fast for the emperor to tolerate, especially as he saw the project of the new imperial state as central to establishing in reality the absolute monarchy that existed in theory alone in the political realities of the previous Chosŏn state. The second was the deep elitism of the club leadership. While their drive to establish a parliamentary body was born of their interest in the western liberal traditions of republicanism, Kang points to their denial of the very ability of the uneducated masses beyond the club’s membership to participate in the political process at all. Moreover, the club was vociferously opposed to armed peasant uprisings in the 1890s, referring to them only as bandits to be suppressed. As in the failed reform movement that preceded them, the Independence Club abandoned the masses and in so doing alienated themselves from the only legitimate progressive force in Korean society. Kang saw the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement as burdened by many of the same errors as its predecessors. He took note first of its commitment to obedience to the law and its refusal to advocate direct armed resistance; obedience to the law of the residency-general was already capitulation. The movement could not hope to successfully undermine colonial authority by submitting to it. A further problem was the widespread acceptance of social Darwinism within the movement. This too, Kang argued, was something of a surrender. Presaging some of the work of Andre Schmid (2002) on this period, Kang observed that if it was, as a function of immutable natural law, only the wealthy and powerful states and peoples that were to survive in a world of competing empires, there was little to recommend Korean independence. This identification with the laws and discourses of the colonizing power was coupled with what Kang saw as the movement’s condescension to the masses. Rather than a potent revolutionary force, the intellectual elites leading the movement saw the people as ignorant, pitiful, and in need of an education so as to be made aware of the conditions of their lives and their identities as members of the Korean nation. With the movement’s fundamental identification with the colonizing power and its rejection of the Korean people as equal partners in forging the direction of the nation, Kang pronounced the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement doomed to failure from its very inception. Like the previous iterations of reform in the late nineteenth century, Kang saw ultimately the failure of reform movements to depend on the people. Without popular participation, a modern nation-state was impossible, and without the modern nation-state, there was no viable resistance to colonization. For Kang, this was the thread that ran through all the reform movements, with the exception of the Tonghak uprising, from the moderates of the early 1880s to the radicals of 1884 to the Kabo Reforms to the Independence Club to the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement on the eve of annexation (Kang 1984, 1994). While writings on late nineteenth-century reform movements have been dominated by questions of the location of the authentic nation, the perceived failures of modernization, and ultimately the search for the reasons these movements failed to save Korea from colonization, more recent research demonstrates a shift away from the nation, the masses, failed modernization, 56

Historiographies of Korean reform movements

and even the question of modernization altogether. This realignment has opened new spaces of inquiry previously precluded by the primacy of the nation and its discontents on the eve of colonization. Research on the late nineteenth century has largely turned in the twenty-first to understanding the cultural moment, the experiences of the modern in the 1890s and 1900s that came to serve as the foundations of the places of Korea in the present. Yi T’aejin (2000) has called for a re-examination of the Kojong reign and the Kwangmu reforms of the Great Han Empire period. In a rhetorical style reminiscent of the historiographical project to correct the perceived distortions of colonial historians, Yi argued that received narratives of Kojong’s incompetence and failure were products of western “amateur historians” and Japanese colonial scholarship that were in urgent need of revisiting; the king-cum-emperor was not a corrupt, self-serving, yet inept monarch but rather an enlightened ruler who launched the nation not on a failed path but rather a succeeding but interrupted path to modernization. His declaration of the Great Han Empire and his assumption of the title of emperor were bold statements of Korean sovereignty to the world. His efforts to centralize state authority in the throne were essential to creating a modern state capable of surviving and thriving in a hostile environment. Yi even found reason to evaluate the emperor more highly than the Independence Club, citing its relationship with the Japanese legation. In Yi’s estimation, the suppression of the Independence Club with its suspect contacts with the Japanese was a perhaps unpleasant but necessary task in the construction of an authentically powerful and sovereign state. The Japanese, Yi suggested, ultimately intervened and terminated this path toward a mature modernity that the Kwangmu reforms, left untouched, would have produced (Yi T’aejin 2000; Kyosu Sinmun Kihoek 2004). Andre Schmid’s (2002) monograph Korea Between Empires, 1895–1919 is a broad exploration of the discursive production of the Korean nation in the myriad publications of the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement and the first decade of the colonial period that he posited as the foundation of modern Korean nationalism. Here Schmid was not concerned with the question of success or failure in resisting colonization; his work was not about what did not happen but rather about what did. The writers and educators of the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement produced an enduring construct of the Korean nation that arguably remains relevant to the present day. The critical distance with which Schmid approached the question of the Korean nation allowed for the creation of a more permeable understanding of the domestic and the foreign. Here Schmid understood the creation of Korean nationalist discourse not in the terms delineated by the 1960s poles of heteronomy and autochthony. The discourses of the Patriotic Enlightenment Movement were not, as earlier scholars like Yi Kwang-nin or Kang Chae-ŏn might have suggested, a matter of an internally developed intellectual system coming into contact with an external body of ideas and practice. Schmid saw the interplay of the local and the global in this formation of nationalist discourses from the very moment of their inception. A further current took shape in the extensive project out of the Korean Culture Research Institute of Ehwa University (Ihwa Yŏdae Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏn) on the question of modernity from 1896 to 1910. The institute had already taken an interest in this period in previous publications (Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏn 1999), but it embarked upon an especially ambitious three-volume project (Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏn 2004, 2006, 2007) to more fully address the origins of Korean modernity. A collective of more than a dozen scholars working in the institute designated this time the “modern enlightenment period” (kŭndae kyemong ki) and identified it as the moment from which the Korean modern emerges. Through close discursive analyses of the print media of the period, especially the Independence Club publication Tongnip sinmun, the authors argue that the print capitalism that arose in Korea facilitated a vibrant public sphere. This discursive space served to mediate world and self so as to produce a distinctly modern sense of individual subjectivity, society, and political practice. The authors argue that there was 57

Joshua Van Lieu

in this period a Korean modernity pre-colonial in origin in which not only the educated elites but also the people (inmin) came to the fore as socio-political actors and the progenitors of Korean modernity writ large (Chŏng Sŏn-t’ae 2006, 2007; Yi Sin-ch’ŏl 2011). In recent years the intersection of religious faith and political action manifest in the Tonghak movement has attracted renewed scholarly attention with the work of George Kallander (2013) and Carl Young (2014). Like Schmid, Kallander and Young both refrain from evaluating the Tonghak faith by the metric of preventing colonization, of success or failure vis-à-vis the nation. They look instead to the ways in which participants understand their own involvement and the political, social, and familial relationships that formed in Tonghak communities and the impacts they had on the dynamics of colonial Korean society and beyond. While Young focuses on the changes in the organizational structure of the Tonghak faith into its later iteration as Ch’ŏndogyo, Kallander has examined the movement as a refuge from material and physical hardship in a world of increasing cultural and geopolitical uncertainty. In moving away from the Tonghak movement as an exclusively nationalist, anti-colonial phenomenon, Kallander’s work opens greater potentials for research into facets of the Tonghak experience not often seen in previous work, such an examination of the impact of the movement on community and family life in rural Korea at the end of the century. Perhaps the most radical departure from both the narratives of the nation and modernization, Yumi Moon’s Populist Collaborators (2013b) examines the Ilchinhoe, an organization often omitted from the historiography of late nineteenth-century reform movements altogether. For decades written off as treasonous stooges of the Japanese, the Ilchinhoe, or the “Advance Together Society,” was advocate for Japanese rule in the years before the annexation. Moon asks her readers not to judge their collaboration anachronistically but to take into consideration the conditions and possibilities of the period in recognition of the conceptual poverty of the collaboration/resistance binary. Moon notes that for some, empire can represent opportunity rather than enslavement, while aligning with the nation does not always result in freedom. More than anything else, the Ilchinhoe, with its overwhelmingly grassroots membership, was an organization concerned with the welfare of the common people. This concern transcended the national and welcomed the creation of a political order that the organization deemed capable of bringing the greatest good. Moon thus maintains that the Ilchinhoe was neither national nor colonial, neither traditional nor liberal. Her work abandons both nation and modernity to create a field of vision now capable of engaging with a more complete accounting of the myriad experiences of the colonial (Moon 2013a, 2013b).

Prospects Research in Korean history has travelled great distances since the first interrogations of colonial historiography in the 1960s. Much of the scholarship through the 1980s and even beyond has been a navigation and a negotiation of the colonial, a coming to terms with both past experience and contemporary legacy. The field also spent years in close cohesion with the telos of modernization theory, but here too both Korean-language and Anglophone literatures have gone to great lengths to sever relationships with this framework and its conceptual limitations. There is now a significant body of literature of intellectual heft that explores the myriad facets of the fin-de-siècle Korean modern through interdisciplinary projects that bring together the theoretical and methodological practices of historians, political scientists, and scholars of literature. These reconsiderations of experiences and dynamics occluded in previous works harnessed to expunging the colonial, to rescuing the nation, and to failures or successes of perceived processes of modernization have yielded empirically rich and theoretically exciting 58

Historiographies of Korean reform movements

results. As the field moves with greater enthusiasm toward research in the global engagements of the Korean modern, some of the most recent work has moved beyond the discursive communities of Korea scholars to speak to issues of more global concern. Kallander and Moon in particular have produced work that not only illuminates questions of concern to that which we might call the Korea field but also speaks to larger issues of the global with their critical engagements with dissent, resistance, collaboration, and the production of spaces of practice beyond the binaries of national/colonial or traditional/modern. These are intellectual spaces of global concern to which the developing scholarship on the late nineteenth-century reform movements in all their permutations is now poised to contribute.

References Chandra, V. (1988) Imperialism, Resistance, and Reform in Late Nineteenth-Century Korea: Enlightenment and the Independence Club. Berkeley, CA: University of California Institute of East Asian Studies. Chang In-sŏng. (2002) Changso ŭi ukuche chŏnch’i sasang. Sŏul: Sŏul Taehakkyo Ch’ulp’anbu. Chang Yŏng-suk. (2010) Kojong ŭi chŏngch’i sasang kwa chŏngch’i kaehyŏngnon. Sŏul: Sŏnin. Cho Chae-gon. (2003) “Ch’ŏng-Il chŏnjaeng kwa 1894-nyŏn nongmin chŏnjaeng” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 40: Ch’ŏng-Il chŏnjaeng kwa kabo kaehyŏk. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Cho Hang-nae, ed., (1993) 1900-nyŏndae aeguk kyemong undong yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Asea Munhwasa. Cho Sŏng-yun. (2003) “Imo kullan” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’ah Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 38: Kaehwa wa sugu ŭi kaltŭng. Sŏul; Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Ch’oe Chun. (1997) Sin pop’an Han’guk sinmunsa. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Ch’oe Ki-yŏng. (1997) Han’guk kŭndae kyemong undong yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Ch’oe Ki-yŏng. (2003) Han’guk kŭndae kyemong sasang yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Chŏng Sŏn-t’ae. (2006) “Ch’aek mŏri e” in Yihwa Yŏdae Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏn, ed. Kŭndae kyemong ki chisik palkyŏn kwa sayu chip’yŏng ŭi hwaktae. Sŏul: Somyŏng Ch’ulp’an. Chŏng Sŏn-t’ae. (2007) “Ch’aek mŏri e” in Yihwa Yŏdae Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏn, ed. Kŭndae kyemong ki chisik ŭi kulchŏl kwa hyŏnsilchŏk simhwa. Sŏul: Somyŏng Ch’ulp’an. Chŏng Yong-hwa. (2004) Munmyŏng ŭi chŏngch’i sasang: Yu kil-chun kwa kŭndae han’guk. Sŏul: Munhak kwa Chisŏngsa. Ch’ŏnga P’yŏnjippu, ed. (1983) Kapsin kabo ki ŭi kŭndae pyŏnhyŏk kwa minjok undong. Sŏul: Ch’ŏnga Ch’ulp’ansa. Cook, H. (1972) Korea’s 1884 Incident. Seoul: Royal Asiatic Society, Korea Branch. Duncan, J. (2006) “The Confucian Context of Reform” in Kim Dong-no, John B. Duncan, and Kim Do-hyung, eds. Reform and the Modernity in the Taehan Empire. Seoul: Jimoondang. Em, H. (2013) The Great Enterprise. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Han U-gŭn. (1968) “Kaehang tangsi ŭi wigi ŭisik kwa kaehwa sasang” in Han’guksa yŏn’gu 2. Han Wŏn-yŏng. (2002) Han’guk sinmun han segi. Sŏul: P’urŭn Sasang. Han’guk Yŏksa Yŏn’guhoe, ed. (1991) 1894-nyŏn nongmin chŏnjaeng yŏn’gu 1: Nongmin chŏnjaeng ŭi sahoe kyŏngjejŏk paekyŏng. Sŏul: Yŏksa Pip’yŏngsa. Han’guk Yŏksa Yŏn’guhoe, ed. (1992) 1894-nyŏn nongmin chŏnjaeng yŏn’gu 2: 18, 19-segi ŭi nongmin hangjaeng. Sŏul: Yŏksa Pip’yŏngsa. Han’guk Yŏksa Yŏn’guhoe, ed. (1993) 1894-nyŏn nongmin chŏnjaeng yŏn’gu 3: Nongmin chŏnjaeng ŭi chŏngch’i sasangjŏk paegyŏng. Sŏul: Yŏksa Pip’yŏngsa. Han’guk Yŏksa Yŏn’guhoe, ed. (1995) 1894-nyŏn nongmin chŏnjaeng yŏn’gu 4: Nongmin chŏnjaeng ŭi chŏn’gae kwajŏng. Sŏul: Yŏksa Pip’yŏngsa. Han’guk Yŏksa Yŏn’guhoe, ed. (1997) 1894-nyŏn nongmin chŏnjaeng yŏn’gu 5: Nongmin chŏnjaeng ŭi yŏksajŏk sŏngkyŏk. Sŏul: Yŏksa Pip’yŏngsa. Hwang, K. (2006) “Governmental Growth in the Taehan Empire Era: Origins of the Modern Korean State” in Kim Dong-no, John B. Duncan, and Kim Do-hyung, eds. Reform and the Modernity in the Taehan Empire. Seoul: Jimoondang. Kallander, G. (2013) Salvation through Dissent. Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Kang Ch’ang-il. (2003) “Samguk kansŏp kwa ŭlmi sabyŏn” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 41: Yŏlkang ŭi igwŏn ch’imt’al kwa tongnip hyŏphoe. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. 59

Joshua Van Lieu

Kang Chae-ŏn (Kyō Zaigen). (1982) Han’guk kŭndaesa yŏn’gu. Sŏul; Hanul. Kang Man-gil. (1978) Pundan sidae ŭi yŏksa insik. Sŏul: Ch’angjak kwa Pip’yŏng. Kang Man-gil. (1984) Han’guk kŭndaesa. Sŏul: Ch’angjak kwa Pip’yŏngsa. Kang Man-gil. (1994) Koch’yŏssŭn han’guk kŭndaesa. Sŏul: Ch’angjak kwa Pip’yŏngsa. Kim Dong-no. (2006) “Views of Modern Reforms as Depicted in the Hwangsŏng sinmun during the Taehan Empire” in Kim Dong-no, John B. Duncan, and Kim Do-hyung, eds. Reform and the Modernity in the Taehan Empire. Seoul: Jimoondang. Kim Dong-no, John B. Duncan, and Kim Do-hyung, eds. (2006) Reform and the Modernity in the Taehan Empire. Seoul: Jimoondang. Kim Do-hyung (Kim To-hyŏng). (2006) “Introduction: The Nature of Reform in the Taehan Empire” in Kim Dong-no, John B. Duncan, and Kim Do-hyung, eds. Reform and the Modernity in the Taehan Empire. Seoul: Jimoondang. Kim In-gŏl. (1997) “1960, 1970-nyŏndae naejaejŏk palchŏllon kwa han’guk sahak” in Kim Yong-sŏp Kyosu Chŏngnyŏn Kinyŏm Han’guk Sahak Nonch’ong Kanhaeng Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Hang’guksa insik kwa yŏksa iron. Sŏul: Chisik Sanŏpsa. Kim Min-hwan. (1988) Kaehwa ki minjok ji ŭi sahoe sasang. Sŏul: Nanam Ch’ulp’an. Kim Min-hwan. (1996) Han’guk ŏllonsa. Sŏul: Sahoe Pip’yŏngsa. Kim, Sun Joo. (2007a) Marginality and Subversion in Korea. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Kim, Sun Joo. (2007b) “Taxes, the Local Elite, and the Rural Populace in the Chinju Uprising of 1862” in The Journal of Asian Studies 66(4): 993–1027. Kim Sŏng-bae. (2009) Yugyojŏk sayu wa kŭndae kukche chŏngch’i ŭi sasangnyŏk. Sŏul: Ch’angbi. Kim Tae-jun. (2004) Kojong sidae ŭi kukka chaejŏng yŏn’gu. Sŏul: T’aehaksa. Kim To-hyŏng (Kim Do-hyung). (1994) Taehan cheguk ki ŭi chŏngch’i sasang yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Chisik Sanŏpsa. Kim Yong-sŏp Kyosu Chŏngnyŏn Kinyŏm Han’guk Sahak Nonch’ong Kanhaeng Wiwŏnhoe, ed. (1997) Hang’guksa insik kwa yŏksa iron. Sŏul: Chisik Sanŏpsa. Kyō Zaigen (Kang Chae-ŏn). (1973) Kindai chōsen no henkaku shisō. Tōkyō: Nihon Hyōronsha. Kyosu Sinmun Kihoek, ed. (2004) Kojong hwangje yŏksa ch’ŏngmunhoe. Sŏul: P’urŭn Yŏksa. Ku Tae-yŏl. (2003) “Rŏ-Il chŏnjaeng” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 42: Taehan cheguk. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Larsen, K. (2008) Tradition, Treaties, and Trade: Qing Imperialism and Chosŏn Korea, 1850–1910. Cambridge, MA: Harvard East Asian Monographs. Lew, Young Ick (Yu Yŏng-ik). (1984) “Yuan Shih-kai’s Residency and the Korean Enlightenment Movement, 1885–94” in The Journal of Korean Studies 5: 63–108. Miyoshi-Jager, S. (2003) Narratives of Nation Building in Korea: A Genealogy of Patriotism. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Moon, Y. (2013a) “Immoral Rights: Korean Populist Collaborators and the Japanese Colonization of Korea 1904–1910” in The American Historical Review 118(1): 20–44. Moon, Y. (2013b) Populist Collaborators. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. No Tae-hwan. (2005) Tongdo sŏgiron hyŏngsŏng kwajŏng yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ilchisa. Pak Sŏng-jin. (2003) Sahoe chinhwaron kwa singminji sahoe sasang. Sŏul: Sŏnin. Pak Ŭn-sik. (1915) Han’guk t’ongsa. Sanghae: Taedong P’yŏnyŏkkuk. Pak Ŭn-suk. (2005) Kapsin chŏngbyŏn yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Yŏksa Pip’yŏngsa. Pak Yŏng-jae. (2003) “Ch’ŏng-il chŏnjaeng” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 40: Ch’ŏngil chŏnjaeng kwa kabo kaehyŏk. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Palais, J. (1975) Politics and Policy in Traditional Korea. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Robinson, M. (1988) Cultural Nationalism in Colonial Korea, 1920–1925. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Schmid, A. (2002) Korea Between Empires, 1895–1919. New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Sin Ch’ae-ho. (1908) “Toksa sillon” in Taehan maeil sinbo, serialized August 27–December 13. Sin Yong-ha. (2000) Ch’ogi kaehwa sasang kwa kapsin chŏngbyŏn yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Chisik Sanŏpsa. Sin Yong-ha. (2003a) “Kapsin chŏngbyŏn ŭi chŏn’gae” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’ah Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 38: Kaehwa wa sugu ŭi kaltŭng. Sŏul; Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Sin Yong-ha (2003b) “Kapsin chŏngbyŏn ŭi yŏnghyang kwa ŭiŭi” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’ah Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 38: Kaehwa wa sugu ŭi kaltŭng. Sŏul; Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Sŏ Yŏng-hŭi. (2003) Taehan Cheguk chŏngch’isa yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Sŏul Taehakkyo Ch’ulp’anbu. Son Hyŏng-bu. (1997) Pak Kyu-su ŭi kaehwa sasang yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Son In-su. (1980) Han’guk kaehwa kyoyuk yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ilchisa. 60

Historiographies of Korean reform movements

Sŏul Taehkkyo Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guso, ed. (2003) Han’guk kŭndae sahoe was munhwa: 19-segi mal esŏ 20-segi ch’o rŭl chungsim ŭro. Sŏul: Sŏul Taehakkyo Ch’ulp’anbu. Tikhonov, V. (2010) Social Darwinsim and Nationalism in Korea. Leiden, Netherlands: Brill. Van Lieu, J. (2009) “The Politics of Condolence: Contested Representations of Tribute in Late NineteenthCentury Chosŏn-Qing Relations” in The Journal of Korean Studies 14(1): 83–115. Van Lieu, J. (2010) Divergent Visions of Serving the Great: The Emergence of Chosŏn-Qing Tributary Relations as an International Politics of Representation. Doctoral dissertation, University of Washington. Wang Hyŏn-jong. (2003) “Taehan cheguk ki iphŏn nonŭi wa kŭndae kukkaron” in Sŏul Taehkkyo Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guso, ed. Han’guk kŭndae sahoe was munhwa: 19-segi mal esŏ 20-segi ch’o rŭl chungsim ŭro. Sŏul: Sŏul Taehakkyo Ch’ulp’anbu. Weems, B. (1964) Reform, Rebellion, and the Heavenly Way. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press. Yang Chin-sŏk. (2003a) “Samjŏng ŭi mullan” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 32: Chosŏn hugi ŭi chŏngch’i. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Yang Chin-sŏk. (2003b) “Samjŏng kaehyŏk ŭi chŏn’gae” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 32: Chosŏn hugi ŭi chŏngch’i. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Yi Hae-myŏng. (1991) Kaehwa ki kyoyuk kaehyŏk yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ŭryu Munhwasa. Yi Ki-baek. (1961) Han’guksa sillon. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Yi Kwang-nin. (1969) Han’guk kaehwasa yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Yi Kwang-nin. (1973) Kaehwadang yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Yi Kwang-nin. (1994) Kaehwa ki yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Yi Kwang-nin. (1999) Han’guk kŭn-hyŏndaesa non’go. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Yi Min-wŏn. (2003a) “Agwan p’ach’ŏn” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 41: Yŏlkang ŭi igwŏn ch’imt’al kwa tongnip hyŏphoe. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Yi Min-wŏn. (2003b) “Taehan cheguk ŭi sŏngnip” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 42: Taehan cheguk. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Yi Se-yŏng. (1997) “1980, 1990-nyŏndae minjuhwa munje wa yŏksahak” in Kim Yong-sŏp Kyosu Chŏngnyŏn Kinyŏm Han’guk Sahak Nonch’ong Kanhaeng Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Hang’guksa insik kwa yŏksa iron. Sŏul: Chisik Sanŏpsa. Yi Sin-ch’ŏl. (2011) “Tongnip hyŏphoe wa manmin kongdonghoe ŭi ‘kŭndaesŏng’ nonŭi kŏmt’o” in Sarim 39: 27–53. Yi T’aejin. (2000) Kojong sidae ŭi chae chomyŏng. Sŏul: T’aehaksa. Yi Wan-jae. (1989) Ch’ogi kaehwa sasang yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Minjok Munhwasa. Yi Wan-jae. (1999) Pak kyu-su yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Chimmundang. Yi Yun-sang. (2003) “Taehan cheguk ki ŭi chaejŏng chŏngch’aek” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 42: Taehan cheguk. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Yihwa Yŏdae Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏn, ed. (1999) Taehan cheguk yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Paeksan Charyowŏn. Yihwa Yŏdae Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏ, ed. (2004) Kŭndae kyemong ki chisik kaenyŏm ŭi suyong kwa kŭ pyŏnyong. Sŏul: Somyŏng Ch’ulp’an. Yihwa Yŏdae Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏn, ed. (2005) Han’guksa yŏn’gu 50-nyŏn. Sŏul: Hyean. Yihwa Yŏdae Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏn, ed. (2006) Kŭndae kyemong ki chisik palkyŏn kwa sayu chip’yŏng ŭi hwaktae. Sŏul: Somyŏng Ch’ulp’an. Yihwa Yŏdae Han’guk Munhwa Yŏn’guwŏn, ed. (2007) Kŭndae kyemong ki chisik ŭi kulchŏl kwa hyŏnsilchŏk simhwa. Sŏul: Somyŏng Ch’ulp’an. Young, C. (2014) Eastern Learning and the Heavenly Way. Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Yu Yŏng-ik (Lew Young Ick). (1990) Kabo kyŏngjang yŏn’gu. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Yu Yŏng-ik (Lew Young Ick). (1998) Tonghak nongmin ponggi wa kabo kyŏngjang. Sŏul: Ilchogak. Yu Yŏng-ik (Lew Young Ick). (2003) “Kabo kyŏngjang” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 40: Ch’ŏng-il chŏnjaeng kwa kabo kaehyŏk. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Yu Yŏng-nyŏl. (2003) “Tongnip hyŏphoe ŭi kibon sasang” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 41: Yŏlkang ŭi igwŏn ch’imt’al kwa tongnip hyŏphoe. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Yun Pyŏng-hŭi. (2003a) “Kapsin chŏngbyŏn ŭi paegyŏng” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’ah Wiwŏnhoe ed. Han’guksa 38: Kaehwa wa sugu ŭi kaltŭng. Sŏul; Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Yu Pyŏng-hŭi. (2003b) “Kapsin chŏngbyŏn ŭi chudo seryŏk” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’ah Wiwŏnhoe ed. Han’guksa 38: Kaehwa wa sugu ŭi kaltŭng. Sŏul; Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe. Yun Pyŏng-sŏk. (2003) “Kukkwŏn ŭi cheyak” in Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe, ed. Han’guksa 42: Taehan cheguk. Sŏul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwŏnhoe.

61

5 Religion 1876–1910 Albert L. Park

Studying the history of religion in Korea is never an easy task. This field of study includes parties affiliated with a specific religion who compete with each other to furnish the authoritative account on the value and influence of religion over time in Korea. Religious parties exhaust their energies to ensure their interpretations of the past become hegemonic in order to authorize and legitimize religious claims and truths in the present. In particular, certain parties, especially those related to Christianity, study Korean religious history as a trajectory of events and developments with a beginning, middle, and end that is preordained by a higher being. Religious parties study the past in this way with the hope of finding the signs that will guide them to their predetermined, brighter future. They rely on history to produce and sustain truths that help shape the contours of religious belief and faith. For these religious parties, historical investigation is a process for crafting a narrative of events and developments that will buttress a specific spiritual cause and enforce religious orthodoxy. This milieu for studying and writing about religion in Korean history has hampered drives for critical, full inquires on the development and evolution of religious ideas, practices, and institutions. First, religious parties have tended to focus on the heroic, spiritual aspects of a religion to show its value, influence, and strength. Second, they deemphasize change within the religion to show its power of continuity from the past to the present. Focusing on the gallant periods of a religion’s history gives a narrow picture of a religion in which all of its sides cannot be comprehensively exposed and understood, while stressing continuity over change ignores the influence of a person’s agency and social happenings over a religion’s development. Failing broadly to socially contextualize the development of religion has curbed discussions on Korean religious history. With the exception of scholarship on the history of Buddhism in Korea by academics such as Jin Y. Park and Robert Buswell and works on new religions by George Kallandar and Carl Young, the inability of academic scholarship to fully study the development of religion in relation to material events, interactions, especially from the economic realm, only intensifies this incomplete understanding of Korean religious history. What these works fail to appreciate and take into account is the “lived religion” approach to studying Korean religious history. This paradigm of analysis views “things as a result of social processes” in that religious ideas and practices originate and gain meaning and value in the context of social relationships, interactions, 62

Religion 1876–1910

and events (Taves and Bender 2012: 10). In particular, the lived religion approach emphasizes practices as processes and calls attention to “its embeddedness and relations within a range of settings and concepts” rather than studying practice as an isolated object of study (ibid.: 13). Lived religion’s emphasis on practice not only allows for a full explanation on how religions change over time and are related to economic, political, and cultural processes, but it also enables engaging and viewing religion as more than just about personal belief and spirituality. Nowhere is the absence of the lived religion paradigm of analysis seen more than in academic publications on the history of Christianity in Korea. Scholars who study Protestant Christianity, such as Sung-Deuk Oak and Timothy S. Lee, have published many works on church history that primarily emphasize the spiritual value of and promote Christianity. The perspectives and methodologies of missiology guide the writing and research of these scholars. A number of works approach the study of the history of Catholicism in Korea with a very narrow focus in that they fail to connect religious developments with social processes. Consequently, these works prevent the study of religious issues from becoming a platform for understanding larger issues and themes, such as modernity, capitalism, authoritarianism, and gender inequality. Their narrow ways of studying Christianity have only diverted readers’ attention away from how Christianity has negotiated and changed in relation to material transformations and developments in modern Korea and has only sustained the substandard approach to studying not only Christianity in Korea, but also Korean religious history. These traditional ways of studying religion in Korean history have ultimately framed religion as nothing other than just as a means for spiritual belief and experiences. Yet, in closely studying religious developments between 1876 and 1910—a time when Koreans experienced the gradual loss of their political independence and immense ruptures in their lives because of the various forces of modernity—it becomes quite apparent that religion’s value and significance extended well beyond the realms of the spiritual and the sacred. At that time, the Treaty of Kanghwa (1876) linked Korea to the capitalist world system and ushered in diverse forces and processes from the outside that tested the strength and influence of established beliefs, customs, and institutions. The forces of capitalism, imperialism, democracy, immigration, and science and industry widely influenced people’s daily happenings from cities to the countryside. As outside powers fought for control of Korea, the new and the old collided to forge an environment of powerful social changes. From Korea’s opening to the outside world to its colonization by Japan in 1910, this time period represented a frenzied moment in history in which nothing, including religion, was left untouched. This frenzied backdrop from the late nineteenth century to the early twentieth century invites a careful consideration of how religions fared and negotiated the milieu of social change. Religions, at that time, were not isolated things, but instead they were embedded in society and lived out within a wide range of settings. Figures from established and new religions were creating and reconceptualizing sacred languages, practices, symbols, and institutions in order to adapt their respective religions to the dynamic social processes that were playing out in society. What was clearly evident during this period was an urgent drive by religious leaders and followers to not only survive this time of change but also to make religion a relevant tool to represent and give meaning to the maelstrom of changes. Koreans from all types of backgrounds sought ways to give meaning to their new experiences because established forms of knowledge and belief failed to do so. Responding to this new demand, religious leaders crafted powerful languages, practices, and customs that could overcome the limits of established belief systems. Many Koreans adopted these fresh forms of representation and relied on them to ground their identity, make sense of new sensations, mediate social relationships, and evaluate and negotiate their daily happenings. During this period, religion was more than just a medium for spiritual experiences; 63

Albert L. Park

it also served as a medium for valuing things, structuring behavior, enhancing and sustaining power, and increasing wealth. Studying religious developments from 1876 to 1910 in relation to material developments and social processes requires being mindful that religions were embraced and practiced for various reasons other than for just encountering the sacred. Alongside being aware of different motivations for embracing religion, it is just as important to pay careful attention to religion being a lived process that has been shaped by realms of power, which has been understudied by scholars of Korean religious history. In large part, the inability of scholars to embrace various forms of theory, especially from the fields of cultural studies and post-colonial studies, has prevented a complete picture on how power dynamics inside and outside of religions determined spiritual language and conditioned the direction of religious groups and institutions. In particular, as religions became more institutionalized, struggles over defining orthodoxy between groups within religions led to campaigns to eliminate heterodoxy and thus differences. Being conscious of power influencing and shaping religion in the history of Korea helps us to avoid assuming that “religion is a transhistorical constant—whether defined in terms of belief, feeling, or symbolic meanings” and to start instead viewing religion as “historically distinct social forms and forces” (Boy 2011).

Legacy: a brief survey of religion before 1876 The religious landscape of Korea before 1876 featured Koreans primarily following Buddhism, Shamanism, or Daoism. Each of these religions was popular because of its power of valuation. Religions furnished people with languages and signs with which they could use to evaluate the importance of something. This process of valuation gave people a framework through which to cultivate desires, make decisions and act creatively, and structure their behavior in relation to others—thus informing and undergirding people’s agency. The state’s ruling philosophy during the Chosŏn Dynasty (1392–1910) was Neo-Confucianism, but it allowed people to practice any religion as long as they never countered or challenged Neo-Confucianism on any large scale. The state lacked elaborate surveillance, punishment mechanisms, and institutional forms of violence, but it was always committed to using any resources it had toward wiping out any dissent. The state showed that it would never tolerate religious opposition and dissent through the way it cracked down on Buddhism. Buddhism entered Korea from the middle to the late part of the fourth century and steadily grew popular among people and rulers of kingdoms on the peninsula. Koryŏ Dynasty (935–1392) leaders showered Buddhist monks and monasteries with tax-free lands and servants and money and gave key monks unfettered access to the courts to be advisors. Blaming Buddhism for weakening the finances of the state, leading leaders astray, and breaking down the Koryŏ political order, Chosŏn leaders and bureaucrats swiftly withdrew the institutional support Buddhists had received from the previous state and conducted campaigns to suppress Buddhist influence starting in the early 1400s. Some of the more aggressive actions against the Buddhist establishment included confiscating temple land, decommissioning hundreds of temples, forcing temple servants to become soldiers, and preventing monks from entering Seoul and crossing the border to China. By the middle of the eighteenth century, there were nearly 1,500 temples—down from over 2,200 temples during the end of the Koryŏ period (Kim 2012: 24–45). Yet, in spite of these crackdowns, Buddhist groups tried to survive and maintain their influence in society through creating new institutions and organizations, such as Temple Fraternities (sach’algye)—voluntary organizations that engaged in economic activities to raise money for Buddhist activities and for the maintenance of rituals and temples. 64

Religion 1876–1910

Chosŏn kings and government hounded Buddhism because they categorized it as heterodoxy. Defining Buddhism as heterodoxy grew out of a fear of it weakening and delegitimizing NeoConfucianism as the authoritative system of knowledge to explain the workings of the universe and how things should be in order for a harmonious social order. There was a genuine fear among statesmen and Neo-Confucian scholars that digressing from the practice of NeoConfucian principles would lead to social breakdown and disorder and even the collapse of the universe—thus ruining the potential for the establishment of an ideal present and future. Because the state was the guardian of the ruling philosophy, it feared that Buddhism’s delegitimization of Neo-Confucianism would also undermine its own authority and legitimacy. In maintaining Neo-Confucianism as the authoritative mechanism for knowing and valuing, the Chosŏn state required people to rely on Neo-Confucianism to make sense of their desires and emotions—to validate or invalidate them. Yet, what happened when certain occurrences and feelings could not be made sensible and explained by Neo-Confucianism? Were people’s feelings about death, spirits, and the supernatural simply considered invalid and left alone because Neo-Confucianism refused to incorporate mystical and otherworldly elements into its cosmology? Shamanism played a significant role in people’s lives in filling in the void left by the inability of standard Neo-Confucian language and concepts to address certain topics. Through its elaborate cosmological order that was inhabited, directed by, and controlled by deities, Shamanism gave people the knowledge to make sense of the unknown and to undergo new encounters and experiences to resolve tensions in their daily lives. For example, during periods of droughts during the Chosŏn era, shamans (mudang) on the behalf of farmers would perform elaborate ceremonies that called for spirits to bring rain. Women from the landed gentry (yangban) also turned to shamans to help them communicate with spirits in order to find the spirit of a deceased family member or resolve a child’s illness. Shamanism gained value as a means for people to overcome their disconcerted feelings of the unknown and any anxieties resulting from them (Walraven 1999: 185). Shamanism was an extremely popular religion, but the Chosŏn state never waged an all-out battle to limit the influence of Shamanism like it had done with Buddhism. It tried to control shamans by requiring them to register and pay taxes and banning them from performing state-sponsored rituals and from entering the capital, but these measures were hard to enforce. Some local government officials took it upon themselves to limit the power of shamanism through violent measures, such as Yi Hyŏn-san—the governor of Cheju Island who ordered the destruction of 129 shamanistic shrines in the early eighteenth century—but there were never any violent campaigns of persecution conducted by the central state. Even if the state had wanted to wipe out Shamanism, it would have been extremely difficult due to it being an unorganized religion with no system of authority and organization over shamans that could be easily identified and dismantled. Authorities recognized that Shamanism gave relief to people in areas that Neo-Confucianism could not sufficiently address and that shamans were far from being radical leaders who called on followers to reject Neo-Confucianism. Consequently, authorities mostly let people practice Shamanism freely. For the most part, people in the Chosŏn period formed their own moral bricolages, which involved combining beliefs and practices from many religions to develop their own systems of belief, that people relied upon to inform their worldviews. As long as Koreans developed their own moral bricolages or practiced Buddhism or Shamanism while still carrying out NeoConfucian practices, the state paid little attention to them. In fact, the state had little to fear in people rejecting the ruling ideology and organizing religious-inspired rebellions as long as the state continually pursued the construction of an ideal Neo-Confucian and cared for the welfare of the people. Yet, starting in the eighteenth century, Chosŏn authorities entered a period of 65

Albert L. Park

flux that featured ideological and social instability as natural disasters and outbreaks of diseases worsened social and economic conditions and as certain Neo-Confucian traditions and structure began to erode due to the rise of new forces, such as capitalism. As social conditions deteriorated, the state struggled to uphold its traditional Neo-Confucian responsibilities of protecting and leading because it lacked money and resources. The breakdown of the Neo-Confucian order led to the rise of new religions that drew people seeking relief from the disorder. For example, Maitreyan millenarian movements, which featured the belief that Maitreya—a Buddhist Messiah—will appear and create a utopian world after the existing world had fallen into a disorderly state, drew people who desired changes that would “save the common people from starvation, epidemics, and oppression and exploitation by the ruling class” (Ro 2002: 35). Other people turned to movements guided by the goals outlined in Chŏnggamnok, which promised a Taoist savior creating a new world and capital for the people. Finally, Catholicism rapidly grew after Yi Sŭng-hun, a scholar who was baptized in Beijing in 1784, returned to Korea to spread the new religion and its promise of salvation to all people regardless of their standing in the social hierarchy system. It was such a popular new religion that there were nearly 4,000 followers of Catholicism even before the arrival of the first Catholic missionary to Korea from China in 1794. Like Buddhism and Shamanism, these new religions offered to people alternative forms of knowing that gave them a sacred interpretation of the transformations in society and new values through which to make sense of feelings that resulted from the breakdown of the long-standing order. Unlike Buddhism and Shamanism, what was particularly striking about these new religions was their power to lead people to question Neo-Confucianism’s legitimacy through public acts, such as the burning of ancestor tablets by two Catholics in 1790, and armed rebellions against the state, such as the Kyŏngnae Rebellion of 1812. Through their experiences of these new religions, people underwent a process of forging new identities that sprung forth awareness that things were not right and were not going to improve. This process unleashed a potent form of agency among followers of these new religions, which inspired them to use violence to overcome the imbalance and instability in society. This historical moment of new religions questioning Neo-Confucianism and rebelling against the state largely arose because of 1) the vast changes threatening customs and structures of traditions and 2) the state being without enough resources to uphold the Neo-Confucian system and wipe out the new religions. The state had crushed Catholicism through persecution campaigns in 1801, 1815, 1846, and 1866, but it was unable to wipe out all of the new religions that were popping up daily. Into the 1870s, there was a growing popularity for new religions among the people because the state was unable to keep up with all of the changes in society and carry out reforms that would align what is (material reality) with what should be (the ideal vision of material reality) as it had done in the early and middle periods of the Chosŏn dynasty.

Religion and modernity in late Choso ˘ n Korea (1876–1910) The rise of modernity in the late nineteenth century sprung forth even more ruptures and changes in society that led to a sharp increase in the number of new religions that tried to bridge the disjuncture between what is and what should be. In the context of late nineteenth century Korea, the modern should be understood as a chronological category that became staged or imagined through ideological processes as a universal period of history that had its origins in the West and was considered the crucial step toward achieving progress and the highest state of being. The features of the modern period that had distinguished it from earlier periods became the chief elements of a model of development that many Koreans and non-Westerners believed 66

Religion 1876–1910

they needed to adopt in order to reach the modern stage of history. For many Koreans at that time, the process of becoming or achieving the state of being modern required the adoption and cultivation of particular features, especially capitalism, industrialization, and urbanization. This normative view of the modern or modernity became dominant among leaders in the state and intellectuals after Japan had used gunboat diplomacy to force Korea to sign the Treaty of Kanghwa in 1876, which officially opened up Korea to the outside world. To King Kojong and nationalist leaders, such as the leaders of the Independence Movement, the threat of Western and Japanese imperialism to Korea’s independence added urgency to becoming modern, which for them was a process that mostly involved adopting ideas, customs, and institutions from the West. Starting in the early 1880s, the challenge for King Kojong and state officials was to balance the new changes that resulted from modernization with the preservation of the Neo-Confucian order. Despite embracing modernity, the state never rejected Neo-Confucianism as its ruling ideology. It clung to traditions while introducing vast reforms that threatened the survival of traditions because the reforms brought changes to the political, economic, social, and cultural realms. The growth of capitalism further threatened the survival of Neo-Confucian practices and customs. Historical evidence has shown that the agrarian economy featured new developments starting in sixteenth-century Chosŏn society that signified the emergence of capitalism in Korea. At that time, agricultural productivity increased through technological innovations and new farming techniques. These developments resulted in surplus crops that were sold at markets, which grew as important sites of vibrant commercial activity. At these markets, new forms of currency, such as silver and cloth, aided the process of selling and exchanging agricultural goods. By the beginning of the nineteenth century, the countryside showed signs of a growing agricultural market with a certain level of rural cultivators moving away from selfsubsistence farming. These capitalist developments gave way to many instances of elites turning away from their traditional responsibilities for the pursuit of wealth, yangban landlords mistreating their peasant tenants by replacing them with more productive tenants or unwilling to provide welfare in the case of natural disasters, and people moving up and down the social hierarchy system with wealthy merchants and farmers purchasing the yangban social status from yangban who were in debt. The indigenous capitalist forces combined with the new forces of modernization to create an uneven society that looked nothing like the ideal society that had been envisioned by Neo-Confucianism. The changes caused from the top and below sharpened the disjuncture between what is and what should be. This new milieu demonstrated that Koreans were starting to enter a period of “breakdown”—“when people are expelled from their old forms . . . before they can find their way in the new structures” (Taylor 2002: 99). Koreans on a mass scale turned to new religions for guidance through and relief from this phenomenon of breakdown. Many people turned to new religions that had emerged near the turn of the century, but other Koreans grew enchanted with the teachings of new religions that were growing popular after 1860. The “old” and “new” new religions were similar in many ways in that they were usually founded by a charismatic person and syncretistic. Yet, new religions after 1860 distinguished themselves from established new religions through the mechanisms they created to spread, promote, and institutionalize their religious principles and practices. These mechanisms facilitated the circulation of information, knowledge, languages, sentiments, and desires between individuals nearby and far away from each other. In this capacity, these mechanisms fostered vibrant networks of intimacy that forged links and exchanges between people, which positioned them to experience new types of social relationships, develop and reflect over their identities, and design different forms of organization. For many followers of new religions, these networks of intimacy became the 67

Albert L. Park

chief mediums through which to organize people toward realizing their visions of an ideal society that embodied the beliefs of their religion. Among the new religions, Tonghak (Eastern Learning) became the most effective new religion to forge vibrant networks for exchange and mobilization. Tonghak originated from what many people perceived as the strange thought and behavior of Ch’oe Che-u (1824–1864). The combination of his own personal problems and the changes erupting throughout society, especially the threat of foreigners coming to Korea, appeared to cause Ch’oe to be without direction and full of anxiety and confusion. Confucianism, for Ch’oe, no longer helped him understand his personal problems or the problems in Chosŏn society. Feeling distressed and disoriented, Ch’oe had an experience one day in April 1860 that fundamentally changed his life. According to Ch’oe, he heard the voice of Sangje, who told him to teach humankind about the way (pŏp) and relieve humanity from sickness. To do so, Sangje gave Ch’oe a symbol that was an “elixir of life” and told him to teach it to others. Sangje promised Ch’oe a fulfilling immortal life if he performed this mission. Ch’oe took the symbol, wrote it on a piece of paper, and consumed it. Immediately, Ch’oe wrote that he grew healthier and stronger and that his “illness” had disappeared. Using his experience with Sangje as a source of inspiration and direction, Ch’oe spent the following months articulating and defining the tenets of his new religious message, especially the meanings and roles of Sangje and Chigi (Ultimate Energy). Ch’oe eventually named his new religion Tonghak (Eastern Learning) in 1861 and often stated that it was a mixture of many religions in that it melded together tenets from other systems of knowledge, such as Catholicism and Confucianism, to produce a religion that truly addressed the needs of the people. From Buddhism, he adopted the ideas of benevolence, and he borrowed ideas about God from the Catholic meaning of God (Ch’ŏnju). From Confucianism and Daoism, respectively, he appropriated the idea of ideal human relations and ethical principles and the concept of changing the internal spirit in order to cleanse oneself from negative elements. Among the most important elements of the Tonghak religion that Ch’oe created and developed was the concept that humans can connect to and become part of Ultimate Reality, which Tracy describes as the force that was the “origin and end of all Reality” and “from which all comes and toward which all moves” (Tracy 1987: 89). Because Ultimate Reality was a force immanent and residing in all, Ch’oe concluded that all individuals possessed the power to become part of and one with Ultimate Reality. Unlike the Christian concept of God as a distant and transcendent being who possessed only divine nature, Ch’oe believed that Ultimate Reality resided within humans, who thereby could connect with this divine force; Ch’oe often heard Ultimate Reality reaffirming the fact that as the main force in the universe, it resided in humans. Ch’oe’s message drew a large following of people who found comfort in the Tonghak message in the midst of change. Ch’oe’s proselytization campaigns unsurprisingly concerned government officials. Worsening social, economic, and political conditions had already begun to expose the contradictions in the Confucian world order and had therefore undermined the state’s power and authority to order reality. The growing popularity of Tonghak and the state’s inability to decipher it caused the state to become uneasy about Ch’oe, and he was arrested with other Tonghak leader and executed in 1864 for spreading a heterodox religion. Succeeding Ch’oe, Ch’oe Si-hyŏng started the process of transforming Tonghak into an organized religion with established doctrines, rites, and rituals and a comprehensive structure of governance. In order to immortalize and spread the founder’s messages, Ch’oe oversaw the compilation and publication of Ch’oe Che-u’s essays and poems in the early 1880s. Next, Tonghak leaders ordered followers to carry out various acts, such as attending a weekly public worship service. Finally, they demanded followers to abide by certain rules, such as abstain from drinking and smoking. 68

Religion 1876–1910

Ch’oe, in particular, told followers that the principle of treating and respecting each individual as divine (sainyŏch’ŏn) should ground their behavior and actions. These reforms and developments were expected to establish disciplined environments that would reinforce belief among followers. Yet, Ch’oe Si-hyŏng and other Tonghak leaders understood that belief could not be sustained by sacred rules and practices alone. It also required the creation of an effective leadership structure. Ch’oe Si-hyŏng built a top-down leadership organization in which central Tonghak leaders selected and appointed other leaders to oversee local chapters. Through this system, the top leadership maintained surveillance and control over the local areas. The central leadership of the Tonghak group further solidified its control over local areas and established a more efficient organizational structure through the implementation of the p’o system in 1884. Under this system, the supreme leader of the Tonghak was at the top. Under him and his assistants was a regionally based organization (p’o). At the bottom, in villages and local communities, was a local congregation (jup). A leadership council presided over regional and local congregations. The council was made up of a chief (kyojang), a teacher (kyosu), a chief administrator (tojip), a judge (chipgang), a counselor (taejong), and a censor (chongjŏng). This council served as the leadership structure in regional offices and local villages wherever Tonghak members lived and thus maintained a disciplined environment in which Tonghak doctrine was practiced. There is no doubt that the process of transforming Tonghak into an organized religion was expected to structure and punish followers in ways that would sustain their belief and make them into ardent followers. Yet, more than just experiencing a system of discipline, Tonghak followers also encountered a system of circulating knowledge that exposed them to ideas that gave meaning to and ordered the changing world around them. As followers performed rituals communally and abided by the same rules, it organized their everyday lives and informed social relationships and identities. Equally important, it laid the foundation for a sacred community that could easily share information and exchange goods. Unsurprisingly, then, this system became a valuable resource to organize movements when a number of Tonghak followers started a rebellion against the Chosŏn state in the 1890s over their disgruntlement over the conditions of society and the government’s persecution of Tonghak followers. In early 1894 in the southwestern province of Chŏlla, Chŏn Pong-jun, a Tonghak leader, mobilized enough followers and resources to capture most of the areas in the Chŏlla provinces by May 1894. Along the way, many slaves, daily workers, and peasants joined this movement. An examination of the demands made by the Tonghak leadership shows that their main grievances were against the state and thus not a class-centered movement. They demanded abolition of unfair taxes, punishment of corrupt local officials, and the prohibition of grain exports. The rebellion had gained steam with its success against the Korean army, but Tonghak forces were ultimately stopped by a combined force of Japanese and Korean troops in December 1894. There are still many debates whether or not the Tonghak Rebellion was a religious-inspired movement. Indeed, despite originally being started by Tonghak members and later supported by the main leaders of Tonghak, the Tonghak Rebellion was less about achieving a new spiritual kingdom based on Tonghak beliefs and more about establishing religious freedom and overcoming foreign imperialism. In fact, the main participants in the revolution were nonTonghak individuals who did not see the movement through religious lenses. Even the Tonghak core leadership, such as Ch’oe Si-hyŏng, never thought of starting a mass social movement to create a new world where the ideal spiritual state could unfold; only after Japan threatened Korea’s sovereignty did Ch’oe support the emerging rebellion. What is less debated is the fact that Tonghak leaders organized the religion in a way that supplied new networks for communication, exchange, and organization for people. 69

Albert L. Park

The end of the rebellion drove many participants toward other new religions that promised the birth of a better world. Many people turned to Chŭngsan-gyo, which was a new religion created by Kang Il-sun. Chŭngsan-gyo promised salvation for anyone in a new world who had “refrain[ed] from mistreating anyone, stay[ed] away from sin, and ke[pt] a pure heart” (Ro 2002: 43). It became a popular new religion, but it lacked the organizational power of Tonghak and therefore never became a significant religion. One of the new religions that had become just as powerful and influential as Tonghak was Protestant Christianity. Unlike Tonghak and other new religions, it was not founded by a single charismatic leader and syncretic. Yet, Protestant Christianity’s appearance in 1884 with the arrival of Dr. Horace Allen, a Presbyterian missionary, gave Koreans another alternative system of belief to established religions—thus becoming a new religion. In fact, it eventually developed a larger presence than Tonghak, especially because it was supported by the Chosŏn state. After the arrival of Horace Underwood (PCUS) and Henry Appenzeller of the Methodist Episcopalian North Church (Methodist North Church) in 1885, King Kojong and his advisors steadily supported Protestant Christian missionaries with the hopes of them helping to modernize Korea by introducing Western medicine, technology, and education.1 Contemporary Protestant Christian leaders in Korea will often attribute the popularity of Christianity in late nineteenth-century Korea to powerful spiritual influences. Yet, looking closely at how the religion was organized and spread enables anyone to see that Christianity grew because it offered new religious language to make sense of the changes in society and created institutions that introduced mechanisms for spreading Christianity and fostering networks. Occurrences at the P’yŏngyang Revival clearly show why so many Koreans grew enamored with Christianity. By all accounts, the P’yŏngyang Revival in 1907 became the watershed moment that fundamentally transformed the future of Protestant Christian activities in Korea. In January 1907, missionaries organized several large tent meetings and prayer meetings in P’yŏngyang, which was considered the center of Christianity in Korea. At first, the revivals evoked very tepid responses from people who attended the various meetings, leaving both missionaries and Korean Christian leaders deeply disappointed and with heavy hearts. The mood of the revival, however, quickly transformed into a state of euphoria when five to six hundred individuals participated in an all-night prayer meeting and “man after man would rise, confess his sins, break down and weep, and then throw himself to the floor and beat the floor with his fists in a perfect agony of conviction” (Lee 1907: 34). Throughout the P’yŏngyang Revival and other subsequent revivals, missionaries consistently called on Koreans to confess their sins and ask God for forgiveness because they believed that sin was the root of all social problems. Koreans responded to this call and revealed the transgressions they had committed against God. Some Christians asked for forgiveness for petty crimes, such as stealing. Many men confessed to hating others, adultery, misuse of funds in churches, pride, envy, murder, and lusting after women (Lee 1907: 34; Ladd 1908: 107–109). The majority of people, however, confessed to sinning against the colonial occupiers by having “hatred of the Japanese, and even . . . murderous thoughts and plans towards them” (Ladd 1908: 107–109). According to observers, the environment at the revival meetings was like a huge storm in which Koreans spent days and nights publicly confessing their sins and seeking God’s forgiveness and approval. One observer described the heightened state of emotion in the revival meetings: “He [a Korean man] beat the hard wooden flooring till his hands bled, he shrieked and begged for mercy. ‘Is this what sin is?’ said the awe-stricken multitudes. ‘We never knew it was so awful. We had thought it a trifle, but, behold, here is what God thinks’” (Gale 1909: 209–210). To Koreans, it was sin that was causing their pain and suffering; it was the root of all of their problems and separated them from God. 70

Religion 1876–1910

Urging Koreans to declare their sins and ask for forgiveness publicly, missionaries made sin into a symbol that explained why Korean society was in a poor state and Koreans were suffering so much. At the time of the P’yŏngyang Revival, Koreans lived in a state of trauma in which all the political, social, and economic events and changes, especially the 1905 Protectorate Treaty, could not be explained by existing signs and symbols. The existing languages failed to explain the origins of the turmoil in Korean society. Unable to supply reasons for their current predicament, people, according to historical accounts, suffered and were in a state of confusion and disarray. By telling Koreans to concentrate on revealing their sins and transgressions, religious leaders enabled Koreans to make a connection between their individual sins and the overall state of their country; humans were alienated from God and therefore were separated from his love because of sin. With this meaning of sin, Koreans were able to name their suffering and pinpoint its origins. Knowing the root cause of their problems gave Koreans the opportunity to endure their current predicament. As Clifford Geertz points out, religious symbolism enables humans to cope with suffering by “placing it in a meaningful context, providing a mode of action through which it can be expressed, being expressed understood, and being understood, endured” (Geertz 1973: 105). The revival meetings became a time when individuals learned a new language with which to speak of their suffering and were able to identify the source of their problems. Through this process, people could overcome the unknown and were now equipped with the knowledge not only to overcome their confused, traumatic state but also to endure and engage present concerns and future possibilities. The P’yŏngyang Revival and the overall revival movement became a defining moment for Protestant Christians because they showed Koreans the value of Christianity in helping them negotiate the challenges in their lives, which helped legitimize Christianity in society. As church leaders preached about sin and the need for repentance, Koreans encountered Christianity not only through the 321 churches that had been built by 1905, but also through the number of Protestant institutions throughout the peninsula that had been established by Protestant institutions. Protestant groups, for example, expanded health services in Korea by introducing Western medicine and establishing medical facilities.2 They also established institutions to create an elaborate social service structure. Building schools and Bible institutes became a priority because educational institutions would be the main means to disseminate religious ideas and beliefs and introduce knowledge and subjects taught in Western schools. PCUS and Methodist North missionaries led the introduction of a new and elaborate educational system in Korea by establishing primary, secondary, and high schools as well as colleges.3 Both Presbyterians and Methodist missionaries and the Young Men’s Christian Association (YMCA) built technical schools called Industrial Education Departments (IEDs) that taught Koreans about industrial labor and industrial capitalism. Missionaries decided that industrial work was the most suitable means to teach the work ethic because both missionaries and Koreans thought of industrialization as a requirement to become civilized and enlightened. Transforming Koreans into productive industrial workers was a process open to both young males and females, but it was anything but equal. IEDs taught vocations to males that involved machinery, while women were expected to learn occupational skills that would require only the use of their hands. Practicing what students learned took place in factory-like settings in buildings that housed IEDs. Because IEDs in the Anna Davis School, the John Wells School, and the Songdo Textile Department taught students how to manufacture textiles, these IEDs set up rows of hand, foot, and power looms on the main floor of the IED buildings. Alongside technical skills, the IEDs also taught students rudimentary business skills. At the John Wells School, students learned how 71

Albert L. Park

to use the abacus and perform simple arithmetic and elementary bookkeeping. Teachers at the school also taught students “modern business methods.” The YMCA IED offered lectures on such themes as “the dignity of labor,” “the value of money,” and “methods in the modern business world.” These classes and lectures provided a definition of success and showed how business transformed a person into an upstanding Christian. As students in IEDs prepared to establish an industrial capitalist society in Korea by learning how to operate a business, manufacture commodities, and market their goods, IEDs also enabled students to conceptualize Korean society as an economic system for producing and exchanging goods and services for money and profit. In fact, IED students could probably imagine the entire world, not just Korean society, as an intertwined economic system as they watched the goods they produced exported abroad. The students encountered new social imaginaries that viewed society as the main space for the performance of capitalist activities. Like the Physiocrats and Adam Smith, IEDs helped promote the belief that “the most important purpose and agenda of society [is] economic collaboration and exchange” (Taylor 2002: 105). Moreover, IED students would have believed that these ideas about economics and society were “correct” since they were validated by religious principles, which were considered the most authoritative and authentic principles. IEDs furnished young Korean students with the knowledge, practices, and language needed to anchor their everyday lives and helped inform the kinds of social relationships they would develop. In fact, in IEDs as well as in churches and other Protestant institutions, Koreans developed new social relationships that led to new commercial developments. Merchants and figures in commerce also found opportunities to come together at church and organize groups to invest in companies throughout the peninsula. In 1911, merchants and commercial figures in the Presbyterian Church started the P’yŏngyang Chŏkŏm Chohap (P’yŏngyang Saving Cooperative) and supplied capital for a silk-reeling company. Alongside the P’yŏngyang Chŏkŏm Chohap, the Kunkŏm Chŏch’uk Siksan Chohap (Cooperative for Thrift, Saving, and Industry) originated in 1917 through the efforts of Korean Christian leaders, missionaries, and Korean lay leaders, who invested in a factory that manufactured socks. The Protestant Church furnished diverse networks for all types of organization—even for nationalistic purposes. Inspired by the life of Jesus Christ, several well-known nationalist leaders not only fully gave themselves to the church but also used their resources and power to organize nationalist campaigns to strengthen Korea politically, economically, and socially. Nationalist figures who were devoted Christians, like An Ch’ang-ho and Sŏ Chae-p’il, believed that Christian principles should inform a new civic morality or public virtue for Koreans and organized movements that embodied Christian values. Attributing America’s greatness to Christianity, Yun Ch’i-ho (1864–1945), a well-known Methodist, spoke out about the need of Christian-based educational and social reforms to produce a stronger national community. An, Sŏ, Yun, and others like them believed that by embracing Christianity and adopting Western-based reforms, Korea would become a modern, powerful country that would be able to resist Japanese imperialism. Perhaps no one at that time was more willing to carry out this model of religious and social development than Yi Sŭng-hun (1864–1930). Yi is known for his nationalist activities in the Sinminhoe (New People’s Association) and for promoting Christianity through various institutions, such as Osan Academy (1907), which he founded as a Christian school. As a leading merchant, Yi played an active role in organizing a number of business ventures with fellow Presbyterians. In 1908, for example, Yi helped start Sangmudongsa, one of the first general merchandise stores in Korea. In 1909, Yi also led the movement to start joint-stock companies through the P’yŏngyang Chagi Chusik Hoesa (Pyŏngyang Porcelain Company), which raised 72

Religion 1876–1910

60,000 won and employed sixty-one Koreans by the time it closed in 1919. Behind all these business ventures was Yi’s hope that Korean companies would be able to compete with Japanese businesses coming into Korea and resist Japan’s takeover of the economy and the country. Despite these nationalistic efforts, the majority of Christians and most missionaries were against the intersection of religion and politics. Contrary to contemporary studies that mythologize Western missionaries and Korean Christians as figures who fought against Japanese imperialism, missionaries, in particular, “conceived as the ultimate goal of their missions the saving of souls, not the amelioration of Korea’s social or political ills” (Lee 2000: 127). Because nationalist activities and sentiments by followers could jeopardize the church’s relationship with the Japanese and divert the church from its main priority of converting Koreans, Protestant missionaries not only kept out of nationalist politics but also exhorted followers to avoid worldly affairs like anticolonial struggles. Moreover, they spoke out little, if at all, against the problems caused by modernization, especially poverty and the dislocation of people’s lives. Homer B. Hulbert, Dr. Frank W. Scofield, and a few other missionaries criticized Japanese colonialism, but the majority of missionaries and Korean Christian leaders called for followers to cultivate their personal relationship with God. For the Christian community, the transformation of Korea should take place first in the individual and not in society. From the late nineteenth century into the first decade of the twentieth century, religious language was valued for its power to interpret and make sense of the transformations occurring in society, while religious institutions, practices, rituals, and rules were well regarded for structuring behavior and everyday life and creating diverse forms of organization and community. The language coming out from the new religions, in particular, became a means for people to talk about modern mystifications and put them into a meaningful framework that could produce an informed awareness and a calm sensibility of the new social milieu. Especially as the forces of modernization and government policies like the Kabo Reforms (1894) and King Kojong’s Fourteen Article Oath (1895), which officially dismantled the Neo-Confucian order, eroded traditions, customs, and long-standing social relationships, the new religions laid down a system of norms, values, and networks that could reground people’s identities and everyday lives that had been shaken by all of the changes. The popularity of new religions among Koreans arose from the desires for systems of knowledge to help them negotiate the social, economic, and political processes erupting around them and visualize the direction and make-up of the present and future.

Religion, power, and belief (1900–1910) The waning of Neo-Confucianism and the rise of new religions contributed to the construction of a pluralistic religious milieu with competing values and belief systems. Koreans in late Chosŏn society even saw diversity within religious groups themselves as followers and leaders held different interpretations of key religious texts and what constituted as sacred practices. Leaders of religions tried to push followers into believing in and abiding by a common set of beliefs and practices, but followers always founds spaces of autonomy where they could work out different religious views and encounter diverse experiences. Into the first decade of the twentieth century, however, followers faced a growing trend of religious organizations centralizing power. Whether out of the need for survival or to crush dissent, certain religious organizations started to streamline their organizations by forging a centralized system of authority, demarcating what was orthodoxy and heterodoxy, and establishing surveillance and disciplinary systems to ensure compliance of new rules. The new forms of power threatened spaces of autonomy and narrow differences 73

Albert L. Park

in thought and practice. As such, structures of power were in place to determine attitudes, sensibilities, desires, and ultimately what and the way followers should believe—thus showing that matters of belief are far from just private and internal. Tonghak underwent significant reforms after the Tonghak Rebellion that led to the dismantling of the existing leadership structure and the renaming of the group as Ch’ŏndogyo in 1905. The execution of Ch’oe Si-hyŏng left a power vacuum in Tonghak leadership between Son Pyŏng-hŭi and Yi Yong-gu. Both men fought over the direction of Tonghak and what Tonghak stood for in society. Son, in particular, sought to align Tonghak activities with the Chosŏn state’s modernization programs and develop Korea into a civilized and enlightened country, while Yi had come to support pro-Japanese organizations. Differences over the interpretation of religious doctrines further divided both individuals. The internal power struggle led to Yi leaving Tonghak to form Sich’ŏngyo and Son to lead Ch’ŏndogyo as each group professed to be the true inheritors of Ch’oe Che-u’s legacy. Following the establishment of Ch’ŏndogyo, Son consolidated the former Tonghak community by issuing strict rules and reforms. He issued the Charter of Ch’ŏndogyo in 1906— a new organizational plan that centralized decision-making power in the leader and established a new bureaucracy that included an office of religious inspectors who communicated the leader’s commands to local followers and required followers to be obedient to the leadership. What was emerging under Son’s leadership was a distinct view and authoritative interpretation of traditional Tonghak language that needed to be followed in order to be identified and recognized as a Ch’ŏndogyo believer; it was a system of interpretation and identification that was backed up by disciplinary mechanisms. Dissent was met with power and punishment. For Buddhism, differences were being narrowed through the new linkages being established between the state and established Buddhist groups. The inflow of Japanese Buddhist groups to the peninsula for the purpose of proselytizing to Koreans and the desire to be free from abuses by yangban and corrupt officials led Buddhist leaders to ask the government for a new regulatory body to oversee Buddhism. In 1902, the Chosŏn state issued the Temple Ordinance that put Buddhist temple and sect under that Bureau of Temple Administration, which was overseen by the Department of the Royal Household. The ordinance established a new administrative structure that supervised the temples and monks. It also instituted new laws and regulations, such as conferring ranks on monks and requiring them to be certified as monks by the state. If any monk disobeyed the new laws, they were to be punished and disrobed (Kim 2012: 154–157). The ordinance provided new forms of protection for Buddhists, but it also opened it up to the possibilities of limiting diversity in Buddhism. The 1902 Ordinance concentrated power under a central authority—that is, the state—who had the means to uniformly organize and develop Buddhism in a particular way, which had not been the case in the late nineteenth century. It is unclear as to how many monks and followers of Buddhism were punished for holding and spreading different views and thus going against the ordinance, but what surely arose was a new system to make sure that Buddhism was organized, practiced, and believed in a singular way. In fact, as more Korean Buddhist temples forged alliances with Japanese Buddhist temples after the Japanese Resident-General’s Office issued the 1906 Regulations on Religion that regulated Japanese Buddhist missionary activities on the peninsula, Korean Buddhist groups became easy targets for outside actors with their own motivations for changing the make-up of Buddhism. Through the 1902 Ordinance and alliances with Japanese Buddhist temples, Korean Buddhists encountered centralized systems of power that threatened the diversity of Buddhism. The first wave of Protestant Christian groups centralizing activities occurred in the first decade of the twentieth century. Immediately following the P’yŏngyang Revival, the Presbyterian Church solidified its presence in Korea by establishing an independent Presbytery of Korea on 74

Religion 1876–1910

September 17, 1907.4 Though this form of reorganization gave the Presbyterian Church a better way to coordinate activities and eliminate the competition to attract Koreans among the various Presbyterian groups, it did lead to the standardization of Presbyterian doctrines and practices. In particular, evangelicalism became the dominate theology in the Presbyterian Church. Imported from the United States, evangelicalism in Korea aimed to simplify the Christian messages by plainly stressing that people were in a natural condition of sin and therefore salvation could be procured only through their acceptance of Jesus Christ as their savior. Moreover, Presbyterian missionaries, especially Samuel A. Moffett, stressed that followers needed to live a pure moral and ethical life and never subject the Bible to any forms of deeper theological investigation because it was directly from the mouth of God. Most importantly, missionaries demanded that followers convert others to Christianity. Evangelicalism promoted this simple message as the crux of Christianity instead of emphasizing theological investigation and social activism to fight political, economic, and social injustice as central to Christian faith. Evangelicals considered the world a place of evil and a breeding ground for sin. Therefore, in order to maintain and preserve their moral life, evangelicals called for followers to refrain from getting involved with political and socioeconomic issues and to focus instead on cultivating one’s moral and religious life and spreading the Christian message. They reinforced this message through forms of punishment, such as demanding that followers spread the message to others as a precondition of baptism and church membership. For those Korean followers who valued Christianity as a vehicle for combating social and economic ills and political oppression, they encountered a Presbyterian establishment that denied them access to Presbyterian services and institutions and tried to limit their influence inside and outside of the church. Influenced by the conservatism of evangelicalism, missionaries and Korean Christian leaders tried to limit the growth of liberal, progressive forms of theology, which were popular among Canadian Presbyterian missions to Korea, and to eliminate dissent. From the 1910s to the 1930s as Koreans experienced Japanese colonialism and mass economic, social, and cultural problems that resulted from the forces of modernity, progressive Korean Christians battled with conservative Christians over the meaning and purpose of Christianity and the church’s resources and institutions for the hope of realizing their respective visions of the nation-state. In fact, this conflict between progressive and conservative forces was found in most religious circles—both established and new. Conservatives and progressives both valued religion because it ordered the world and grounded their daily lives and identities. Yet, they fought over how to incorporate change into religion and adapt religious traditions to the present. Gaining an edge in this conflict was extremely challenging in light of the Japanese colonial state heavily regulating religion and sometimes waging all-out wars against religion, like it had against Shamanism since the 1910s because it was an “irrational” religion. During and after colonialism, the challenge for many progressive religious groups was to make sure religion remained as an open source of enchantment, exploration, and imagination and to prevent it from becoming an unchanging force of closure, discipline, and punishment that only features narrow thoughts and practices. Religion today in South Korea remains a powerful force that continually influences political, economic, social, and cultural structures at a time when many Koreans are seeking various systems of belief for guidance and support with rapid changes happening around them daily—just like many Koreans had in the late Chosŏn period. Continuously studying the relationship between religion and social trends and processes in society allows for greater understanding of how religions change over time. Yet, more importantly, it enables for great clarity as to why religion remains popular among Koreans and serves as a valuable tool to negotiate modernity despite long-standing arguments by intellectuals that religion would lose significance with the rise of modernization 75

Albert L. Park

and secularization and the decline of spiritual belief. In short, studying the relationship between religion and social processes serves as a vital vehicle for raising provocative questions and drawing up answers about the human condition under modernity and the role of religion in creating values and mechanisms through which to negotiate and makes sense of the myriad social, economic, political, and cultural forces surrounding modern subjects.

Glossary Tonghak (Eastern Learning): Tonghak was one of the first major new religions that was founded in 1860 by Ch’oe Che-u. As a nativist religion, the main principles of Tonghak were drawn from traditional Korean religious and philosophical systems, such as Confucianism and Shamanism. It is mostly known as one of the primary forces behind major peasant rebellions in the 1890s that became known as the Tonghak Rebellion. Ch’ŏndogyo (Religion of the Heavenly Way): Ch’ŏndogyo became the new name of Tonghak in 1905. During the period of Cultural Rule (1920–1927), it was an influential institution that had a major role in shaping the political, economic, social, and cultural landscapes in new directions through publications such as Kaebyŏk (Creation) and Nongmin (Peasant) and social movements that included its rural reconstruction campaigns (1925– 1937). The Ch’ŏndogyo church linked religious principles to social activism and became a significant nationalist force under Japanese occupation. Chŭngsan-gyo: Chŭngsan-gyo was a new religion created by Kang Il-sun in the late nineteenth century. It grew in popularity in the aftermath of the Tonghak Rebellion. Former Tonghak followers and new believers were drawn to its message of the imminent arrival of a utopian world. It promised salvation for all in this new world as long as individuals lived a moral and upstanding life that avoided the mistreatment of others. It became a popular new religion, but it lacked the organizational power of Tonghak and therefore never became a major organized religion. Ultimate Reality: Ultimate Reality is a religious term coined by David Tracy that generally refers to a sacred force that is the creator and mover of all existence. As the creative and preserving force that exists in all objects and beings in the universe and the everyday world, Ultimate Reality, according to Tracy, refers to specific forces in religions, such as God in Christianity. Tonghak Rebellion: This rebellion was one of the largest peasant rebellions in Korean history and lasted from early 1893 to December 1894. Inspired by Tonghak (Eastern Learning), peasants sought to achieve economic security and to expel foreigners, especially the Japanese, who threatened Korea’s independence. Though peasants had successfully battled government troops, a combined fighting force of Japanese and Korean troops put an end to the rebellion. 1902 Temple Ordinance: The 1902 Temple Ordinance was a series of reforms of Buddhism carried out by the Korean government. The government set up the Bureau of Temple Administration to supervise and regulate temples. State reforms were set up as way to centralize temple activities in order to thwart the advances of Japanese Buddhism in Korea. P’yŏngyang Revival: The P’yŏngyang Revival consisted of a series of revival meetings held throughout P’yŏngyang and other parts of Korea in 1907. Strong turnout and the outpouring of emotions at the meetings led to the P’yŏngyang Revival energizing evangelicalism in Korea. The revival inspired Western missionaries and Korean Christian leaders to organize new campaigns to convert Koreans to Christianity. 76

Religion 1876–1910

1906 Regulation on Religion: The 1906 Regulation on Religion was issued by Japanese authorities in Korea in December 1906. The regulation stipulated strict controls over Buddhist missionary activities in Korea. Among the number of stipulations, Japanese Buddhist sects in Korea were required to register with the Government General’s Office and receive approval for missionary activities. This regulation further centralized Buddhist affairs in Korea and placed them under government supervision. Industrial Education Department (IED): Industrial Education Departments were spaces in Protestant missionary schools where Koreans were taught the merits of industrialization and learned skills appropriate for industrial occupations. IEDs took place in factorylike settings where male and female students worked with machinery, such as power looms. Western missionaries used these spaces to discipline Koreans physically and mentally, who they perceived as “lazy,” in order to transform them into productive workers and to indoctrinate them with the belief that modernity could only be achieved through industrialization. Ch’oe Si-hyŏng (1827–1898): Ch’oe Si-hyŏng followed Ch’oe Che-u as the leader of Tonghak. He was widely credited with turning Tonghak into an organized religion by consecrating the teaching of Ch’oe Che-u and setting up institutions that would spread Tonghak teachings. Following the Tonghak Rebellion, he was executed by the government. Son Pyŏng-hui (1861–1922): Son Pyŏng-hui was the third leader of Tonghak, who oversaw its transition to being renamed Ch’ŏndogyo. In addition to setting up a new bureaucratic structure, Son established a printing house to publish and spread Ch’ŏndogyo writings. A firm believer in the concept of Civilization and Enlightenment, Son argued for industrialization, military expansion, and educational, health and sanitation programs. His views on Civilization and Enlightenment were challenged by Ch’ŏndogyo figures, such as Yi Tonhwa, starting in the 1920s as they reconceptualized the meaning of modernity. Yi Seung-hun (1756–1801): Yi was the first baptized Korean Catholic in China. He returned to Korea to promote Catholicism, which was growing as a new religion. He was later executed by the government in 1801 for spreading Catholic teachings. Yi Sŭng-hun (1864–1930): Yi is known for his nationalist activities in the Sinminhoe (New People’s Association) and for promoting Christianity through various institutions, such as Osan Academy (1907), which he founded as a Christian school. As a leading merchant, Yi played an active role in organizing a number of business ventures with fellow Presbyterians. In 1908, for example, Yi helped start Sangmudongsa, one of the first general merchandise stores in Korea. In 1909, Yi also led the movement to start joint-stock companies through the P’yŏngyang Chagi Chusik Hoesa (Pyŏngyang Porcelain Company). Behind all these business ventures was Yi’s hope that Korean companies would be able to compete with Japanese businesses coming into Korea and resist Japan’s takeover of the economy and the country. Ch’oe Che-u (1824–1864): Ch’oe Che-u founded Tonghak in 1860. As a fallen elite, Ch’oe characterized Tonghak as mixture of various religions. He melded together tenets from other systems of knowledge, such as Catholicism and Confucianism, to produce a religion that would address the contemporary needs of the people. He adopted the ideas of benevolence from Buddhism while he borrowed ideas about God from the Catholic meaning of God (Ch’ŏnju). Ch’oe appropriated the concept of ideal human relations from Confucianism and, from Daoism, the idea of changing the internal spirit in order to cleanse oneself from negative elements. The government found him and his teachings a threat to the Confucian order and had him executed in 1864. 77

Albert L. Park

Notes 1

2

3

4

The following denominations came after the arrival of Allen, Underwood, and Appenzeller: the Presbyterian Church in the United States (PCUS) (1892), the Methodist Episcopalian South Church (1896), the Presbyterian Church of Victoria, Australia (1889), and the Canadian Presbyterian Church (1898). In P’yŏngyang, Presbyterian North missionaries built the Caroline Ladd Memorial Hospital in 1905, while other Presbyterian North missionaries worked to construct Severance Medical College and Nursing School in 1905. In many mission stations, such as Canadian Presbyterian missions, small medical facilities existed that offered basic medical services to local people. PCUS missionaries built a number of primary schools and established secondary schools for girls, such as Sungui Girls Academy (1912), and secondary schools for boys, such as Sungsil Academy (1897) and Sungin Academy (1907). In Seoul, Methodist North missionaries constructed a vast array of schools, including Paejae Boys’ School in 1885 and Ewha Girls’ School in 1886, which later became Ewha University. The new Presbytery included the Presbyterian North, the Presbyterian South, the Canadian Church, and the Australian Church.

References Boy, J. D. (2011) ‘Thinking about Revolution, Religion and Egypt with Talal Asad,’ The Immanent Frame (blog), Social Science Research Council, February 23, 2011, http://blogs.ssrc.org/tif/2011/02/23/ thinking-about-revolution-religion-and-egypt-with-talal-asad (accessed November 2012). Gale, J. (1909) Korea in Transition, New York, NY: Eaton and Mains. Geertz, C. (1973) The Interpretation of Cultures, New York, NY: Basic Books. Kim, H. I. Empire of the Dharma: Korean and Japanese Buddhism, 1877–1912, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. Ladd, G. T. (1908) In Korea with Marquis Ito. New York, NY: Charles Scribner’s Sons. Lee, G. (1907) ‘How the Spirit Came to Pyengyang [sic]’, Korea Mission Field, March: 34. Lee, T. S. (2000) ‘A Political Factor in the Rise of Protestantism in Korea: Protestantism and the 1919 March First Movement’, Church History, 69–1: 116–142. Ro, K. (2002) ‘New Religions and Social Change in Modern Korean History’, Review of Korean Studies, 5–1: 31–62. Taves, A. and Bender, C. (eds.) (2012) What Matters? Ethnographies of Value in a Not So Secular Age, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Taylor, C. (2002) ‘Modern Social Imaginaries’, Public Culture, 14–1: 91–124. Tracy, D. (1987) Plurality and Ambiguity: Hermeneutics, Religion, and Hope, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Walraven, B. (1999) ‘Popular Religion in a Confucianized Society’, in Haboush, J. and Deuchler, M. (eds.) Culture and the State in Late Chosŏn Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center.

Bibliography Anderson, E. (2014) Christianity and Imperialism in Modern Japan: Empire for God, New York, NY: Bloomsbury Academic Publishing. Baker, D. (2002) ‘Hananim, Hanŭnim, Hanullim, and Hanŏllim: The Construction of Terminology for Korean Monotheism’, Review of Korean Studies, 5–1: 105–131. Buswell, R. (ed.) (2007) Religions of Korea in Practice, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Buswell, R. and Lee, T. (eds.) (2006) Christianity in Korea, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Cha, P. (2012) ‘Unequal Partners, Contested Relations: American Missionaries and Korean Christians, 1884–1907’, The Journal of Korean Studies, 17–1 (Spring 2012): 5–37. Choi, H. (2009) Gender and Mission Encounters in Korea: New Women, Old Ways, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Choi, J. (2006) The Origin of the Roman Catholic Church in Korea: An Examination of Popular and Government Responses to Catholic Missionaries in the Late Chosŏn Dynasty, Norwalk, CA: The Hermit Kingdom Press. 78

Religion 1876–1910

Chung, C. (1995) A Korean Confucian Encounter with the Modern World, Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, Berkeley. Clark, C. (1930) The Korean Church and the Nevius Methods, New York, NY: Fleming H. Revell. –––– (1932) Religions of Old Korea, New York, NY: Fleming H. Revell. de Bary, W. and Haboush, J. (eds.) (1985) The Rise of Neo-Confucianism in Korea, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Deuchler, M. (1992) The Confucian Transformation of Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Council on East Asian Studies. Duncan, J. (2000) The Origins of the Chosŏn Dynasty, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Gale, J. (1909) Korea in Transition, New York, NY: Young People’s Missionary Movement of the United States and Canada. Grayson, J. (2002) Korea—A Religious History, London: RoutledgeCurzon. Haboush, J. and Deuchler, M. (eds.) (1999) Culture and the State in Late Chosŏn Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. Horlyck, C. and Pettid, M. (eds.) (2014) Death, Mourning, and the Afterlife in Korea: From Ancient to Contemporary Time, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Kallander, G. (2013) Salvation through Dissent: Tonghak Heterodoxy and Early Modern Korea, Eastern Scripture, and Other Tonghak Sources, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Kendall, L. (1985) Shamans, Housewives and Other Restless Spirits, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Kim, C. (2006) ‘Preaching the Apocalypse in Colonial Korea’, in Buswell, R. and Lee, T. (eds.) Christianity in Korea, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai`i Press. Kim, H. (2012) Empire of the Dharma: Korean and Japanese Buddhism, 1877–1912, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. Kim, S. (2007) Marginality and Subversion in Korea, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Ladd, G. (1908) In Korea with Marquis Ito, New York, NY: Charles Scribner’s Sons. Lee, J. and Sunim, S. (2012) ‘Monastic Education and Educational Ideology in the Late Chosŏn Period’, The Journal of Korean Religions, 3–1: 65–84. Oak, S. (ed.) (2004) Sources of Korean Christianity, Seoul: Hanguk kidokkyo yŏksa yŏn’guso. –––– (2010) ‘Healing and Exorcism: Christian Encounters with Shamanism in Early Modern Korea’, Asian Ethnology, 69–1: 95–128. –––– (2013) The Making of Korean Christianity: Protestant Encounters with Korean Religions, 1876–1915, Waco, TX: Baylor University Press. Paik, G. (1970) The History of Protestant Missions in Korea, 1832–1910, Seoul: Yonsei University Press. Park, A. (2014) ‘A Sacred Economy of Value and Production’, in A. Park and D. Yoo (eds.) Encountering Modernity: Christianity in East Asia and Asian America, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Park, A. and Yoo, D. (eds.) (2014) Encountering Modernity: Christianity in East Asia and Asian America, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Park, C. (2003) Protestantism and Politics in Korea, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Park, P. (2009) Trial and Error in Modernist Reforms: Korean Buddhism under Colonial Rule, Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, Berkeley. Park, Y. (2014) ‘Between Mission and Medicine: The Early History of Severance Hospital’ in A. Park and D. Yoo (eds.) Encountering Modernity: Christianity in East Asia and Asian America, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Rausch, F. (2012) ‘Like Birds and Beasts: Justifying Violence against Catholics in Late Chosŏn Korea’, Acta Koreana: 73–106. –––– (2013) ‘The Bishop’s Dilemma: Gustave Mutel and the Catholic Church in Korea, 1890–1910’, The Journal of Korean Religions, 4–1: 43–70. –––– (2014) ‘Dying for Heaven: Persecution, Martyrdom, and Family in the Early Korean Catholic Church’, in C. Horlyck and M. Pettid (eds.) Death, Mourning, and the Afterlife in Korea: From Ancient to Contemporary Time, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Ro, K. (2002) ‘New Religions and Social Change in Modern Korean History’, Review of Korean Studies, 5–1: 31–62. Sangkil, H. and Wegehaupt, M. (2012) ‘The Activities and Significance of Temple Fraternities in Late Chosŏn Buddhism’, The Journal of Korean Religions, 3–1: 29–63. Schmid, A. (2002) Korea between Empires, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. 79

Albert L. Park

Shin, M. (2002) ‘Nationalist Discourse and Nationalist Institutions in Colonial Chosŏn, 1914–1926’, unpublished thesis, University of Chicago. —— (ed.) (2014) Everyday life in Joseon-Era Korea: Economy and Society, Leiden, Netherlands: Global Oriental. Van Buskirk, J. (1931) Korea: Land of the Dawn, New York, NY: Missionary Education Movement of the United States and Canada. ‘The Village Gilds [sic] of Korea’, Transactions of the Korea Branch of the Royal Asiatic Society, 4, pt. 2 (1913): 13–44. Walraven, B. (1994) Songs of the Shaman: the Ritual Chants of the Korean Mudang, London: Kegan Paul International. –––– (1999) ‘Popular Religion in a Confucianized Society’, in J. Haboush and M. Deuchler (eds.) Culture and the State in Late Chosŏn Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. –––– (2002) ‘Weavers of Ritual: How Shaman Achieve their Aims’, The Review of Korean Studies, 5–1: 85–104. –––– (2012) ‘Buddhist Accommodation and Appropriation and the Limits of Confucianization’, The Journal of Korean Religions, 3–1: 105–116. Weems, B. (1964) Reform, Rebellion, and the Heavenly Way, Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press. Wells, K. (1990) New God, New Nation, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Yi, T. (2007) The Dynamics of Confucianism and Modernization in Korean History, Ithaca, NY: Cornell East Asia Program. Young, C. (2002) ‘Tonghak and Son Pyŏng-hui’s Early Leadership: 1899–1904’, Review of Korean Studies, 5–1: 63–83. –––– (2005) ‘Embracing Modernity: Organizational and Ritual Reform in Ch’ŏndogyo, 1905–1910’, Asian Studies Review, 29: 47–59. –––– (2014) Eastern Learning and the Heavenly Way: The Tonghak and Chŏndogyo Movements and the Twilight of Korean Independence, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press.

80

6 The transformation of the Choso ˘ n economy in the Open Port Period, 1876–1910 Owen Miller

Introduction: economic problems of nineteenth-century Choso ˘n Korea’s relative isolation from the emerging world system during the latter centuries of the Chosŏn Dynasty (1392–1910)1 was a double-edged sword. It protected Chosŏn from outside interference and helped the dynasty to last an exceptionally long time. But when the modern capitalist world did arrive, it was a sudden and shocking experience. To make matters worse, by this time Korea’s island neighbour had already set out decisively on the path of modernisation and it was Japan who would eventually come to dominate the Chosŏn economy and then annex the country in 1910. The opening of Korea’s ports, beginning with the Kanghwa Treaty of 1876, marked a major turning point in Korea’s history, after which it rapidly entered the modern capitalist world. For Korea, the shock of encountering a new world was not just political, it was undoubtedly economic too. This chapter will consider in detail the profound economic changes wrought by that entry, alongside the inherent problems of the pre-existing economic system and the responses of major actors within Korean society to changing economic conditions. Scholarly work on the economic history of this period has been heavily shaped by Korea’s subsequent experience of colonial rule (1910–1945). Japanese historians of the early twentieth century such as Fukuda Tokuzō aimed to demonstrate the inevitability of Korea’s annexation by showing that its economic past was backward and stagnant. Korean scholars, both during the colonial period and even more so since, have made great efforts to ‘overcome’ the historiography of stagnation and show that Chosŏn was attempting to modernise itself in the nineteenth century. They have also emphasised the way in which Japanese imperialism in the late nineteenth century acted as an obstacle to Chosŏn’s independent modernisation and the development of an indigenous capitalism. The debate about Korea’s late nineteenth-century economic history continues today, with varying evaluations of the economic dimensions of the Kabo (1895–6) and Kwangmu Reforms (1897–1907) and starkly differing opinions on the inevitability of Chosŏn’s economic decline and eventual domination by Japan. However, scholarship on this period has also developed in recent decades, and it now seems possible to move beyond simple dichotomies, to take into account both the relative weakness of the Chosŏn state and its agency in economic 81

Owen Miller

modernisation. It is also possible to produce a more detailed picture of the geopolitical setting for economic change, balancing the particular role played by Japanese imperialism with the complexity of late nineteenth-century northeast Asian geopolitics. The shift away from old dichotomies will be beneficial for our historical understanding of Korea’s loss of economic and, ultimately, political sovereignty. However, although this period is a relatively well-studied one in Korean history, there are still many areas, such as the economics of everyday life or the relations between the state and commerce, where future research is likely to change our perception of late nineteenth-century Korea.2 Before turning to the main topic of this chapter, we need first to look briefly at the state of the Chosŏn economy prior to the port opening. The economy of late Chosŏn was far from being a ‘natural’ or ‘self-sufficient’ economy in which commerce and manufacture barely existed, as some later Japanese historians would come to believe.3 The market had an increasingly important place in the economy of late Chosŏn, from the local markets that connected villages with local and national commercial networks, through the national markets in raw materials and luxury goods, right up to the level of international trade, which was largely carried out through the structures of interstate tribute and diplomatic relations within the ‘Chinese world order’. There was a deep intertwining of state and market in late Chosŏn: since the introduction of the Taedong tax system in the early seventeenth century, the state had come to rely on merchants to procure the goods it needed for its own functions and for its tribute trade with Qing China. It also came to use merchants to transport and dispose of goods it collected as tax (mainly rice, cotton cloth and hemp). Big merchants, for their part, relied on the state and its bureaucracy to provide them with business and to protect their privileges against interlopers (although exactly who counted as a privileged merchant could change over time). Thus, despite the growth of markets, the Chosŏn state, with its formidable capacity to collect and redistribute wealth, was still the most important integrating factor in the late Chosŏn economy. By the mid-nineteenth century, the Chosŏn state was facing considerable fiscal problems, and this in turn threatened the health of the economy as a whole. The nineteenth century was marked by a long-term trend of decreasing tax revenues for central government, and by the 1860s, the state found itself facing serious fiscal problems. The Taewon’gun4 attempted to solve government’s shortage of revenue by various means, including the importation of Qing coinage and the first minting of a multi-unit coin (the 100 mun coin, called tangbaekchŏn, minted in 1867). However, the Taewon’gun also spent prodigiously on projects such as the renovation of Kyŏngbokkung Palace and strengthening of the military. Thus, by the time Korea’s modern period began in earnest with the first port opening in 1876, the government was having problems meeting its expenditure requirements, and matters were no doubt made worse by the unexpected and sizeable tributary expenses associated with the death of the Qing Tongzhi Emperor in 1875. These financial problems would continue to dog the Chosŏn government for the next two decades and had profound effects on the economy as a whole and the ability of the state to respond to the challenges of the Open Port Period (1876–1910). First, the government’s straitened circumstances weakened the traditional merchant class that relied heavily on official procurement trade and also contributed to inflationary pressures in the 1880s. Second, its lack of revenue made it difficult for the government to carry out even the limited modernising reforms it embarked on in the early 1880s and late 1890s or to support any meaningful development of infrastructure, trading companies or manufacturing. This in turn made the Chosŏn state all the more reliant on outside powers, thus setting up a negative reciprocal relationship between Chosŏn’s own financial weakness and the imperial designs of its neighbours, China and Japan. 82

Transformation of the Choso˘n economy

The impact of port opening When Chosŏn signed its first modern treaty with a foreign power in 1876, it had already been over 30 years since the Treaty of Nanking had opened Chinese ports (besides Canton) to British trade and 18 years since Japan had signed the Ansei Treaties with the USA and a series of other European powers. The Chosŏn government and ruling elite was therefore at a significant disadvantage since its two neighbours had already learned the hard way about the reality of unequal treaties. Japan was now ready to impose one on another country. The story of the Kanghwa Treaty is fairly well known. Japan used the very gunboat diplomacy that had been used against itself more than 20 years earlier, first creating a military incident off Kanghwa Island with its ship Unyō in September 1875, then blockading the island and finally sending the Kuroda Mission early in 1876 to negotiate a treaty. Chosŏn had rebuffed earlier attempts by Western powers to open trading relations, even when accompanied by military force as in 1866 and 1871. But this time there were various reasons for Chosŏn’s decision to sign its first modern-style treaty, among them the fact that Japan was seen as different from the Western barbarians, a country that was at least partially within the Chinese world order and which had previously had neighbourly (kyorin) relations with Chosŏn. It is apparent that there was also a great deal of naivety about what the provisions of the treaty actually meant and no understanding of the inequality built into the terms. Those terms were undoubtedly disadvantageous for Chosŏn, and they began the process of weakening Korean sovereignty that culminated in the Japanese annexation of 1910. Besides the opening of the port of Pusan and the agreement to open two further ports in due course,5 the treaty granted extraterritorial rights to those Japanese merchants and officials who came to live in the newly opened ports. This was the same unequal system that the Western powers had imposed on China and Japan, under which foreign merchants in the treaty ports who were suspected of a crime had to be tried under the law of their own country, effectively creating a system of impunity. The most notoriously unequal economic provision of the treaty was the system of tariffs it introduced, under which there was a complete moratorium for Japanese goods imported to Korea while Korean goods exported to Japan were subject to a five per cent duty. Chosŏn did not sign its next treaty until the United States-Korea Treaty of 1882, which was in fact negotiated on Chosŏn’s behalf by the Qing Commissioner for Northern Ports, Li Hongzhang. This treaty had rather better terms than the Kanghwa Treaty, recognising the autonomy of the Chosŏn state to set trade tariffs and fixing those tariffs initially at ten per cent on imports from the US and five per cent on Korean exports to the US. However, the Treaty did give US residents the same property rights and extraterritorial privileges as Japanese traders, so in that sense it was every bit as much of an unequal treaty. This was followed rapidly in 1883 by a United Kingdom-Korea Treaty and then a series of other treaties with Western countries, all of which were closely modelled on the US-Korea Treaty. However, the detail of the United Kingdom-Korea Treaty was actually somewhat worse than the US-Korea Treaty in that it denied Chosŏn’s tariff autonomy by introducing conventional tariffs, fixed at sevenand-a-half per cent on British imports and five per cent on Korean exports.6 It also allowed British merchants to begin to make inroads outside of the treaty ports in the capital itself. In fact this particular trend had already begun in 1882, and in that case it was the Chinese who were the pioneers in opening Korea. After the Imo Soldiers’ Mutiny of July 1882, a first modernstyle trade agreement was negotiated between Qing and Chosŏn,7 which allowed Chinese merchants to reside and open shops in Seoul itself, as well as travel to other parts of inland Korea and to engage in inter-port trade. A similar agreement was reached with Japan the following 83

Owen Miller

year, and thus by the mid-1880s both Japanese and Chinese merchants were operating in the very heart of Chosŏn, competing with each other and with Korean merchants.8 The Treaty of Kanghwa and those that followed in the 1880s had a profound effect on the Chosŏn economy, primarily by rapidly integrating Chosŏn into the international system of trade. What this meant in practice was a radical shift from a system of very limited regional trade centred on luxury goods and based on the state-controlled tribute trade with Qing to a system of free trade with low tariffs in which Chosŏn was very much the inferior partner, completely lacking the productive base of the Western powers or even the emergent industry of Meiji Japan. The opening to international trade saw Chosŏn swiftly placed in an international division of labour in which it exported agricultural goods and raw materials and imported manufactured goods. This can be seen clearly in the trade figures for the period after port opening. Initially, exports of agricultural produce, mainly cowhides and rice, outweighed imports, but as the 1880s wore on, manufactured goods, largely cotton, increased rapidly, and from 1885 Chosŏn began to record trade deficits that continued until the annexation in 1910. The trade figures also show that from the late 1880s, rice and beans dominated Chosŏn’s exports, while cotton usually made up more than half of all imports annually from the mid-1880s up until 1900. The first decades after the opening of ports also saw significant growth in Chosŏn’s foreign trade overall, with the real value of trade increasing by 16 times between 1885 and 1910.9 The new international trade of the 1880s was, however, still dominated by the two countries with which Chosŏn had traded for hundreds of years under the traditional East Asian system of regional trade: China and Japan. On the one hand, Japan dominated Chosŏn’s export market in rice and beans, absorbing more than 90 per cent of Korean exports until the late 1890s. On the other hand, imports were more balanced, most were from Japan during the Open Port Period as a whole, but Chinese imports increased rapidly during the 1880s when Qing dominated Chosŏn politically, to peak at 49 per cent in 1893. The manufactured cotton cloth that made up the majority of Chosŏn’s imports before the mid-1890s came originally from factories in Europe, mainly Britain, and so Japanese and Chinese merchants were effectively acting as intermediaries in trade between Korea and the capitalist countries of Europe. China’s rising export trade with Chosŏn in the 1880s and early 1890s came from its merchants’ ability to dominate the trade in European cotton through their access to the most important East Asian trade port: Shanghai. Japan’s failure in this intermediary trade encouraged it to focus on exporting its own manufactured cloth to Chosŏn, something it became increasingly successful at during the 1890s. However, the decisive blows in the trade war between China and Korea were dealt by real wars: first the Sino-Japanese War of 1894 and then the Russo-Japanese War of 1904–5. The Sino-Japanese War in particular halted China’s challenge for dominance of Korean imports, and the post-war period saw the Japanese share of imports reaching 72 per cent in 1895. Although Chinese merchants returned to Chosŏn after the war and were able to recover some of their former share of Korea’s foreign trade, they were dealt another blow at the time of the Russo-Japanese War, after which their share of imports dropped as low as 14 per cent in 1906.10 By the late 1890s then, the Chosŏn economy was already locked into a particular set of economic relationships; a variation of the hierarchical international division of labour mentioned above. On the one side, Chosŏn was a market for the manufactured products of Japan’s newly emerging industries, while on the other, Japan imported and consumed Chosŏn’s agricultural products. More specifically, this has been characterised as a ‘rice-cotton exchange system’ in which relatively cheap rice from Korea fed the workers of Japan’s industrial areas, helping to keep wages low. Japanese-produced cotton could then be sold in Chosŏn, helping to make profits for the Japanese textile industry.11 84

Transformation of the Choso˘n economy

Government insolvency, inflation and the traditional commercial system It is difficult to quantify exactly the fiscal crisis of the Chosŏn government in the 1880s and 1890s, but we do know that for periods of time it had great difficulty in paying salaries to its officials and soldiers as well as bills to merchants for the goods it procured. Already by the late 1870s, the government owed some 1 million yang to tribute and guild merchants. A decade and a half later, in the early 1890s, the government still owed hundreds of thousands of yang to the guild merchants of Seoul. We also know that the recorded cash holdings of the central government reached a nadir in 1881 at 367,000 yang, having once peaked at 7,000,000 yang in 1809.12 The consequences of government insolvency became clear in 1882 when soldiers in Seoul mutinied over the non-payment of salaries and the adulteration of their rice payments. But the effects were also felt by the traditional commercial system of the capital, centred around the merchant guilds, called sijŏn, that supplied the government with a variety of commodities and were especially important in procuring goods for the tribute missions to Qing. The government traditionally paid the guilds high, fixed prices to secure the goods it needed and allowed them to sell off large quantities of rice or cotton at market prices, often making good profits. However, from the mid-1870s, government debts to the merchants began to mount, although government demands for goods did not decline but in fact increased, partly due to the increased diplomatic activity of the period. To make matters worse, the government for the most part still demanded the goods it purchased at the longstanding fixed prices, even while inflation soared in the 1880s (for reasons we will return to in the next section). This situation brought some of the merchant guilds to the brink of bankruptcy and forced many individual merchants out of the market altogether. A particularly acute case was that of the Myŏnjujŏn – a guild selling domestically produced silk cloth – which in 1892 petitioned the Chosŏn government, claiming that it was losing 80–90,000 yang a year in its trade with the government and was now owed a total of 200,000 yang, a phenomenal amount of money for the time. It, alongside a number of the other guilds, also complained about the problem of inflation, which, combined with the fixed prices paid by the government, could lead to considerable losses or at best meagre profits. For other traditional big merchants, such as those belonging to the main cotton guild in Seoul – the Paengmokchŏn – the biggest problem facing them was not inflation or government insolvency but rather competition from Chinese and Japanese merchants who had entered Seoul after the trade agreements of 1882 and 1883. As noted above, cotton cloth was the main import to Chosŏn in the 1880s and 1890s and the trade in Western-produced cloth was dominated by Chinese merchants. This influx of manufactured cloth couldn’t fail to have a negative effect on the business of the Paengmokchŏn in particular, although tensions between Korean and foreign merchants were much broader. In the late 1880s this led to organised collective action by the Seoul guilds to recover their monopolies in the face of competition from foreign merchants. This action reached a climax in the first month of 1890 when all the Seoul guilds participated in a merchants’ strike, closing their shops for a week and protesting in front of the Chosŏn Foreign Office. The Chosŏn government was sympathetic to their plight and wanted to renegotiate the terms of its trade agreements with China and Japan in order to remove foreign merchants from the capital to Inch’ŏn or nearby ports on the Han River. But with the powerful Chinese ‘Imperial Resident’ Yuan Shikai based in Seoul and exerting considerable political influence, as well as strong objections from the Japanese, the government was in no position to achieve this.13 85

Owen Miller

There were a number of possible measures that the Chosŏn government could have taken in the 1880s in order to improve its financial situation and alleviate the problems of the merchants. Probably the most effective would have been to completely overhaul the taxation system, consolidate the fragmented central financial institutions and attempt to balance the budget. But this was politically difficult to achieve in the 1880s, and by the time this sort of comprehensive reform did get underway with the Kabo Reforms of 1894–5, the state and the reformers were firmly under Japanese influence. Another route was to seek foreign loans to supplement government revenues, something that Chosŏn did in fact do in the 1880s, but only with very limited success.14 The actual approach chosen by the government was to muddle through, continuing to spend well beyond its means while at the same time attempting to protect the traditional commercial system from the worst of the consequences. Certainly in the late 1880s and even in the early 1890s, the Chosŏn state was still strongly committed to preserving the traditional commercial system centred around the privileged merchants of the Seoul guilds. Despite its own profound weakness, it tried to find ways of doing this, such as partially abandoning the fixed price system, allowing merchants to be paid out of local government revenues rather than the central coffers and cracking down on predatory practices towards merchants by branches of government.15 The government also turned to an old and previously unsuccessful method of supplementing its revenues: the minting of debased cash. A five mun coin called the tang’ojŏn was minted in 1883–4 and again in 1888, with an intrinsic value only two times that of the traditional one mun coin, while a debased one mun coin was minted in Pyongyang in 1893. The inevitable result of the debased coinage was series of bouts of sharp inflation, which can be seen quite clearly in the Seoul market prices listed in government gazettes of the 1880s, Hansŏng Sunbo and Hansŏng Chubo. This was joined by other inflationary pressures in the 1880s and early 1890s such as bad harvests and the increasing exports of Korean rice, which meant that rice prices began to be influenced not only by conditions in Korea but also by demand in the export market, Japan. Overall there was a gradual tendency for the prices of Korean rice and other consumer goods to catch up with prices in closely connected markets such as Japan. The very sharp rises in prices in the 1880s have been termed a ‘price revolution’; a one-off transformation that irrevocably destroyed the relative price equilibrium of the late Chosŏn period, which had been underpinned by the powerful system of state redistribution.16 The economic turmoil of the 1880s, particularly in Seoul, had significant social and political consequences. The rioting and political turmoil that followed the Imo Soldiers’ Mutiny of 1882 and the Kapsin Coup of 1884 in Seoul had an obvious economic dimension as many ordinary city-dwellers found their livelihoods threatened by inflation, shortages, government insolvency and the encroachment of Chinese and Japanese merchants. There were almost certainly other less-well-known episodes of urban unrest during this period, and it is also known that during periods of acute inflation or shortages in the late 1880s and early 1890s, significant parts of the capital’s population left the city for villages in the surrounding countryside where food could be found more easily and cheaply. In the 1890s, as Japanese merchant capital penetrated the interior of Chosŏn, the state attempted to solve its financial crisis by raising taxes and local government officials turned to increasingly corrupt practices, the same sorts of problems arose in the countryside. This worsening economic situation for already poor Korean peasants was no doubt the main impetus behind the growth of the millenarian Tonghak movement and ultimately the huge peasant uprising that broke out under its banner in early 1894.

86

Transformation of the Choso˘n economy

New merchants and new markets While a combination of government insolvency and the arrival of international trade in Korea began to destroy the centuries-old traditional commercial system, new markets and new groups of merchants also began to grow at a fast pace. In the 1880s and 1890s, a commercial revolution was taking place in Korea. As we have seen, this revolution could be very destructive and for many people, including both poor city dwellers and once-wealthy merchants, it was a disaster. But for others, there was a bonanza. In addition to the merchants who came to Chosŏn from all over China and Japan to try their hand in the new treaty ports, there were also many beneficiaries from closer to home. Chief among these beneficiaries was the group of Korean merchants called kaekchu who acted as intermediaries between foreign merchants and domestic traders. They had existed before the port opening as a layer of merchants who helped to facilitate trade by working as middlemen or providing financial or lodging services. Now at the treaty ports they came to play a crucial role carrying out consignment trade with Japanese and Chinese merchants and were able to grow rapidly in numbers and wealth, reaching almost 500 by the late 1890s in the treaty ports of Pusan, Inch’ŏn and Wonsan. For a while their position at the nexus between international trade and domestic markets was very lucrative, and they were able to open offices in Seoul and the treaty ports to represent their interests. However, the kaekchu remained to a large extent subordinate to the Japanese and Chinese merchants that they dealt with, unable to match their capital and lacking in the concerted state backing that they enjoyed. Japanese merchants, for example, were given low interest loans, while the Japanese government put considerable efforts into supporting maritime shipping for the sake of its merchants. In addition, the unequal treaties gave the foreign merchants a number of advantages over their Korean counterparts, particularly in legal disputes. Having said this, it is not the case that the Chosŏn government completely neglected its merchants. Despite its financial constraints, it did attempt to support the kaekchu and other merchants by providing capital from local tax receipts using a system known as oehoek. Although this system came to be used more frequently after the Kabo Reforms of 1894, it was still a rather unstable means of supporting merchant capital and it could never level the playing field between Korean and Japanese or Chinese merchants. As a result, the kaekchu became increasingly dependent on their foreign counterparts, often relying on them for capital, then becoming indebted to them and finally going bankrupt.17 A broader social change spurred by the opening of ports was the growth of the landlord class in the countryside. Landlords and rich peasants were another group who were able to benefit from the growth of international trade and the demand for Korean rice, accumulating wealth and land as rice prices rose. Merchants who made their fortune in the treaty ports or developing inland trade could now invest their money in land and become major landlords. Meanwhile, poorer peasants continued to be pushed into landless status and were not in a position to benefit from the demand for rice since they had to either consume or quickly sell the rice they produced. The Open Port Period in general saw the market emerge as the dominant mode of economic integration in Chosŏn society, while other aspects of capitalism such as wage labour and industrial production still remained very marginal. The number of local markets in the country had remained static during the nineteenth century, but during the Open Port Period the numbers began to grow again as commerce became increasingly important in the Korean countryside. At the same time, the treaty ports themselves – Pusan and Inch’ŏn in particular – grew from small towns to significant commercial cities, overtaking Seoul as the centre of Chosŏn commerce. These new treaty ports, with their foreign residents and kaekchu, began to exert a considerable force over 87

Owen Miller

the rest of the economy, absorbing distribution routes and production areas into their orbit. Most dangerously, they sucked rice out of the regions surrounding them, causing periodic shortages, and these shortages even affected the capital and other major cities like Pyongyang, causing unrest, as mentioned above. The Chosŏn government attempted to ease these problems by using its power to prohibit the export of rice (using a measure called panggok), but Japanese traders and government objected strongly to this state intervention and brought suits for compensation. By the late 1890s, therefore, it became increasingly difficult for the government to use this means of controlling the market.18 The Kabo Reforms of the mid-1890s, which will be considered in more detail in the next section, also acted to reduce the power of the state to redistribute resources outside of the market, chiefly by monetising taxation. This went along with the more general decline in the economic power of the state, as recounted in the previous section, to further spur the growth of the market. Another factor in the growth of the market during this period was the introduction of modern financial institutions and communications infrastructure, beginning in the second half of the 1880s. However, an even bigger boost to market growth came in the early 1900s with the development of a national rail network that could safely and speedily link treaty ports, cities, commercial towns and their agricultural hinterlands.

Modernisation and industrialisation: early state-led development versus foreign encroachment From early in the Open Port Period the Chosŏn government adopted a pragmatic modernisation and self-strengthening policy aimed at countering the threat from the ‘foreign barbarians’. However, prior to the Kabo Reforms of 1894–5 this state-led modernisation took place largely within the limits set by the framework of the slogan ‘Eastern ways, Western means/technology’ (tongdo sŏgi). This meant that the early reforms focused on limited changes to government institutions and attempts at modernisation that focused on strengthening the military through better training and more modern equipment. At the same time, the government did begin to encourage some new forms of economic activity. In the early 1880s the government directly set up a number of modern-style companies and supported others to found trading companies through special tax breaks. In 1883 the Chosŏn state set up a publications office (Pangmun’guk), which would begin to introduce Koreans to knowledge about the rest of the world and to ideas about capitalism, by printing the first Korean newspaper, the Hansŏng Sunbo. Then in 1884 the state established the first post office in Seoul and set up a postal service between Seoul and Inch’ŏn, providing for the first time a public channel of communication between the capital and the nearby treaty port. Meanwhile, the government also began to explore ways to develop Korean industry on a more modern basis by hiring Chinese advisors on sericulture and textile manufacturing. It set up a model farm intended to introduce modern agricultural techniques from the US, established a modern paper mill under state control and supported the founding of a Korean steamship line intended to compete with the Japanese in the early 1890s. However, all these attempts at economic modernisation in the 1880s and early 1890s were extremely limited in their scale and further compromised by the more general weakness of the Chosŏn state, with its parlous finances and limited access to modern technology. While the Chosŏn state was actively pursuing a form of limited modernisation in the late nineteenth century, much of the new economic infrastructure and the earliest signs of industrialisation were in fact brought to Korea by its encroaching neighbours. It was the Chinese and Japanese who brought modern-style banks to Chosŏn as well as shipping lines and the telegraph system (first installed on the Korean peninsula by the Chinese in 1885, although there was already 88

Transformation of the Choso˘n economy

a Pusan-Nagasaki undersea cable owned by the Japanese). It was also they who introduced some of the first modern manufacturing facilities, such as the brick kilns established in the environs of Seoul in the mid-1880s by the Chinese or the mechanised rice mills established by the Japanese in the treaty ports from the late 1880s. In order to serve Chosŏn’s growing resident Japanese communities in the late nineteenth century, Japanese businessmen also established industrial enterprises producing soy sauce, tobacco and distilled spirits, but this sort of small-scale manufacturing was still a far cry from the extensive industrialisation that was taking place in Japan itself at the same time. By the end of the 1890s, some Korean-owned factories were also being established, mainly in textiles and often operated by government officials or rich merchants. The reform government that came to power in the summer of 1894 with the backing of the Japanese military forces then occupying Seoul and was led by members of the Enlightenment Party who had long wanted to emulate Japan’s Meiji reforms and transform Chosŏn into a strong modern nation. With some irony they finally got their chance to enact these reforms just as Chosŏn’s two neighbouring powers fought a bloody war for supremacy on its soil and a huge peasant uprising wracked the countryside. Under these circumstances and after almost 20 years of unequal treaties and foreign encroachment into the Chosŏn economy, it is no surprise that the reformers were unable to emulate Meiji Japan in Korea. However, the Kabo Reforms that began in 1894 and carried on into 1895 did bring many important top-down economic changes. More specifically, the reforms represented a series of radical changes in the economic operation of the state which then had profound impacts on society at large.19 Perhaps the most important economic reform of this period was the thorough overhaul of taxation that simplified the diverse and complex tax system and completely monetised it for the first time. Although taxation had already become increasingly monetised in the late Chosŏn period, taxes were still being collected in rice and cloth alongside cash prior to the Kabo Reforms, which meant that these commodities were often used as currencies too and could theoretically be exchanged with cash at official rates. Besides tax reform, a modern-style government budget system was introduced, the currency was placed on a silver standard and the buying and selling of slaves was prohibited. This latter reform was fairly straightforward since slave ownership had been declining for a long time and all state-owned slaves had been manumitted almost a century before.20 Japan’s victory in the Sino-Japanese War of 1894 brought a decisive end to Qing’s status as suzerain over Chosŏn, and with this centuries of Korean tribute to China were also brought to an end. The Kabo Reforms officially declared the abolition of the annual tribute missions, and this had significant economic as well as geopolitical implications since the elite guild merchants of Seoul were responsible for providing large quantities of tribute goods for the missions. With the disappearance of this form of procurement, a large part of the guilds’ raison d’être also disappeared. This wasn’t the only blow that the Kabo Reforms dealt to the traditional commercial system. They also did away with the monopoly privileges of the largest and wealthiest guilds in the capital (often referred to as the Six Guilds) and the privileges enjoyed by the pedlars’ guilds. At the same time, the reform government introduced new regulations on the establishment and operation of modern-style companies in an attempt to shift commerce from the old monopoly-based system to one based on competition among companies. This attempt to develop the Chosŏn economy by fostering new businesses was one area where the aims of the Kabo Reform government clashed most clearly with their Japanese supporters. While the former wanted to support Korean businesses in order to strengthen the economy, the latter were already preparing the way for their eventual colonisation of Korea and were busy seeking concessions that would benefit Japanese capital. Thus, Japan used means 89

Owen Miller

such as loan conditions to try to prevent the Chosŏn state from developing Korean businesses. However, even after the fall of the Kabo government and the establishment of the Great Han Empire in 1897, the new government continued the policy of trying to strengthen Korean business so that it could compete with foreign capital. The government continued to be closely involved in the establishment of new companies. However, unlike the self-strengthening period of the 1880s, it did not directly establish enterprises itself but rather worked closely with private businessmen, some of whom even came from a traditional merchant background. The Great Han Empire government also supported the development of modern infrastructure in the areas of communications and shipping and founded or supported a number of schools designed to educate engineers and businessmen.21 In 1898, the government began a much-needed modernstyle land survey to determine the value of all land in the country and to establish ownership rights and cultivation rights. This survey used modern techniques and aimed at increasing tax revenues and establishing modern property rights regulated by the state, but it was never completed and stopped at the time of the Russo-Japanese War.22 While the Chosŏn governments of the 1890s strove to support nascent modern industry and business, foreign capital was also making considerable headway into the Chosŏn economy. In the mid-1890s, while Japan was temporarily on the back foot, a variety of countries moved in to gain economic concessions. Between 1895 and 1897, US, British, French and German companies all gained mining rights in Chosŏn, mainly for gold mines, such as the British mine at Ŭnsan in northeastern Korea, owned by Chosen Corp. Ltd., or the American mine at Unsan, owned by the Oriental Consolidated Mining Company. The Russians and the Japanese gained rights to other natural resources such as timber, fishing grounds and coal. Both the Americans and the French signed railway concession deals in 1896, with the US businessman James R. Morse getting a concession to build a railway between Seoul and Inch’ŏn and the French civil engineering company Fives-Lille a similar one for a line between Seoul and Ŭiju on the border with China. Two years later in 1898, an agreement was reached between the Great Han Empire and a pair of American businessmen to set up a company that would begin the electrification of Seoul, install water mains and construct a tram system, the first in Asia. It is significant, however, that neither the Seoul-Inch’ŏn rail line nor the Seoul-Ŭiju line were actually completed by American or French companies, but instead hit practical and political obstacles and were taken over by Japanese companies. This was also a sign of Japan regaining its political and economic influence in Chosŏn in the late 1890s as it built on its dominance of Chosŏn trade and saw off its European and American competitors.23

The Choso ˘ n economy in the first decade of the twentieth century After the Russo-Japanese War of 1904–5, Japan was finally in a position to begin the process of turning Chosŏn into a colony in earnest. This it did with the Protectorate Treaty of 1905, which gave Japan complete control of Chosŏn’s foreign relations and stationed a powerful Japanese resident-general in Seoul. Although the Chosŏn state had been gradually losing its sovereignty over the three decades since the Kanghwa Treaty, it was the Protectorate Treaty that put the country firmly on the path from semi-colony to colony. As a result, Japan was able to place its advisors into the Chosŏn government and gain almost complete control over economic policy, setting about restructuring the Chosŏn economy in its own favour almost immediately. One of the first measures was a complete reform of the currency system that abolished the existing money and introduced a new Chosŏn currency subordinated to the Japanese yen. The basic unit of the currency system also changed from the traditional yang (made up of 100 mun 90

Transformation of the Choso˘n economy

coins) to the won (using the same Chinese character as the Japanese yen). This meant that Chosŏn was essentially brought into the Japanese currency system, bringing great advantages for Japanese merchants doing business in Korea. Korean merchants, however, were hit very hard by the currency reform. Despite facing competition from foreign merchants and losing their official monopoly, the Seoul merchant guilds had adapted and were still dominating the capital’s retail commerce at the turn of the century. But the 1905 currency reform caused them a huge financial shock, leaving them extremely short of cash. As a result, many merchants had to sell or pawn their assets to get cash, and many are said to have been bankrupted. The Chosŏn Residency-General also carried out a reform of government finances and taxation in 1905, which brought the tax collection system more firmly under central control and put the state treasury in the hands of the Japanese Dai-ichi Bank. These reforms also sought to separate more clearly the finances of the state from the finances of the Korean imperial house. The main aim of the reforms was to increase tax revenues in order to fund the nascent colonial state and the infrastructure projects – chiefly the expansion of the railway system – that the Japanese saw as crucial to their domination of Korea. In 1909 the colonial government established the Bank of Korea (its name was later changed to Bank of Chōsen) and transferred to it the central banking functions formerly held by Daiichi Bank. In this period the Japanese Resident-General also set up a series of other financial institutions to facilitate the development and exploitation of the Korean economy. Among them were the Agricultural-Industrial Bank, founded in 1906, and the Oriental Development Company, founded in 1908. The latter played a particularly infamous role during the colonial period by acquiring huge amounts of Korean land and also promoting Japanese colonial settlement of Korea. Another very important development in the years leading up to the annexation was the breakneck construction of a nationwide rail network. The first line, connecting Seoul with Inch’ŏn, had been taken over by the Japanese from its American concession holder in 1898 and the bulk of the line completed in 1899. In 1905, the first major route – the Seoul-Pusan line – was completed by a Japanese syndicate essentially controlled by the Japanese state. The SeoulŬiju line, which had originally been a French concession, was also taken over by the Japanese and completed at speed during the Russo-Japanese War, reaching completion in 1906. In the same year, the whole of the Chosŏn railway system, now consisting of three lines, was formally nationalised in a move aimed at confirming the control of the Japanese. By 1910, then, Chosŏn had 1,086 kilometres of railways, directly under Japanese control, that linked Japan via Pusan with the main commercial and administrative centres of the Korean peninsula and on up into Manchuria. Although, it is worth noting that it was not until 1911 that a rail bridge over the Yalu River was completed at Ŭiju, finally connecting the Chosŏn rail system with Manchuria.24 Neither the Chosŏn government nor the foreign investors they initially gave concessions to had the capital necessary to build the main trunk routes through the Korean peninsula. In the end it was actually the Japanese state, driven initially by military concerns at the time of the Russo-Japanese War, that carried out the construction of the two main lines. The development of the rail system absorbed large amounts of resources and was the focus of Japanese capital exports to Korea in the pre-annexation period. Railways were an effective way for Japan to increase its control over Korea economically and politically, just as other colonial powers did elsewhere in the world. They also laid the way for its later military expansion beyond the Korean peninsula into northern China. It was Koreans who paid a heavy price for their construction, with large areas of land confiscated and many thousands of Korean workers conscripted to work in dangerous conditions as the railways were built rapidly in mountainous territory. 91

Owen Miller

Conclusion The opening of Chosŏn’s ports from the 1870s brought a series of dramatic economic changes to Korea. The external influences and interference of this period did not act upon an unchanging Chosŏn society but found a country already undergoing profound changes and facing crises that were largely internally generated. Certainly the most prominent economic change of this period was the arrival of modern international trade, which transformed forever the Chosŏn economy and the lives of millions of people by introducing new commodities (principally factory-produced cotton) and spurring the production of others (mainly rice and beans). In a short space of time, Chosŏn was detached from the Chinese world order, with its circumscribed and ritualised international trade, to become a small part of the global capitalist system. And as we have seen, this had profound effects not just in the treaty ports but throughout Korean society, as the influence of the international market reached into remote parts of the country. The changes wrought by the arrival of international trade were often reinforced by the financial crisis of the Chosŏn state, which in the 1880s had reached a position of insolvency. Thus, the traditional commercial system of the capital was hit by both competition from foreign merchants and the inability of the government to pay for the goods it procured. It was also a combination of the decline of state-centred redistribution and articulation with the world market that caused the high inflation and periodic shortages of the late nineteenth century that so affected the lives of ordinary Koreans. Koreans could and did respond to the economic challenges of this new period in creative ways, both at a private level and at the level of the state. Successive Chosŏn governments attempted – with varying success – to introduce economic reforms, establish modern economic institutions and foster the development of the economy through state-led or state-supported enterprises. But at every turn these reforms and initiatives were held back by interference from the imperialist powers, primarily China and Japan; lack of government funds; lack of knowledge and technical expertise; and political divisions within the Chosŏn elite over which direction to take. Meanwhile, at the private level, absorption into the capitalist world system did mean riches for some private merchants, landlords and farmers who had much to gain from Japan’s demand for Korean rice. Then in the first decade of the twentieth century, Japan gained the upper hand in the geopolitical struggle over Korea, allowing it a free hand to reform Chosŏn’s economy in a direction beneficial to its own capital and to its broader strategic aims. The most prominent question arising from this period is why Chosŏn’s efforts to effect economic modernisation in the late nineteenth century failed and Japan was ultimately successful in colonising Korea. Like most historical questions, the picture is complicated and multi-faceted and a full and definitive answer might be impossible, but we can point to some of the primary factors behind this failure. One of the most fundamental was the near bankruptcy of the Chosŏn state in the late nineteenth century, resulting partly from its narrow and declining tax base. Without capital, economic reforms and state-led self-strengthening were doomed to failure. And while there were meaningful attempts at reforming the taxation system, particularly with the Kabo Reforms, they were almost certainly too late and probably too little, since they did little to tackle the fundamental problem of land measurement. The governments of the late nineteenth century were constantly plagued by political divisions and in-fighting but were also divided around quite fundamental issues about how far reforms should go. Put simply, there was no political revolution that could clear the way for a decisive programme of reforms, a programme that would have to attack some vested interests. By the time thorough reforms were carried out in 1894–5, they were already compromised by direct Japanese interference. As was noted at the beginning of this chapter, the weakness of the Chosŏn state forced it to rely on a series of outside powers (China, Russia and finally Japan) and this tended to compromise its efforts at modernisation almost as soon as they began. 92

Transformation of the Choso˘n economy

It goes without saying that foreign encroachment into the Chosŏn economy was one of the main factors behind the failure to modernise independently. As noted at the beginning of this chapter, by the time Chosŏn was forced into the world system, its neighbours, Japan in particular, had gained a significant head start in the process of capitalist modernisation. Thus, from the very beginning of Chosŏn’s entry into the global system, it faced economic interference from the imperial powers in a variety of forms. There were the aggressive trade practices of Japanese and Chinese merchants built on the unequal treaties and backed by their respective governments; the manipulation of the Chosŏn government through the control of foreign loans; the scramble for economic concessions in the 1890s; and finally Japan’s direct takeover of Chosŏn economic policy in the early 1900s. From the very beginning in 1876, Chosŏn had lost a considerable part of its economic sovereignty and it was never able to regain this. For good or ill, Chosŏn did begin the process of economic modernisation in the Open Port Period, but it did not do so on its own terms and it did not lead to the establishment of a ‘strong and wealthy’ independent nation, as the Meiji Restoration had done in Japan.

Notes 1 For the most part I will use Chosŏn and Korea interchangeably in this chapter. However, the government of the period in question will usually be referred to as Chosŏn. 2 For more on the origins of the stagnation theory of Korean history, see: Miller, ‘The idea of stagnation in Korean historiography.’ In the 1970s a major debate developed among Korean historians over the economic and land reform efforts of the Kwangmu government, centred around Kim Yongsŏp, Sin Yongha and Kang Mangil. See: Kim, Y. S. ‘Kwangmu nyŏn’gan ŭi yangjŏn saŏp e kwanhan il yŏn’gu’; Sin, Y. H. ‘Nonjaeng: ŭi munjejŏm’. A recent example of negative views of nineteenth-century economic history would be Yi Yonghun’s new stagnationist historiography in ‘Chosŏn hugi kyŏngjesa ŭi saeroun tonghyang kwa kwaje’. Examples of recent innovative work on this period include Larsen, Tradition, Treaties, and Trade; Yi, S. N. Cheguk kwa sang’in; and Duus, P., The Abacus and the Sword. 3 Miller, ‘The idea of stagnation in Korean historiography’, pp. 4–5. 4 As King Kojong was too young to rule, his father Yi Ha-ŭng acted as regent with the title Hŭngsŏn Taewon’gun. 5 The ports of Wonsan (on the east coast) and Inch’ŏn (close to Seoul) were opened in 1880 and 1883, respectively. In the years 1897–99, a series of further ports were opened to foreign trade: Mokp’o, Chinnamp’o, Kunsan, Masan, Sŏngjin and Pyŏngyang. 6 Conventional tariffs are tariff levels that are negotiated between the two parties and then fixed, thus abrogating the right of the parties to set their own tariffs independently. 7 Regulations for Maritime and Overland Trade (Cho-Ch’ŏng sangmin suryuk muyŏk changjŏng). 8 Larsen, Tradition, Treaties and Trade, chapters 4 and 7. 9 The figures used here are based on table 6–1 in Yi, H. C., Han’guk kyŏngje t’ongsa, p. 258. 10 The trade figures used in these two paragraphs are based on table 6–2 in Yi, Han’guk kyŏngje t’ongsa, p. 260. 11 Yi, H. C., Han’guk kyŏngje t’ongsa, pp. 264–5. 12 See Pak, S. K. and Pak, S. I., ‘Chosŏn hugi chaejŏng ŭi yakhwa sijam e kwanhan koch’al’, p. 147. 13 Larsen, Tradition, Trade and Treaties, pp. 203–4; Son Chŏngmok, Han’guk kaehanggi tosi pyŏnhwa kwajŏng yŏn’gu, pp. 182–93. 14 Larsen, Tradition, Trade and Treaties, pp. 145–157. 15 Miller, The Silk Merchants of the Myŏnjujŏn: Guild and Government in Late Chosŏn Korea. 16 Pak, I. T., ‘Sŏul ŭi sungnyŏn mit misungnyŏn nodongja ŭi imgŭm, 1600–1909’, p. 66. 17 Yi, H. C., Han’guk kyŏngje t’ongsa, pp. 282–4. 18 McNamara, Trade and Transformation in Korea, p. 32; Yi, Han’guk kyŏngje t’ongsa, p. 280. 19 For more on the Kabo Reforms, see: Lew, Y. I., ‘The Reform Efforts and Ideas of Pak Yŏng-hyo, 1894–1895’; Wilkinson, The Corean Government: Constitutional Changes, July 1894 to October 1895. 20 On Korean slavery and its decline, see: Kim Bok Rae, ‘Nobi: A Korean System of Slavery’. 21 Yi, H. C., Han’guk kyŏngje t’ongsa, pp. 276–7. 93

Owen Miller

22 Choi, W. K., ‘The Legalization of Land Rights under the Great Han Empire’. 23 Duus, Peter, The Abacus and the Sword, chapter 4. 24 Yi, H. C., Han’guk kyŏngje t’ongsa, pp. 307–13.

References Choi, W. K. (2005) ‘The Legalization of Land Rights under the Great Han Empire’, in Pang Kie-chung and Michael D. Shin (eds.) Landlords, Peasants and Intellectuals in Modern Korea, Ithaca, NY: Cornell East Asia Series. Deuchler, M. (1977) Confucian Gentlemen and Barbarian Envoys: The Opening of Korea, 1875–1885, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Duus, P. (1995) The Abacus and the Sword: The Japanese Penetration of Korea, 1895–1910, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Furuta, K. (2001) ‘Inchon Trade: Japanese and Chinese Merchants and the Shanghai Network’, in S. Sugiyama and Linda Grove (eds.) Commercial Networks in Modern Asia, Surrey: Curzon Press. Han, U. G. (1970) Han’guk kaehanggi ui sang’ŏp yŏn’gu, Seoul: Ilchogak. Kim, B. R. (2003) ‘Nobi: A Korean System of Slavery’, Slavery & Abolition: A Journal of Slave and PostSlave Studies, 24:2: 155–168. Kim, O. K. (1992) Chosŏn wangjo chaejŏngsa yŏn’gu IV – kŭndaep’yŏn, Seoul: Ilchogak. Kim, T. J. (1974) ‘A Survey of Government Finances of the Late Yi Dynasty (1895–1910)’, Korea Journal, 14:2: 24–29. Kim, Y. S. (1968) ‘Kwangmu nyŏn’gan ŭi yangjŏn saŏp e kwanhan il yŏn’gu’, Asea yŏn’gu, 31. –––– . (2005) ‘The Two Courses of Agrarian Reform in Korea’s Modernization’, in Pang Kie-chung and Michael D. Shin (eds.) Landlords, Peasants and Intellectuals in Modern Korea, Ithaca, NY: Cornell East Asia Series. Kuksa p’yonch’an wiwonhoe. (2003) ‘Kaehang hu ŭi sahoe kyongjejŏk pyŏndong’, in Han’guksa, 39, Seoul: Kuksa P’yŏnch’an Wiwonhoe. Larsen, K. (2008) Tradition, Treaties, and Trade: Qing Imperialism and Chosŏn Korea, 1850–1910, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. Lew, Y. I. (1977) ‘The Reform Efforts and Ideas of Pak Yŏng-hyo, 1894–1895’, Korean Studies, 1: 21–61. McNamara, D. L. (1996) Trade and Transformation in Korea, 1876–1945, Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Miller, O. (2007) The Merchants of the Myŏnjujŏn: Guild and Government in Late Chosŏn Korea, unpublished PhD thesis, University of London. –––– . (2010) ‘The idea of stagnation in Korean historiography: From Fukuda Tokuzō to the New Right’, Korean Histories, 2:1. Pak, I. T. (2004) ‘Sŏul ŭi sungnyŏn mit misungnyŏn nodongja ŭi imgŭm, 1600–1909’, in Y. H. Yi (ed.) Suryang kyŏngjesa ro tasi pon Chosŏn hugi, Seoul: SNU Press. Pak, S. K. and Pak, S. I. (1988) ‘Chosŏn hugi chaejŏng ŭi yakhwa sijŏm e kwanhan koch’al’, Tongbang hakchi, 60. Palais, J. B. (1975) Politics and Policy in Traditional Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Sin, Y. H. (1978) ‘Nonjaeng: ŭi munjejŏm’, Ch’angjak kwa pip’yŏng, 49: 143–183. Son, C. M. (1982) Han’guk kaehanggi tosi pyŏnhwa kwajŏng yŏn’gu, Seoul: Ilchisa. Wilkinson, W. H. (1897) The Corean Government: Constitutional Changes, July 1894 to October 1895, Shanghai: Statistical Department of the Inspectorate General of Customs. Yi, H. C. (2012) Han’guk kyŏngje t’ongsa, fifth edition, Seoul: Haenam. Yi, S. N. (2007) Cheguk kwa sang’in, Seoul: Yŏksa pip’yŏngsa. Yi. Y. H. (2004) ‘Chosŏn hugi kyŏngjesa ŭi saeroun tonghyang gwa kwaje’, in Y. H. Yi (ed.) Suryang kyŏngjesa ro tasi pon Chosŏn hugi, Seoul: SNU Press. Zo, K. Z. (1976) ‘The Impact of the Opening of Korea on Its Commerce and Industry’, Korea Journal, 16:2: 27–46.

94

7 The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion Carl Young

In the early spring of 1894, a massive peasant uprising broke out that involved members of the Tonghak movement, a new Korean religion, as well as many other peasants. It is known through a variety of names today such as the Tonghak Rebellion, the Tonghak Peasant War and the Tonghak Revolution.1 This rebellion, centred in the southern provinces of Ch’ŏlla and Ch’ungch’ŏng, was the largest one in Korean history and involved many Tonghak adherents in its leadership. Although the majority of the insurgents were not members of the Tonghak religion, its organisational structure helped facilitate the organisation and cohesion of the rebellion. The success of the rebels in early 1894 led the Korean government to appeal to China for aid in putting down the uprising. When China sent troops to help the Korean government, Japan used this as a pretext to send its own soldiers to Korea, even though the Korean government and the rebels had established an uneasy truce by this time. This led to the Sino-Japanese War of 1894–1895, and Japan’s victory in the war marked the beginning of its ascendancy as a modern imperial power. The rebellion and the Sino-Japanese War also led to a domestic coup d’état in the Korean government supported by the Japanese. The new administration launched the modernising Kabo Reforms, which changed the traditional governing structure of Korea between 1894 and 1896. This Japanese intervention led to a second stage of the rebellion in late 1894, which was brutally and quickly put down by government and Japanese troops. In spite of the rebellion’s failure, it acted as a catalyst that helped to provoke events that profoundly affected Korea both domestically and internationally. The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion can thus be seen as a watershed marking a new era in Korean history. Its revolutionary consequences are the reason why so many scholars and activists have looked at and analysed this event so profoundly.

What was Tonghak? Tonghak arose in the last half of the nineteenth century, a period of domestic and international turmoil in Korea and East Asia. Its founder, Ch’oe Che-u, an educated but impoverished yangban, started preaching his new synthesis of Eastern philosophy and folk traditions among peasants and marginalised members of the educated classes in southeastern Korea after a profound experience with the divine in 1860. Ch’oe Che-u had wandered for several years before this, 95

Carl Young

searching for answers to what he felt was a spiritual void in his life that the contemporary interpretations of Neo-Confucianism that were then prevalent in Chosŏn Korea were unable to answer. Ch’oe Che-u was also socially marginalised because of his poverty and his status as a secondary son born of a concubine that barred him from many opportunities that would be open to a person of his education. He also observed the social problems in Chosŏn Korea and was increasingly concerned by the growing power of the West in China and the activities of Catholics in Korea. Eventually, this led to an ecstatic spiritual experience that occurred during a time of illness. The divine spoke to Ch’oe Che-u in a voice that seemed to come from both within and outside himself, something that would later develop into a belief that God pervades all creation and all human beings. The divine revealed a sacred incantation and a diagram that Ch’oe needed to draw and then burn and drink the ashes so that he could be healed. Ch’oe was indeed healed after following these instructions. Ch’oe Che-u started preaching about his experience to his family and friends in his local area near Kyŏngju and gained a reputation as a healer with his sacred diagram and incantations. The chanting of the various forms of the Tonghak incantation and the healing ritual were easily accessible to those without much education. Ch’oe Che-u also discussed his experience with scholars and laid out his doctrine in an intellectual style as well. He emphasised how his new teaching, which he called Tonghak, or Eastern Learning, not only combined the best of Confucianism, Buddhism, and Daoism but also went beyond them by revealing the true nature of the divine that was carried within all creation. His goal was to make his teaching a new spiritual foundation for Chosŏn society to enable it to withstand the onslaughts of both power and ideas coming from Western countries. The implication of this teaching was that all human beings, regardless of status or education, carried a part of the divine within them. By applying Tonghak teachings and rituals, one could come into contact with the divine and bring it out within oneself and benefit both the individual and society. This combination exercised a dual appeal to both people with some education and those who followed a more oral folk tradition. The new doctrine also emphasised a more direct contact with the divine for all people, regardless of education or social class, which also drew a large audience. The popularity of this new doctrine quickly drew the attention of local officials, who were concerned about the appeal of this unorthodox teaching, especially for its deviations from Neo-Confucianism and the threat to social hierarchy implied in the new doctrine. In the end, Ch’oe Che-u was arrested and finally executed in 1864. His new religion was declared illegal, his writings were burned, and the organisation was forced underground. The new religion refused to die, however. Ch’oe Che-u’s successor, Ch’oe Si-hyŏng, reorganised Tonghak as an underground movement in the 1870s and 1880s. Although Tonghak remained illegal, persecution occurred only sporadically, with long periods of peace in between. This allowed Tonghak to spread and consolidate itself, mainly in central Korea and increasingly in the southwestern part of the country. Again, the majority of the believers were poor agriculturalists, but many of the leaders were marginalised members of the educated classes who were alienated from the Chosŏn political and social system and the orthodox Neo-Confucianism that gave it intellectual support. Tonghak’s local sections were re-established in 1878, and this was further expanded by the establishment of regional groupings (p’o) that combined many local branches (chŏp) together in a quasi-military style by 1884. Both the chŏp and the p’o were connected to distinct networks of Tonghak preachers and their converts. Six officers helped run the regional organisation, and this was often supplemented by a leader (taejŏpchu) chosen by the leaders of the local branches. Although there is some debate about the exact timing of the organisation of several chŏp into a larger regional grouping, names of the p’o were apparent by 1893 and numbered around 96

The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion

50 by that time. This period also saw a certain standardisation of Tonghak rituals as well as the compilation of Tonghak’s scriptures in both classical Chinese and vernacular Korean. This again allowed it to appeal to a dual audience of marginalised educated people and poorer peasants without much education. It could also lead to different approaches to the faith, a more philosophical one for the educated and another that drew on the rituals based on folk tradition for those who were less literate. The fact that there were a variety of approaches to access divine power in Tonghak may have increased its appeal among a wider swath of Chosŏn rural society. Tonghak did offer opportunities for the poor and uneducated to be part of a movement that had ways for them to directly access divine power and be part of a network that met regularly and reinforced social relationships outside of normal state-centred structures. The literary tradition within Tonghak was attractive to marginalised intellectuals and permitted them also to find a new way to find spiritual and social satisfaction. The reforms in the religion’s organisation and the compilation of scriptures and other ritual and doctrinal works during this period helped to bolster the effectiveness and the esprit de corps of the new religion. These contributed to Tonghak’s growing success and strength in spite of official government persecution. By the 1890s, Tonghak had strong local underground networks throughout southern Korea loosely united under Ch’oe Sihyŏng’s religious leadership.

Early rumblings The period from the late 1870s to the late 1880s was also an important period in Korean political history because foreign powers and a new order of international relations imposed by the West affected Korea in its regional position in East Asia. Japan was the first to break down the barrier in 1876, forcing an unequal treaty on Korea similar to those which had been imposed on itself and on China by the Western powers. Treaties were signed with other Western powers throughout the 1880s. However, the Western powers generally had their attention diverted elsewhere, so the main foreign competition over Korea was between Japan and China. This international rivalry exacerbated the official corruption and social misery already existing in Korea, with the added threat of a possible loss of independence. By the 1890s, Ch’oe Si-hyŏng and other leaders had left their places of refuge in southern Kangwŏn province to pursue their activities in Ch’ungch’ong and Ch’ŏlla provinces, where the majority of Tonghak believers were now concentrated. After years of relative relaxation, local government persecution of Tonghak started increasing in Ch’ungch’ong and Ch’ŏlla, further indicative of Tonghak’s growth in these regions and growing government ideological defensiveness. Tonghak believers also became more vocal about their desire to clear the name of their founder and legalise their religion. This was given further impetus by the legalisation of Catholicism as a result of the Franco-Korean treaty in 1886. In common with other Koreans, Tonghak followers were also victims of government corruption which led to land and tax abuses. Many were also resentful of the growing presence of Japanese merchants, who were not averse to exploiting and swindling Korean peasants. All these grievances combined together in two petition movements by Tonghak followers in 1892 and 1893 to clear Ch’oe Che-u’s name. The petition in 1892 was given from a mass meeting near Chŏnju to the governors of Ch’ŏlla and Ch’ungch’ŏng provinces. This was done without Ch’oe Si-hyŏng’s permission by local Tonghak leaders. The movement aimed to dissociate Tonghak from the label of heterodoxy. The petition was couched in very traditional Confucian terms and asserted that Tonghak was not heretical, but instead united the best of Confucianism, Buddhism, and Daoism, and was substantially similar to Confucianism in its 97

Carl Young

principles. It also denounced the activities of Japanese merchants which brought difficulties to the people and also complained that there was too much Western and Japanese influence in Korea. Finally, the petition also protested against the persecution of Tonghak believers and demanded the release of Tonghak prisoners and the clearing of Ch’oe Che-u’s name. The movement had both political but also very religious demands. The 1892 petition was rebuffed and as the persecutions and abuses continued, pressure mounted for another petition movement in 1893. Taking advantage of the birth of a royal prince, the petitioners were able to mix with the celebratory crowds in the capital to stage a mass march by Tonghak followers that brought the petition to the gates of the royal palace itself. The movement continued to pledge loyalty to the king and emphasised that Tonghak doctrine combined the best of Confucianism, Taoism, and Buddhism, all of which were allowed by the state. However, unofficial actions by some of the petitioners, such as the posting of threatening placards on the property of Christian missionaries, revealed a strong anti-Western and anti-Japanese stance among many of the protestors. There may even have been a desire to overthrow the government on the part of others. The government accepted the petition and told the demonstrators to disperse, which they did. However, no action was taken afterwards to satisfy their demands. The movement also wound down as prominent Tonghak leaders around Ch’oe Si-hyŏng were worried about the potential for violence, which they opposed. There was also apparently increasing dissatisfaction from many Tonghak petitioners that the movement was taking a more political tone, focussing more on political reforms and anti-foreign campaigns than on clearing Ch’oe Che-u’s name and the legalisation of Tonghak. It is interesting to note that Ch’oe Si-hyŏng was not the prime mover behind these demonstrations. He gave in to pressure from other Tonghak leaders, chiefly from Ch’ŏlla province, to go forward with the petitions. It is likely that he did this because these leaders were going to go ahead with these actions anyway and he wanted to maintain some control over the whole process. Still, Ch’oe Si-hyŏng originally opposed these movements, mainly because he did not think that it was an opportune time to engage in such action. Ch’oe Si-hyŏng emphasised passive reform, spiritual regeneration, and the importance of organising Tonghak to improve its effectiveness in spreading its spiritual message. Growing pressure, especially from leaders and believers from Ch’ŏlla province, forced him to compromise and allow actions that he was not comfortable with. The events surrounding the petition movement also revealed increasing tensions between Ch’oe Si-hyŏng and those close to him and other Tonghak leaders who may have had a broader socio-political agenda than Ch’oe Si-hyŏng. This may have led to differences in doctrine and religious priorities. These trends may have been reinforced by Tonghak’s leadership and organisational structure, which was only loosely centralised around Ch’oe Si-hyŏng’s leadership. This decentralised structure was effective in an era of underground preaching but made coordination more difficult between different Tonghak leadership networks and had the potential of giving rise to independent streams of teaching and authority. This made it more difficult for Ch’oe Si-hyŏng to keep control over local congregations, especially at a time of persecution that caused difficulties in communications. This difficulty would again reveal itself in the course of the 1894 rebellion.

The first stage Although the main Tonghak leadership wanted to settle their grievances with the government through peaceful means, events took a violent turn when Chŏn Pong-jun, a local Tonghak leader in Kobu in the southwestern province of Ch’ŏlla, started an armed rebellion in the spring 98

The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion

of 1894 after Tonghak followers and other peasants were abused by corrupt officials. This was to become the largest peasant revolt in Korean history, with repercussions both domestically and internationally. The Kobu uprising began in the first lunar month of 1894 and was led by Chŏn Pong-jun, a local Tonghak leader. There is a great deal of confusion surrounding many events connected to 1894 because it was such a chaotic time and there was a large variety of localised issues that overlapped with the major events of the two stages of the rebellion. As well, local leaders often acted for their own motivations with little coordination with the national movement. We actually know little about Chŏn Pong-jun, except through the small number of petitions that he sponsored and through the minutes of his trial. He first gained prominence in Tonghak during the 1893 petition movement and seems to have had contacts with anti-foreign officials and the Taewŏn’gun, King Kojong’s father, who was well known for his anti-foreign tendencies but who was now marginalised. It appears that he was a fairly recent convert to the faith, although his local influence and dynamism quickly brought him to prominence in local Tonghak circles in Ch’ŏlla province. It is highly likely that he was a fallen yangban, just like Ch’oe Che-u and many others in the Tonghak leadership, although he could also have been a wealthy commoner. There was a wide variety of backgrounds in the rebellion’s leadership and many of them were educated. Although most of the rebel fighters were mainly from the lower agricultural classes, a large proportion of the leadership came from the marginalised educated classes or rich farmers, along with poor farmers. Although the 1894 rebellion is often known as the Tonghak Rebellion or Tonghak Revolution, only a minority of the peasant rebels were Tonghak followers. However, there were many conversions to Tonghak during the different stages of the uprising. Even in the initial uprising in Kobu, only about 300 of the approximately 500 rebels were Tonghak followers. Others had close personal relations with Chŏn Pong-jun. Still, Tonghak believers formed an important part of the leadership and the rank and file, and this continued through the next stages of the rebellion. It could be that Tonghak’s congregational organisation, and most importantly, its recent role in the petition movements of the past couple of years, already provided experience in organisation for political and social action that gave Tonghak followers a prominent role in the 1894 rebellion’s organisation. Local problems had motivated the original uprising, but the close contacts between Chŏn and other like-minded Tonghak believers in Ch’ŏlla led to the growing spread and success of the rebellion. About a month after the beginning of the Kobu uprising, letters were sent by the Kobu rebels to other Tonghak congregations in Ch’ŏlla province. Demands were made to reform corruption in official circles while maintaining support for the king and the welfare of the nation. However, not as much emphasis was placed on what had been traditional Tonghak demands, such as religious freedom or the clearing of Ch’oe Che-u’s name. Uprisings spread throughout much of Ch’ŏlla province. There were some uprisings in Ch’ungch’ong and Kyŏngsang provinces as well, but they quickly dispersed. A possible reason is that Ch’oe Si-hyŏng’s authority was stronger here and he may have been more successful in ordering Tonghak followers in these provinces to cease their actions. Not all Tonghak believers were involved in the uprising led by Chŏn Pong-jun. Ch’oe Sihyŏng’s initial reaction was lukewarm at best. He seemed resigned to the fact that the rebellion had happened and praised Chŏn’s motivations of filial piety and humanity. However, he ordered Chŏn not to be hurried in his actions and to desist and not defy the will of Heaven. Chŏn obviously disregarded this order and so did most of the leadership in Ch’ŏlla province that followed in the rebellion. However, most of the Tonghak organisation elsewhere, including most of the senior leadership that was going to assume a prominent role in Tonghak in the years after 1894, 99

Carl Young

decided to follow Ch’oe Si-hyŏng’s leadership and did not participate in the spring uprising.2 In spite of this, there appears to have been little outward hostility between Ch’oe Si-hyŏng and Chŏn Pong-jun. Some scholars believe that Ch’oe’s support of the rebellion has been downplayed in historical memory so as to protect his reputation due to the rebellion’s failure. This division was further reflected with the increasing use of the term namjŏp, or Southern Assembly, to describe Tonghak leaders and followers, mainly in Ch’ŏlla province, who engaged in the first stage of the rebellion. This was used to distinguish these Tonghak believers from the pukchŏp, or Northern Assembly, centred on Ch’oe Si-hyŏng. The term namjŏp is rarely seen before 1894 and appears most often in non-Tonghak government, Japanese and bureaucratic documents relating to the uprising. However, it is clear that Chŏn Pong-jun himself started to use this term to designate his followers in Ch’ŏlla and to distinguish himself from the older leadership. Some have asserted that this was mainly a geographic designation, and it is true that there was not a complete separation of the Northern and Southern Assemblies and that Ch’oe Si-hyŏng conserved overall religious leadership over Tonghak. However, there are also clear differences in the emphasis placed by the leaders of the two divisions over doctrinal, political and social issues. Ch’oe Si-hyŏng placed a much greater emphasis on spiritual and religious issues over overt socio-political action. Although there was technical unity between these two divisions of Tonghak, criticism between them continued well into the late summer of 1894. This can again be indicative of some of the challenges Tonghak faced due to its loose decentralised leadership structure compounded by difficulties in communication between different regional networks of Tonghak followers. The success of the rebels alarmed the Korean government. Under previous agreements made with China and Japan, the Korean king appealed to China to send troops to help put down the insurgency. China agreed to send military aid, but this led Japan to exercise its option to send troops to protect its interests as well. The Korean government, realising its mistake, tried to make peace with the rebels in June 1894 by allowing them some input into local government through the establishment of advisory agencies under Tonghak rebel control called chipkangso that were to help government officials administer areas under rebel control. The first stage of the rebellion came to an end because both the government and the rebels were worried about Chinese and Japanese intervention and this forced both into a compromise that neither side was very comfortable with.

Uneasy interlude The Korean government’s fears of instability were well warranted. In spite of the peace, neither Japan nor China withdrew their troops from Korea. As tensions rose between Japan and China, the Japanese brought the Korean government under their control by engineering a palace coup in late July 1894. This brought in a new administration that instituted government reforms based on Japan’s Meiji restoration. These Kabo reforms, as they are commonly known in Korean history, addressed many of the concerns that the rebels had raised. However, the fact that Japanese influence was behind these innovations raised suspicions and made the reform regime increasingly unpopular. Clashes between Chinese and Japanese forces in Korea occurred shortly after the coup, making Korea a battlefield in a regional war for supremacy between China and Japan that would culminate in a Japanese victory the following year. The Sino-Japanese War of 1894–1895 was one of the major first steps of Japanese imperial expansion that would continue in various stages up until the end of World War II. Both the Tonghak rebels in Ch’ŏlla province and the new government in Seoul were increasingly ill at ease with each other through the summer of 1894 in spite of the truce. Many 100

The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion

of the rebels shared popular unease at the dependence of the new reform administration on Japanese support and were distrustful of the foreign ideas on which the government’s new policies were based. The government felt a growing anxiety that the rebels were an alternate centre of power, almost independent of it. The summer of 1894 also saw the establishment of the new chipkangso which gave input into local government, mainly in Ch’ŏlla province. There were also chipkangso established in some areas of Ch’ungch’ong province and these were supervised by Ch’oe Si-hyŏng. Again, difficulties in communication and differing local conditions led to different versions of the aims of the chipkangso as well as to different actions. Land redistribution appears to have been the main unifying agenda for the chipkangso, but because of the short time that these institutions existed (little more than three months), it is very difficult to see much action on this issue. Tensions between the Northern and Southern Assemblies were also evident, with some evidence of efforts to get certain p’o to switch sides. Ch’oe Si-hyŏng was also concerned at the on-going arms build-up in areas controlled by the namjŏp, seeing it as a threat to the areas under his control. He actually issued an official statement that Chŏn and those affiliated with him were traitors to the state and heretics of the Tonghak faith. There appear to have been some divisions even within the namjŏp. Chŏn Pong-jun was an important leader in Ch’ŏlla, but he was certainly not the only one. There were other important Tonghak leaders in the south, such as Kim Kae-nam and Sŏ Chang-ok, who dominated their local areas. Kim Kae-nam was increasingly autonomous in his area and consolidated his local power without much reference to outside leadership. He was also less cooperative with government authorities, and when the second stage of the rebellion began in the autumn of 1894, he was reluctant to give much support to Chŏn and the other Tonghak rebels. There was coordination between the namjŏp leaders but also increasing autonomous action. Again, Tonghak’s decentralised leadership structure made it not only difficult for Ch’oe Si-hyŏng to impose centralised leadership but also made for a lack of a unified agenda on the part of the Southern Assembly as well. In spite of this, there were many conversions to Tonghak during this time, especially in Ch’ŏlla but also in other provinces. However, the situation during the summer of 1894 reveals that there were significant tensions between Tonghak leaders and a lack of a unified agenda among Tonghak believers, even within the rebel faction.

The second stage Renewed disturbances occurred in the end of the summer of 1894, when government troops attacked Tonghak believers without regard to the distinction between those who followed Ch’oe Si-hyŏng and those who followed the rebel leader Chŏn Pong-jun. This engendered great indignation on the part of both Tonghak factions and led to calls for united action to drive out all foreign troops from Korean soil and reform the government. Although he had condemned many of Chŏn Pong-jun’s actions as illegal, Ch’oe Si-hyŏng agreed to unite with him in joint action to “clear the Master’s [Ch’oe Che-u’s] name and fulfil the Way” in October 1894. The main motivation in this second stage of the rebellion that now united Tonghak followers was anti-Japanese action and a desire to liberate the monarch from foreign hands. On the new reformist government’s side, a growing apprehension of greater regional autonomy with the new role of the chipkangso likely motivated its anti-Tonghak actions. Although Tonghak followers provided most of the leadership and its regional structure was instrumental in organising the rebel forces, Tonghak’s importance in the second stage of the 1894 rebellion was less obvious than in the first stage and the proportion of non-Tonghak participants was greater. The field of action of the rebels also expanded, some into the central and northern 101

Carl Young

provinces of Kangwŏn and Hwanghae. Kim Ku, the Korean nationalist activist, joined Tonghak at the age of 18 in 1893 in his native Hwanghae province. In his later memoirs, he wrote that Tonghak’s aim was to form a new people and establish a new nation when the “True Lord would come to Kyeryongsan.” This statement is highly reminiscent of the Chŏnggamnok, an old prophetic and divinatory work that was popular among much of the peasantry. It prophesied the establishment of a new dynasty of justice at Kyeryong mountain and often acted as an inspiration for other peasant rebellions. Again this shows the often different understandings that Tonghak believers themselves had of their religious and socio-political motivations. In his trial after his capture, Chŏn Pong-jun admitted that there were more non-Tonghak participants than Tonghak believers in the rebellion.3 The forces led by Chŏn Pong-jun and those forces loyal to Ch’oe Si-hyŏng united together in Ch’ungch’ŏng province in November 1894. After a few initial victories over government troops, the rebel forces suffered a terrible defeat with great loss of life in a battle near Kongju in December 1894. The rebel troops scattered into disparate groups and were never able to recover the initiative.

The aftermath By the beginning of 1895, the rebellion was all but over. The combined Korean government and Japanese troops targeted the main centre of rebel power in Ch’ŏlla and southern Ch’ungch’ŏng provinces. These areas were the centre of Chŏn Pong-jun’s Southern Assembly (namjŏp) faction, which had participated in the first phase of the rebellion. They had been the major focus of Tonghak strength before the uprising, but the military action resulted in massacres of Tonghak believers, the destruction of their religious and military organisation and the arrest and execution of the most important Tonghak leaders of the area, including Chŏn Pong-jun and most of his prominent lieutenants. Many believers also fled, never to return.4 There was not much left of the Southern Assembly faction on which to build a revitalised organisation. The case was different for the Northern Assembly (pukchŏp) faction headed by Ch’oe Sihyŏng and those loyal to him. After the defeat in Kongju, Ch’oe Si-hyŏng fled north with his loyal lieutenants, eventually ending up in the Ch’ungju/Hongju area of north Ch’ungch’ŏng province by the end of 1894. They later fled to Inje county in Kangwŏn province in the first lunar month of 1895. This was familiar territory for Ch’oe Si-hyŏng as he had wandered a lot in hiding in this area during the 1880s. Kangwŏn province had had some sporadic rebel activity in 1894, but there were not as many Tonghak followers as in the southern and central provinces, and the rebel movement was put down. Anti-Tonghak activities started immediately after the uprising occurred, mainly led by local Confucian scholars who were deeply opposed to what they perceived as Tonghak’s heresy. Because of this, there was not as great a need for government or Japanese troops to put down the rebellion in this area. Although government suppression of Tonghak was not concentrated in these areas, the search for these leaders was very intense, and there were many close calls. Government authorities knew that Ch’oe Si-hyŏng had fled towards the east and they engaged in great efforts to capture him. This was to start several years of wandering from place to place amidst great suffering in the mountains of Kangwŏn and north Ch’ungch’ŏng until Ch’oe Si-hyŏng was finally captured and executed in 1898. Before his death, Ch’oe Si-hyŏng trained new leaders to rebuild Tonghak’s organisation. Son Pyŏng-hŭi took over the central leadership in 1900 and embarked on a program of 102

The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion

re-organisation, preaching and standardisation of doctrine. In 1906, the name of the revitalised Tonghak organisation was changed to Ch’ŏndogyo, in part to signal a new direction for the religion in the midst of the social and political changes happening in Korea in the early twentieth century. Ch’ŏndogyo continued to exist after the imposition of Japanese colonialism and was prominent in the March First anti-Japanese demonstrations in 1919 and in other nationalist cultural and social movements in the 1920s and early 1930s. It continues to exist as a small religion in South Korea today. The area in southern Ch’ŏlla province continued to be a centre of peasant resistance during the late 1890s. Localised peasant rebellions drew from some of the teachings and most importantly, the organisation of the old Tonghak rebels. Some former Tonghak rebels converted to Christianity (a good example of this is the nationalist leader Kim Ku), while others gravitated to other new religions, including the Chŭngsan’gyo movement, in the early twentieth century.

The legacy of the 1894 Tonghak Rebellion The main aim of the rebellion appears to have been to reform social and economic abuses, and in the second part of the rebellion, to expel foreign troops from Korea. A further complication is that because of Tonghak’s decentralised structure, there was often no unified agenda and there were many conflicting views and trends. Many Koreans have attempted to show that the Tonghak Rebellion displayed a native form of modern democracy and nationalism in order to prove that Korea was going through the stages of progress that evolutionary ideologies such as Marxism and modernisation theory laid out as necessary for progress and development. However, this can be highly debatable, especially in view of the movement’s fragmentation and lack of a unified agenda. The modern ideas of democracy and nationalism had foreign origins, and Tonghak was not in contact with these foreign ideas at the time of its founding or at the time of the 1894 rebellion. The fact that the Tonghak rebels may not have had an organised programme that could bring in modern nationalism and democracy in no way reduces their historical importance or minimises their fight against injustice. Although the 1894 rebellion was ultimately unsuccessful, it helped spark developments that helped reform much of the corruption in government. It also provoked events that led to the introduction of those institutions and ideas that led to profound changes to the structure of the state and started a debate concerning the direction of the nation in an increasingly unstable East Asia. Ironically, these changes were initiated by a government that was supported by the Japanese, the exact opposite of what the Tonghak rebels wanted. In spite of this, immense changes resulted from the rebellion and Korea would never be the same again. As a result, the 1894 rebellion proved a watershed which helped to open up a new era in Korean history. Because the consequences of the rebellion heralded a new phase in Korean history, modern Korean historians, from communists to right-wing nationalists, have written abundantly on the 1894 Tonghak peasant revolutionary movement, each trying to incorporate it into their interpretation of Korean history. The struggle of oppressed peasants against a corrupt and exploitative regime and the rebels’ fight against the Japanese invaders is a great inspiration for presentday fights against injustice and threats to the nation. Many studies of the 1894 Tonghak Rebellion are focussed on its value as an example of a heroic popular nationalist struggle. Mainstream South Korean nationalist histories usually consider Tonghak as being a response to the problems of the nation during the late Chosŏn dynasty. The following quote from an article by Shin Yong-ha is typical of many assessments of Tonghak by South Korean historians: 103

Carl Young

Tonghak, established in 1860 by Ch’oe Che-u, was a religious thought founded and propagated to ‘sustain the nation and provide for the people (poguk anmin)’ and ‘save the oppressed people (kwangje ch’angsaeng)’ by achieving a simultaneous breakthrough in the national and the feudal crises which the Korean people faced in the mid-19th century. (Shin Yong-ha 1994: 59) Another Korean historian, Lee Young-ho, is even clearer as to the nationalist credentials of Tonghak in the 1894 rebellion: The Peasant War of 1894 was an anti-feudal and anti-imperialistic movement with the aim of establishing a modern nation-state by overcoming the feudal and national crises. (Lee Young-ho 1994: 90) These are good examples of the general consensus that Tonghak was anti-feudal and nationalist in nature during the 1894 peasant uprising. Tonghak is deemed to have been created to overthrow the Chosŏn dynasty’s governmental and social structure and contained within it the indigenous seeds that could lead to the creation of a modern nation-state with democratic elements to replace the old “feudal” system. According to this viewpoint, Tonghak combined the common people’s desire for social justice, relief from oppression and participation in government with the defence of the nation from foreign, especially Japanese, incursions. Young-ick Lew (1991) is one of a minority of historians who see the ideology of the 1894 Tonghak Rebellion as a proto-nationalist, rather than a fully-fledged modern nationalist, movement. He asserts that Tonghak at this time was more inspired by the Neo-Confucian “Way of the Sages” than by ideas of modern nationalism or democracy. However, he does agree that Tonghak “was infused with a strong patriotic ardour, a burning desire to protect the nation from foreign aggression, and with the egalitarian dream of abolishing the yangban class system.” In this he is generally joined by the few foreign historians who have done much work on Tonghak. The first major English-language work by Benjamin Weems (1964) was a short, general work mainly concentrating on internal events of the religion and how it interacted with the changes in Korean society. More recently, books by Paul Beirne (2009) and George Kallander (2013) have also focussed more on the internal religious history of Tonghak and its doctrines and structure rather than engaging in the nationalist debate. In general, the Tonghak peasant uprising of 1894 is seen within a wider context of other movements which arose in the 1890s, including the Kabo reforms of 1894–1896 and the Independence Club in 1896–1898. These are all deemed important in contributing to early modernising nationalism in Korea. Starting from the early 2000s, there has been a growing trend among mainstream Korean historians to look at the complexities of the rebellion itself and also on its consequences. This has helped to move some of the Korean debate about Tonghak beyond the “nation” question (although it is still important) and has added a welcome, more multi-faceted view of Tonghak and the rebellion. In the late 1960s, the minjung movement arose as a resistance movement against the military regimes that ruled South Korea from the early 1960s to the mid-1980s. The word minjung was coined late in the nineteenth century from two Chinese characters meaning “the people” and “a group or mass.” The minjung movement in the late twentieth century interpreted it as meaning the “oppressed mass of the people” who are the true locus of the nation and who produce change in history. Minjung historiography has some similarities to Marxism. As opposed to class struggle in Marxism, however, the minjung can be a class coalition of all the oppressed (labourers, peasants, 104

The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion

artisans, dissident intellectuals, etc.), albeit mainly from the lower strata of society. The minjung are deemed to cause change in history in their attempts to regain their subjectivity (chuch’esŏng) and exercise their rightful role in society. Since the composition of the minjung can be different in various periods of history, minjung historians search for groups and movements that can be said to constitute the minjung in different points of Korean history. Minjung historiography accepts some of the premises of more mainstream South Korean nationalism but stresses the importance of popular rather than elite movements. This has influenced later research by more traditional historians, leading to a cross-fertilisation between traditional nationalist and minjung nationalist histories. This has led minjung historians to emphasise the 1894 Tonghak peasant uprising as the classic example of a minjung movement, mainly because of its origins among the oppressed peasantry. In the Tonghak Rebellion, the minjung rises up to destroy oppression and protect the nation. One of the most prominent minjung historians, Kang Man-gil, considers the Tonghak Rebellion “a large-scale anti-imperialist and anti-feudal struggle that has important significance in the history of the struggle of our minjung.” The exaltation of the Tonghak movement implies a rejection of the more elite nationalist movements, such as the Kabo Reforms and the Independence Club, that also occurred around this time and which are traditionally considered as contributing to modern Korean nationalism. This is mainly because they were not based on minjung culture. The Tonghak movement is thus the proper place to look for the minjung dynamic and spirit and the true locus of the beginnings of modern Korean nationalism. As demonstrated by Nancy Abelman (1996) and Namhee Lee (2007), among others, historical memory of the rebellion and its leaders, notably Chŏn Pong-jun, played an important part in the art, music and motivational practices of the student, farmer, and labour movements in the 1970s and 1980s. Another important stream of nationalism is that incarnated by North Korea. The relationship between the North Korean Communist regime and Tonghak/Ch’ŏndogyo is a mixed one. In the late 1920s, some Ch’ŏndogyo believers founded a political party, the Ch’ŏndogyo ch’ŏngudang (Ch’ŏndogyo Young Friends’ Party) that advocated national self-strengthening on the basis of Ch’ŏndogyo values. The northern wing of Ch’ŏndogyo’s political party was forced into a coalition with the Korean Workers’ Party, along with the northern wing of the Korean Democratic Party, and this structure still technically exists today, although the Korean Workers’ Party selects and controls the members of the two other parties. However, Ch’ŏndogyo as a religion, like any religion in the north, is tightly controlled. This leads to a mixed assessment of Tonghak’s and Ch’ŏndogyo’s contributions to Korean history. The official North Korean history, Chosŏn chŏnsa, praises the foundation of Tonghak by Ch’oe Che-u as a movement to oppose Chosŏn’s feudal system and incursions by foreigners. The greatest weakness of Tonghak is that this desire was encapsulated in the form of “religious superstition,” which restricted the development of a “social consciousness.” The Tonghak Rebellion was important in promoting the demise of Korean feudalism, but the lack of a proletariat to lead the struggle doomed it to failure and weakened its “anti-imperialistic fighting consciousness.” Tonghak activities tend to be lumped into a “bourgeois phase” that includes the activities of the Independence Club and culminates in the March 1919 demonstrations, which is the terminal point of this stage. In spite of the Tonghak Rebellion’s failure, it set off events such as the Sino-Japanese War of 1894–1895 that marked the rise of Japanese imperialism, which eventually snuffed out Korea’s independence in 1910. It also had a profound impact domestically, leading to the Kabo Reforms of 1894 and thereby launching a debate in Korea on nation-building and self-strengthening that would have a profound effect on Korea, even as it eventually became colonised by Japan. The rebellion’s precedent of the lowly, the oppressed and the disenfranchised rising up against 105

Carl Young

corruption and injustice still provides inspiration to contemporary movements for social justice and continues to be an important ingredient in the building of Korean identities. The rebellion’s on-going legacy still resonates today.

Notes 1

2

3

4

It has become fashionable to use the term “Tonghak Revolution” in South Korea, especially among progressive circles that attach a positive value to revolution as a change of political and social order. However, in English, the use of the word “revolution” tends to be applied to successful uprisings in which the rebels themselves take over government and establish a new order based on their agenda. As will be seen, the Tonghak peasant rebels were ultimately unsuccessful in their uprising and the application of their agenda. This is the reason that this article will refer to this event as a rebellion rather than a revolution. However, this does not mean that this event did not have wide-ranging consequences that had a strong effect on Korea’s domestic and international circumstances. Some Tonghak believers outside of Ch’ŏlla province also staged disturbances during the spring phase of the rebellion, and some Tonghak branches in Ch’ŏlla apparently were not active at this time. There appears to have been some overlap. English translations of sections of Chŏn Pong-jun’s trial and other documents related to the Tonghak Rebellion can be found in chapter 30 of Yŏng-ho Ch’oe et al. 1997, Sources of Korean Tradition, Volume 2, Columbia University Press, New York. The most recent official Ch’ŏndogyo history, the Ch’ŏndogyo yaksa, asserts that there may have been up to 500,000 people massacred in the aftermath of the failure of the rebellion. It is difficult, however, to get an exact number of the people killed in the months following the rebellion.

References Abelman, Nancy (1996) Echoes of the Past, Epics of Dissent, University of California Press, Berkeley, CA. Beirne, Paul (2009) Su-un and His World of Symbols: The Founder of Korea’s First Indigenous Religion, Ashgate Publishing, Farnham, Surrey. Ch’oe, Chungmoo (1995) “The Minjung Culture Movement and Popular Culture” in Kenneth M. Wells (ed.), South Korea’s Minjung Movement: The Culture and Politics of Dissidence, University of Hawaii Press, Honolulu, HI. Cho, Jae-gon (1994) “The Connection of the Sino-Japanese War and the Peasant War of 1894,” Korea Journal, vol. 34, no. 4 (Winter 1994), pp. 45–58. Kallander, George (2013) Salvation through Dissent: Tonghak Heterodoxy and Early Modern Korea, University of Hawaii Press, Honolulu, HI. Kim, Yong Choon and Yoon, Suk San (2007) Chondogyo Scripture: Donggyeong Daejeon (Great Scripture of Eastern Learning), trans. Central Headquarters of Ch’ondogyo, University Press of America, Lanham, MD. Ko, Seok-kyu (1994) “Activities of the Peasant Army during the Chipkangso Period,” Korea Journal, vol. 34, no. 4 (Winter 1994), pp. 31–44. Lee, Ewha (1994) “A Study of the Relationship between the Reform of Misgovernment and the Kabo Reform,” Korea Journal, vol. 34, no. 4 (Winter 1994), pp. 76–89. Lee, Namhee (2007) The Making of Minjung: Democracy and the Politics of Representation in South Korea, Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY. Lee, Young-ho (1994) “The Socioeconomic Background and the Growth of the New Social Forces of the 1894 Peasant War,” Korea Journal, vol. 34, no. 4 (Winter 1994), pp. 90–100. Lew, Young-ick (1991) “The Conservative Character of the 1894 Tonghak Peasant Uprising: A Reappraisal with Emphasis on Chŏn Pong-jun’s Background and Motivation,” Journal of Korean Studies 7 (1990–91), pp. 149–180. Shin, Soonchul and Lee, Jinyoung (2008) A Short History of the Donghak Peasant Revolution, trans. Singh, Rohini and Lee, Chongmin, Donghak Peasant Revolution Memorial Association, Seoul. Shin, Susan (1978) “The Tonghak Movement: From Enlightenment to Revolution,” Korea Forum (1978), pp. 1–60. 106

The 1894 Tonghak Rebellion

Shin, Susan (1979) “Tonghak Thought: The Roots of Revolution,” Korea Journal, vol. 19, no. 9 (September 1979), pp. 11–19. Shin, Yong-ha (1990) Formation and Development of Modern Korean Nationalism, Daekwang Munhwasa, Seoul. Shin, Yong-ha (1994) “Conjunction of Tonghak and the Peasant War of 1894,” Korea Journal, vol. 34, no. 4 (Winter 1994), pp. 59–75. Suh, Young-hee (1994) “Tracing the Course of the Peasant War of 1894,” Korea Journal, vol. 34, no. 4 (Winter 1994), pp. 17–30. Weems, Benjamin (1964) Reform, Rebellion, and the Heavenly Way, University of Arizona Press, Tucson, AZ. Wells, Kenneth M. (1995) “The Cultural Construction of Korean History” in Kenneth M. Wells (ed.), South Korea’s Minjung Movement: The Culture and Politics of Dissidence, University of Hawaii Press, Honolulu, HI. Young, Carl (2014) Eastern Learning and the Heavenly Way: The Tonghak and Ch’ŏndogyo Movements and the Twilight of Korean Independence, University of Hawaii Press, Honolulu, HI.

107

This page intentionally left blank

Part II

The colonial period

This page intentionally left blank

8 The politics of assimilation Koreans into Japanese Mark E. Caprio

The legacy that Japan’s assimilation policies had on colonial-era Korea (1910–1945) was perhaps felt greatest after the country’s liberation from Japanese rule. It was from this time that the Korean people faced the daunting task of separating those among their fellow compatriots worthy of patriotic honors from those guilty of traitorous crimes. Decisions regarding the latter group rested on criteria being established that determined the acts of collaboration that were serious enough to render punishment for betrayal of the Korean people. Similarly, liberation also required Koreans to rewrite their national narrative to incorporate the patriotic heroes of the past four decades of Japanese suzerainty: which acts of heroism merited their gaining immortality? While all periods of foreign occupation develop both supporters and detractors, it could be argued that assimilation policy produced deeper divisions among the people it subjugated as it preached an intention to develop a more intimate relationship between colonized and colonizer. Indeed, it challenged these people to abandon their “inferior” heritage for a more “advanced” one. Introduced as a gradual process, the Japanese accelerated their efforts to assimilate Koreans as Japan expanded its military adventures across the Chinese mainland and throughout much of the Pacific Ocean region. Japan’s assimilation policy aimed to culturally absorb the Korean people into the Japanese race, at least this was the impression left by the colonizers’ rhetoric. If successful, it would mean the Korean people absorbed as Japanese, the borders of Japan redrawn to incorporate the Korean peninsula as one or a group of prefectures. Korea and Koreans, in other words, would cease to exist. In practice, however, the initial decades of colonial administration demonstrated a greater tendency to discriminate and separate than to accept and unify. The war years displayed signs of willingness to correct this contradiction between rhetoric and practice, leading some to conclude that Japan was ready to implement its assimilation goals (Fujitani 2011). However, the war’s abrupt conclusion prevents us from advancing this conclusion. Would the Japanese have continued the wartime advances that the Japanese allowed the Koreans had Japan retained the Korean peninsula after the war, or were they simply temporary (and progressively desperate) measures rendered necessary under total war conditions? Japanese might conclude its failure to assimilate the Korean people to be a result of the relatively short duration of Japan’s colonial rule: even under normal circumstances they saw this as a 50- to 100-year process. However, the available evidence also suggests that, like other similar 111

Mark E. Caprio

assimilation examples, the administration’s intention was not to assimilate Koreans as internal Japanese subjects (kokumin) but as peripheral imperial subjects (shinmin). They would be granted privileges as valued members of the empire but not at a level enjoyed by their Japanese counterparts.

Goals of assimilation The Japanese establishment of assimilation as their colonial policy can be traced to even before the Meiji government appeared in 1868, to the late eighteenth century when the Tokugawa regime experimented with the policy in Ezo (present-day Hokkaido) to integrate the indigenous tribes on the island that was being explored by Russian adventurers. The Japanese rejuvenated this policy over the Meiji period (1868–1912) as Japan’s empire officially incorporated Ezo and later expanded to annex the Ryukyu Islands (present-day Okinawa) and Taiwan. Thus, by the time Korea entered the empire in 1910, the Japanese had accumulated a rather lengthy resume of applying assimilation to peoples it occupied. Still, Japanese writing at the time of Korea’s annexation felt compelled to justify Japan’s choice of administration. This was probably a reaction to the vicious attack that assimilation faced from the late nineteenth century, particularly by Social Darwinists and Scientific Colonial thinkers who argued it an illusion to expect that peoples of different breeds and culture could appreciate, much less absorb, advanced political and cultural institutions that assimilation policy introduced to them. Japanese countered by explaining that the racial and cultural similarities that they had long enjoyed with the Korean people would ensure them success where the European had failed. Japanese should have little problem assimilating Koreans. The Japanese casually drew from these European examples. Writers listed examples of assimilation, occasionally as positive or negative models. They did not analyze the specific differences between approaches or consider why some European colonial powers enjoyed greater success than others. The English, for example, offered a political variety of assimilation that contrasted with that of the French and German culture-centered assimilation policy.1 Yet the Japanese listed these examples as if they were all applying a set policy in their colonies. While both forms experienced rebellions among the subjugated peoples, English efforts succeeded in strengthening internal security: the union arrangement England forged with these states prevented them from forming alliances with its enemies—first the French and later the Germans. This was not always the case with the French, whose relationship with the Algerian people was not nearly as cordial as that which the English held with the Welsh or Scots.2 Japanese rhetoric that preached the Korean future as Japanese suggested an intimate internal level of assimilation that the colonized were ill-prepared to honor, one that saw the Korean peninsula eventually becoming integral Japanese territory by a process frequently witnessed in nation-building efforts. Eugene Weber brilliantly traces one such occurrence of this intense level of assimilation in his history of nineteenth-century French efforts to amalgamate the “savages” of France’s southern provinces, peoples who the northern French claimed to be ignorant of their culture and language (Weber 1976). This effort was in part influenced by similar unification efforts taking place at France’s eastern border in the Prussian-led movement to unite territories that constitute the modern German state. Indeed, similar processes of nation building also were taking place at this time in Italy, post-Civil War United States, and Meiji, Japan. Though this process shared resemblance to that of colonial assimilation, it differed in intensity. The peoples involved all residing within long-established borders of the newly formed state, they already imagined to be of the same people even though an intense assimilation process was necessary 112

The politics of assimilation

to integrate them culturally, politically, and economically. Thus rhetorically it made little sense to describe this process as assimilation. Rather, assimilation as a policy made more rhetorical sense when used to describe a peripheral people’s incorporation into the more advanced colonizer population, primarily because to the colonizer this hierarchical relationship clearly justified their imposing their culture on the colonized. The assimilation approach introduced by the Japanese in Korea resembled that seen in other peripheral colonial situations—those just off the traditional borders of the colonial homeland including Meiji-era additions of territories that surrounded the main Japanese islands. The Japanese in Korea advertised a gradual advancement of the policy that educated a minority of Koreans in the new, segregated school system the government-general created and elicited the assistance of a minority of the traditional Korean elite to assist the colonizers administer the territory. The differences in the school systems underline the inferior social position that the Korean was expected to fill. Compared to that arranged for the expatriate Japanese, Korean elementary education was shorter in duration, accommodated more students per class, and was funded less generously. The high concentration on Japanese language study stole valuable time from more important subjects that Koreans needed to compete with their Japanese counterparts. We can also assume that the inferiority of this education, along with the stigma of having attended a Korean school, dogged Korean youth as they sought employment or attempted to advance their education. Similar situations were also found among Ainu, Ryukyuan, Taiwanese, as well as Alsace and Algerian children residing in similar colonial situations at the time. The most interesting debates among the Japanese regarding assimilation policy occurred soon after annexation, just before the government-general finalized its Education Act in 1911. Those contributing their thoughts on Korean education focused on curriculum particulars such as the language and emphasis of instruction but also touched on the overall purpose of the education: the product that the system intended to nurture. Many of the participants in this discussion, who included politicians as well as academics, warned against the government-general offering Korean students an inferior education. They questioned the bias that the Korean was inherently inferior, arguing that, just as the Japanese at the time of the Meiji Restoration had been behind, so too was the Korean of today. They too could catch up if given the chance. Still others criticized assimilation as a policy that simply attempted to clone the Korean as Japanese. One official believed that the Korean people would be unable to advance unless the Japanese dramatically adjusted their prejudices that viewed the Japanese-Korean relationship in terms of superiority-inferiority. Embedded in these discussions was the idea that Japanese were not appropriate assimilators and thus should consider a change in policy (Caprio 2009: 92–96). The Japanese were forced to reform their general approach to governing Korea after the 1919 March First Independence Movement. On this occasion, Koreans, joining other colonized peoples empowered by statements by United States president Woodrow Wilson and Soviet leader Vladimir Lenin that condemned colonial occupations, took to the streets to demand an end to imperial rule. The protests, in which hundreds of thousands of Koreans in every province participated, were brutally suppressed by the police using heavy-handed methods that were widely condemned. These reforms generally offered the Korean people more cultural space, though the Japanese maintained, at least in their rhetoric, that their long-term goal remained assimilation. The reforms, pushed by Prime Minister Hara Takashi and Governor General Saitŏ Makoto, provided Koreans with the right to publish indigenous newspapers and assemble freely. They encouraged the Japanese to endeavor to learn more about Korean culture and even to study the Korean language. It has been argued that the purpose of this switch from the brutal “military rule” (budan seiji) to “cultural rule” (bunka seiji) served to co-opt the often illegal anti-Japanese 113

Mark E. Caprio

activities by Korean intellectuals by providing for them legitimate opportunity (Robinson 1988: 4). The government-general argued these reforms as harboring the purpose of allowing Japanese to more accurately read Korean sentiments as measures to prevent future March First demonstrations. Vice-Governor General Mizuno Rentarō used the value of indigenous newspapers to express this value as follows: They offered the administration “access to Korean thought as Koreans expressed their feelings in their newspapers.” Likening the newspaper to a chimney that spews smoke (Korean sentiment), Mizuno stated his belief that the reason why the March First Movement blew out of proportion was because the Japanese lacked the means of reading Korean intentions. Building a chimney (newspaper) to let the smoke escape from the kitchen allowed the Japanese access to Korean sentiment and intentions (Mizuno 1999: 52). Did this advancement of Korean language-based media detract from Japan’s assimilation policy? Michael Robinson’s research suggests it provided an avenue for advancing Korean identity that strengthened the people’s ties to Korean culture (Robinson 1988, 1998). This conclusion was also one reached by two late-1920s reports drafted by the government-general (Caprio 2009: 255–86). The 1920 reforms also contained a provision for increasing the number of schools to allow more Korean children opportunity for education. However, a more important advancement was the integration of schools for Japanese expatriate children in 1920. Prior to this time, Korean children who wished to pursue advanced study were required to travel to Japan, where they first had to pass a two-year preparation course to allow them to “catch up” to the Japanese who had spent two additional years in elementary school. The reform granted admittance to the more advanced school system, provided the student had a sufficient capacity in the Japanese language. Statistics suggest that the Korean population in these schools remained consistent at ten percent up through the last few years of colonial rule, when the Japanese ceased to offer separate figures for Koreans and Japanese. Despite the integration of schools, the two populations often remained segregated outside of the classroom. According to one student at Suwŏn College of Agriculture, Japanese and Koreans lived in separate wings of the dorm; they formed separate versions of the same club; and they even had the university library carry separate volumes of the same book (Kang 2001: 54). On the other hand, there are elderly Japanese who still maintain contacts with Korean classmates from this time. The March First Movement also had adverse influences on the views that Japanese residents held toward the Korean people. At the time of annexation, few outwardly expressed negative views toward annexation and their government’s decision to adopt an assimilation policy. Ukita Kazutami, editor of the popular magazine Taiyō, perhaps expressed a majority view in declaring, “The Japanese should have relatively few problems in assimilating Koreans” peacefully, as in the case of the English relationship with the Scots, and avoid the violent conditions that the English have experienced with the Irish (Ukita 1910). Yet the demonstrations of March 1919 left a deep and negative impression on the Japanese, some changing their views on assimilation as they observed Koreans marching down the streets of Seoul demanding Korean independence. The journalist and long-time resident of Korea, Hosoi Hajime, contributed the changes he experienced in an eight-part article that he contributed to the journal Nihon oyobi Nihonjin (Japan and the Japanese). He wrote: “[At this moment] I completely forgot the joy I experienced ten years previous when the lives of our 20 million Korean brothers and sisters were refocused as our compatriot siblings.” The “naïve” Japanese, he continued, had only themselves to blame for this disturbance as they neglected their “elder brother” responsibilities: “We treat [Koreans] as things at the bottom. . . . We show no signs of love, chivalry, but only menace.” The Japanese harbor a “stepchild mentality” toward a Korean people they vowed to advance by colonization (Hosoi 1919). 114

The politics of assimilation

Hosoi presents a rare case of a Japanese expression of opposition to Japan’s assimilation policy, although the immediate post-March First Movement period produced more open dissent than at other times. It is thus difficult to ascertain the extent to which Japanese truly supported this policy. Jun Uchida’s work on the Japanese settler community suggests it to have been rather extensive (Uchida 2011: 132–36). Most telling were the situations that challenged Japanese to practice what they preached, such as a petition presented by the Chōsen sansei shingikai kōsein (The Korean Political Participation Deliberation Committee) that appeared in 1929 calling for Korean suffrage. At the time the Japanese government granted a limited number of Japan-based Korean residents suffrage privileges, calls came for these rights to be extended to the peninsula. The National Diet rejected one such petition on the grounds that Koreans were inappropriate for this right. They would sway the results and cause troublesome results to emerge. This response also noted that if Japanese could only offer Koreans partial rights, it was better to not grant them any rights at all (Caprio 2009: 138). The relatively small number of Japanese-Korean marriages presents another measure for ascertaining the extent to which assimilation found acceptance among Japanese. Part of the reason behind this result may have been legal issues. Japanese women marrying Korean men would, as was customary by law, enter their husband’s family register and thus lose their status as Japanese. For that reason, many married couples did not officially register their marriages as was required. A second reason was social pressure: the Japanese community frowned upon mixed marriages. Recollections left by Japanese women reveal their being ostracized by their family and friends after marrying a Korean or being criticized for even considering such a move (Takasaki 2002: 178). Finally we see hesitation on the part of the Japanese for accepting Korean participation in the military. This reluctance persisted even after the war turned from Japan’s favor. Lack of trust in the Koreans eventually delayed the Japanese from including the Koreans in the universal conscription system until the final year of the war (Palmer 2013: 98). The inferior education system established primarily for Korean children, although some Japanese children also attended these schools, contributed to their maintaining a lower social status. However, the Japanese’ generally negative attitude toward Koreans also contributed to this result. Even Koreans who had enjoyed academic success evidently had trouble making it in their own society. Professors of Keijō (Seoul) University noted as such in a roundtable discussion on Korean students: few employers would accept Korean job applications, and most people (Japanese and Korean) preferred Japanese to Korean doctors (“‘Jinkenka no Chōsen wo Kataru’ zadankai” 1939). Other Koreans reported their Japanese classmates securing employment at higher levels that paid higher salaries and gaining faster promotion upon entering the government offices (Im 2011: 211–13). The pay discrepancies persisted despite the 1920 reforms requiring both Koreans and Japanese to be paid equally for their services. This reform, however, targeted base pay, while neglecting “hardship” stipends established to encourage Japanese to work on the peninsula. The wartime situation changed Korean status as young Japanese men were called from the peninsula to serve on the battlefield. Following the July 1937 Incident at the Marco Polo Bridge, the government-general explored different ways in which the Japanese could develop the proper attitude required of all Koreans under the wartime circumstances. The location of the peninsula, situated between the Japanese homeland and the Chinese war front made Korean cooperation particularly critical. From this time, the government-general initiated a Naisen ittai (Japan-Korea, one body) campaign to strengthen the relationship and to demonstrate to Manchurians the advantages that Koreans had gained by choosing cooperation with Japan. Toward this end, it compiled a 100-plus-page proposal and gathered a number of Japanese and Koreans to discuss how 115

Mark E. Caprio

to render practical this rather vague construct. Japanese participants tended to emphasize the status quo as well as the positive effect that the proposal would have on the Korean people. We find one notable exception in comments offered by Tagawa Jōichirō, who suggested the need to integrate the two family registration systems and ending Korean language publications. We shall see below how the Korean comments targeted more practical modifications to help achieve this goal (Caprio 2009: 162–63) It was under these wartime circumstances that the Japanese instituted many of the policies that continue to haunt Japan-Korea relations to this day. In considering these practices against Japan’s assimilation ambition, we find a mixed degree of consistency between policy and practice. Key to this evaluation is to determine the extent to which the Korean participation the government-general demanded was consistent with that expected of Japanese subjects. Korean participation in the Japanese military, which began in 1938 with the formation of a volunteer corps and continued in 1944 with forced conscription, helped advance Korean assimilation as it advanced the colonized in an institution that Japanese men were expected to participate. Whether the recruits were afforded treatment equal to that afforded the Japanese recruit at a similar rank is an important question requiring further investigation. Forced labor issues also require similar consideration. Did the recruitment and job allocation of Koreans resemble a similar practice directed toward Japanese subjects, or did the practice place the colonized in jobs deemed too dirty or dangerous for Japanese labor? The latter appears to be closer to the truth, particularly with those women forced into comfort women duty. Accurate numbers of the number of comfort women by nationality are apparently not available. However, although Japanese women did serve in this capacity, the majority of women were from among the colonized (Hicks 1994: 17–18). My purpose here is not to render moral judgment over any wartime institution but to measure the Japanese inclusion of Koreans against that of Japanese to ascertain the extent to which the policy was consistent with Japan’s assimilation goals as stated in its rhetoric. Inclusion of Koreans only advanced assimilation if it brought the colonized people closer toward an inclusion similar to that expected of the colonizers. In one case—conscription—it did, while in another—forced labor—it apparently did not. Additionally, other means of Korean participation were employed by the Japanese to argue assimilation’s success. Among the most notorious was the Name Order of 1940 in which Koreans were pressured into adopting Japanese names. Other measures were taken requiring Koreans to visit Shinto shrines, properly commemorate Japanese holidays by attending ceremonies, and to display the Japanese flag outside their homes. The government-general offices maintained meticulous records on Korean participation. However, the question remains as to whether these apparent displays of Japanese affinity translated in the Korean people advancing toward integration as Japanese. That the Japanese often tied participation to external reward (while punishing noncompliers) weakens confidence in the conclusions drawn by the colonizers. Specifically, often the administration used the Shinto shrine as a venue and name changing as a criteria for distributing wartime ration tickets. The government-general officially advised Korean name changes from 1939, and an estimated 80 percent of Koreans complied with this directive with the idea that they could more easily pass for Japanese if their names were Japanized. Indeed, Koreans had on occasion adopted Japanese names for this very reason, to counter discrimination. Ken Kawashima discusses this as a ploy adopted by Japan-based Koreans to fool landlords who refused to rent to non-Japanese (Kawashima 2009: 106). Did this measure succeed in its purpose: allowing Koreans to better integrate as Japanese? Perhaps it did at the informal level. But when Koreans were required to submit their family register, such as for school registration or job employment, they revealed their ethnic origins as the document registered when the applicant had adopted 116

The politics of assimilation

a Japanese name. Indeed, one such Korean found the word “Chōsenjin” (Korean) stamped across her Japanese name on a document she required to secure employment as a teacher. Also, as Koreans began settling into Japanese communities, the police assumed the responsibility of distinguishing between the two peoples. For this purpose they devised a list of characteristics unique to Koreans that included their peculiar pronunciation of certain Japanese sounds, the way they washed their face, the way that men looked at women, and their walking style (Kang 2003: 63–64). The apparent contradictions we find between Japanese words and actions regarding Korean assimilation can be best explained in a number of ways. First, Japan followed a rather common pattern, one observable in similar situations such as French Algeria and German Alsace and Lorraine. Like the Japanese, these colonizers never matched their idealist rhetoric with appropriate action, even toward the colonized who accepted their administration and fought in their wars. From this we can perhaps conclude cultural assimilation to have been a rather difficult goal to realize to the extent the colonizers maintained an attitude of superiority over the people to be assimilated. This was certainly the case shared by Japanese in Korea. These examples also share the consistency of the expatriate who has relocated to the colony holding the strongest feelings against assimilation lest the uplifting of the colonized compromise the relatively superior position they had gained upon entering this foreign society. Indeed, in general the lifestyles of Japanese residing in the urban environments suggest a conscious effort to avoid relationships with Koreans on a basis of equality. They could employ them as household help or factory hands but not socialize with them as fellow subjects of the empire. Thus from the Japanese standpoint, we can perhaps conclude that while the Japanese preached an internal assimilation that suggested eventual inclusion of the Korean as Japanese subjects, their policies over the duration of this period sought to maintain the people at the lower peripheral level. It teased the people with assimilation rhetoric while extending to them inferior examples of institutions provided for internal Japanese subjects that integrated the majority of Koreans at a level that would all but guarantee the preservation of differences that separated the two peoples.

Korean responses to Japanese assimilation Japanese rhetoric of assimilation elicited strong polemic responses from the Koreans, primarily as it promised to, depending on one’s perspective, either take from or give to the colonized a people’s identity. The discrepancy between rhetoric and practice, however, could not have pleased anyone. Those opposed to the policy were thus given justifiable reason to exploit Japan’s promises of assimilation to strengthen Korean national sentiment. To the contrary, the policy’s supporters could criticize Japan’s apparent unwillingness to fulfill these promises. Indigenous newspapers provided the former with their most important medium for voicing their objections, at least until they were ordered to close under wartime reforms. Supporters enjoyed uninterrupted access to Japanese publications to put forth their views and were often strongly encouraged (or coerced) by the Japanese authorities to do so. Cultural nationalists took advantage of the 1920 reforms to voice their general opposition to Japanese rule. The Tong’a ilbo (East Asian Daily), one of the newspapers allowed publication rights from this time, took the lead in criticizing Japanese assimilation ambitions. It used its editorial section to directly attack the Japanese culture: Japanese footwear (geta) and traditional dress (kimono) were impractical. It attacked the schools that the Japanese established to develop Koreans as Japanese: the system accommodated but a fraction of children interested in attending school, and it forced them to study in a foreign language. The newspaper soon learned that any attack 117

Mark E. Caprio

on the apex of Japanese culture and politics—the imperial household—would be severely punished. In September 1920 its publication rights were suspended for over a half-year when it argued the three imperial treasures (the jewel, mirror, and sword) to be objects of superstition. Individual writers, a number who had apparently integrated to varying degrees into Japanese society, also voiced criticism of Japan’s Korean policies. One Yi Yŏng-sun offered his remarks to the Japanese magazine Jiyŭ (Freedom) in May 1937, just months before Japan’s war in China escalated. Yi focused his commentary, titled “Japanese-Korean Unity” (Naisen yŭwa), on areas where the Japanese failed to live up to their assimilation promises. If, he argued, the Japanese were serious about creating this unity, “why were Koreans not offered military-duty rights? Is it because Koreans do not have patriotism? Why can’t the Koreans participate in elections? Is it because they are uneducated?” He continued by highlighting the contemptuous attitude he had experienced in his interactions with Japanese acquaintances. He personally had invited Japanese to his house and lent them money, only to see them leave without even saying goodbye and without repaying their loan. Yi believed this attitude to be typical of a people in similar shoes, likening it to that which separated blacks from whites in the United States. Perhaps American blacks could understand the euphoria experienced by Koreans upon hearing of Son Ki-jŏng’s victory in the marathon at the 1936 Olympics held in Berlin—for they too no doubt had felt a similar joy in seeing Joe Louis score knockout victories over white opponents. Yi’s attitude thus placed assimilation’s failure on Japanese shoulders. Rather than Koreans rejecting their assimilation advances, it was the Japanese who rejected their successes (Yi 1937: 90–92). Other Koreans were more proactive in their support of Japan’s assimilation policies, particularly during the heat of Japan’s wars from the 1930s. As emphasized in the 1938 Naisen ittai strengthening report, Korean support was vital to Japan’s success in its continental plans. Perhaps due to the expanded opportunities that the wartime situation produced, an increasing number of Koreans agreed to cooperate with the Japanese at this time. Some of these Koreans were rather prominent, including the educator Yun Ch’i-ho, independence leader Ch’oe Rin, female educator leader Kim Hwal-lan (Helen Kim), and Korean historian Ch’oe Nam-sŏn. These Koreans appearing in newspapers where they offered advice on how best to support Japan’s cause surely carried tremendous influence among their readers given their name value. Japanese also used these Koreans to assist in the recruitment of Koreans for the volunteer military, to solicit monetary donations to the military, and to join Japanese at rallies held to commemorate war victories. Cooperative Koreans, many of whom sat on advisory committees for the Japanese, were given the chance to voice their views on a number of occasions. One venue was the committee meetings held in conjunction with the Naisen ittai strengthening proposal mentioned above. Though a minority among the participants, transcripts demonstrate their active participation in these gatherings. There suggestions appear to have been more practical than those expressed by the Japanese. Koreans advised an increase in the number of Shinto shrines to allow Koreans more convenient access to them, a leveling of the tax system to permit Koreans to contribute their fair share to the colony’s revenues, and increased integration of Koreans and Japanese in the residential areas. Yi Sung-u, however, introduced a more fundamental problem: the Japanese failure to recognize the Korean as a potential national subject (kokumin) of the empire. To many Japanese, he explained, Koreans remained hopelessly backward, a people stranded in an ancient time due to inferior government management of the colony (Caprio 2009: 189–93). A minority of Koreans offered extreme views of support for the Japanese that left little doubt over their belief that the superiority of the Japanese way left little if any room for Korean identity. One such view was presented by Hyŏn Yŏng-sŏp3 in his The Path that the Koreans Must Take 118

The politics of assimilation

(Chōsenjin no susumu beki michi). Describing himself as “one Japanese national” (Nihon kokumin no hitori), Hyŏn emphasized the optimism that the Naisen ittai movement had injected in the Korean people. Much work remained, however, before Koreans completely understood their imperial responsibilities. Tracing Korea’s transition from the “hell . . . [of] colonial Han Chinese” rule prior to 1910, he saw Japan’s annexation as opening the door for Korean rejuvenation, for the emergence of a shin Chōsen (new Korea) that would replace the people’s previous han Shinajin (half-Chinese) existence. The Korean people, however, to date had failed to take advantage of the opportunities that annexation presented them. They continued to maintain their traditional culture while resisting the “majestic existence” (genzen to sonzai) of Japanese culture. Koreans must endeavor to “become Japanese” by “widely accepting the Japanese culture.” This required their accepting the fact that Korea would never again retain its status as an independent country. If Koreans wished to enjoy the benefits of this people—compulsory education, military service, and freedom of residence—they would have to demonstrate their commitment to adopting the Japanese spirit. Contrary to the views held by Yi Yŏngsun, Hyŏn Yŏng-sŏp saw the ball as resting in the Korean court. The keys to their destiny lay in their accepting their inescapable fate as Japanese. How successful were the Japanese? As mentioned above, officials were able to point to increasing numbers of Koreans participating in ways that suggested their acceptance of Japanese assimilation policy. As the number of Korean children attending elementary school increased, officials estimated that the number of Koreans competent in the Japanese language increased (1933, 760,000; 1937, 1.2 million) (Caprio 2009: 145). The Japanese could also point to the increasing numbers of Korean men volunteering for enlistment in the imperial military (2,946 [406], 1938; 303,294 [6,300], 1943) (Kang 1997: 370), despite low acceptance rates, as further evidence of their success. These rather impressive numbers, however, required scrutiny rather than blind acceptance. Can we accept as fact, as the Japanese did, that Koreans simply finishing elementary school produced Japanese fluency? To what extent was the Korean’s decision to “volunteer” for military service his own volition? Indeed, other criteria such as name changes, marriages, and shrine visitations require similar consideration before conclusions can be drawn. The question of colonial-era collaboration remains unresolved to this day as contemporary Koreans compile lists of those deemed guilty of traitorous crimes more than a half-century in the past. The question also remains why heroes of the March First Independence Movement— Ch’oe Rim and Ch’oe Nam-sŏn helped organize the movement—would turn to supporting the Japanese a little over a decade later. One possibility is that they had no choice should they choose to remain in Korea: only those who left the country or chose prison life enjoyed the luxury of non-cooperation. More recent research has suggested that collaborator efforts were influenced by pan-Asian ideas that the Japanese had been advanced since the beginning of the century. Koreans considered collaborators supported a regional Asian identity over a more traditional Korean nationalist one (Shin 2006; Moon 2013). The geopolitical situation that the Korean peninsula confronted suggested the advantage of alliance with Korea’s Northeast Asian neighbors, China and Japan, on a basis of equality to provide the country with its most promising chance at regaining a sense of sovereignty. The hopes of such Koreans may have been raised following Japan’s incorporation of Manchuria, which was followed by calls for Koreans to be used as an example of the benefits that the Manchurian people might enjoy should they cooperate. The flying geese image, with Japan leading the twin rows of Asian states advancing in V-formation, suggests otherwise. Like assimilation policy rhetoric, the direction of the coexistence and co-prosperity promised by the Japanese would be directed from the colonial homeland at the apex, with little input from the rear. 119

Mark E. Caprio

Conclusions Kim Chanjung, in his review of the 100 years of “zainichi” under Japanese imperial rule, advances the idea that Koreans have of recent made significant advances in assimilating into Japanese society. Over the past few decades, more Koreans have admitted that their more significant friendships are with Japanese, rather than fellow Japan-based Koreans. Significant increases are also seen in these Koreans marrying with Japanese and their choosing to naturalize as Japanese. Likewise, Japanese as well are more accepting of this minority than in the past, as witnessed by restrictions in education and employment being relaxed. This is not to say that Japanese have completely overcome their negative impressions of Koreans and that Koreans live free of prejudice. However, after seven or eight decades following annexation, attitudes are progressing in a positive direction toward successful annexation (Kim 2010, 222–52). These advances have encouraged one zainichi scholar to foresee in the near future the end of this minority population (Chung 2001). Although the circumstances are very different, Kim’s analysis of contemporary successes enjoyed by Koreans lends clues as to why the colonial and immediate postcolonial eras did not succeed in advancing Korean assimilation. First is the time factor. As noted above, the threeplus decades of direct Japanese rule was simply too short a time span to except extraordinary results. Korean populations that Kim discusses have passed through three to four generations of Japanese influence. The 60 to 80 years corresponds roughly to the estimates made by Japanese who envisioned assimilation as a 50- to 100-year process. A second factor is the change in attitudes that Japanese and Koreans hold toward each other. Unlike the years of colonial occupation, arguments can no longer be sustained that claim absolute superiority of the Japanese over the Korean, as they were in earlier decades. The present assimilation process assumes a level of equality not possible up through 1945, particularly against the backdrop of economic advancement by both Japan and South Korea. The arrogance of superiority that most Japanese assumed during the decades of colonial rule was perhaps the most important roadblock to realizing successful integration with the Korean people. Attitudes of Koreans in Japan have also been influenced by the above factors. They entered a new relationship with the Japanese following Japan’s defeat in World War II by assuming a touch of arrogance themselves. Japan, as defeated nation, no longer commanding the position as global power, Koreans, as a liberated people sought to demonstrate their independence while residing in Japan, once even demanding a slice of Japanese territory to be administered by Koreans. This attitude was short-lived, and Allied occupation forces demonstrated little sympathy for Korean anti-Japanese sentiment. This helped rejuvenate antagonistic attitudes between the two peoples and a quick return of the colonial-era discriminatory practices. More recent generations find themselves a minority in Japanese society but hold increasingly less affinity with their ethnic homeland. With discrimination practices easing, and a Japanese population increasingly more acceptable of them as Korean, these generations of Japan-based Koreans have less incentive than their parents and grandparents to remain at the peripheries of Japanese society. Problems remain. Times of political discord between peninsula and archipelago over both present and past issues remind us that Japanese-Korean assimilation remains a work in progress. The progress that the two peoples have realized, however, is that which could only come through a rethinking of the attitudes that Japanese held toward Koreans over the decades of colonial rule. Indeed, the illusion of superiority that Japan’s contemporaries brought to their colonial administration, rather than the inability of the colonized to understand or accept this policy, prevented the successful assimilation of any foreign people. Prime Minister Hara Takashi, a devout assimilationist, perhaps said it best in his criticism of Japanese administration policy in Korea following the March First demonstrations: you cannot expect a people to change while administering them as fools (Hara 1998). This advice continues to hold to the present. 120

The politics of assimilation

A note on historiography Research entertaining questions posed in this chapter has increased remarkably as of recent. General studies that consider the sincerity behind Japan’s intentions in promoting assimilation rhetoric have examined this issue from a policy level (Caprio 2009) as well as at a cultural level (Henry 2014). These studies have also considered the Korean reaction to this policy, although a dedicated examination of the effect that Japan’s assimilation policy had in encouraging collaboration remains to be written. Translations of Korean literature written during this period by Japanese (Kajiyama 1995) and Koreans (Yuasa 2005; Yom 2005) have added a direct interpretation of participant reaction to our understanding of Japan’s assimilation policy and Korea’s reaction. Studies that isolate various aspects of the colonial relationship that indirectly touch on various assimilation questions have divided on their evaluation of Japanese views toward Korea and Korean culture. On the one hand, two studies on Japanese exploitation of Korean labor (Kawashima 2009; Driscoll 2010) adopt a critical neo-Marxian that emphasize Japanese atrocities. On the other hand, two studies that consider cultural exchanges under this colonial relationship (Atkins 2010; Yecies and Shim 2011) view the relationship on more benevolent terms. Two further studies that focus on Korean acceptance into the Japanese military (Fujitani 2011; Palmer 2013) suggest that the wartime period (1931–1945) encouraged more positive views among Japanese of this colonized people. Finally, pioneer research on the attitudes of Japanese settlers in Korea (Uchida 2011) has demonstrated the negative reaction to assimilation that expatriates adopted, one similar to resistance that Europeans in French Algeria displayed to this policy. The chapter that remains to be written is the residue that Japanese policy in general, and assimilation policy in particular, left on the Korean peninsula following liberation in 1945.

Glossary Kokumin Shinmin Budan seiji Bunka seiji Chōsenjin Geta Kimono Naisen yūwa Naisen ittai Han Shinajin Shin Chōsen genzen to sonzai zainichi

国民 臣民 武断政治 文化政治 朝鮮人 下駄 着物 内鮮融和 内鮮一体 半シナ人 新朝鮮 儼然の存在 在日

national subjects imperial subjects military rule cultural rule Korean Japanese traditional shoes Japanese traditional dress Japanese-Korean unity Japan-Korea one body half-Chinese new Korea majestic existence Japan-based [Korean]

Notes 1

2

This is not to say that the English believed the Celtic culture that dominated these states was superior to, or even on a par with, their culture. The Welsh remember one such attack on their language as the “Brad y Llyfrau Gleision” (Treachery of the Blue Books) (Roberts 1998). The violent confrontations that the English faced with the Irish more closely resembles this FrenchAlgerian relationship, a result of centuries of mistreatment of the Catholics in general and Irish in particular. 121

Mark E. Caprio

3

Hyŏn Yŏngsŏp’s cousin, Peter Hyŏn, authored Mansei, the classic novel about a boy growing up under Japanese colonial rule. Peter introduces his cousin as the black sheep of the family when he married a Japanese woman. The family remained under lock and key in an isolated house in the back when guests came to the house (Hyŏn 1986: 62).

References Atkins, E. (2010) Primitive Selves: Koreana in the Japanese colonial gaze, 1910–1945. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Betts, R. F. (1961) Assimilation and Association in French Colonial Theory, 1890–1914. New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Caprio, M. E. (2007) ‘The 1920 Colonial Reforms and the “June 10 (1926) Movement”: a Korean search for ethnic space’, in L. H. Yung, Y. C. Ha, and C. Sorensen (eds.) Colonial Rule and Social Change. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Caprio, M. E. (2009) Japanese Assimilation Policies in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Ching, L. T. S. (2001) Becoming “Japanese”: colonial Taiwan and the politics of identity formation. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Chung, D. K. (2001) Zainichi Kankokujin no shūen [The end of the Japan-Based Korean]. Tokyo: Bunshun shinsho. De Ceuster, K. (2001) ‘The Nation Exorcised: the historiography of collaboration in South Korea’, Korea Studies 25, no. 2: 207–42. Driscoll, M. (2010) Absolute Erotic, Absolute Grotesque: the living, dead, and undead in Japan’s imperialism, 1895–1945, Durham, NC, Duke University Press. Dudden, A. (2005) Japan’s Colonization of Korea: discourse and power. Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Duus, P. (1995) The Abacus and the Sword: the Japanese penetration of Korea, 1895–1910. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Eckert, C. J. (1991) Offspring of Empire: the Koch’ang Kims and the colonial origins of Korean Capitalism, 1876–1945. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Fanon, F. (1967) Black Skin, White Masks, trans. C. L. Markmann. New York, NY: Grove Weidenfield. Fujitani, T. (2011) Race for Empire: Koreans as Japanese and Japanese as Americans during World War II. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Hara, T. (1998) “Chōsen toōchi shaken” [A Personal Opinion on Korean Administration], in Saitō Makoto kankei monjo, reel 104 (1919), Japanese Diet Library. Hechter, M. (1975) Internal Colonialism: the Celtic fringe in British national development, 1536–1966. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Henry, T. A. (2014) Assimilating Seoul: Japanese rule and the politics of public space in colonial Korea, 1910–1945. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Hicks, G. (1994) The Comfort Women: Japan’s brutal regime of enforced prostitution in the Second World War. New York, NY: W.W. Norton. Horio, M. (1910) “Shinkokumin no kyōiku” [Education for the new people of the nation]. Kyōiku jiron (September 5, 1910): 13–15. Hosoi, H. (1919) “Chōsen no tōchi” (Korean Administration). Nihon oyobi Nihonjin (October 1, 1919): 30–38. Howell, D. L. (1994) ‘Ainu Ethnicity and the Boundaries of the Early Modern Japanese State’. Past and Present 142: 75–87. Hyūn, Y. (1940) Chōsenjin no susumu beki michi [The path that the Korean must trod]. Keijō: Ryokuki renmei. Hyun, P. (1986) Man Sei! the making of a Korean American. Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Im, M. (2011) Nihon teikoku to daiminzoku ni tsukaeta kanryō no kaisō [Reflections of a Bureaucrat who worked for Imperial Japan and the Republic of Korea]. Tokyo: Soshisha. “‘Jinkenka no Chōsen wo Kataru” zadankai’ [A Roundtable Discussion on “Korea Under the Incident”] (1937). Bungei shunjū 64: 246–64. Kajiyama, T. (1995) The Clan Records: five stories of Korea. Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Kang, D. (1997) Chōsenjin Gakuto shutsujin [Korean student military service]. Tokyo: Iwanami shoten. 122

The politics of assimilation

Kang, D. (2003) Kantō dai shinsai: Gyakusatsu no kioku [The Great Kanto Earthquake: Memories of Genocide]. Tokyo: Seikyūbunkasha. Kang, H. (2001) Under the Black Umbrella: voices from colonial Korea. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Kawashima, K. C. (2009) The Proletarian Gamble: Korean workers in interwar Japan. Durham, NC, and London: Duke University Press. Kerr, G. H. (1958, revised edition 2000) Okinawa: The History of an Island People. Rutland, VT: Charles E. Tuttle Co. Kim, C. (2010) Kankoku heigo hyakunenn to “zainichi.” [The Hundred-Year Korean Annexation History of “Zainichi”] Tokyo: Shinchō sensho. Kim, R. E. (1998) Lost Names: scenes from a Korean boyhood. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Lamley, H. (1970–71) “Assimilation Efforts in Colonial Taiwan: the fate of the 1914 movement.” Monumenta Serica 29: 496–520. Marshall, B. K. (1994) Learning to be Modern: Japanese political discourse on education. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Moon, Y. (2013) Populist Collaborators: the Ilchinhoe and the Japanese colonization of Korea, 1896–1910. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Morris-Suzuki, T. (1998) Re-inventing Japan: time, space, and nation. New York, NY: M. E. Sharpe. Mizuno, R. (1999) Mizuno Rentarō kaisōroku, kankei bunsho [Memoirs and official papers of Mizuno Rentarō], ed. R. Nishio. Tokyo: Yamagawa shuppansha. Oguma, E. (2002) “Nihonjin” no kyōkai [The boundaries of the “Japanese”]. Tokyo: Shinyōsha. Palmer, B. (2013) Fighting for the Enemy: Koreans in Japan’s war, 1937–1945. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Podoler, G. (2011) Monuments, Memory, and Identity: constructing the colonial past in South Korea. Bern: Peter Lang. Roberts, G. T. (1998) The Language of the Blue Books: the “perfect instrument of empire.” Cardiff: University of Wales Press. Robinson, M. E. (1984) “Colonial Publication Policy and the Korean Nationalist Movement” in R. Myers and M. Peattie (eds.) The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895–1945. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Robinson, M. E. (1988) Cultural Nationalism in Colonial Korea, 1920–1925. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Robinson, M. E. (1998) “Broadcasting in Korea, 1924–1937: colonial modernity and cultural hegemony” in S. A. Minichiello (ed.), Japan’s Competing Modernities: issues in culture and democracy, 1900–1930. Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Ruedy, J. (1992) Modern Algeria: the origins and development of a nation. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University. Schmid, A. (2002) Korea Between Empires, 1895–1919. New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Shin, G. (2006) Ethnic Nationalism in Korea: genealogy, politics, and legacy. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Shin, G. and Robinson, M. E. (eds.) (1999) Colonial Modernity in Korea. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Siddle, R. (1996) Race, Resistance and the Ainu of Japan. New York, NY: Routledge. Takasaki, S. (2002) Shokuminchi Chōsen no Nihonjin [Japanese of colonial Korea]. Tokyo: Iwanami shinsho. Uchida, J. (2011) Brokers of Empire: Japanese settler colonialism in Korea, 1876–1945. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. Ukita, K. (1910) “Kankoku heighō no kôka ikan” [What are the effects of Korean annexation?] Taiyō (October 1, 1910): 2. Weber, E. (1976) Peasants into Frenchmen: the modernization of rural France, 1870–1914. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Weiner, M. (ed.) (1997) Japanese Minorities: the illusion of homogeneity. London: Routledge. Yecies, B and Shim, A. (2011) Korea’s Occupied Cinemas, 1893–1948. New York, NY: Routledge. Yi, Y. (1937) “Naisen yūwa wa doko e?” [Where Is Japanese-Korean unity], Jiyū (May 1937): 90–92. Yom, S. (2005) Three Generations, trans. Y. Yu. New York, NY: Archipelago Books. Yuasa, K. (2005) Kannani and Document of Flames: two Japanese colonial novels, trans. M. Driscoll. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

123

9 Colonial modernity E. Taylor Atkins

A new highway now runs beneath Mt. Samhak, And all become a playboy in the wind of automobiles. —‘Ch’unch’ŏn Arirang’ (Kim et al. 1948: 258; Kim 1988: 10) All usable trees were sold as telegraph poles, All pretty girls as entertainers. —‘Chŏngsŏn Arirang’ (Kim 1988: 10)

Old-fashioned people thought it was heresy to think things they had never thought, but it was actually the comprehension of new truths that the old-fashioned people had never known before. A son must always be better than his father. Otherwise there would be no such thing as progress. People who are behind the times, however, dislike it when newcomers know more than they do. Old-fashioned people are thus often responsible for the tragedy that results from the clash of modern and traditional thought. —The Heartless (Mujŏng) (Yi Kwangsu 1917: 252) The first half of the twentieth century was a bewildering, disorienting time for Koreans. The people of Chosŏn had once prided themselves on excelling the Chinese in the implementation of an ideal Neo-Confucian order. But in the modern hierarchy of nations, Korea rated poorly, and in the age of ‘high imperialism’ even such presumed moral perfection seemed of little use to the cause of national survival. The privileged few who constituted the ‘enlightenment’ (kaehwa) generation understood well what it meant to lose national sovereignty to Japan, accepted Social Darwinism as the merciless, ‘inviolate’ principle of international relations (Schmid 2002: 37–38), had some notion of how industrial capitalism would affect material and social life, and grasped the monumentality of the Yi court’s failure to prevail against both domestic dissent and predatory foreign powers—but they were no less distressed or flummoxed than the less worldly majority. Both the kaehwa intellectuals and their country cousins expressed their perplexity eloquently in their respective literatures. 124

Colonial modernity

The oral literature of commoners depicted a world turned upside down, if not gone completely mad. Those who are fluent of speech are summoned to court, Those who can work get to the public cemetery, Girls who can produce get to be whores, And those who have muscles are called to slave labor. —’Ponjo Arirang’, Kyŏnggi (Sŏng and Chang 1949: 3–4; Cho 1974: 49) Poisonous grass grows before a virtuous woman’s gate. A peony flower blooms before a whore’s gate. —’Arirang t’aryŏng’, Muju, North Chŏlla (Im 1971: 424; Kim 1988: 9) As soon as a new road emerged, I lost my love. Automobiles always remind me of my lost love . . . —’Chindo Arirang’ (Kim 1988: 6) These fragments of folk songs (minyo) from the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries depict the devastation of sacred landscapes, working bodies, and feminine virtue. They offer prescient critiques of the transformative effects of modern technologies and their attendant mindsets; even the wind generated by a passing automobile could change an observer into a dandy ‘playboy’. If a sense of loss necessarily accompanies modernity (Lears 1994: 4–5), their songs indicate that Korean commoners grasped and felt it deeply. For the newly emergent Korean literati—writing in vernacular han’gŭl rather than in classical Chinese (hanmun)—modernity was not so unwelcome; indeed, they were among its strongest advocates and beneficiaries. But they were well attuned to its challenges and costs. They spun dramatic fictional narratives around the very real, unprecedented ethical dilemmas and uncomfortable social situations that the modern age and colonial subjugation presented to Koreans. Yi Kwang-su’s 1917 novel, The Heartless (Mujŏng), opens with a series of awkward encounters and observations that illustrate the sense of anxiety and disorientation. Protagonist Yi Hyŏngsik, an English teacher, has a ‘code-switching’ conversation with a friend, peppered with Japanese and English words and phrases. He feels ‘powerless’ because ‘he did not have the power of money, in a world dominated by money. . . . Most of the worries of modern day people . . . had to do with not having money. It was no surprise that people valued money in a world in which one could purchase someone’s body and even their soul if one had the money . . .’. When calling on a pupil (a young aristocratic woman preparing to study abroad in the United States) for the first time, he observes, ‘In former times, a guest would never have been allowed past the inner door; just being allowed to enter the inner door was a big change from the old ways’ (Yi 1917: 79–80, 131). Throughout The Heartless, characters are torn between fidelity to the ‘old’ ideals of filial sons and ‘virtuous women’, and the ‘new’ order of ‘free love’ (chayu yŏnae, consensual marriage without parental involvement), female self-determination, and individual ambition. For some of the older characters, modernity is little more than an affectation (255–259, 301); Hyŏngsik and his fiancée Sŏnhyŏng are thus ‘children . . . who had lost the traditions of thought transmitted for generations from their ancestors, and were wandering about, not knowing what would be appropriate for them to choose from the confusion of Western 125

E. Taylor Atkins

thought. They had been thrown into a world without standards for life, or ideals of a nation, and without someone to guide them in the world’ (324). ‘Colonial modernity’—which Park Chan Seung (2008) has elegantly defined as ‘a particular articulation of the universal notion of “modernity” in the colonial context’ (105)—has come into fairly widespread use as an analytical term among scholars of modern imperialism. They have taken advantage of its concision to depict historically specific conditions in disparate regions of the late nineteenth- and early twentieth-century imperial world, such as Egypt, Indochine, the Dutch East Indies, China, sub-Saharan Africa, Siam, British India, and Manchukuo.1 Although its application in Anglophone and Japanese scholarship on Korea has been prodigious, ‘colonial modernity’ (sikminji kŭndaesŏng) has proven far more controversial a concept among Korean scholars, some of whom regard it as another way of unduly crediting the Japanese colonial occupation for the ‘genesis of modernization in Korea’ (Cho 2012: 655; Lee, et al. 2013: 10–16). The word ‘modernity’ designates a host of interrelated historical conditions and ways of looking at time, space, and human relations: reliance on rationalism, science, and technology to bring order and efficiency to human affairs; a notion of progressive time, in which the present moment is perceived as a profound departure from—and improvement on—traditions and precedents; a sense that humanity has detached from and transcended the limits of the natural environment; industrial capitalism and specialisation of labor; urbanism and cosmopolitanism; mass media and consumer capitalism; individualism and subjectivism; increased mobility of people, commodities, capital, and information; and the rise of the nation-state as the standard unit of socio-political organisation, governed by a centralised, bureaucratic state authority whose ever-widening purview includes public health and sanitation, education, national defence, legislation and law enforcement, protection of property rights, regulation of commerce, economic planning, and credentialing. Historians generally agree on a concept of modernity that encompasses capitalist democratic, socialist, and fascist political arrangements. They also acknowledge that the sense of triumphal achievement that celebrates progress is tempered by nostalgic yearning for preindustrial modes of production and ways of life. ‘It was . . . modern urban life’, Henk Schulte Nordholt (2000) observes, ‘that invented the traditional village and produced the memory of the good old rural way of life that belonged to the past’ (102). Whereas ‘colonial modernity’ suggests these historically specific conditions and their attendant lifestyles and mindsets, ‘colonial modernisation’ (sikminji kŭndaehwa) refers to the ‘compressed’ process of social, economic, political, and cultural engineering directed toward attaining those conditions within a colony (Lee 2011: 90). The latter phrase is the subject of much dispute among historians of East Asia, because for some it implies that Japanese imperial rule was beneficial to former colonies such as Taiwan and Korea and territories under military occupation like Manchukuo and the collaborationist Reorganized National Government of China. The colonial modernisation argument presumes to take a neutral, clear-eyed stance, unmoved by indignant nationalist emotion; it employs quantitative analysis to balance the humiliating loss of sovereignty and imperial abuses against the valuable infrastructural, commercial, sanitary, educational, and managerial investment and expertise Japanese brought to territories under their administration. Unsurprisingly, right-wing historical revisionists in Japan, such as the Society for the Dissemination of Historical Fact (SDHF), favour this argument. However, there are Korean scholars (Kim Unt’ae and An Pyŏngjik, among them) who do not dismiss it lightly in toto (Park 2010: 74–77), though they still take umbrage at the triumphal self-congratulation the theory encourages in some of their Japanese counterparts. Proponents of colonial modernisation theory contend that, whether or not Japanesesponsored efforts to modernise colonial and client territories were intended to benefit local populations, they clearly did, by creating transportation and communication infrastructure, 126

Colonial modernity

educational and entrepreneurial opportunities, agricultural innovation, mass media, and new technologies, all of which enabled the colonies to integrate within the modern world. These laid the groundwork, some say, for economic development and prosperity in the late twentieth century, particularly in Taiwan and the Republic of Korea (Cumings 1984; McNamara 1990; Eckert 1996). Advocates of this historical narrative regard it as far more constructive than counterfactual speculation about whether or not Koreans, Taiwanese, and Chinese could have accomplished modernisation without Japanese interference. Korean nationalist historiography (minjok sahak) emerged in part to counter the ‘distorted’ claims of beneficent Japanese rule and the incapacity of Koreans to self-modernise, creating an alternative balance sheet in which the only real ‘benefit’ of colonial subjugation was a deepened nationalist identity and spirit of resistance among the Korean people. If modernisation directed by the colonial regime is the process, then presumably colonial modernity would be its result or product. But that schema itself distorts somewhat the political agenda that is implicit in colonial modernity scholarship, but which its critics tend to understate or overlook. For many scholars, colonial modernity intimates greater contribution and agency from colonised populations: rather than being a unilateral imposition by omnipotent imperial regimes, it is a modernity conceived, refashioned, and lived by people under colonial domination, sometimes in conformity with and sometimes in opposition to the colonial state’s visions. Colonial modernity, then, consists of ‘neither disfigured nor unsuccessful replications of any prior stable object, artifact, or concept from another place or time’ (Barlow 1993: vi-vii); rather, it is an ‘alternative’ modernity selectively marshaled to promote the welfare and improve the lives of locals, rather than to further the financial or strategic interests of imperial overlords. If it encourages anti-colonial nationalism, it also fosters other forms of identification that compromise the homogeneity nationalism idealises. Traditionally disadvantaged constituencies are able to use new mass media to participate in the public sphere and assert their interests (Limapichart 2009). Colonial modernity is negotiated—as are most things in colonial settings—between colonisers and colonised, and amongst the colonised, exhibiting attributes peculiar to each locale. Therefore it is more akin to Antonio Gramsci’s theory of ‘hegemony’ than to a model in which violent coercion is the only means of maintaining control: conflict between the political/economic elite and ‘subaltern’ classes is managed through a complex negotiation in which relatively minor concessions are made to subaltern demands and sensibilities in exchange for a more general acquiescence to authority. Hegemony is a process by which the status quo is ‘normalised’ or ‘naturalised’, so that no other political or economic order seems remotely viable, even to those who remain disadvantaged by it. Colonial modernity’s foremost theorist, Tani E. Barlow, begins from the Marxist premise that ‘colonialism and modernity are indivisible features of the history of industrial capitalism’ (1997: 1; 2012: 623–624). First and foremost, the concept draws attention to the fact that modernity was imagined, constructed, and experienced within a world of empires. Colonial modernity is thus a critique of ‘modernisation theory’, the belief (shared by Marxists and nonMarxists alike) that civilisations and nation-states progress at different paces through universal stages of economic, political, and social development toward national self-determination and emancipation of the individual citizen/subject. Modernisation theory has a ‘tendency naively to disavow power differentials’ that colour experiences of modernity (1997: 6) and to portray ‘Euro-American influence in Asia [as] historically moderate, benign, humanistic, benevolent and helpful’ (2012: 623). On the contrary, exploitation of colonial resources made European, North American, and Japanese modernisation possible; that is, modernity was not a previously accomplished state of being that facilitated or enabled imperial conquest and colonisation of ‘less developed’ areas of Africa, indigenous America and Australasia, the Middle East, and Asia. 127

E. Taylor Atkins

Secondly, in contrast to prior depictions of the imperial world as a field of interaction between discrete regions at different stages of historical development (modern or primitive, civilised or savage, East or West), colonial modernity encourages transnational thinking and highlights ‘historical synchronicity’ (Barlow 1993: vi; 2012: 629–630); scholars thus frame metropolitan and colonised regions as a ‘unitary field of analysis’ (Schmid 2000: 953). A corollary of this is acknowledgment of the mutual impact of colony and métropole on one another: although their relations are explicitly unequal, cultural influence and institutional development flow in both directions, rather than simply from the stronger party to the weaker. The possession of colonies profoundly transformed and defined imperial nation-states in myriad ways, from their economic, military, and political structures to their imaginative lives (Thomas 1994; Cooper and Stoler 1997: 1; Shin and Robinson 1999: 5; Schmid 2000: 958). Without colonialism, there would likely have been no Tintin or Tarzan, no Bōken Dankichi or Babar the Elephant. If ‘colonial modernity enables us to understand synchrony between Empire and colony’, it likewise promotes a sense of ‘diachrony between colonial and postcolonial periods’ (Cho 2012: 59). Piercing the historiographical boundary between ‘colonial’ and ‘postcolonial’ eras to examine continuities, persistent inequities, and legacies, colonial modernity ‘helps us focus squarely on the unevenly borne heritage of imperialist occupation and colonial domination’ (Barlow 1993: v; Dirlik 2007: 110). What some call the ‘postcolonial condition’—or, more colloquially, the ‘colonial hangover’—thus falls within the concept’s scope. One of the more controversial aspects of a colonial modernity approach is its attention to ‘everyday life’ and material culture under conditions of colonial subjugation. The prevailing structural critiques of empire, as well as the shopworn dichotomies of coloniser/colonised and collaboration/resistance, obscure ‘some of the density, richness, and complexity of the original ecosystem’ in which people lived their lives (Shin and Robinson 1999: 4–5). While some scholars welcome this attention to the ‘subconscious, intangible dimensions of colonial life’ (particularly because it often allows for greater scrutiny of gender and culture), critics claim it is ‘at the expense of structural historical narratives’ and the realities of colonial coercion and violence (Do 2004: 202–203; Park 2010: 70, 83; Cho 2012: 652, 656; Lee et al. 2013: 14, 16–30; Kim 1996: 21, 43). Moreover, with its emphasis on urbanisation, consumerism, mass media, industrial capitalism, and leisure in the ‘nascent “bourgeois public sphere”‘ (Arunima 2003: 74), colonial modernity scholarship naturally gravitates toward urban spaces and their residents, neglecting the rural majority. For scholars whose primary intents are to expose Japanese imperialism as ethnocide, to document and memorialize the collective suffering of the Korean masses (minjung), and to trace the occupation’s impact on post-liberation Korean political and social development, studies of the ‘subjectivity’ of ‘new women’ (sinyŏsŏng) in literature, or the impact of chemical seasoning (MSG) on modern palates (Jun 2005), for instance, seem inconsequential by comparison. In the charged political climate of contemporary East Asia, in which the Korean and Chinese states remain unconvinced by Japanese government expressions of contrition for colonial and wartime atrocities, some Korean scholars think studies of the ‘micro-dimension’ experiences and thoughts of colonised Koreans detract from more substantial inquiries into colonial-era economic exploitation, political repression, and human rights abuses, the effects of which linger to this day. Frequently criticised by their North American, European, and Japanese counterparts for their nationalist outrage, Korean historians retort that it is much easier to take a ‘post-nationalist’ posture when one does not actually reside in a former colony (Cho 2012: 658). Despite such criticisms, colonial modernity remains an attractive shorthand descriptor to many scholars who focus on the period of Japanese occupation (1910–45). Scholars do appear to agree that a fundamental social transformation transpired in colonial Korea (Shin and Robinson 1999: 128

Colonial modernity

11; Lee et al. 2013: 14). The conditions of colonial modernity noticeably flattened the explicitly hierarchal and patriarchal social order of Chosŏn; novel forms of prestige and identity, and new routes to individual advancement, gradually supplanted heredity and Chinese learning in determining social status. In The Heartless, Hyŏngsik recognises an idle old man in P’yŏngyang who had once been a provincial official, living in ‘desolate loneliness’: Before 1894, when the old man was in his prime, he must have thought the rivers and mountains of P’yŏngyang, and all the people in the world existed for him. With the cannonfire from Ŭlmil Pavilion in 1894, though . . . [h]e became a person abandoned by the world, and young people whom he did not know and had never seen before, took over. He knew nothing about railroads, telegraphs, telephones, submarines or torpedo boats. . . . Since he would never realize what this new world was like, it was as though he were living outside of the world, even though he dwelled within it (215). It would be overreaching to say that yangban lineage and Sinocentric erudition lost all social importance, but they became far less valuable than a modern education and material wealth in determining one’s social position. Never before had it been so socially advantageous to be conversant in international affairs, foreign languages, the natural and social sciences, mathematics, engineering, and business (ironically, precisely the types of knowledge promoted by eighteenthcentury ‘practical learning’ [sirhak] scholars and routinely dismissed by Neo-Confucian elitists). There are fundamental disagreements among scholars about how ‘emancipating’ this social revolution actually was: some argue that old modes of caste-based oppression were simply replaced with new class- and ethnic-based ones (Park 2010: 88–96). Furthermore, since this transformation occurred within a space under colonial dominion, there were implicit, unadvertised limits to what an ambitious modern Korean could achieve. Even the privileged son of a former noble house, with a degree from a Japanese university, could not realistically aspire to a civil service or private sector career in which he would have supervisory authority over Japanese. A welleducated daughter could hope for little more than becoming the ‘wise mother and good wife’ (hyŏnmo yangch’ŏ, an inversion of the analogous Japanese term ryōsai kenbō) in a scientifically managed middle-class household, a civic ideal encouraged not only by ingrained Confucian tradition but also by both Christian missionaries and Japanese civil law (Choi 2009: 9). Although inequality is certainly a persistent characteristic of capitalist modernity, in a colonial modern society the opportunities for advancement and emancipation that modernity promised were systematically circumscribed and unevenly distributed according to the logic of colonial relations: regardless of education, occupation, income, or lineage, Koreans would always be disadvantaged compared to Japanese settlers. Furthermore, in a colonial modern society, Koreans routinely faced hard choices, mundane and monumental, about when and how to comply or resist, or when and how to choose national over personal and familial interests. Therein lie the conceptual essence and key insights of ‘colonial modernity’. Shin and Robinson (1999) have noted that modernity in colonial Korea was refracted through the lens of imperial Japan (10). Uniquely among modern imperial powers, from the mid-1850s Japan had itself been subjected to substantial imperial pressure by the United States, Russia, and European countries, via the mechanism of the unequal commercial treaty. The leaders of the Meiji state that came to power in 1868 observed imperialist predations on the Asian continent and fixated on the Korean peninsula as the key to their own homeland security. With increasing rural unrest, continuing subservience to China’s floundering Qing dynasty, and a vacillating royal court beset with factional intrigue (which, ironically, Japanese meddling only exacerbated), 129

E. Taylor Atkins

Chosŏn appeared destined to become someone’s colony, Meiji leaders surmised. Nearly three decades before the actual annexation in 1910, Japanese officials worked with Chosŏn dissidents to resuscitate the Korean monarchy by undermining it, hoping to install a pro-Japanese, Meijilike modernisation regime to govern the peninsula. Modernity in Korea essentially began with this generation of reformers, Kim Okkyun (1851–94), Sŏ Chae-p’il (1864–1951), Hong Yŏng-sik (1855–84), and others who formed the Enlightenment Party (Kaehwadang). It was no accident that they used the Sino-Korean equivalent of the Japanese term kaika (literally, ‘opening’) from the Meiji-era slogan ‘civilisation and enlightenment’ (bunmei kaika); Kim Ok-kyun was a disciple of Japan’s foremost public intellectual, Fukuzawa Yukichi (1835–1901), the man who almost singlehandedly defined and embodied that slogan for most Japanese. Another Fukuzawa protégé, Yu Kil-chun (1856–1914) wrote, ‘In an enlightened society, myriad affairs and things are thoroughly studied and managed, and innovation is attempted at all times. There is heroic spirit for greater achievement, and indolence is totally absent’ (quoted in Ch’oe et al. 2000: 250). The kaehwa faction’s reliance on Japan may seem naïve or foolish in hindsight, but in the 1880s its members believed that Korean independence and modernisation would best be served by accepting Japanese assistance and cutting ties with the Qing. Their fourteen-point agenda included the abolition of formal status distinctions and yangban aristocratic privilege, as the Meiji government had legally erased samurai status through a series of edicts (haitōrei) in the 1870s; cessation of tributary relations with Qing and assertion of Chosŏn’s political independence; land tax reform; and reorganisation of government administration, military, and police forces (Ch’oe et al. 2000: 255–256). The failure of the Enlightenment faction’s December 1884 coup attempt, in historian Yŏng-ho Ch’oe’s (1982) estimation, was ‘an unmitigated disaster for modern Korea’: the ‘attempted coup totally besmirched the image of the enlightenment movement’, and ‘deprived Korea of a viable model for reform and modernisation as the image of Meiji Japan became tarnished in the eyes of many Koreans . . .’ (108, 120). The fact that several of the Kapsin Coup’s masterminds sought refuge in Japan inspired little confidence; those who would later aspire to bring kaehwa to Korea would be dogged by suspicions that they were too pro-Japanese (ch’in’il) to be trusted. Japanese sponsorship of another attempt at a Meiji-style ‘revolution from above’, the so-called Kabo Reforms (1894–95), virtually guaranteed their failure (Ch’oe et al. 2000: 272–276). Over the next decade, a number of private organisations arose in the rechristened Taehan Empire to push for modernisation through fundamental political, educational, and social reforms: some, like the Independence Club (1896–98), Korean Association for Self-Strengthening (1906–07), and New People’s Association (1906–11), rejected Japanese assistance; others, particularly the Advance in Unity Society (1904–10), worked closely with Japanese officials, believing that political reform and capitalist modernity were unattainable without their guidance (Moon 2013). Ironically, Japanese interventions to assist sovereign Korea’s self-strengthening efforts were so ham-fisted and selfserving as to delegitimize and undermine the whole enterprise. Japan was not the only source of modern ideas, institutions, technologies, and practices in Korea. Indeed, the abortive Kabo ‘revolution from above’ was precipitated in part by a ‘revolution from below’: the wholly indigenous, millenarian Tonghak movement that preached social equality. Although its original name meant ‘Eastern Learning’, as opposed to ‘Western Learning’ (sŏhak), this syncretic faith’s doctrine of ‘humans are Heaven’ (innaech’ŏn) and admonishment to ‘treat each person as you treat Heaven’ (sainyŏch’ŏn) clearly resonated with modern notions of the rights and dignity of the individual. Benjamin Weems (1964) has argued that ‘the implications of the doctrine were as staggering to the controlling groups in nineteenthcentury Korea as had been the impact of the theories of John Locke or Rousseau upon the 130

Colonial modernity

controlling elements in eighteenth-century France and England’ (13). In their 1894 uprising, Tonghak rebels pointedly destroyed slave registries to throw the centuries-old slave system into chaos and compel emancipation. Renamed Ch’ŏndogyo (Teaching of the Heavenly Way) in late 1905, the faith became ‘modern’ in its organisational structure, propagation tactics, and implicit nationalism. Moreover, as publisher of colonial Korea’s longest-lived women’s magazine, New Woman (Sinyŏsŏng), Ch’ŏndogyo sponsored a major forum for public discussion of women’s issues (Lee 2011: 96). Protestant missionaries from North America and Europe had a deeper impact on notions and experiences of modernity in Korea than they did in either China or Japan. Besides adding thousands of Koreans to the Christian flock, missionaries opened schools, churches, clinics, and hospitals that were preferable to what the regime offered. At the beginning of the colonial period, at least, Korean girls were much better served by schools opened by missionary women, where they could continue their studies much further than in the Japanese schools; they could even aspire to enter Ewha University (founded by American missionary Mary F. Scranton in 1886) or attend college overseas. Many Koreans came to regard the missionary presence as a haven or refuge from their colonial reality. They took spiritual comfort in the Christian message and detected a distinct advantage in learning modern ways and ideas directly from ‘the source’, rather than secondhand from their imperial overlords. They also realised that the whole notion of ‘liberty’ was conspicuously absent from Japanese versions of modernity. ‘When a people saturated in the Bible comes into touch with tyranny’, Canadian missionary F. A. McKenzie (1920) wrote in the wake of the March First uprising, ‘either one of two things happens, the people are exterminated or tyranny ceases’ (7). By all accounts, Korea was one of the most intensively developed colonies in the world. The peninsula’s strategic value to Japan’s continuing encroachments into Northeast Asia in the 1920s and 1930s was multifaceted: it was a site for factories, mills, capital investment, and military garrisons, a source of labor, food, and raw materials, and, eventually, even of soldiers. The consequent transformation was most visible in cities, especially those in which substantial numbers of Japanese settled. Kyŏngsŏng (Keijō/Seoul), Taegu, P’yŏngyang, Mokp’o, and other Korean cities, much like urban spaces elsewhere in the colonial world, were marked by the incongruities of the modern and the antiquated, the Western/Japanese and the indigenous, the planned and the unintended, a ‘mystifying mix of surface and depth, past and present, confinement and mobility’ (Johnson 2003: 317, 330; Myers 2003; Kim 2008; Arnold 2012: 122; Min 2013: 500–501). Case studies of the capital (Henry 2014), the old inland city of Taegu (Kim 2008) and the new port town of Mokp’o (Park 2008) depict ‘dual cities’ in which Japanese and Korean residential areas were clearly demarcated and improvements in infrastructure, sanitation, and other city services were unevenly distributed. In each case, Korean residents protested against construction or demolition projects that were of no benefit to them, but city councils dominated by the minority Japanese habitually overrode such objections. Only adult males who paid five wŏn in city taxes per year were eligible to vote, which virtually guaranteed disproportionate Japanese representation in city government. According to Park (2008), in 1935 eligible voters in Mokp’o consisted of 883 Japanese and 551 Koreans, nearly all of them industrialists, merchants, or landowners (118–122). With so little Korean representation in city government—and what there was comprising a compradore class deeply enmeshed in the Japanese-dominated economy— there was little to prevent the transformation of Korean cityscapes to serve Japanese interests. In 1906 Japanese residents successfully conspired with a ch’in’il local governor to demolish the fortress wall of Taegu (Kim 2008: 82–83). In Kyŏngsŏng, the Government-General of Chōsen (GGC) tore down most of the Kyŏngbok palace complex and obnoxiously placed its neoclassical 131

E. Taylor Atkins

granite headquarters in front of what was left, obscuring capital residents’ view of their monarchy’s former grandeur. Despite all the official propaganda about the ‘progress in Chōsen’ under Japanese rule, Japanese settlers could be incredibly stingy about sharing its benefits with their Korean neighbors. Japanese residents of Taegu vetoed the city administration’s 1924 plan to upgrade the streets and sewage system in Korean residential areas (Kim 2008: 88–89). Appeals for piped water, paved roads, street lighting, and garbage collection in Mokp’o’s Korean North Village, to match those of the Japanese South Village, also went unheeded (Park 2008: 123–130). The number of rural migrants into both cities continued unabated, however, further straining city services and exacerbating the difference in living conditions between Koreans and Japanese. Rural Korea lagged far behind but was by no means unaffected by modernity. Throughout the peninsula, railroads, telecommunications, irrigation and construction projects wrecked geomantic havoc, ignoring Korean sensibilities about sacred spaces, auspicious landmarks, ancestral burial sites, and fertile soils. ‘Our good farm lands are taken away for railroads’, farmers wailed, ‘Our beautiful maidens become prostitutes’ (quoted in Nahm 1975: 201). To be sure, railroads served Japanese military and economic interests first and foremost, but, as was the case in British India and other colonies, also facilitated the integration of distant regions into coherent national space. In 1899, Japanese completed an American-initiated rail line connecting Kyŏngsŏng to coastal Inch’ŏn; three years later, they secured from the Taehan court rights to build the Kyŏngbu line between Kyŏngsŏng and the southeastern port of Pusan. When hostilities with Russia began in 1904, the Imperial Japanese Army rushed to complete the project to facilitate the transport of troops to the front lines. In its urgency, the IJA sometimes seized agricultural land and commandeered local labor. Peasants occasionally sabotaged rail lines that passed though their lands, risking summary execution. Within a short timespan, by linking the Kyŏngbu and French-managed Kyŏngŭi (between the capital and Ŭiju) lines, Japanese had succeeded in connecting the southeastern tip of the peninsula to the northwestern border with China with 950 kilometres of rail line (Nakano 2007). A 1936 railway map shows a substantial rail network linking the capital to Mokp’o in the southwest, Kyŏngju in the southeast, Masan in the south, Najin in the extreme northeast, and Sinŭiju in the northwest (where passengers and cargo could connect to the Trans-Siberian Railroad). As was the case in Japan, the rural peasantry, nominally esteemed in Confucian cosmology, assumed greater prominence in the modern political imagination. Clark Sorensen (in Shin and Robinson 1999) has argued that colonial-era intellectuals identified agrarian cultivators (nongmin) as a Marxist ‘class’ (kyegŭp) in which the very core of Korean national identity (minjoksŏng) resided (288–290). It was in the colonial period, then, that the peasantry assumed political importance as the basis for ‘the people’ (minjung), the ‘agents of social transformation and progress’ (Wells 1995: 25; Shin 1999: 792). But, again, as in Japan, rural folk themselves saw little actual benefit from such exalted discursive status. By the early 1930s, tenant farmers comprised over half of rural Korean households, paying both fixed rents and variable proportions of the harvest to absentee landlords, whose primary concern was to maximize their own wealth through commercial agriculture. Dong-No Kim (in Lee et al. 2013) contends that cultivators bore much of the costs for new seeds, machinery, fertilizers, and irrigation systems for the regime’s Program to Increase Rice Production—for Japanese consumption (162–163). Peasants were endlessly inventive in their methods of passive resistance, sometimes replacing rice with wheat or barley, or refusing to harvest crops altogether (Shin 1996: 137–138). Unable to thrive in the market economy, or even to consume the crops they tended, millions of rural Koreans flocked to cities to engage in wage labor, which promised but was no guarantee of an improved quality of life. 132

Colonial modernity

However, Gi-Wook Shin and Do-Hyun Han (in Shin and Robinson 1999) contend the GGC was not completely oblivious or indifferent to nongmin, who were, after all, providing an increasing portion of the rice consumed in the métropole, nor were farmers themselves passive in asserting their interests. Agrarian activists mounted a fully realized critique of colonial modernity, advocating agrarian self-sufficiency rather than integration into the capitalist market, moral reconstruction, and collectivism (Shin 1999: 794–800). The state-sponsored Rural Revitalization Program (1932–40) worked with villages to address agrarian immiseration and resolve disputes between tenants and landlords. Shin and Han point to ‘modest achievements in improving rural economic welfare’ resulting from ‘noncoercive measures to cultivate consent’ in the countryside. In a rare show of well-informed cultural sensitivity, the regime invoked the moral principles of the traditional hyangyak (village compact) to persuade farmers to invest in the campaign. By encouraging village collectives to take charge of their own affairs, and ‘selectively attempt[ing] to incorporate peasants’ demands into state policy’, the GGC sought to cultivate economic and ‘spiritual’ rejuvenation. ‘In addition to Meiji reform ideology in the form of agrarianism and a social policy approach’, Shin and Han conclude, ‘internal developments within Korea crucially shaped the course of the rural campaign’ (88–90, 94–95). The cultural history of colonial Korea has benefited immensely from the colonial modernity approach. Whereas earlier histories narrated the decline of traditional arts and leisure pursuits, or their purposeful erasure by Japanese assimilation policies, recent scholarship recounts the adaptation of traditional music, dance, theater, visual arts, literature, and amusements to modern tastes and mass-mediated modes of delivery. The everyday creative and consumptive activities of Koreans reveal multiple complexities of life under colonial rule that are far more compelling— sometimes even inspiring—than a simple account of cultural degradation and atrophy. The mixture of Euro-American, Japanese, and Korean elements made the cultural marketplace vibrant, distinctive, and emblematic of colonial modernity. As cinema (yŏnghwa), ‘new fiction’ (sin sosŏl), popular songs (kayo), and ‘new theater’ (singŭk) increasingly commanded the attention of audiences, the number of practitioners of traditional arts shrank noticeably during the colonial period; but it is also true that, as these traditions were (re)invented, canonised, and represented in new media, their prestige value and import as signifiers of Korean cultural distinctiveness grew. Musicologist Andrew Killick’s (2012) examination of ch’anggŭk opera is a terrific case study of performers adapting and transforming their art for the modern cultural marketplace while highlighting its ties to traditional aesthetics and Korean cultural identity. In the first decade of the twentieth century, some artists joined forces to create troupes and appropriated the singing techniques and canonical stories of p’ansori—originally performed by a lone itinerant bard (kwangdae) and a drummer (kosu) in outdoor public markets—for indoor, multi-actor theatrical stage productions. As in Morocco (Dieste 2012), China, and Japan, the spectacle and novelty were enhanced significantly by the onstage presence of women; some of the first Korean actresses were former kisaeng who had been dismissed from government employment by the Kabo Reforms. Although its twentieth-century origins and the influence of American stage plays, Chinese changxi (‘singing plays’), and Japanese shinpa (quasi-kabuki agitprop melodramas) make the ‘traditionality’ of ch’anggŭk debatable (52–61), Killick notes, it retains a ‘traditionesque’ aura: ‘Visually, ch’anggŭk is a parade of traditional Korean clothing, architecture, and landscape; aurally, it can include almost the whole spectrum of Korean musical styles. Thematically, it centers on traditional Korean stories with (at least ostensibly) traditional Korean Confucian morals’ (27). From 1903 to 1912, and again in the late 1930s, ch’anggŭk thrived as a popular form of vernacular entertainment in both urban theaters and provincial tent-shows. It proved popular and durable enough that the colonial regime thought it well suited to promote its intensified ‘national 133

E. Taylor Atkins

language’ policy and assimilation agenda in the late 1930s and 1940s and to foster Korean support for the war effort (Park 2003: 103). Nayoung Aimee Kwon (2014) characterizes a 1938 Japanese production of the venerable p’ansori/ch’anggŭk opera Ch’unhyang chŏn as an attempt to satiate parallel yet inconsonant nostalgic desires. For Koreans, Ch’unhyang was part of the nationalist agenda to resuscitate and promote ‘national tradition’ within the cultural realm, which ‘took on rising symbolic import as a metonym for the identity of the absent nation and its lack of political sovereignty’ (117). For Japanese, Ch’unhyang was ‘colonial kitsch’, an exotic curio of peninsular culture, one of many ‘mass-produced objects for indiscriminate imperial consumption’ (115, 121). The quintessential modern entertainment was, of course, the motion picture. The Japanese benshi, who provided narration, context, and commentary for silent film audiences, and whose celebrity often exceeded that of the actors onscreen, was transplanted to Korea as pyŏnsa. In most respects, the pyŏnsa’s responsibilities and skill set mirrored those of his Japanese counterpart (there are no records of female pyŏnsa, although there were female benshi): in addition to extemporaneous eloquence, charisma, and wit, he needed to be conversant enough in foreign (Euro-American and Japanese) cultures to offer contextual explanation during showings of imported films. Two named pyŏnsa mastered Japanese well enough to perform for Japanese audiences. Yet the pyŏnsa was not simply a Japanese transplant; he was an example of the refraction of imported culture that characterizes colonial modernity. Pyŏnsa had the power to shape audiences’ experiences and interpretations of the films they watched. Film scholar Kim Ryŏsil (2004) makes a persuasive case that the 1926 blockbuster Arirang was not a self-contained nationalist allegory, but became one whenever pyŏnsa Sŏng Tong-ho (1904-?) ‘read’ it to audiences (18, 20, 21–22). When narrating Ben Hur: A Tale of the Christ, Sŏ Sang-p’il (1901?) likened the slave revolt to the Korean independence struggle (Maliangkay 2005). If Japanese police were absent, then, pyŏnsa not only interpreted the wider world for their audiences but also kept the embers of nationalism aflame. Also emblematic of the complexities and paradoxes of Korean colonial modernity were the kisaeng. These courtesan-entertainers—analogous if not quite identical to Japanese geisha—are usually known as carriers of traditional Korean vocal and instrumental music, dance, calligraphy, and poetry, and to some degree that was their function in the colonial period. However, like their South Asian counterparts, the tawa’if (Jha 2009), they were also prominent in new electronic media as popular entertainers, performing newer Korean, Japanese, and even EuroAmerican material on theater stages, radio broadcasts, and 78 RPM records. To be sure, their greater visibility and audibility were not uncontroversial, and traditionalists and Japanese Koreaphiles were chagrined to see kisaeng expanding their repertoire. The stigma of a kisaeng’s presumed sexual availability titillated and scandalised audiences. No longer reserved for government officials, kisaeng were ‘accessible’ to a greater variety of men, anyone who could pay. The Heartless features several lengthy ruminations by protagonist Hyŏngsik, as he struggles to reconcile compassion for his childhood friend Yŏngch’ae and revulsion at the (unfounded) thought of her acquiescing to the sexual demands of possibly hundreds of ‘dissipated’ men after she became a kisaeng (Yi 1917: 111–114, 174–175). When an elite man rapes Yŏngch’ae, he feels no remorse, since ‘the virtue of chastity was for women of good family, not kisaeng . . . a special kind of creature that was beyond morality and ethics’ (165). The Japanese regime’s decision to license kisaeng as sex workers, legally indistinguishable from prostitutes with no artistic skills, had significantly diminished the kisaeng’s already wobbly social standing. Having been released from servitude to the Yi royal house and provincial governments, colonial-era kisaeng were trained at ‘licensing academies’ (kwŏnbŏn) (Hŏ 2008). Kwŏnbŏn were 134

Colonial modernity

mostly self-governing and enabled kisaeng of lower rank to breach the hierarchical structure of their profession. Several former government kisaeng (kwangi) used kwŏnbŏn to transmit traditional arts to a younger generation of Korean women. But kwŏnbŏn curricula also adapted to evolving popular tastes and marketplace realities, which meant that some kisaeng were also adept pop chanteuses (Kawamura 2001: 125–127, 147–148). Like contemporaneous Egyptian almas, they added contemporary pop songs to the traditional repertoire of art music that had long been their preserve (Lagrange 2009). Although Japanese media depicted them as icons of a timeless eroticism (Kawamura 2001; Atkins 2010: 175–184), there is substantial evidence that kisaeng took full advantage of burgeoning mass media and their position outside of patriarchal family structures to promote a modern consciousness and female autonomy; recent studies indeed maintain that kisaeng were among the vanguard of the Korean feminist movement (Min 2013: 511). Kisaeng exploited new massmedia technologies and entertainment venues to earn their livelihoods, preserve their independence, and participate fully in the public sphere. They took their arts out of bars and teahouses, playing and singing music on radio broadcasts and recordings and even performing dances in large theaters in Japan. In January 1927, seventeen kisaeng joined forces to launch a new magazine entitled Changhan (‘Long Suffering’) to share information and dispel negative stereotypes about themselves. ‘Henceforth, this magazine, covering the kisaeng community, is now finally raising its voice’, Pak Nok-chu declared in the first edition (whose cover image depicted a kisaeng in a birdcage). ‘This magazine is a mouthpiece through which we can publicize our lives, opinions, sorrows and joys unreservedly’ (quoted in Kim 2005). This feminist manifesto echoed similar statements made by Japan’s ‘new women’ in the journal Bluestocking (Seitō, 1911–16) and two Korean publications entitled New Woman (Sinyŏja, 1920, and Sinyŏsŏng, 1923–34), while still representing the viewpoints of a distinctive professional class. Kisaeng would be not only the topics of public discourse, but participants in it. The voices of kisaeng were thus distinctive, constitutive elements of Korean colonial modernity. Kisaeng participated in the explosive growth of the popular music industry in Northeast Asia in the 1910s and 1920s. Most Japanese recording companies opened facilities on the peninsula, recorded a variety of Korean singers and instrumentalists, and imported wholesale the various genres of popular music that were au courant in imperial Japan. Although relatively few Koreans could afford phonographs, and slightly more could purchase radios, new forms of popular music were prominent in urban soundscapes, blaring from cafes, department stores, radios, and theaters. Traditional Korean fare, including abridged p’ansori operas, vied with so-called trot (t’ŭrott’ŭ, from ‘foxtrot’, or ppongjjak), fashionable songs (yuhaeng ch’angga), jazz (chaejŭ), popular songs (taejung kayo), ‘new folk songs’ (sin minyo), and European classics for listeners’ attention. In fact, those who lament the ‘colonisation’ of musical culture frequently blame Japan for the hegemony of Western art music in modern Korea. Yet it is also true that regional indigenous styles became more widely known nationwide as a result of electronic media (Seo 2010: 184). In Ch’ae Man-sik’s (1903–50) novel Peace Under Heaven (T’aep’yŏng ch’ŏngha, 1938), radio enables the oily Master Yun Tu-sŏp to hear ‘southern songs’ (namdo minyo) of provincial Chŏlla while residing in Kyŏngsŏng (12–14). The consumers of modern entertainments, the living embodiments of la modernité coloniale, were young urbanites whose sensibilities favoured the new and the now, and whose fashions, outlooks, behaviors, and mating rituals constituted an entirely new set of ‘customs’ (p’ungsok), largely inspired by Western movies (Min 2013: 503). Like the indigenous middle classes in other colonial societies, ‘What they aimed at in the first place was not a nation, but a lifestyle. And access to such a lifestyle could be obtained by joining the framework of the colonial system and in doing so consolidating the colonial regime’ (Nordholt 2011: 438). The appearance of ‘new 135

E. Taylor Atkins

women’ and ‘modern girls’, in particular, generated a degree of moral panic and nationalist indignation, not unlike that which afflicted ‘jazz-age’ Japan. Less judgmental observers regarded the modern girl as ‘an embodiment of the transition from the old practices to the new ways, an ambivalent figure who could manifest different possibilities depending on whether she focuses on material consumption or moral vision and advanced knowledge’ (Choi 2013: 73). Yet the controversy these icons generated in the media—where they were vilified as decadent, bourgeois, ‘seductive’, and materialistic—was way out of all proportion to the actual number of middleclass urban women who could actually sustain ‘consumerism and new adventures in urban modern space’ (Choi 2013: 72–80). Critical public scrutiny of women’s deportment and conduct was a fundamental characteristic of colonial modernity. In the age of high imperialism, female autonomy was a key index for measuring a society’s progress from savagery to civilisation (Choi 2009: 5; Tran 2012: 411). Moreover, as was the case elsewhere in the world, conflicts between tradition and Western modernity were ‘enacted on women’s bodies and representational praxis’: women were expected to ‘balance desired modernity against undesirable Western values’ (Oza 2006: 94; Tran 2012: 412). That is, women’s levels of engagement in public life, their fashion choices and consumptive habits, their interactions with men and expectations of marriage, and their personal aspirations all indicated how advanced or behind Korea and other colonies were compared to their imperial masters, but also how far removed they had become from still-cherished ancestral beliefs and customs that were the very foundations of national identity and cultural integrity. High-profile ‘new women’ who put their Western education and expertise to work managing households and raising children were hailed for their contribution to the ‘revitalization of the nation’; those who expressed ‘intellectual, artistic, or sensual desires’, questioned the virtue of chastity, publicly divorced their husbands, spent money frivolously on cosmetics and imported luxury goods, or otherwise led ‘scandalous lives’ became ‘objects of caricature and derision’ (Yoo 2008: 58–59; Choi 2009: 21–23; Lee 2011: 98–100; Min 2013: 495, 507–508). This is not to say that men were exempt from scrutiny and controversy—in 1927, one writer defined a ‘modern boy’ as a man ‘whose facial complexion is more like a woman’s’ (quoted in Choi 2013: 76)—but Korean men donned Western apparel and cut their long hair decades before women followed suit, and with more official approval. Although hardly immune from criticism, men had greater latitude when ‘going modern’ than women did (Min 2013: 511–513). In public spaces, modernity was visually and aurally conspicuous: wires (electrical, telegraph, and telephone), railways and paved roads, newspapers and magazines, automobiles, brick and stone buildings, street lights and neon signs, train whistles, radios, machinery, and other noises all signified the progress required for civilisation. ‘The noises of the city were those of civilization. A nation prospered the louder those noises were’, Yi Kwang-su mused wryly in The Heartless. ‘The sounds of wagon wheels, and steam and electric-powered engines combined to give rise to civilization in all its brilliance. Modern civilization was a civilization of noise. There was not yet enough noise in Seoul’ (300). But the domestic sphere, the private space that a family inhabited, and the relationships within it could indicate modernity as well. Private life was subject to public scrutiny and discussion; nutrition, childrearing, budgeting, furnishing, hygiene, marital and parental relations were measured by the yardstick of progress. Nationalist intellectuals in Korea, as in Bengal, Egypt, and elsewhere in the colonial world, believed nation-building began at home: ‘the domestic [was] an inseparable part of the national’, and ‘proper management’ of the household according to best practices of ‘domestic science’ was thus an essential endeavour (Chakrabarty 1993: 5–7; Lagrange: 2009, 242–243; Yoo 2008: 85–94 ; Choi 2009: 10–11; Lee 2011). In an influential 1930 editorial, Kang Kyŏng-nae (1906–44) wrote, ‘child-rearing and food preparation are not 136

Colonial modernity

simply an important issue for the home but can also be socially pertinent. In this sense, then, the domestic and the social together make up one large cohesive body’ (quoted in Hanscom, et al., 2013: 136). Although care for elderly parents remained a social virtue, and multigenerational households an economic necessity, the focus of modern domesticity was the conjugal household—sans concubines—consisting of a wife and husband with ‘modern consciousness’, who raised children in a deliberate, earnest manner for future service to the nation (minjok). As prescribed in Korean and Japanese print media in the 1920s and 1930s, such modern households were marked by monogamous, companionate marriages between consenting adults, frugal budgeting, industriousness, nutritious homemade meals, social awareness, and diligent schooling. Wives were paradoxically admonished to be both spendthrifts and consumers of a dizzying array of new products to promote the health, wealth, and hygiene of their families. Though still outranking their spouses in the household hierarchy, husbands were to respect their wives’ intellects and opinions and to observe sexual discipline, eschewing secondary marriages and dalliances with kisaeng. As Ji-Eun Lee (2011) notes, however, a perusal of mass media from this era can be misleading: there was a basic incongruence between such ambitious discourse and the socioeconomic realities of most Korean families. In this respect, ‘new women’, ‘modern boys’, and ‘modern families’ reflected Korean colonial modernity more generally. ‘Japan ran a deeply penetrating and meticulously controlled colonial governing system’, Lee continues, ‘which rendered a colonial culture that appeared similar to that of the empire; the resemblance is striking when compared to British or French colonies. But inwardly, colonial space was enormously complex and uneven, with poignant differences between Japanese and Koreans, and between Korean people themselves’ (114–116). In a critique of colonial modernity historiography, political scientist Hong-Yung Lee claims that it ‘appears to make the same intellectual mistake attributed to the Korean nationalist discourse, namely extrapolating the implications of findings beyond what the findings warrant. . . . Being able to detect the subtleties, gray areas, and contradictions of the period, while not losing overall perspective of the basic nature of colonialism is what is required for good scholarship’ (26–27). Specifically, Hong takes exception to studies that claim the economic growth and prosperity in the Republic of Korea in the last quarter of the twentieth century was a beneficial outcome or legacy of the Japanese colonial occupation. Although I am unaware of any reputable scholar who would argue openly that Japanese colonial rule was good for Korea (Japanese right-wing revisionists hardly qualify as ‘reputable’), it is perhaps fair to say that in their zeal to correct the excesses of Korean nationalist historiography and be provocative, some historians who have embraced the colonial modernity framework have understated the ‘colonial’ aspects of their subject matter (Do 2004). Hong is surely right when he states, ‘The political cost of Korea’s colonial experience was too high compared with its speculative advantages’ (25). The most conspicuous evidence of this ‘political cost’ is the persistent ‘one nation, two states’ arrangement on the Korean peninsula, a direct consequence of the schism within the colonial-era nationalist movement between socialist revolutionaries and moderate ‘cultural nationalists’ (Robinson 1988). ‘In calling for reforms within the confines of colonization’, Ellie Choi (in Hanscom et al. 2013) writes, ‘moderates like Yi Kwang-su were criticized by more radical nationalists for ignoring their colonized status and seeking sanctuary in the realm of culture. For Korean bourgeois intellectuals, this retreat to culture (culturalism) was motivated by . . . the desire to avoid politics altogether, to work within the parameters of the colonial state, and to avoid interruption of their work by being arrested’ (2–3). Like a scar, the 38th parallel bears witness to this colonialera disagreement on the future of the Korean nation. 137

E. Taylor Atkins

To some degree the colonial modernity debate is a matter of emphasis: whereas some scholars focus on the empowerment, emancipation, and opportunities modernity offered to Koreans (glass half full), others stress the discrimination, injustice, and cruelty colonialism inflicted on them (glass half empty). As heated as the discussion about colonial modernity in Korea has been, if it results in fuller, more nuanced and sensitive histories of the period and its people, and in more dialogue and collaboration between Korean and non-Korean scholars, it will have been productive.

Note 1

Colonial modernity is a rare example of a theoretical stance that originated among historians of East Asia and was subsequently adopted by historians in other fields.

References Arnold, D. (2012) ‘The problem of traffic: the street-life of modernity in late-colonial India’, Modern Asian Studies 46(1): 119–141. Arunima, G. (2003) ‘Face value: Ravi Varma’s portraiture and the project of colonial modernity’, Indian Economic and Social History Review 40(1): 57–79. Atkins, E. (2010) Primitive Selves: Koreana in the Japanese Colonial Gaze, 1910–1945, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Barlow, T. (1993) ‘Editor’s introduction’, positions: East Asia cultures critique 1(1): v–vii. –––– . (1997) ‘Introduction: on “colonial modernity”‘, in T. Barlow (ed.), Formations of Colonial Modernity in East Asia, Durham, NC: Duke University Press: 1–20. –––– . (2012) ‘Debates over colonial modernity and another alternative’, Cultural Studies 26(5): 617–644. Ch’ae, M. (1938; 2003) Peace Under Heaven, Chun Kyung-Ja (trans.), Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe. Chakrabarty, D. (1993) ‘The difference-deferral of (a) colonial modernity: public debates on domesticity in British Bengal’, History Workshop 36: 1–34. Cho, D. (1974). ‘Oral literature and the growth of popular consciousness’, in S. Y. Chun (ed.) Folk Culture in Korea, Korean Culture Series 4, Seoul: International Cultural Foundation: 43–57. Cho, Y. (2012) ‘Colonial modernity matters? Debates on colonial past in South Korea’, Cultural Studies 26(5): 645–669. Ch’oe, Y. (1982) ‘The Kapsin coup of 1884: a reassessment’, Korean Studies 6: 105–124. Ch’oe, Y., Lee, P., and de Bary, W. (eds.) (2000) Sources of Korean Tradition, vol. 2, From the Sixteenth to the Twentieth Centuries, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Choi, H. (2009) ‘“Wise mother, good wife”: a transcultural discursive construct in modern Korea’, Journal of Korean Studies 14(1): 1–33. Choi, H. (comp., trans.) (2013) New Women in Colonial Korea: A Sourcebook, London: Routledge. Cooper, F., and Stoler, A. (eds.) (1997) Tensions of Empire: Colonial Cultures in a Bourgeois World, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Cumings, B. (1984) ‘The legacy of Japanese colonialism in Korea’, in R. Myers and M. Peattie (eds.), The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895–1945, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press: 478–496. Dieste, J. (2012) ‘Representing modernity: the nationalist theater in colonial northern Morocco’, Journal of Islamic Studies 23(2): 199–224. Dirlik, A. (2007) ‘The historiography of colonial modernity: Chinese history between Eurocentric hegemony and nationalism’, Journal of Modern Chinese History 1(1): 97–115. Do, M. (2004) ‘The implications of colonial modernity without colonialism’, Korea Journal 44(2): 189–209. Eckert, C. (1996) Offspring of Empire: The Koch’ang Kims and the Colonial Origins of Korean Capitalism, 1876–1945, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Hanscom, C., Lew, W., and Ryu, Y. (eds.) (2013) Imperatives of Culture: Selected Essays on Korean History, Literature, and Society from the Japanese Colonial Era, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Henry, T. (2014) Assimilating Seoul: Japanese Rule and the Politics of Public Space in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Hŏ, Y. (2008) ‘Kankoku kenban (1908–1942) ni okeru kiisen kyōiku no naiyō to buyō kyōiku’, Buyōgaku (Choreologia) 31: 48–59. 138

Colonial modernity

Hyun, T. (2003) Writing Women in Korea: Translation and Feminism in the Colonial Period, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Im, T. (comp.) (1971) Han’guk minyojip, vol. III, Seoul: Jipmundang. Jha, S. (2009) ‘Eurasian women as tawa’if singers and recording artists: entertainment and identity-making in colonial India’, African and Asian Studies 8: 268–87. Johnson, A. (2003) ‘The savage city: locating colonial modernity’, Nineteenth-century Contexts 25(4): 315–332. Jun, K. (2005) ‘Colonial modernity and the social history of chemical seasoning in Korea’, Korea Journal 45(2): 9–36. Kawamura, M. (2001) Kiisen: ‘mono iu hana’ no bunkashi, Tokyo: Sakuhinsha. Killick, A. (2012) In Search of Korean Traditional Opera: Discourses of Ch’anggŭk, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Kim, C. (1996) ‘The characteristics of the system of Japanese imperialist rule in Korea from 1905 to 1945’, Korea Journal 36(1): 20–49. Kim, I. (2008) ‘Colonial modernization of the traditional city of Daegu’, Korea Journal 48(3): 77–103. Kim, K. (2005) ‘Reevaluating lives of Kisaeng’, Korea Times 17 June 2005. Kim, R. (2004) ‘Ariran to wa nani deatta ka? Kankoku kōnichi minzoku eiga no keisei’, Eizōgaku/Iconics 72: 5–27. Kim, S., Ch’oe, S., and Pang, C. (eds.) (1948) Chosŏn minyo chipsŏng, Seoul: Chŏngŭmsa. Kim, S. (1988) ‘Arirang: modern Korean folk song’, Korea Journal 28(7): 4–19. Kwon, N. (2014) ‘Conflicting nostalgia: performing The Tale of Ch’unhyang in the Japanese empire’, Journal of Asian Studies 73(1): 113–141. Lagrange, F. (2009) ‘Women in the singing business, women in songs’, History Compass 7(1): 226–250. Lears, T. J. (1994) No Place of Grace: Antimodernism and the Transformation of American Culture, 1890–1920, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Lee, H., Ha, Y., and Sorensen, C. (eds.) (2013) Colonial Rule and Social Change in Korea, 1910–1945, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Lee, J. (2011) ‘New women to new housewives: changing discourses in Sinyŏsŏng, 1923–34,’ U.S.-Japan Women’s Journal 40: 90–121. Lee, Y. (2004) ‘Colonial modernity and the investigation of land customs: a comparison of Japan, Taiwan, and Korea’, Korea Journal 44(2): 149–173. Limapichart, T. (2009) ‘The emergence of the Siamese public sphere: colonial modernity, print culture and the practice of criticism (1860s–1910s)’, South East Asia Research 17(3): 361–399. Maliangkay, R. (2005) ‘Classifying performances: the art of Korean film narrators’, Image and Narrative 10. Available online at www.imageandnarrative.be. McKenzie, F. A. (1920) Korea’s Fight for Freedom, New York, NY: Fleming H. Revell Co. McNamara, D. (1990) The Colonial Origins of Korean Enterprise, 1910–1945, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Min, Hyun Jeong. (2013) ‘New women and modern girls: consuming foreign goods in colonial Korea’, Journal of Historical Research in Marketing 5(4): 494–520. Moon, Y. (2013) Populist Collaborators: The Ilchinhoe and the Japanese Colonization of Korea, 1896–1910, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Myers, G. (2003) ‘Colonial and postcolonial modernities in two African cities’, Canadian Journal of African Studies 37(2/3): 328–357. Nahm, A. (1975) ‘Themes of popular songs and poems of the Koreans as an oppressed people, 1910–1945’, in C. Kim and D. Mortimore (eds.) Korea’s Response to Japan: The Colonial Period 1910–1945, Kalamazoo: Center for Korean Studies, Western Michigan University: 188–230. Nakano, A. (2007) ‘Korea’s railway network the key to imperial Japan’s control’, The Asia-Pacific Journal: Japan Focus, Available online at www.japanfocus.org/-Nakano-Akira/2533 (accessed 29 September). Nordholt, H. (2000) ‘Localizing modernity in colonial Bali during the 1930s’, Journal of Southeast Asian Studies 31(1): 101–114. Nordholt, H. (2011) ‘Modernity and cultural citizenship in the Netherlands Indies: an illustrated hypothesis’, Journal of Southeast Asian Studies 42(3): 435–457. Oza, R. (2006) The Making of Neoliberal India: Nationalism, Gender, and the Paradoxes of Globalization, London: Routledge. Park, C. (2003) Voices from the Straw Mat: Toward an Ethnography of Korean Story Singing, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Park, C. (2008) ‘Colonial modernity and the making of Mokpo as a dual city’, Korea Journal 48(3): 104–132. 139

E. Taylor Atkins

Park, C. (2010) ‘Japanese rule and colonial dual society in Korea’, Korea Journal 50(4): 69–98. Park. P. (2005) ‘Korean Buddhist reforms and problems in the adoption of modernity during the colonial period’, Korea Journal 45(1): 87–113. Ray, U. (2012) ‘Eating “modernity”: changing dietary practices in colonial Bengal’, Modern Asian Studies 26(3): 703–729. Robinson, M. (1988) Cultural Nationalism in Colonial Korea, 1920–1925. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Schmid, A. (2000) ‘Colonialism and the “Korea problem” in the historiography of modern Japan: A review article’, Journal of Asian Studies 59(4): 951–976. –––– . (2002) Korea Between Empires, 1895–1919, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Seo, J. (2010) ‘Dual broadcasting and diglossia in the Japanese colonial period’, Seoul Journal of Korean Studies 23(2): 173–194. Shin, G. (1996) Peasant Protest and Social Change in Colonial Korea, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Shin, G. (1999) ‘Agrarianism: a critique of colonial modernity in Korea’, Comparative Studies in Society and History Shin, G., and Robinson, M. (eds.) (1999) Colonial Modernity in Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard East Asia Center. Society for the Dissemination of Historical Fact. Available online at www.sdh-fact.com. Sŏng, K., and Chang, S. (1949) Chosŏn ŭi minyo, Seoul: Kukche Ŭmak Munhwasa. Thomas, N. (1994) Colonialism’s Culture: Anthropology, Travel and Government, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Tran, N. (2012) ‘Woman as nation: tradition and modernity narratives in Vietnamese histories’, Gender and History 24(2): 411–430. Weems, B. (1964) Reform, Rebellion, and the Heavenly Way, Association for Asian Studies Monographs and Papers, No. XV, Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press. Wells, K. (1995) ‘The cultural construction of Korean history’, in South Korea’s Minjung Movement: The Culture and Politics of Dissidence, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press: 11–29. Yi, K. (1917; 2005) Mujŏng: Yi Kwang-su and Modern Korean Literature, A.S.H. Lee (trans.), Ithaca, NY: Cornell University East Asia Program. Yoo, T. (2008) The Politics of Gender in Colonial Korea: Education, Labor, and Health, 1910–1945, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

140

10 Women, gender, and social change in colonial Korea Sonja M. Kim

Reform! . . . Liberation! This is the call of women who have been confined to the deep, dark, inner chambers for thousands of years . . . Truly the time has come for change . . . In order to reform society, we must first reform the family, society’s most basic and fundamental unit. In order to reform the family, we have to liberate women, who are the masters of the house. And we must first liberate women if we are to catch up with the rest of the world, be competitive, lead lives that can be respected by other states, and transform our social structure. —Inaugural editorial, Sin yŏja (1920)1

In 1920 the inaugural issue of the journal Sin yŏja (New Woman) called forth a new world, premised on the liberation of women. Likening women to slaves whose time for awakening had come, the journal modeled the feminist group Seitō (Bluestocking) in Japan. Its founder, female literary figure Kim Wŏn-ju, envisioned the journal to not only provide space for and voice to the literary and artistic expressions of its female contributors but also inspire its targeted female readership to effect social change. Women were to work in society, make gains beyond acknowledgement provided by “empty slogans” such as “equality” or “respect for women,” and “build a social order that is the envy of the world.” Although Sin yŏja published only four issues, as Korea’s first journal with a clear feminist platform, it attests to shifting attitudes in regards to gender relations in early twentieth-century Korea. Sin yŏja also heralded an explosion of public discussion concerning the “woman question” within an expanding publishing landscape enabled by the Japanese colonial state’s Cultural Politics (munhwa chŏngch’i) in the aftermath of the 1919 nationalist March First movement (Robinson 2014). This chapter provides an overview of the dynamic transformations related to gender during the colonial period from 1910 to 1945. Determining whether things were better for women under Japanese colonial rule than in the previous Chosŏn period is not the aim. The lived experiences of women depended on a multitude of factors, including their socio-economic class, marriage and reproductive status, education and skills, age, family support, religion, and location (e.g. urban, rural, industrial, near a railroad), among others. Rather, this chapter finds more productive an examination of the development of social institutions in the realms of education, labor, law, religion, and health which promoted gendered norms, behavior, and structures. These, 141

Sonja M. Kim

in turn, shaped the opportunities that became available to women. Evolving at the interstices of transnational and transcultural encounters, Japanese imperialism, and Korean nationalist politics, these institutions grappled with Korea’s patriarchal traditions at the same time they endorsed modernist practices. The end result was a reconfiguration of Chosŏn Confucian gender ethics as manifested by the modern “Wise Mother, Good Wife” (hyŏnmo yangch’ŏ) construct. Scholars place “Wise Mother, Good Wife” at the core of a new gender discourse emerging around the turn of the twentieth century, propagated through schools and debated in public literary spaces and the courtroom. (Choi 2009b; Yoo 2008; Lim 2011) Stress on women’s maternal role was particularly reflected in colonial reproductive politics. (Park 2014a; Kim 2008b) The high value placed on women’s roles in the domestic sphere buttressed a colonial order premised on the nuclear family as the basic unit of society. It also, however, made possible for the agency women exercised on issues pertinent to them by providing the means by which women worked within, challenged, and negotiated those social institutions, thereby destabilizing the very harmony families managed by wise mothers and good wives were to provide. Nevertheless, gender politics of colonial Korea solidified the patriarchal nature of the household, laying the groundwork for continued institutionalized forms of gender inequalities (Shin 2006; Moon 2005) and the “heteronormative assumptions” of the post-1948 South Korean state (Choi 2015). Social change for women was also uneven, concentrated in urban areas and on a relatively small scale.

Reframing women As discussed in the previous chapters, the sense of urgency felt among Korean leaders in the aftermath of the 1894 Sino-Japanese War and encroaching Japanese imperialism fueled attempts to redefine Korea’s intellectual traditions, guide reform efforts along the rubric “civilization and enlightenment” (munmyŏng kaehwa), and redirect duties and loyalties of the people to new conceptualizations of Korea as a nation. Accordingly, women and the domestic sphere with its related institutions and practices became a major focus of attention. The highlighting of the household and the most intimate human relations among family members as significant components to nation-building stemmed from a longer tradition. Confucian worldviews linked the domestic to the rise and fall of the dynasty, radiating outward to a universal harmony “all under heaven.” Thus, the Chosŏn court targeted kinship practices, promoted Confucian values of filiality and wifely chastity, and prescribed spatial and symbolic divisions in the home based on sex (Deuchler 1992). Likewise, Korean nationalist thought in the late nineteenth century continued the organic relationship between the family and the larger collective. On these grounds, gender ideology was an integral part of Korea’s pursuit of modernity, and women as in other parts of the world were incorporated into nation-building projects. Early twentieth-century primers for women highlighted biographies of exemplary women—foreign and Asian—who as filial daughters, faithful wives, or sacrificing mothers performed extraordinary and patriotic feats (Hyun 2004). The roles women performed in the domestic space framed their citizenship and shaped their interpersonal relations, education, work, and health care. For example, in response to news of the 1898 petition to King Kojong on behalf of women’s formal education, one writer supported the cause, arguing that it would enable women to become better companions and helpmates (naejo) to their husbands and educators of their children (Oh 2009). Women, hence, were to contribute to the nation through their husbands and sons. What a woman was to be or do, however, defied simple definitions. “Woman” was a novel social and political category that had to be conceived on new grounds. In fact, there was no Korean word for “woman.” Just as the term nation (minjok) did not exist in the Korean vocabulary 142

Women, gender, and social change

before this era, so too did writers experiment with terms such as punyŏ (literally, married female) and puin (married woman) before settling on yŏja (female person). The term today used to translate “woman,” yŏsŏng, did not commonly appear in print media until the 1920s. These early discussions of women often portrayed them as a metonym for the nation or marker of civilization. The position of women reflected the status of the nation and provided the rationale for reform measures such as the eradication of concubinage, child marriage, and social stigma against widow remarriage (Yoo 2008). Women’s education was promoted so that women could partake in nation-building processes and the causes of “civilization and enlightenment.” Nonetheless, these discussions also attributed women with a humanity that granted them not only the potential but also the opportunity to act as autonomous and equal individuals. At the same time the 1898 petition mentioned earlier expressed women’s “loyalty and devotion to the country,” it also asserted women had the same capacity as men at learning and thus the ability to contribute to society in public and direct ways (Oh 2009). It is this tension between womenas-individuals and idealization of women-in-the-household that continued to characterize gender politics of colonial Korea.

Women’s education, shifting the domestic The notion that proper womanhood was defined by her domestic roles coalesced in the new schools that became available for girls. Besides court-regulated female occupations such as the medical worker ŭinyŏ or entertainer kisaeng, women did not receive formal education during the Chosŏn dynasty. This changed starting in 1886 with the Christian mission school Ewha haktang, the predecessor of today’s premier Ewha Woman’s University in South Korea. Other schools soon followed. Between 1886 and 1910, an estimated fifty private and mission girls’ schools were established (Choi 2009a). The state opened the first public high school for girls, Hansŏng kodŭng hakkyo, in 1908. The term “Wise Mother, Good Wife” first emerged in Korea in 1906 in a mission statement for a private girls school modeled on Japanese schools. Students were to learn the academic subjects and crafts that would prepare them for their future as mothers and wives. As private, mission, and public girl schools set out to educate women, the “Wise Mother, Good Wife” ideal evolved “through a convergence of Chosŏn’s Confucian notions of pudŏk (womanly virtue), Japanese gender ideology of ryōsai kenbo (“good wife, wise mother”), and American Protestant missionary notions of domesticity” (Choi 2009b). After Korea became a colony in 1910, the Educational Ordinances of the Government-General of Korea (GGK) stipulated that higher education for girls was to “foster in them feminine virtues . . . the education given there . . . must conform to the cultivating of moral character and equipping them as good housekeepers,” thereby institutionalizing “Wise Mother, Good Wife” in a gendered curriculum.2 Schools were to train girls for their future tasks in the home and incorporated domestic curriculum such as sewing, cooking, and childrearing. However, by emphasizing instruction “in the knowledge and art useful in making a livelihood,” the GGK also laid the groundwork for technical, scientific, even vocational education students received. (Kim, In prep) It also shaped the scientification and professionalization of housework, emphasizing hygiene, thrift, and utility in the 1930s image of the “Wise and Prudent Professional Housewife” (Yoo 2008). Access to education, however, remained severely restricted. Many families remained reluctant by custom to send their daughters to school or were limited due to finances. Moreover, the GGK disqualified many private and mission schools from operation and did not mandate primary education in Korea as the Japanese government did in Japan. The number of girls’ high schools dwindled down to six by 1919, half the number of high schools for boys (Yoo 2008). More 143

Sonja M. Kim

than 90 percent of Korea’s female population remained illiterate, with the literacy rate improving only to a dismal 16 percent in the late 1930s (Choi 2013). Sex ratios in schools remained skewed. In 1937, colonial statistics recorded a number of 64,809 female students, less than one-third the figure of male students.3 Women seeking higher education often had to leave the country, with Japan as the most common destination for study (Park 1990). Higher education marked women with a middle- or upper-class status, prone to leftist critiques of its bourgeois and urban nature (Choi 2009b). While schools idealized women’s role in the newly designated private spaces of the family and home, they did expose their students to new ideas and cultivated skills that presented women opportunities to participate publicly in society in ways they were unable to before, such as travel abroad, produce work in literary publications, or financially support oneself as a professional (Wells 2004). This gave rise in the 1920s to the phenomenon of the New Woman (sin yŏsŏng). Associated with the female student, the term was used to differentiate young women educated in the new forms of learning from those perceived as more traditional women. New Woman also indicated the visible presence of “a small group of elite women who became public figures in art, literature, educational, journalism, and politics” (Choi 2013). A contradiction emerged. On one hand, educated women were symbols of modernity, civilization, and pride. On the other hand, their very public engagements raised anxieties as they permitted new forms of social interactions between men and women. Performed in new urban spaces of leisure such as the café, dance halls, theatre, restaurants, train station, and department store, such male-female relations were seen to compromise women’s sexual morality. If women postponed or rejected marriage or motherhood, they posed a threat to the stability of the family. Women’s consumptive behavior suggested an orientation to the individual self that flew in the face of “Wise Mother, Good Wife.” These castigations converged on the media icon of the Modern Girl, whose flagrant materialism, loose sexuality, and lack of morals were often conflated with the New Woman. Such anxieties ignited public discussions on love, female sexuality, marriage, and family. What differed now from earlier discussions was that women such as those involved with the journal Sin yŏja actively participated in these debates, having gained the language and will to articulate publicly their opinions, desires, and critiques (Kwon 1998; Yoo 2008). The gendered configuration of women as housewives also opened the grounds on which women demanded new relations with their husbands, thereby altering relations within the family and producing new social affects and practices such as romance. They called for “free love” and “free marriage,” or the freedom for women and men to choose their spouses, producing what Bodurae Kwon calls the emergence of romance.4 Male-female relationships could be based on mutual respect, companionship, love, or shared mission and camaraderie such as Red Love in leftist circles (Barraclough 2014). The romanticized domestic ideal of the “Sweet Home” that unfolded in the 1930s may have strategically marketed material goods such as modern residential architecture and household products to urban housewives and placed men in incomeearning roles as “Salaryman,” but it also “invoke[ed] the idea of a nuclear family based on love, respect and sense of selfhood” (Choi 2014). Some couples, inspired by such ideals, adapted new-style weddings as well, such as wearing Western dress of male suit and white bridal gown and hosting the wedding at the venue of a church (Jung-Kim 2008). In fact, newspapers sensationalized “stories of women who committed suicide due to early marriage, forced marriage, male infidelity, or failed relationship or marriage” (Jung-Kim 2005). Insinuations of a lesbian relationship may have further scandalized the double-suicide of female students Hong Ok-im and Kim Yong-ju. But these reports suggest that women sought to actualize their desires for new kinds of relationships with their partners to the extent that they would choose death when 144

Women, gender, and social change

those relationships did not seem possible, in this case a forced marriage for Kim, who the media portrayed as indifferent and absent. Other women such as artist and writer Na Hyesŏk questioned the double standard placed on women that castigated any sexual transgressions on the part of women while accepting men’s multiple liaisons. She critiqued the “Wise Mother, Good Wife” ideal altogether, noting that she had not “heard of any curriculum that emphasizes ‘good husband, wise father,’” and saw it “making women into mere appendages of men” by exhorting women’s “conduct as good spouse and wise parent” but failing to “develop the mind.”5 Kim Wŏnju’s 1926 short story “Awakening” depicts the classic theme of love-betrayal-abandonment, but here the devoted and filial (to her in-laws) housewife protagonist leaves her husband and child upon learning of her husband’s affair, mirroring Henrik Ibsen’s Nora of A Doll’s House, literature that was central in colonial period discussions surrounding New Women and critiques of the patriarchal family system (Kim 2010). Civil courts faced suits from women filing for divorce from cheating husbands and from families who sought the return of their wayward daughters-in-law (Lim 2013). Na Hyesŏk herself divorced after she pursued an affair of her own, unhappy in a marriage with a philandering husband (Choi 2013). Unfortunately for many women, they discovered that their relationships with men often fell short of the ideals they fostered during their education. Kim Hwallan forewent marriage altogether, determined to dedicate her life to the cause of women’s education (Wells 2001).

A maternalist agenda Women’s relationship with their children was just as ambivalent. The bio-politics of the colonial government oriented women’s bodies and reproduction for the management of the colonial population. In the efforts to “mobilize Koreans as crucial human resources,” colonial administrators understood population increase as a means of national/imperial power and thus “made explicit the maternal role and centrality of fertile bodies for the state and empire,” particularly in the context of imperialist expansion into Manchuria after 1932 (Park 2014a). This skewed reproductive labor as the responsibility primarily of women, placing women’s sexual, conjugal, and reproductive experiences and capacity under medical and scientific scrutiny. In this way, women’s bodies became legible and governable. The means of collecting this data brought women in contact with the colonial state via researchers who were often bio-medical physicians. Knowledge of female bodies invited interventions in the most private spaces in the attempts to reform practices determined detrimental to the pro-natalist agenda of the colonial state. For example, women’s child-birthing and -rearing customs were the subject of health campaigns that ostensibly sought to address the problem of infant mortality. Certain forms of contraceptives were restricted, presented as harmful to women’s bodies and moral conduct, but as all forms became unavailable with escalation of the Pacific War, access was likely denied when they conflicted with pro-natalist mobilizations (Kim 2008b). Anxieties about sterility fueled the publication of informative articles on venereal diseases. They also provided the rationale for the introduction of prostitution licensing and systematic inspection of women in sex industryrelated work to monitor venereal disease (Park 2014b). This intersected with new forms of sex workers such as the kisaeng, the female entertainer with Chosŏn roots but transformed in the new colonial economy (Barraclough 2012b), and the Café Waitress and Bar Girl, whose emergence was directly related to the new leisure spaces of urbanizing metropolises such as Seoul (Jung-Kim 2005). Ironically, while promoting the interests of the Japanese empire, reproductive bio-politics of the colonial state in Korea inadvertently converged with interests of women, particularly 145

Sonja M. Kim

those in relation to reforms in the family. For example, Japanese physician Takaki Kudō’s gynecological research of incarcerated Korean women concluded that the custom of marrying women early or at a young age, often before the maturity of their reproductive organs, produced “sick wombs” that directly correlated to Koreans’ higher propensity towards female murderers, particularly of spousal- or husband-murder, relative to other countries (J. Park 2013). While Kudō’s statistical contradictions and data manipulation are suspect, his research promulgations condemned early marriage and the maltreatment of women by their mothers-in-law and husbands, practices deemed oppressive to women. Likewise, concern for the reproductive health and increased viability of women’s fertility promoted eugenic arguments for birth control (i.e. “limiting birth” sana chehan) and smaller families. Mothers were to plan and space the timing of their pregnancies so as to maximize maternal health through prolonged postnatal care which was believed to produce healthier babies. Albeit a pro-natalist position, these arguments were presented by women at the same time they pushed female-centered reasons on the agenda, such as postponing pregnancy to gain time to pursue one’s education or interests (Kim 2008b). Women also advocated the health screening of potential husbands so that women could avoid the misfortune of contracting venereal disease and implicitly encouraged women’s agency in choosing a spouse. In addition, women were exhorted to learn the new sciences in school and wield modern health practices on themselves and in their homes so as to safeguard the viability of their fertility and the health of their family members. This formed the rationale for women’s higher education in the health fields and allowed for the professionalization of women in nursing, midwifery, and medicine (Kim, In prep). Moreover, many women actively sought new medical interventions, whether in the form of patent medicines, infant welfare clinics, or gynecological expertise of physicians, not to meet imperialist goals but for personal reasons, such as whether to resolve perceived problems with fertility (including the conception and successful raising of sons beyond infanthood) or modernist visions of domesticity (Kim 2014). Nevertheless, female-centered arguments on the whole were subsumed to colonial bio-politics that prioritized the stability of nuclear families with women entrenched firmly in their proper domestic roles. Women may have sought medical intervention to meet personal goals, but those goals were often conditioned by the patriarchal nature of the family that necessitated the birth of sons for lineage or household preservation. Women may have employed modern practices and material goods, yet the new lifestyles they promoted, whether in the Christian home, “Sweet Home,” or other home based on newly envisioned male-female or parent-child relations, continued to premise women’s role in the domestic space. In short, women became subjects, citizens, and members of society foremost in their biological and social roles as mothers, as expressed in the phrase “mothers of citizens” (kungmin chi mo, 國民之母) repeated in different expressions throughout the period. This explains the categorization of women in colonial administrative thought into reproductive and non-reproductive bodies.

Mobilizing women The division between reproductive and non-reproductive female bodies is perhaps most flagrant in the realm of health and medicine. The bio-medical research on women’s bodies, for instance, posed different questions and calibrations for women who experienced and had yet to experience menopause (Park 2014a). Puinbyŏng or “women’s disease” was presented in print media as of concern for women before menopause. While women were to be “Wise Mothers, Good Wives,” it became apparent that some women were excluded from this moniker, particularly those involved in sex-related work. Health screening of female sex workers operated on a logic that placed them as the vectors of venereal disease and hence a threat to the stability of the nuclear 146

Women, gender, and social change

family, not on notions of the women’s rights to adequate medical care. Medical discussions of women’s health marginalized other concerns such as cancer that did not focus on or were not related to women’s reproductive activity (gestation, delivery, lactation) and fertility (Kim 2008a). Perhaps the most extreme form of colonial mobilization of non-reproductive female bodies was the system of Japanese military sexual slavery, euphemistically coined “comfort women” (wianbu), which recruited an estimated 200,000 women. This system inflicted and sanctioned institutionalized sexual violence on particular women by imprisoning women to provide sexual services to the Japanese military at the warfront (Chung 1997). Built on a theory of male sexuality and morale in war, this system disproportionately mobilized lower-class Korean women, enabled by patriarchal practices in Korea related to the labor and sex trafficking of women (Soh 2008). This raises the question of Korean complicity in the recruitment of “comfort women” and operation of this system as well as the continued silencing of these women’s voices in the contemporary gendered, discursive practices that place the chastity of Korean women and men’s humiliation or failure to protect that chastity at the center of the issue (Yang 1998b). “Comfort women” were not to be mothers. In fact, they were to use condoms in a time of restricted access to contraceptives, and many testimonies attest to the forced abortions inflicted on their pregnant bodies. Moreover, their reproductive health was of little concern, and many report infertility and other lingering gynecological problems in its aftermath. The industrial sectors’ mobilization of women’s labor also operated on an axis of women’s reproductive capacity. The visibility of the Factory Girl or yŏgong in the 1920s and 1930s developed in the context of rapid industrialization and rural impoverishment brought about by the colonial government’s industrial promotion policies (Yoo 2008). Korean women’s entrance in the colonial wage market was a highly gendered process. Young rural women migrated to work in factories as part of family strategies that relied on their wages. In so doing, they forged new identities and experiences that changed new dynamics in family structures and contributed to debates on new womanhood. Their employment heavily deployed sexual division of labor based on women’s marital and reproductive status. Employers exploited gendered domestic norms to naturalize manager-worker relations, with female workers placed under the paternalistic (and potentially sexually abusive) care of male managers, a common plot in colonial literature (Barraclough 2012a). Women workers were perceived as temporary wage laborers, working between childhood and marriage, in tasks premised on their supposed feminine skills and traits— dexterous fingers, patience, docility, and endurance. They dominated light industries in textiles and food processing. Women who worked after marriage often held jobs that offered flexibility such as in cottage industries or piece work that could be accomplished at home, agricultural wage work, the service sector in urban areas (restaurant, street vendors), or part-time/seasonal hires in food processing or rubber factories (Kim 2009). Vocational training or education offered female workers was overwhelmingly focused on “womanly skills,” “moral cultivation” with etiquette, and “rules for factory life” and not on technical skills that would further their possibility for promotion or permanent employment. Similar management techniques resurfaced in postwar industrializing South Korea, accounting for the pattern noted by Seungsook Moon of women “mobilized to be domestic” (Moon 2005). Female workers, however, did not sit idly to their poor working conditions. Female workers organized numerous labor unions and strikes, raising demands such as maternal leave, the right to nurse their children while working, and protections at the workplace. Some resisted with their feet, their high turnover plaguing managerial efforts to secure worker productivity. In fact, other non-elite working women too formed consciousness of selves as working women and took part in organized labor activities (Jung-Kim 2005). Both kisaeng and café waitresses published their own journals, Chang Han (Lasting Regret, 1927) and Yŏ sŏng (Woman’s Voice, 147

Sonja M. Kim

1934), respectively, seeking to better their working conditions. Female students too organized strikes in protest of student life such as dormitory regulations. In the 1920s, Korean nursing students at mission hospitals waged strikes to protest their conditions both as students and as hospital workers (Kim, In prep). Many women found other opportunities to mobilize. During the colonial period, women’s range of activities expanded tremendously, forming over 400 women’s organizations organized around a broad array of religious, educational, political, and social issues. The Protestant Church presented women with unprecedented opportunities to receive education and exercise leadership (Strawn 2013). The establishment of the Korean Young Women’s Christian Association (YWCA) in 1923 was the culmination of Korean Christian women’s groups and stood at the forefront of women’s organizational efforts promoting the rights and equality of women in education, work, and the family (Choi 2013). In fact, many of the women leaders who led more radical or alternate lifestyles were leaders in Christian organizations. Other religious practices such as Ch’ŏndogyo, successor to the indigenous Tonghak religion, Buddhism, and shamanism arguably posed challenges to traditional gender roles as well and perhaps deserve more scholarly analysis. In 1927, women’s organizations coalesced under the umbrella of the nationalist women’s organization Kŭnuhoe. Dominated by socialist women, Kŭnuhoe articulated an understanding of gender oppression as emerging from socio-economic structures. Increasing pressure from colonial censors and masculinist nationalist or socialist imperatives, nonetheless, curtailed the integration of class struggle in the women’s movement as feminist platforms became sidelined (Wells 1999). Leftist critiques did not disappear, however. Recent scholarship on leftist literature suggests that while mainstream socialist narratives may not grant “revolutionary agency nor autonomous subjectivity” to women’s struggles and subsume their activities under the revolution, leftist women writers such as Kang Kyŏng-ae produced a variant feminism to address the plight of lower-class women (Park 1998; S. Park 2013). Besides the pen, the courtroom was also used by women to protect and promote their interests. A discussion of women’s rights would not be complete without an examination of customary laws related to the family. Since the Chosŏn period, kinship regulations held implications for women’s rights in regards to property and ritual inheritance, marriage, divorce, exercise of legal authority, and responsibilities toward the household and its members. The categorization of women into primary and secondary wives, for instance, resulted in mothers being the arbiter of social status and legitimacy to their sons in elite families (Deuchler 1992). Scholars point to Japanese colonial legal practices that maintained “customs” such as corporal punishment and kinship practices in a modernized legal system with a series of customary laws (Lee 1999; Yang 1998a). Colonial regulations restructured the family into nuclear households, appointing the eldest son to inherit the household headship and slating younger brothers to separate when they marry, becoming heads of their households (Sorenson 2013). While customary family law continued the patriarchal principles of patrilineality and primogeniture, conflicts arose when widows presumed the role (albeit temporary) of house-heads in the absence of sons. As house-heads, widows wielded the authority to appoint the next house-head, adopt, and manage inherited property. When interests of widows clashed with those of the lineage, it was often left to the courts to resolve (Lim 2011). Women figured prominently in legal suits involving adoption and inheritance, both as the plaintiff, as women exercised legal agency to protect their interests, and as defendants, reflecting the anxieties posed by the reality of women’s mobility. Their physical absence (women did leave their husbands, failed to receive a legal divorce, or lived with other men in relationships without marriage and therefore were not recognized by courts) posed problems for lineages that no longer saw these women as serving their households (Lim 2013). 148

Women, gender, and social change

Yet the courts often ruled in favor of widows within the context of shifting definitions of family that increasingly became defined legally as nuclear. This was consistent with other legal practices that ruled in favor of the rights of the nuclear family over that of the lineage. Revisions in 1939 to the family law opened adoption to sons-in-law and non-kin, claiming to expand heirship rights to daughters indirectly through their husbands. Nevertheless, colonial customary family law failed to grant widows full inheritance rights as permanent house-heads or expand women’s inheritance and property ownership rights in general. By solidifying the patrilineal household-headed nuclear family now backed by modern law, the Japanese colonial state preserved the patriarchal family order. The postwar South Korean state continued the househead-based nuclear family system until the 2005 Family Law revision, which effectively abolished the house-head system (Shin 2006). In reflecting on her divorce, Na Hyesŏk noted the powerlessness men faced, “I feel great pity for the men of the educated class in Korea. They aren’t allowed to enter the political arena, which should be their primary arena. There’s no way for them to use the knowledge they have acquired and developed.”6 Like the rethinking of womanhood, masculinity too faced a myriad of challenges to redefine itself in the face of Japanese colonial rule. Korean men, while unable to take high leadership positions in politics or the government, were able to take high-profile positions in the arts, industry, and society. Whether it was the Social Darwinist-infused sacrificial spirit of patriotic soldiers in muscular nationalist narratives, confidence of the successful entrepreneur, or emasculated and perhaps effeminate media icon Modern Boy (the counterpart to Modern Girl), images of Korean modern manhood varied (Tikhonov 2007; Jung-Kim 2005). Yet, marriage and fatherhood were not as life-altering for men as they were for women. As Na continued, “I also feel pity for the women of the educated class, that is, New Women. They still spend their childhoods and married lives within the feudal family system, so that their lives are incredibly complex and chaotic.” The colonial period witnessed a reconfiguration of womanhood that remained premised on women’s roles in the domestic space yet was infused with new conceptualizations of equality, rights, and humanity. Female education guided by the framework “Wise Mother, Good Wife” served foremost to produce mothers and housekeepers who met collective directives. Education outfitted women with not only what was presented then as advanced scientific learning and skills but also the tools and confidence to raise their voices in the world of publishing, organizations, and courtrooms. The colonial period produced a generation of educated women who would take leadership roles in postcolonial Korea. Their activities and publications brought to the forefront the “woman question.” Women’s critiques themselves, however, failed to move beyond the framework of the family as the basis of society. Even the journal Sin yŏja’s radical call for women’s liberation was premised on her location in the domestic space. It is this “woman question” and patriarchal nature of the family now codified by law and practice that both emergent states (DPRK and ROK) had to grapple, as other chapters in this volume attest.

Glossary “Wise Mother, Good Wife” (hyŏnmo yangch’ŏ) Cultural Politics (munhwa chŏngch’i) Sin yŏja (New Woman, the journal) “civilization and enlightenment” (munmyŏng kaehwa) New Woman (sin yŏsŏng).

149

Sonja M. Kim

Notes 1 2

3 4 5 6

“Ch’anggansa,” Sin yŏja 1 (1920): 2–3. As translated and reprinted in Choi 2013, 30. GGK, “Instructions Concerning the Enforcement of the Chosen Educational Ordinance,” November 1, 1911, in Government General of Chosen, Manual of Education in Chosen (1920), Appendix, 13. Reprinted in Singminji Chosŏn kyoyuk chŏngch’aek saryo chipsŏng, vol. 2, Seoul, Korea: Taehaksŏwŏn, 1990. P. Kim, Hakkyo pak ŭi Choŏn yŏsŏngtŭl [Korean women outside of school], translated by K. Cho and U. Kim, Seoul, Korea: Ilchogak, 2005, 92. B. Kwon, Yŏnae ŭi sidae: 1920 nyŏndae ch’oban ŭi munhwa wa yuhaeng [Age of dating: culture and trends of the early 1920s], Seoul, Korea: Hyŏnsil munhwa yŏngu, 2003. Na Hyesŏk, “Isang chŏk puin,” Hakchigwang 3 (December 1914): 13–14. As translated and reprinted in Choi 2013, 29. Na Hyesŏk, “Ihon kobaekghang: Ch’ŏnggu ssi ege,” Samch’ŏlli 6 (1934): 84–94. As translated and reprinted in Choi 2013, 135.

References Barraclough, R. (2012a) Factory Girl Literature: Sexuality, Violence, and Representation in Industrializing Korea, Berkeley and Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press. Barraclough, R. (2012b) ‘The Courtesan’s Journal: Kisaeng and the Sex Labour Market in Colonial Korea’, Intersections: Gender and Sexuality in Asia and the Pacific, 29. Barraclough, R. (2014) ‘Red Love and Betrayal in the Making of North Korea: Comrade Hô Jông-suk’, History Workshop Journal, vol. 77:1. Barraclough, R. (2015) ‘A History of Sex Work in Modern Korea’, in M. McLelland and V. Mackie (eds.) Routledge Handbook of Sexuality Studies in East Asia, London: Routledge. Choi, H. (2009a) Gender and Mission Encounters in Korea: New Women, Old Ways, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Choi, H. (2009b) ‘“Wise Mother, Good Wife”: a Transcultural Discursive Construct in Modern Korea’, Journal of Korean Studies, 14: 1–34. Choi, H. (2009c) ‘Women’s Literacy and New Womanhood in Late Chosŏn Korea’, Asian Journal of Women’s Studies, 6: 88–115. Choi, H. (2012) ‘In Search of Knowledge and Selfhood: Korean Women Studying Overseas in Colonial Korea’, Intersections: Gender and Sexuality in Asia and the Pacific, 29. Choi, H. (2013) New Women in Colonial Korea: a Sourcebook, London: Routledge. Choi, H. (2014) ‘The Missionary Home as Pulpit: Domestic Paradoxes in Early Twentieth-Century Korea’, in H. Choi and M. Jolly (eds.) Divine Domesticities, Canberra, Australia: Australian National University Press. Choi, H. (2015) ‘Constructions of Marriage and Sexuality in Modern Korea’, in M. McLelland and V. Mackie (eds.) Routledge Handbook of Sexuality Studies in East Asia, London: Routledge. Choi, K. (1999) ‘Neither Colonial nor National: the Making of “New Woman” in Pak Wansŏ’s “Mother’s Stake 1”’, in G. Shin and M. Robinson (eds.) Colonial Modernity in Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Choi, S. (1985) ‘Formation of Women’s Movements in Korea: From the Enlightenment Period to 1910’, Korea Journal, 25: 4–15. Chung, C. (1997) ‘The Origin and Development of Military Sexual Slavery in Imperial Japan’, positions: East Asia Cultures Critique, 5: 219–253. Deuchler, M. (1992) Confucian Transformation of Korea: a Study of Society and Ideology, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Hyun, T. (2003) Writing Women in Korea: Translation and Feminism in the Colonial Period, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Jung-Kim, J. (2005) ‘Gender and Modernity in Colonial Korea’, unpublished thesis, University of California, Los Angeles. Jung-Kim, J (2008) ‘The New Woman and New-Style Weddings in Colonial Korea’, The Review of Korean Studies, 11: 15–40. Kim, J. C. H. (2009) To Live to Work: Factory Women in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945, Redwood City, CA: Stanford University Press. 150

Women, gender, and social change

Kim, J. E. (2008) ‘Missing Partners: Single Motherhood in Korean Literature and Film of the Japanese Colonial Period’, The Review of Korean Studies, 11: 83–103. Kim, S. (2008a) ‘Contesting Bodies: Managing Population, Birthing, and Medicine in Korea, 1876–1945’, unpublished thesis, University of California, Los Angeles. Kim, S. (2008b) ‘Limiting Birth’: Birth Control in Colonial Korea’, East Asian Science, Technology, and Society: an International Journal, 2: 335–359. Kim, S. (2014) ‘Missionaries and a “Better Baby Movement” in Colonial Korea’, in H. Choi and M. Jolly (eds.) Divine Domesticities, Canberra, Australia: Australian National University Press. Kim, S. (In prep) Women and Health Care in Colonial Korea, Honolulu: University of Hawai’i Press. Kim, Y. (1995) ‘Under the Mandate of Nationalism: Development of Feminist Enterprises in Modern Korea’, Journal of Women’s History, 7: 120–146. Kim, Y. (2010) Questioning Minds: Short Stories by Modern Korean Women Writers, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawai’i Press. Kwon, I. (1998) ‘“The New Women’s Movement” in 1920s Korea: Rethinking the Relationship between Imperialism and Women’, Gender and History, 10: 381–405. Lee, C. (1999) ‘Modernity, Legality, and Power in Korea under Japanese Rule’, in G. Shin and M. Robinson (eds.) Colonial Modernity in Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Lim, S. (2011) ‘Enemies of the Lineage: Widows and Customary Rights in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945’, unpublished thesis, University of California, Berkeley. Lim, S. (2013) ‘Women on the Loose: Household System and Family Anxiety in Colonial Korea’, in W. Yeh (ed.) Mobile Subjects: Boundaries and Identities in the Modern Korean Diaspora, Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, Berkeley. Moon, S. (2005) Militarized Modernity and Gendered Citizenship in South Korea, Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Oh, S. (2009) ‘Letters to the Editor: Women, Newspapers, and the Public Sphere in Turn-of-the-Twentieth Century Korea’ in J. Haboush (ed.) Epistolary Letters: Letters in the Communicative Space of the Chosŏn, 1392–1910, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Park, H. (1998) ‘Ideals of Liberation: Korean Women in Manchuria’, in E. H. Kim and C. Choi (eds.) Dangerous Women: Gender and Korean Nationalism, New York, NY: Routledge. Park, Jihang (1990) ‘Trailblazers in a Traditional World: Korea’s First Women College Graduates, 1910–1945’, Social Science History, 14: 533–558. Park, Jin-kyung (2013) ‘Husband Murder as the “Sickness” of Korea: Carceral Gynecology, Race, and Tradition in Colonial Korea, 1926–1932’, Journal of Women’s History, 25: 116–140. Park, Jin-kyung (2014a) ‘Bodies for Empire: Biopolitics, Reproduction, and Sexual Knowledge in Late Colonial Korea’, Korean Journal of Medical History, 23: 203–238. Park, Jin-kyung (2014b) ‘“Picturing Empire and Illness:” Biomedicine, Venereal Disease, and the Modern Girl in Korea under Japanese Colonial Rule’, Cultural Studies, 28: 108–141. Park, S. (2013) ‘Rethinking Feminism in Colonial Korea in Colonial Korea: Kang Kyŏngae and 1930s Leftist Women’s Literature’, positions: East Asia Critique, 21: 947–985. Robinson, M. (2014) Cultural Nationalism in Colonial Korea, 1920–1925, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Shin, K. (2006) ‘The Politics of the Family Law Reform Movement in Contemporary Korea: a Contentious Space for Gender and the Nation’, The Journal of Korean Studies, 11: 93–126. Soh, C. (2008) The Comfort Women: Sexual Violence and Postcolonial Memory in Korea and Japan, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Sorenson, C. (2013) ‘The Korean Family in Colonial Space—Caught between Modernization and Assimilation’, in H. Lee and Y. C. Ha (eds.) Colonial Rule and Social Change in Korea, 1910–1945. Strawn, L. (2013) ‘Protestant Bible Education for Women: First Steps in Professional Education for Modern Korean Women, Journal of Korean Religions, 4: 99–121. Tikhonov, V. (2007) ‘Masculinizing the Nation: Gender Ideologies in Traditional Korea and in the 1890s–1900s Korean Enlightenment Discourse’, Journal of Asian Studies, 66: 1029–1065. Wells, K. (1999) ‘The Price of Legitimacy: Women and the Kŭnuhoe Movement, 1927–1931’, in G. Shin and M. Robinson (eds.) Colonial Modernity in Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Wells, K. (2004) ‘Expanding their Realm: Women and Public Agency in Colonial Korea’, in L. Edwards and M. Roces (eds.) Women’s Suffrage in Asia: Gender, Nationalism and Democracy, London: RoutledgeCurzon. 151

Sonja M. Kim

Yang, H. (1998a) ‘Envisioning Feminist Jursiprudence in Korean Family Law at the Crossroads of Tradition/Modernity’, unpublished thesis, New School for Social Research. Yang, H. (1998b) ‘Re-membering the Korean Military Comfort Women: Nationalism, Sexuality, and Silencing’ in Elaine H. Kim and Chungmoo Choi (eds.) Dangerous Women: Gender and Korean Nationalism, New York, NY: Routledge. Yoo, T. J. (2005) ‘The “New Woman” and the Politics of Love, Marriage, and Divorce in Colonial Korea’, Gender History, 17: 295–394. Yoo, T. J. (2008) The Politics of Gender in Colonial Korea: Education, Labor, and Health, 1910–1945, Berkeley and Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press. Yoo, T. J. (2009) “The Biography of Ch’oe Yŏng-suk and the Politics of Gender in Colonial Korea’, Journal of Women’s History, 21: 161–163. Yoshimi, Y. (2000) Comfort Women: Sexual Slavery in the Japanese Military during World War II, New York, NY: Columbia University Press.

152

11 Nationalist movements before 1945 Franklin Rausch

Nationalism is one of the most significant ideological forces on the Korean peninsula today in both the north and the south. In fact, a substantial portion of the tension in the region is connected to the failure to establish a unified state for the Korean nation. Moreover, of the factors making unification and an easing of tensions difficult, one of the most important is the very different forms of nationalism followed by the north and south. While it is common to place the origins of the division of the peninsula in post–World War II superpower politics, its roots can also be found in the different way Koreans responded to imperialism, particularly that of Japan, in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, and the colonial period of 1910–1945, when Korea was under direct Japanese rule. This chapter will therefore explore Korean nationalism, first by briefly considering pre-modern Korean identity, and then examining the development of nationalist thought from 1875, the year of the Kanghwa Forts Incident, in which Japan forced Korea to “open” to the modern world, to 1945, when Korea was liberated from Japanese rule. In particular, it will focus on how Korean nationalists adapted other ideologies, such as liberalism or Communism, in hopes that they would help them build a strong and independent nationstate, and on how the colonial experience shaped Korean nationalism.

Pre-modern roots of Korean nationalism Scholars of nationalism debate whether nationalism is a product of modernity or whether it existed, at least in some form, in pre-modern times (Gat 2012). These debates also influence Korean scholars, with some arguing that something very close to modern nationalism existed in Korea since the Koryŏ Dynasty (918–1392) or even since unified Silla (668–935) (Pak 2008). For our purposes, rather than engaging directly with this debate, we will focus on how there did exist in pre-modern Korea1 a sense that there was a close relationship between the dynastic states that ruled the peninsula, the people who were ruled, the land on which those people lived and which the state claimed sovereignty over, the language they spoke, and the values they shared. While it is difficult to assess a sense of identity among the common people, Azar Gat has pointed out that their reactions during times of foreign invasion can provide us some sense of whether or not a group of people feel such an identity (2012). In this case, it is worth noting that many Koreans, including the common people, would stubbornly, though in the 153

Franklin Rausch

end unsuccessfully, resist the Mongol invasions of the thirteenth century. Moreover, the first written reference to Tan’gun, the mythical founder of the Korean nation, appeared in the Samguk Yusa (Memorabilia of the Three Kingdoms), a text written shortly after Korea finally submitted to Mongol overlordship, signifying that subjugation did not mean an end to Korean identity (Timothy Lee 2009).2 Similarly, during the Japanese invasions of 1592–1597, known as the Imjin War, common people, led by local gentry or Buddhist monks, would rally to the defense of their country, even when the king or high officials had fled (Hawley 2005). It is true that Korea under the Chosŏn Dynasty (1392–1910) was a vassal state of Ming Dynasty China (1368–1644), and Korea participated, largely enthusiastically, in the Sinocentric world order. This should not, however, be seen as the denial of a Korean identity. Korea was still an independent country that maintained its own army and foreign policy, and while it might adopt Ming law, it felt free to revise that law as needed to fit Korean realities (Marie Kim 2012: 22). During this time, the deeply Confucian King Sejong even ordered the creation of a Korean alphabet, han’gŭl (Mi-rim Yoo 2006). Moreover, the commitment to Neo-Confucian civilization and gratitude for Ming intervention on Korea’s behalf during the Imjin War led to such stubborn Korean resistance that the rising Qing Dynasty (1644–1912) had to invade twice (1627 and 1636) to obtain their submission. Even after the Ming fell, Koreans still performed Confucian rituals venerating their emperors and identified themselves as the last bastion of true civilization, not only strengthening, at least among the elite, their sense of selves as Koreans but also providing them with a mission, the preservation of that Confucian civilization (Haboush 1999). Moreover, while Chosŏn Korea was an extraordinarily hierarchical society, the dynasty had long encouraged the values associated with Confucian civilization, both among elites and among the common people, and they had diffused all throughout society, providing Koreans with shared values and decreasing the gap between elite and commoner worldviews (Deuchler 1977). The growing sense of this identity can be seen in the use of words like tongp’o (literally meaning “same womb” and figuratively meaning something like “compatriot”) to refer to all Koreans. For instance, King Yŏngjo (r. 1724–1776), when calling for an end to certain harsh punishments against the common people, referred to them using this term (Pak 2010). Thus, before the modern period, there existed on the peninsula a group of people who spoke the same language, had their own alphabet, and had lived under the rule of two continuous dynastic states over roughly the same territory for nearly a millennium, giving rise to an identity that was increasingly claimed by both commoners and elites. At the same time, this was not modern nationalism. The commoners were still subjects—they were not expected to participate actively or even comment publicly on government matters. Moreover, their identity was more closely connected to the dynastic states that ruled them than to an independent sense of Koreanness. Thus, while not quite modern nationalism, there were the pieces of a distinctive Korean identity in existence. It would be under the pressure of foreign imperialism that some Koreans would begin to weld those disparate pieces together into a modern national identity.

Development of modern nationalism: 1876–1910 In 1875, a Japanese flotilla purposefully provoked the batteries of Kanghwa Fort, an important installation that guarded the capital Seoul, into firing upon it. Japanese forces subsequently seized the fort and used the threat of recriminations over the incident to force the Chosŏn state to accept an unequal treaty. King Kojong (r. 1863–1907), fearing the Japanese might invade and believing that a more open foreign policy than that followed by his father was warranted, accepted the Treaty of Kanghwa, which was signed in 1876. In the years that followed, the United States 154

Nationalist movements before 1945

and other Western powers signed treaties with Korea, and thus the country opened to influence from nations outside the traditional Sinocentric world order (Deuchler 1977). The opening of the country brought Koreans into contact with numerous new ideologies. One of the most powerful was modern nationalism, which had as its goal the creation of a powerful nation-state in which the people would actively identify with and sacrifice for the nation. The nation was to rule itself, to be its own master, so domination or even substantial influence by foreigners was anathema. For Korean nationalists, this would mean departure from the hallowed tradition of honoring China as a suzerain and elder brother state and attempting to establish a relationship of equality, as called for by modern international law (Schmid 2002: 56–101). In addition to reformulating its relationships with other countries, the Korean state also had to transform itself into a strong centralized government that, through such institutions as public schools, could develop an educated populace who could actively serve the nation and instill in them a sense of nationalism. Success in such projects would in turn bring the national power necessary to maintain independence. Moreover, because in the Western system of international law nation-states were understood to be the only true sovereign actors in the world, it was legal for them to impose their rule over territories whose polities did not, in their view, measure up to “civilized” standards. Thus, Koreans had to quickly establish a powerful nationstate or risk becoming a colony. Nationalism was not the only new idea to enter Korea. Other, related ideologies came in as well. One of the most important was the concept of “civilization and enlightenment” thought (J. bunmei kaika, K. munmyŏng kaehwa), a term coined by the Japanese intellectual, educator, and reformer Fukuzawa Yukichi (1835–1901) but which today could be fairly equated with “modernity” and the process of “modernization” (Craig 2009: 33–41) This body of thought, neither the product of a single individual or school, is defined by the notion of progress—that such things as knowledge, the arts, culture, and government advance through hierarchical stages, from inferior to superior. Thus, the nation-state stood above, and was better than, the premodern state and far beyond the tribal confederacy. The progress of knowledge was closely associated with the great advances made in science and technology that made it possible for the members of more advanced societies to control their environment, promising greater prosperity, comfort, and happiness in the future (Adas 1989). Industrial output, average lifespan, and rates of disease could all be measured empirically and compared, providing scientific proof of which countries were more advanced, more “civilized,” than others. Similarly, one of the highest marks of civilization was to bring the fruits of modernity to a country that had not been able to progress on its own, enabling nation-states to justify colonization as either an act of altruism or enlightened self-interest (Dudden 2005: 8–9; Adas 1989: 199–270). No contradiction was seen between imperialism and liberal democracy, which, like empire-building, was seen as the mark of an advanced country. While civilization and enlightenment offered promises of a glorious tomorrow to nationalists, Social Darwinism, the application of Charles Darwin’s and Herbert Spencer’s ideas about natural selection to human society, promised a dark future should they fail to modernize. Social Darwinism held that the world was an arena where vicious struggles for survival between various nations and races took place, in Korean, literally the “strong eat and the weak are meat” (yakyuk kangsik). If the weak failed to modernize, it was their own fault, and the strong had every right to take from them what little they had, as they were simply following the scientific laws of the universe (Tikhonov 2010). One reaction to Social Darwinist visions of a world locked in eternal and bloody struggle was Pan-Asianism. According to this ideology, though of different nations (China, Japan, and Korea), because they were of the same (yellow) race, Asian people should unite against (white) imperialism (Rausch 2012). Japan was often assigned a special place by 155

Franklin Rausch

Korean nationalists as a leader and educator of other Asian countries, as it was the first one to successfully establish a modern nation-state. Chinese and Koreans who ascribed to Pan-Asianism hoped that Japan would act as a benevolent leader of Asia and help them modernize without infringing on their sovereignty. In practice, Japan would often use Pan-Asianist ideals to justify taking increasing control over its neighbors in a way little different from that of the white empires (Schmid 2002: 87–101; Ch’oe 2003: 104–13). For Korea to survive as an independent country, it needed to adopt modern nationalism and the accompanying ideologies of modernity. Doing so would mean remaking the state and its relationship to society and the nation and therefore naturally raised questions about identity. What did it mean to be a Korean? What had to be criticized and abandoned? What must be reformed? Who should Korea look to as a model of reform: China, Japan, or the United States? How much leeway should the state allow public discussions of these questions? Different Koreans answered these questions differently. For instance, in 1884 a group of “progressive” Korean officials, who believed Korea should follow Japan by adopting radical reform, launched a violent coup against another group who followed China’s more conservative model known as “selfstrengthening.” The progressives seized the king and for three days issued reforms influenced by civilization and enlightenment thought before a Chinese army restored power to the king and the pro-China faction (Cook 1982). It wasn’t just elites who reacted to Korea’s changing situation—the common people did as well. Exposure to the vagaries of international trade combined with religious oppression and government corruption led leaders of the Tonghak faith, a new religion founded in Korea in 1860, to launch a rebellion in 1894. Though the rebels, by no means all followers of the religion, initially vented their wrath against the Chosŏn state, they also attacked foreigners, and when China and Japan sent troops to help put down the rising, they fought with them too. Once this proto-nationalist movement was suppressed, fighting broke out between Chinese and Japanese troops, resulting in the Sino-Japanese War (1894–1895). Japan won the war but lost the peace when King Kojong escaped its clutches and hid in the Russian Embassy following the Japaneseordered assassination of his wife Queen Min (Duus 1995; Larsen 2008). After Kojong returned to his palace in 1897, the Chosŏn state enjoyed a period of relative peace in which it could actively pursue reform. For example, in order to break away from the Sino-centric diplomatic order and assert its own independence, King Kojong was transformed into the Kwangmu Emperor, officially making him the equal of his Chinese and Japanese counterparts. Similarly, the old gate which had been used to welcome Chinese embassies was torn down and an “Independence Gate” erected in its place. Such changes were not simply cosmetic. They contained within them deep shifts in how more and more Koreans saw their country—no longer as a vassal of China but as an independent nation-state (Schmid 2002). Similarly, there were major reforms in the government, and many Kabo-era projects begun when Korea was briefly under Japanese dominance, such as the cadastral survey and the household registry, were continued. The state also proved its willingness to actively support industry and the economic development of the country, a major change from previous Confucian-driven neglect (Hwang 2006). There were, however, numerous factors working against the Chosŏn government’s transformation into a modern nation-state. As James Palais has shown, the Chosŏn Dynasty was able to endure for so long (over 500 years) because it effectively worked out a balance of power between the throne and the yangban elite that served both their needs (1991: 4–19). The stability this brought, however, made it impossible for either the monarch or officialdom to gain the strength necessary to establish the centralized institutions needed to transform Korea into a modern nation-state capable of defending itself from foreign empires, overcoming opposition to reforms, 156

Nationalist movements before 1945

or even agreeing over what reforms needed to be taken. Moreover, the weakness of the state itself meant that it was perpetually cash-starved, and there proved to be insufficient time for its limited program of reforms to bear fruit before Korea’s independence fell victim to great power politics (Larsen 2008). The issues new ideologies also raised about Korean identity made reform difficult, in particular because of differences of opinion regarding the relationship between the Chosŏn Dynasty and the Korean nation-state. Those who saw the two as inseparable, such as the royal family and those officials whose worldview and position were dependent upon them, would not enact reforms that might harm the interests of the dynasty. This question of the nationstate and its connection to the dynasty led to an ambiguous relationship between the state and non-governmental actors in the growing public sphere as newspapers began appearing in Korea, allowing more and more Koreans to engage in public discourse. These newspapers introduced Koreans to new concepts, such as “nation” and “citizen” (utilizing the word “tongp’o” to ease the transition in thinking) and also helped spread new ideas about history and culture in which the Korean nation and people stood at the center (Pak 2008). While many of these newspapers first appeared in Chinese or in mixed Korean and Chinese, one of the most important, The Independent, was completely in han’gŭl (though it was also printed in an English edition). This newspaper was the organ of the Independence Club, founded in 1896. Dominated by proAmerican proponents of civilization and enlightenment thought, in addition to publishing its newspaper, it sponsored public speeches, meetings, and debates. Moreover, it was particularly effective at mobilizing public support and so played an important role in the return of the King from the Russian consulate, his crowning as emperor, and the erection of the Independence Gate. However, when the club was no longer deemed useful by the state and had, by working for the establishment of a legislature that would have real power and be filled with many members of the club, become a threat to the old order, it was violently suppressed. Establishing a legislature and working with the club would have helped to create the linkage between the people and the government (nationalistic democracy) necessary for building an independent nation-state. However, it would also have weakened the power of the monarch and the officials dependent on him for their power and was therefore disbanded, illustrating the limits of reform during the Kwangmu era (Chandra 1988). Despite the crushing of the Independence Club, many Koreans were still willing to work to transform their country into an enlightened nation-state in the growing public sphere as private citizens. In part, this was because civilization and enlightenment thought closely connected the progress of individuals with the advancement of their nations, encouraging non-officials to take an active role in national affairs. However, Korean activists disagreed over what should be done. Some believed that Japan would benevolently help Korea to modernize and become a truly independent state and so supported its increasing influence on the peninsula. The leadership of the Ilchinhoe, a large and powerful populist organization, was particularly welcoming and even petitioned Japan to annex Korea (Moon 2013). Similarly, those Koreans who favored Pan-Asianism might see growing Japanese involvement in the peninsula as the necessary price for modernization. Civilization and enlightenment thought thus proved to be a two-edged sword: nationalists frequently criticized Korea for its failure to live up to enlightened standards in order to spur on reform, but such criticism could also be utilized to justify Japan’s increasing control of Korea (Schmid 2002: 101–138; Wells 1990: 48–70). Even among those who agreed that independence came first, there was still the question of whether to resist peacefully or violently. While Koreans struggled over the future of their developing nation, Japan followed up its victory in the Russo-Japanese War (1904–1905) by establishing a protectorate in Korea. In 1907, 157

Franklin Rausch

the Korean Emperor secretly dispatched representatives to the peace talks being held in The Hague. As Korea had been forced to sign away its right to diplomatic representation in the 1905 protectorate treaty, this act was used as a pretext to force his abdication, leading to the ascension of his much more pliable son Sunjong (1874–1926). He in turn signed another treaty giving Japan even more power. In addition, the Korean army was disbanded. This turned out to be a mistake, as the now unemployed soldiers took their arms and fled, forming “righteous armies” (ŭibyŏng) that joined other such bands to violently oppose Japan. Their continuous attacks led Japan to undertake a brutal pacification campaign, which resulted in the deaths of thousands, mostly Koreans, including soldiers and civilians (Yong Ha Shin 1991: 207–276). Korean nationalists also engaged in individual acts of violence. In 1908, Chang In-hwan (1875–1930) and Chŏn Myŏng-un (1884–1947) assassinated Durham White Stevens (1851–1908) (Dudden 2005: 81–89).3 In December of the following year, Yi Chae-myŏng (1890–1910) severely wounded the pro-Japanese prime minister of Korea Yi Wan-yong (1857–1926). He had been inspired by An Chung-gŭn’s successful October assassination of Itō Hirobumi (Cho 1994; Rausch 2012).4 However, these lone acts of violence were not enough, and in 1910, five months after the execution of An Chung-gŭn, Japan formally annexed Korea. Korean nationalists had to shift from trying to save the nation to restoring it.

Nationalism: persecution and unity, 1910–1919 Armed resistance in the form of “righteous army” bands would continue for several years after annexation, when brutal Japanese pacification campaigns destroyed them or forced them out of the peninsula, typically to Manchuria. At the same time, Japan enacted other policies aimed at controlling and disciplining the Korean populace. The colonial police force (many of whose members were Koreans) and gendarme were expanded and given the power to both make arrests and inflict summary punishments (Chulwoo Lee 2000). For instance, the police enforced sanitary ordinances that governed the disposal of waste and where and how animals could be butchered, and could hand out summary punishments as they saw fit (Henry 2014: chapter 2). The enforcement of such laws was a part of Japan’s promise, which served to justify its colonial project in Korea, that it would modernize the country. Modernization would also allow Japan to develop and extract resources from Korea, strengthening the empire. As Japan had justified its annexation of Korea by arguing that it was best suited to modernize the country owing to their shared racial ancestry, Japan adopted a policy of assimilation, asserting that it would raise up its long-lost Korean cousins and make them into modern Japanese subjects (Caprio 2009). Nationalists naturally opposed such policies, as they would weaken a sense of Korean identity. The effects of the policy of assimilation were, however, limited because of the racial prejudice of many Japanese who both disliked Koreans and did not want them to rise, as doing so would make them competitors for limited jobs. Thus, schools, which theoretically could have done much to encourage assimilation, owing to the preferential treatment of Japanese and prejudice against Koreas, instead served as markers of separation, rather than similarity, and encouraged resistance to the regime (Oh and Kim 2013). Japanese authorities used the coercive powers of the colonial state to suppress nationalists and the threat they posed to colonial rule. For instance, the flourishing and independent Koreanlanguage press was shut down. Moreover, coercion was even used against those who might peacefully challenge the state. In 1911, 123 Korean nationalists were arrested on the false accusation that they had plotted to assassinate the Governor General of Korea. Confessions were obtained through the liberal use of torture, some of which even claimed that Protestant 158

Nationalist movements before 1945

missionaries were part of the plot and had provided weapons. In the end, 105 of these men were sentenced to prison terms of up to ten years. While limited somewhat by Western criticism, the savagery of such actions was a clear signal to nationalists that they must tread carefully lest they face brutal punishment (Kang 1997; Choi 2007). This incident illustrates an important fact about Korean nationalism during this time—its religious core. Of the 123 men arrested, the vast majority of them were Protestant Christians. While foreign missionaries sought to be apolitical and focused on evangelical activities, their status as citizens of nations that Japan had to maintain good relations with (most were Americans and British) meant that the Japanese colonial government did not have a completely free hand in how it treated members of their flock. In addition, Japan had to guarantee a certain amount of religious freedom in order to maintain its claims that it had come to bring “civilization” to Korea. Thus, churches served as spaces where Koreans could meet and discuss the issues they faced. Moreover, the churches and the institutions connected to them, particularly schools, provided a structure that could be used to organize challenges to the colonial state. Finally, while not overtly challenging the colonial state, the democratic organization of Protestant Christianity, particularly Presbyterianism, as well as the existence of missionary schools, meant that Koreans would be presented with stories of freedom and resistance against tyranny and presented with a democratic and capitalistic modernity different from that enacted by the Japanese colonial state in Korea, providing a foundation from which to challenge Japanese authority (Wells 1990: 84–89; Park 2014). Korean Protestant Christians even developed their own distinctive forms of nationalism (Wells 1990). While not Christian, the successor of Tonghak, Ch’ŏndogyo (Religion of the Heavenly Way), also, in the name of religious freedom, was given some space to develop similar ideas (Park 2015). Koreans living outside the peninsula had more freedom to openly discuss how the Korean nation could be restored. For instance, working in Shanghai, the nationalist Sin Ch’ae-ho (1880–1936), who had written biographies of Korean military heroes before annexation, continued this work in 1916 through his novel Dream of Heaven (Kkŭm hanŭl), which was dedicated to the restoration of the martial spirit in Korea (Jager 2003; Em 2000). This was itself a continuation of nationalist theorists who had argued that while the Korean state, which was seen metaphorically as a “body,” might weaken or even die, the Korean national “spirit” could continue to live, and through cultivation, regain its state (Shin 2006). The growing popularity and promise of liberalism in the 1910s, as well as the collapse of dynastic resistance to the Japanese colonial state (the royal family had been incorporated into Japan’s imperial house), led to exiled nationalist leaders Sin Kyu-sik and Pak Ŭn-sik to issue a declaration in 1917 that proclaimed that Korean sovereignty lay not in the emperor but in the people, rhetorically rejecting the Japanese empire’s attempt to use the house of Yi to control the people and aligning the nationalist movement with a republican form of government (Pak 2008). The victory of liberal democracies in World War I (1914–1918) and American president Woodrow Wilson’s calls for national self-determination, which coincided with the death of Korea’s last independent monarch, Kojong, convinced many nationalists that they should launch a movement that would peacefully demand Korean independence. Protestant and Ch’ŏndogyo nationalists, as well as some Buddhists, organized what has become known as the March First Movement. All of the signatories of the March First declaration of independence belonged to one of these three religions, and twenty-nine of them assembled in a Seoul restaurant on that day in 1919. Their declaration was read out loud, and they were then arrested by the police, leaving the movement without its leaders. The declaration was read out loud by other nationalists, with students mobilized largely through religious schools passing out copies and 159

Franklin Rausch

national flags, leading to widespread demonstrations that quickly spread throughout the peninsula, mobilizing as many as one million people (out of a population of approximately twenty million) to take part. Unfortunately, national self-determination was intended only for ethnic minorities in Europe who had been part of the defeated Central Powers—Japan was an ally and so not affected. Thus, the liberal democracies did not support the Korean bid for independence, and the Japanese colonial government, shocked at the ability of Korean nationalists to organize the movement in complete secrecy, reacted with brutal violence, killing thousands (Chong-Sik Lee 1963; Ku 1985). Though the March First Movement failed in its attempt to win independence for Korea, it illustrates two important aspects of Korean nationalism. First, the March First Movement was truly a mass movement. The suffering of colonization and the shame of foreign rule, experienced largely through the coercive power of the colonial state, which penetrated more deeply into society than the Chosŏn Dynasty, led to the painful realization of the sad fate of a nation that loses its own state. The experience of colonial rule, with accompanying ethnic prejudice, which excluded Koreans from the higher levels of power, gave Koreans a stronger sense of their own identity and a consequent desire to obtain their own state which they themselves would govern. This led to a feeling of unity among Koreans in which their national identity trumped all others, allowing people who made conflicting religious claims to work together. Secondly, not only was nationalism spreading among the Korean populace, it was reaching people who had previously stood at the margins of Korean political life—the youth and women. It was not only older men who participated in the movement, but women as well. Even in the countryside, young female teachers might lead their students in shouts of “Long live Korean independence!” (Hildi Kang 2001: Chapter 2). The entry of such new political actors is well illustrated by the poignant and tragic story of Yu Kwan-sun (1902–1920). This young woman came from a rural family who had converted to Christianity. Through their contact with Western missionaries, Yu was able to attend a Christian school, exposing her to an understanding of Protestant nationalism. This inspired her to take part in the March First Movement, leading to her arrest and death from torture in a Japanese prison. Nationalism had thus taken root as a worldview for which many Koreans, both young and old, men and women, of different religions, would struggle and die for.

Nationalism divided, 1919–1930s Almost immediately following the beginning of the March First Movement, exiled Korean nationalists leaders met in Shanghai, formally establishing the Provisional Government of the Republic of Korea in April of 1919. While very few Koreans actually lived in Shanghai, the comparative freedom of the city and its proximity to Korea and to the large Korean populations in Manchuria and the Soviet Union made it an ideal location. One of the first acts of the new government was to send a delegation to the Paris Peace Conference in an unsuccessful bid to secure Korean independence. In addition, as the provisional government sought to establish a democratic, liberal republic, it sought assistance from Western countries. The United States received particular attention, with the eventual first president of the Republic of Korea, Syngman Rhee (Yi Sŭng-man) (1875–1965), along with other Korean nationalists, making contact with American politicians and attempting to win sympathy for Korean independence through public speeches and publications. At the same time, despite its political orientations, the provisional government also made contact with the Soviet Union and received some aid from it. However, while enjoying some support at first, by 1921, factional struggles, the heavy160

Nationalist movements before 1945

handedness of its first executive, Syngman Rhee, and a lack of funds led to the decline of the government’s influence. Though it would continue to exist until Korea’s liberation in 1945, it would fail to unite all Koreans into a common nationalist struggle (Chong-Sik Lee 1963). The situation in Korea itself was quite complex. The March First Movement failed in its immediate goal of securing Korea’s independence, leading to the death of thousands. Moreover, after the refusal of Western democracies to intervene on Korea’s behalf, it was not clear what strategy Korean nationalists should turn to next. The Japanese colonial government, realizing that its previous policy had been too strict, shifted to the so-called “cultural policy.” While surveillance and the number of police actually increased under this policy, the government relaxed some of the more onerous aspects of colonial rule, for example by abandoning the policy of summary flogging (Chulwoo Lee 2000), and allowed for more space for Koreans to discuss national affairs, including even the eventual possibility of independence. Thus, though censored and at best semi-free, Koreans were able to launch their own journals and newspapers, establishing a public sphere in which they could discuss what direction Korean nationalism should take (Yong-jick Kim 2013). The new “cultural policy” led to the development of “cultural nationalism,” which abandoned attempts at immediate political reform in favor of developing Korea’s “culture.” Nationalists such as Yi Kwang-su, the Japanese-educated author of “A Theory of National Reconstruction” (Minjok kaejoron) blamed Korea’s colonization on the under-developed nature of Korean culture and argued that elite-led mass education of the Korean people would transform them morally and spiritually, bringing modernity and national independence (Robinson 2014; Shin 2006). Two examples of the activities carried out by cultural nationalists were the campaign to establish a university in Korea, which would train leaders for the future, and a movement for Koreans to buy Korean-made goods, which would further develop Korean business. By taking this approach, Korean nationalists could both work for the modernization and independence of Korea without running afoul of the massive coercive power possessed by the Japanese colonial state. While initially meeting with success, such campaigns had certain limitations. For instance, while it would not utilize naked coercion, the Japanese state undercut and subverted these movements: the colonial government established a university (though it made sure that it served the interests of Japanese living in the colony before Koreans) and courted Korean business leaders, encouraging them to choose class and empire over nation (Robinson 2014; Eckert 1991). Japanese oppression had united Koreans during the March First Movement behind a religiously affiliated leadership. However, the growing public sphere, the failure of liberal democracies to assist Korea, and the success of the Russian Revolution (1917) led some Korean nationalists to turn away from such “bourgeois” forms of nationalism and look to Marxism and socialism as both an alternative means of modernization and as a way gaining national independence. Korean newspapers and journals began to discuss such ideas more freely and Korean Communist parties were even established in Russia (1918) and in Shanghai (1919). A Communist party was even established for a short time in Korea in 1925 before it was forcibly disbanded by the Japanese colonial state (it would be reformed and dissolved several more times) (Ch’ŏn 2008). While the rise of the nationalist left, made possible by the new “cultural policy,” divided the nationalist movement, there were attempts at union. For instance, from 1927 to 1931, left and right united in the Sin’ganhoe (New Trunk Association) to pursue nationalist activities. However, in the end, the left, led by underground Communists, dissolved the organization, realizing that instead of being able to use it to control the nationalist right, it was undermining 161

Franklin Rausch

their own cohesion (Chong-Sik Lee 1963; Ch’ŏn 2008). Such a result is not surprising considering the theoretical differences between the sides. The left saw the right, which within the Korean was comprised almost wholly of cultural nationalists, as unrealistic in their belief that once Korea became sufficiently advanced enough, Japan would just peacefully permit Korean independence. Moreover, even if they did obtain independence, Korea would still face the class divisions and economic inequality that leftists opposed. In fact, the left saw the university and buy Korean movements as attempts by rightist nationalists to selfishly pursue their own class interests under the cloak of Korean nationalism. Instead of emphasizing such bourgeois concerns, leftist nationalists argued that Koreans should focus on the workers and peasants. Moreover, rather than pursuing apolitical movements, nationalists should seek alliances with socialist movements in other countries in order to bring worldwide national and economic revolutions (Robinson 2014). Though ultimately correct that the Japanese empire would not simply allow Korea to go without a fight, whenever the left attempted to organize anything like a political revolution, it faced the full force of state coercion (Caprio 2013). Thus, on the peninsula itself, the rise of the left split the nationalist movement and exposed the limitations of cultural nationalism but was unable to establish a new strategy that could unite the movement or resolve the basic issue that allowed Japan to control Korea: its near complete monopoly of the use of violence. At the center of these divisions was the fact that nationalism is not an all-encompassing ideology that can exist on its own. Nationalism had to mix with another ideology, be it liberal democracy or socialism, in order to establish a working government. No longer not the only hegemonic force within Korean nationalism, but facing criticism that religion actually prevented the rise of modernity and national liberation, religious nationalists also looked to their own traditions to develop ways to deal with both the problem of colonization and the growing economic and social dislocations that arose from Korea’s increasing integration into both the Japanese empire and the world economy. In addition to being important leaders within traditional cultural nationalist circles that sought to make Korea a Christian democracy similar to the United States, some religious leaders, particularly Protestants and members of Ch’ŏndogyo, looked to a reconstructed and revitalized countryside as providing an alternative path to modernity outside of both industrial capitalism and socialism in which villages organized around spirituality, selfsupport, and mutual aid would resolve the serious economic and social issues Korea faced and allow the peasants to live happy and fulfilled lives. Moreover, these movements located Korean national identity within the countryside, with the implication that the liberation of the peasantry would also lead to national liberation (Park 2015). The “cultural policy” also meant a greater space for Korean scholars to conduct research, access new intellectual trends, and publish their findings. And since scholars who were proponents of the Japanese colonial project in Korea presented the policy of assimilation as a kind of family reunion and presented pre-annexation Korea as a stagnant country that could not govern itself, it was natural for Korean nationalists to enter the world of academia to challenge such claims, thereby chipping away at the arguments justifying colonization. In particular, Korean nationalist historians looked back to ancient history to show the existence of powerful, advanced Korean states. For instance, Ch’oe Nam-sŏn (1890–1957), the author of the March First Movement’s declaration of independence, presented Tan’gun, the putative ancestor of the Korean nation, as a historical figure who had ruled a major civilization. Such focus on Tan’gun pointed to an essentialized, immutable, and biological origin of Korean identity, signifying that imperial attempts at assimilation were doomed to fail. Similarly, studies on Korean language, linguistics, and literature were also intended to heighten a sense of difference between Koreans and Japanese, a necessary defense against assimilation and a foundation from which to build a future nationstate (Shin 2006). 162

Nationalist movements before 1945

Years of violence, 1931–1945 While the Japanese colonial state was willing to tolerate the nationalist movement within the peninsula to a certain degree, those who went too far faced its coercive power, suffering torture, imprisonment, and death. The coercive power of the government meant that, with the exception of largely spontaneous outbursts of violence, such as the student protests of 1929 that were sparked by Japanese harassment of Korean schoolgirls, nationalist movements within the peninsula remained largely peaceful. In contrast, nationalists in exile had more freedom to work for independence, and while some, like Syngman Rhee, would utilize peaceful means, such as attempting to win American support for Korean independence (Lew 2014), others would turn to violence. In particular, after the mid-1910s, violent resistance to Japanese colonial rule in Korea was centered largely in Manchuria, as large areas within it were outside the reach of Japan or any effective government for that matter. Korean nationalists located there would launch raids across the border into Korea or attack Japanese targets within the region. As on the peninsula, these Korean nationalists were not united, particularly after the Russian Revolution and the growing interest of Koreans in Communism. Fighting could even break out between Communist and non-Communist Korean nationalists, though over time, the former became the dominant force, thanks to assistance from the Soviet Union and later from Chinese Communists (ChongSik Lee 1963; Yŏm 2008). Something of the shape and significance, as well as the limitations, of the Korean nationalist movement in Manchuria can be seen in the early career of Kim Il Sung, the future dictator of North Korea. Kim’s father died while he was young, soon to be followed by his mother, leaving the young man an orphan. Fortunately for Kim, he had an opportunity to receive an education, attending both Korean and Chinese-language schools and completing the eighth grade, before he fell in with a Communist guerrilla band in Manchuria. Kim proved to be an adept guerrilla fighter whose active career lasted from 1932 to 1941, a time when many guerrilla fighters were killed or defected to the Japanese. Moreover, Kim won several significant victories against Japanese forces in battles involving hundreds of men and even managed to destroy a Japanese police station in Korea. However, increasing Japanese power in Manchuria forced him to retreat to the Soviet Union in 1941, where he would remain largely inactive until Japan’s surrender. In fact, Kim was absorbed formally into the Soviet Union’s army, a connection that helped ensure that country’s support but illustrates the limitations of Korea’s power. Similarly, under the principle of “one country, one party,” Kim was forced to join the Chinese Communist Party. This, along with the fact that Kim frequently fought under Chinese command in armies with a Chinese majority, illustrates how Korean Communists were largely under the control of their more powerful allies. At the same time, it was such links that helped insure Chinese and Soviet support for the establishment of the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea with Kim at its head and his failed 1950 invasion of Korea (Suh 1988; Yŏm 2008). Right-wing nationalists also engaged in violence. Kim Ku (1876–1949), operating out of Shanghai and receiving support from overseas Koreans in places like Hawaii, organized two well-known violent attacks against Japanese targets. The first, known as the Sakuradamon Incident, occurred in January of 1931 when Yi Pong-chang (1900–1932) threw a hand grenade at what he thought was Japanese Emperor Hirohito’s carriage (he had the wrong one). The attack only killed two horses, but Japanese attempts to censor positive Chinese news accounts of the incident led to increased tensions and were likely one of the causes of the 1932 Shanghai Incident. The second, known as the Hongkou Park Incident, occurred in Shanghai in April of that year and involved Korean nationalist Yun Pong-gil (1908–1932) throwing a bomb at a crowd of Japanese dignitaries gathered in honor of the emperor’s birthday, killing a Japanese general and official. 163

Franklin Rausch

While Yi and Yun were executed, and Kim Ku himself would have been captured by the Japanese if it were not for Chinese assistance, the attacks did show that Koreans were willing to resist Japan and that at least some were willing to die for Korean independence. Furthermore, the attacks won Kim Ku Chinese support, allowing him to revive the moribund Korean Provisional Government and for the training and equipping of Korean soldiers and spies to be used against Japan. Such support would increase following Japan’s invasion of China in 1937 (Chong-Sik Lee 1963). While those nationalists outside of Korea could work positively for nationalist goals, those inside the country would find it increasingly difficult after the Manchurian Incident of 1931 to do anything but survive increasing Japanese pressure with something of their principles intact. In response to the rise in militarism in Japan in the 1930s, pressure on Koreans to assimilate, and after 1937, assist in Japan’s war effort against China, rapidly increased. For instance, beginning in 1934, only Japanese could be used at schools. In 1939, independent Korean newspapers, which had come under ever stricter censorship, were forced out of business. In that same year, Koreans were also forced to adopt Japanese surnames. Any independent Korean institutes were either dissolved or subverted and taken over. Whereas during the dark years of the first decade of colonial rule, churches had served as a sanctuary for some now limited freedom, Koreans were forced, often through heavy-handed tactics and transparent coercion, to worship at Shintō Shrines. Christians, particularly conservative Protestants, fiercely opposed such measures, leading to imprisonment and the death of several dozen while they were in custody (Choi 2007; Park 2015; Wi Jo Kang 1997). Under such conditions, many Koreans, including nationalists, who lived under Japanese rule were forced to publicly participate in ritualistic acts demonstrating their loyalty to the empire, such as bowing at Shintō Shrines. For many, such acts were carried out grudgingly and out of fear—and for the Japanese colonial state, that was enough (Hildi Kang 2001). However, outspoken nationalists were expected to issue public statements exhorting Koreans to participate in the war effort, praise the emperor, and proclaim their loyalty to the empire. Nationalists such as Ch’oe Nam-sŏn and Yi Kwang-su gave in. While such acts of national apostasy could be read simply as giving in out of a desire to reap the benefits of collaboration and avoid the substantial losses that would have accrued with, what must have appeared quixotic, acts of bravery. Particularly in the early years of the war when Japan was winning, the attractions and power of Japanese modernity and the Pan-Asianism that promised to liberate Asia from Western imperialism must have been persuasive. For nationalists who had spent years of suffering and pain to seemingly no avail, with Japan promising to become ever more powerful with the prospects of spreading its influence throughout Asia, the temptation to join what appeared to be the winning team must have been strong (Michael Kim 2007). Following the war, Yi Kwangsu even argued that he had sought to act as a shield for the Korean people—resistance would not have worked—the Japanese would have simply taken the resources and labor they desired. Better than to work with them, in victory Koreans would share in the spoils, in defeat, as colonial subjects, they could not be blamed (Treat 2012). Moreover, one could in a sense both believe in the empire and be a Korean nationalist—that seems to have been the case with Park Chunghee, future dictator of the Republic of Korea, who both wrote a letter in blood to the Japanese Emperor asking to be admitted into a military academy and exalted national heroes, such as Yi Sun-shin, famous for fighting against the Japanese (Chong-Sik Lee 2012). In the end, Japan would be defeated and Korea liberated, not substantially through any Korean actions but through the forces of geo-politics. The lack of a distinctly Korean victory meant there would be no single Korean person or party that could claim credit and use that prestige 164

Nationalist movements before 1945

to effectively unite the Korean people. Instead, right-wing nationalists, through the patronage of the United States and the United Nations, would gain power in the south, with Communist nationalists eventually gaining power in the north under the sponsorship of the Soviet Union. Left- and right-wing visions of what an independent and modern Korean state should look like led to a fratricidal civil war that killed millions of Koreans and hundreds of thousands of American, Chinese, and United Nations forces. But unlike most other civil wars, international intervention, while aiding the belligerents for a time, prevented them ultimately from finishing the war. Koreans would thus obtain part of the nationalist dream, national independence, and, at least in the south, modernity, but would still feel the heavy hand of great power politics. The painful psychic wound of the failure to obtain the nationalist goal of one nation, one state, despite liberation from colonial rule, continues to haunt the peninsula. The continued division of Korea still serves as a potential point of conflict and of proliferation of nuclear weapons. Internally, the colonial period and the nationalism that developed during it still influence the two Koreas to this day. North Korean concerns about independence are rooted much in the desire to avoid foreign domination once again, and even in a globalized South Korea, antiJapanese feelings, particularly over such emotional issues as the comfort women and collaboration with the Japanese, are still strong. The anti-colonial nature of Korean nationalism, by emphasizing the importance of autonomy and independence, can mask the fact that Japanese nationalism has also shaped that of Korea. North Korea’s xenophobic nationalism focused on the purity of the Korean race owes much to Japanese ultra-nationalism (Myers 2011), and Park Chŏng-hee (Pak Chong-hŭi) consciously patterned much of his own style of rule after Japanese history (Chong-Sik Lee 2012).

Areas for further research A great deal of excellent work has been done on Korean nationalism, particularly in examining the connection between nationalism and other ideologies. Recently, English-language scholarship on nationalism has been willing to challenge nationalist narratives—for instance, Yumi Moon, in her work on the Ilchinhoe, frequently seen from the nationalist perspective as arch-traitors, has sensitively explored their perspective, showing how many of its members were guided by a sincere populism. Similarly, Brandon Palmer’s recent work on Japanese mobilization of Koreans for labor and military service, while carefully tracing the use of force in such efforts, also shows that at least some Koreans volunteered freely and used what limited agency they possessed to advance within the empire (2013) rather than to work against it. In general, English-language scholarship tends to focus on narratives that challenge nationalism and to take critical approach focusing on deconstruction. While an important balance for Koreanlanguage scholarship, which is often written from a nationalist perspective, the emphasis on such studies among scholars working in English has led to certain lacunae. With the possible exception of Gi-Wook Shin’s work (2006), there has not been a comprehensive history of Korean nationalism in English since Chong-Sik Lee (1963). English monographs focusing on a particular nationalist figure, even important ones such as Kim Ku or Cho Man-sik, are also largely lacking. While religion is closely related to Korean nationalism, studies on such connections are often hagiographical in nature, focusing on how a particular religion helped serve the Korean nation. A notable exception is Albert Park’s recent book on rural reconstruction efforts among Ch’ŏndogyo activists and Protestant Christians, which, while focusing primarily on modernity, touches on nationalism because of its subjects focused on a distinctly agrarian Korean nation, illustrating the rich work still yet to be done on religion and nationalism (Park 2015). More 165

Franklin Rausch

such studies are needed, particularly ones that focus on new Korean religions, which, despite often being established by Korean nationalist leaders, receive little attention in English-language sources. Thus, while the foundation for research on Korean nationalism has been established, the house is still far from complete, and more builders are certainly needed.

Notes 1 2

3 4

It should be noted that the word “Korea” itself is a modern term. According to legend, a god descended in what is now the Korean peninsula and was approached by a tiger and a bear, who both wanted to be human. The god told them that they could, if they stayed within a cave and ate only certain types of food. The tiger was unable to do so, but the bear did and was transformed into a beautiful human woman. She and the god then begat a son, Tan’gun—the ancestor of the Korean people. Durham White Stevens was an American who technically worked for the Korean government but actually served Japanese interests. It is interesting to note that all of these nationalists were also Christians (both Catholic and Protestant).

References Adas, Michael. (1989) Machines as the Measure of Men: Science, Technology, and Ideologies of Western Dominance, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Caprio, Mark E. (2009) Japanese Assimilation Policies in Colonial Korea, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. –––– . (2013) ‘The 1920s Colonial Reforms and June 10 (1926) Movement’, in Hong Yung Lee, YongChool Ha, and Clark W. Sorensen (eds.) Colonial Rule and Social Change in Korea, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Chandra, Vipan. (1988) Imperialism, Resistance and Reform in Late Nineteenth-Century Korea: Enlightenment and the Independence Club, Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, Berkeley. Cho, Kwang. (1994) ‘An Chunggŭn ŭi aeguk kyemong undong kwa tongnip chŏnjaeng [An Chunggŭn’s patriotic enlightenment movement and independence war]’, Kyohoesa yŏn’gu 9 (November): 65–96. Ch’oe, Kiyŏng. (2003) Han’guk kŭndae kyemong sasang yŏn’gu [A study of modern Korean enlightenment thought], Seoul: Ilchogak. Choi, Jai-Keun. (2007) The Korean Church under Japanese Colonialism, Seoul: Jimoondang. Ch’ŏn, Myŏng-hyŏk. (2008) ‘Sahoe chŭi inyŏm kwa undong’ [Socialist ideology and movements], in Han’guksa yŏn’guhoe (ed.) Saeroun Han’guksa kiljabi [New guiderail to history], Seoul: Chisik sanŏbsa. Chung, Chai-Sik. (1995) A Korean Confucian Encounter with the Modern World: Yi Hang-no and the West, Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, Berkeley. Cook, Harold F. (1982) Korea’s 1884 Incident: Its Background and Kim Ok-kyun’s Elusive Dream, Seoul: Royal Asiatic Society, Korean Branch. Craig, Albert M. (2009) Civilization and Enlightenment: The Early Thought of Fukuzawa Yukichi, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Deuchler, Martina. (1977) Confucian Gentlemen and Barbarian Envoys: The Opening of Korea, 1875–1885, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. –––– . (1992) The Confucian Transformation of Korea: A Study of Society and Ideology, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Dudden, Alexis. (2005) Japan’s Colonization of Korea: Discourse and Power, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Duus, Peter. (1995) The Abacus and the Sword: The Japanese Penetration of Korea, 1895–1910, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Eckert, Carter J. (1991) Offspring of Empire: The Koch’ang Kims and the Colonial Origins of Korean Capitalism, 1876–1945, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Em, Henry. (2000) ‘Minjok as a Modern and Democratic Construct: Sin Ch’aeho’s Historiography’, in G. Shin and M. Robinson (eds.) Colonial Modernity in Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. –––– . (2013) The Great Enterprise: Sovereignty and Historiography in Modern Korea, Durham, NC: Duke University Press. 166

Nationalist movements before 1945

Gat, Azar, with Alexander Yakobson. (2012) Nations: The Long History and Deep Roots of Political Ethnicity and Nationalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Haboush, JaHyun Kim. (1999) ‘Constructing the Center: The Ritual Controversy and the Search for a New Identity in Seventeenth-Century Korea’, in J. Kim Haboush and M. Deuchler (eds.) Culture and State in Late Chosŏn Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Hawley, Samuel. (2005) The Imjin War: Japan’s Sixteenth-Century Invasion of Korea and Attempt to Conquer China, Seoul: Royal Asiatic Society, Korea Branch. Henry, Todd A. (2014) Assimilating Seoul: Japanese Rule and the Politics of Public Space in Colonial Korea, 1910–1945, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Hwang, Kyung Moon. (2005) Beyond Birth: Social Status in the Emergence of Modern Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. –––– . (2006) ‘Government Growth in the Taehan Empire Era: Origins of the Modern Korean State’, in Dong-no Kim, John B. Duncan, and Kim Do-hyung (eds.) Reform and Modernity in the Korean Empire, Seoul: Jimoondang. Jager, Sheila Miyoshi. (2003) Narratives of Nation Building in Korea: A Genealogy of Patriotism, Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Kallander, George. (2013) Salvation through Dissent: Tonghak Heterodoxy and Early Modern Korea, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Kang, Hildi. (2001) Under the Black Umbrella: Voices from Colonial Korea, 1910–1945, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Kang, Wi Jo. (1997) Christ and Caesar in Modern Korea: A History of Christianity in Politics, Albany, NY: State University of New York Press. Kim, Dong-no, John B. Duncan, and Kim Do-hyung. (2006) Reform and Modernity in the Korean Empire, Seoul: Jimoondang. Kim, Hwansoo. (2014) ‘Seeking the Colonizer’s Favors for a Buddhist Vision: The Korean Buddhist Nationalist Paek Yongŏng’s (1864–1940) Imje Sŏn Movement and His Relationship with the Japanese Colonize Abe Mitsuie (1862–1936)’, Sungkyun Journal of East Asian Studies 14, no. 2 (April): 171–193. Kim, Kwangshik. (2000) ‘Buddhist Perspectives on Anti-religious Movements in the 1930s’, Review of Korean Studies 3, no. 1 (July): 55–75. Kim, Marie Seong-hak. (2012) Law and Custom in Korea: Comparative Legal History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kim, Michael. (2007) ‘The Aesthetics of Total Mobilisation in the Visual Culture of Late Colonial Korea’, Totalitarian Movements and Political Religions 8, no. 3–4 (September–December): 483–502. Kim, Yong-jick. (2013) ‘Politics of Communication and the Colonial Public Sphere’, in Hong Yung Lee, Yong-Chool Ha, and Clark W. Sorensen (eds.) Colonial Rule and Social Change in Korea, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Ku, Dae-yeol. (1985) Korea under Colonialism: The March First Movement and Anglo-Japanese Relations, Seoul: Royal Asiatic Society, Korea Branch, Seoul Computer Press. Larsen, Kirk. (2008) Tradition, Treaties, and Trade: Qing Imperialism and Chosŏn Korea, 1850–1910, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. Lee, Chong-Sik. (1963) The Politics of Korean Nationalism, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. –––– . (2012) Park Chung-hee: From Poverty to Power, Palos Verdes: The KHU Press. Lee, Chulwoo. (2000) ‘Modernity, Legality, and Power in Korea under Japanese Rule’, in G. Shin and M. Robinson (eds.) Colonial Modernity in Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Lee, Timothy. (2009) ‘What Should Christians Do about a Shaman-Progenitor?: Evangelicals and Ethnic Nationalism in South Korea’, Church History 78, no. 1 (March): 66–98. Lew, Young Ick. (2014) The Making of the First Korean President: Syngman Rhee’s quest for Independence, 1875–1948, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Myers, B. R. (2011) The Cleanest Race: How North Koreans See Themselves—And Why It Matters, Brooklyn, NY: Melville House. Moon, Yumi. (2013) Populist Collaborators: The Ilchinhoe and the Japanese Colonization of Korea, 1896–1910, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Oh, Seong-cheol and Ki-seok Kim. (2013) ‘Expansion of Elementary Schooling under Colonialism: Top Down or Bottom Up?’, in Hong Yung Lee, Yong-Chool Ha, and Clark W. Sorensen (eds.) Colonial Rule and Social Change in Korea, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Palmer, Brandon. (2013) Fighting for the Enemy: Koreans in Japan’s War, 1937–1945, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. 167

Franklin Rausch

Pak, Ch’an-sŭng. (2008) ‘Minjok chuŭi inyŏm kwa undong’ [Nationalist ideology and movements], in Han’guksa yŏn’guhoe (ed.) Saeroun Han’guksa kiljabi [New guiderail to history], Seoul: Chisik sanŏbsa. –––– . (2010) Minjok, Minjok chuŭi [Nation, Nationalism], Seoul: Sohwa. Palais, James. (1991) Politics and Policy in Traditional Korea, Cambridge, MA: Council on East Asian Studies, Harvard University. Park, Albert L. (2014) ‘A Sacred Economy of Value and Production: Capitalism and Protestantism in Early Modern Korea (1885–1919)’, in Encountering Modernity: Christianity in East Asia and Asian America, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. –––– . (2015) Building a Heaven on Earth: Religion, Activism, and Protest in Japanese Occupied Korea, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Park, Chung-Shin. (2003) Protestantism and Politics in Korea, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Park, Hyun Ok. (2005) Two Dreams in One Bed: Empire, Social Life, and the Origins of the North Korean Revolution in Manchuria, Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Rausch, Franklin. (2012) ‘Visions of Violence, Dreams of Peace: Religion, Race, and Nation in An Chunggŭn’s A Treatise on Peace in the East’, Acta Koreana 15, no. 2 (December): 263–291. Robinson, Michael Edson. (2014) Cultural Nationalism in Colonial Korea, 1920–1925, 2nd Edition, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press. Schmid, Andre. (2002) Korea between Empires, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Shin, Gi-Wook. (2006) Ethnic Nationalism in Korea: Genealogy, Politics, and Legacy, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Shin, Yong Ha. (1991) Formation and Development of Modern Korean Nationalism, Seoul: Dae Kwang Munhwasa. Suh, Dae-Sook. (1988) Kim Il Sung: The North Korean Leader, New York, NY: Columbia University Press. Tikhonov, Vladimir. (2010) Social Darwinism and Nationalism in Korea: The Beginnings 1880s–1910s, Survival as an Ideology of Korean Modernity, Leiden, Netherlands: Brill. Treat, John Whittier. (2012) ‘Choosing to Collaborate: Yi Kwang-su and the Moral Subject in Colonial Korea’, The Journal of Asian Studies 71, no. 1 (February): 81–102. Weems, Benjamin B. (1964) Reform, Rebellion and the Heavenly Way, Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press. Wells, Kenneth M. (1990) New God, New Nation: Protestants and Self-Reconstruction Nationalism in Korea, 1896–1937, Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. Yŏm, Inho. (2008) ‘Hangil Chŏnsŏn T’ongil kwa Minjok haebang undong’ [Anti-Japanese frontline of the unification and national liberation movements], in Han’guksa yŏn’guhoe (ed.) Saeroun Han’guksa kiljabi [New guiderail to history], Seoul: Chisik sanŏbsa. Yoo, Mi-rim. (2006) ‘King Sejong’s Leadership and the Politics of Inventing the Korean Alphabet’, The Review of Korean Studies 9, no. 3 (September): 7–38.

168

Part III

Division and war

This page intentionally left blank

12 The division of Korea and the rise of two Koreas, 1945–1948 Jongsoo Lee

When Emperor Hirohito announced Japan’s surrender in World War II on August 15, 1945, there was euphoria among Koreans both in and outside the Korean peninsula. As they rejoiced in their liberation from 36 years of Japanese colonial rule, they expected speedy restoration of independence to Korea as a sovereign state. However, what soon greeted them was not immediate independence but the partition of the peninsula into two halves at the 38th parallel by the occupying troops of the Soviet Union and the United States. Although these foreign troops were welcomed as liberators, Koreans grew increasingly unhappy as time went on and it became clear that immediate restoration of independence was not forthcoming and that the partition of the peninsula was becoming more permanent. The story of how the Korean peninsula was partitioned at the 38th parallel is a classic example of Great Power politics, reminiscent of the partition of the Americas since the voyages by Columbus, the partition of Africa at the Berlin Conference of 1884–1885 and the partition of the ex-Ottoman territories after World War I by the European colonial powers. In these cases, “understandings” were reached, either officially or in secret agreements, among the European colonial powers, and the European powers arbitrarily redrew the boundaries of these lands to suit their own interests often in ways that did not reflect the existing political, ethnic, tribal, cultural or linguistic loyalties and solidarities. The opinions of the native Americans, Africans, Arabs and other peoples, whose lands were being divided up by the European colonial powers, were not consulted. Therefore, although the masses of Koreans rejoiced on August 15, 1945, those Korean leaders who understood the realities of international power politics and the geopolitical balance of power in Northeast Asia had much to worry about Korea’s future after Japan’s defeat. Kim Ku, a prominent leader of the exiled Korean nationalist independence activists in China, later recorded in his memoirs that the news of the Japanese surrender came not as a cause for jubilation but rather as an occasion for utmost concern and disappointment. Leaders such as Kim Ku knew that Japan’s defeat was achieved by the military might of the Allied Powers and that the Koreans themselves contributed little militarily to the Allied victory. In the case of Kim, Kim and his Korean Provisional Government in exile in China had been covertly working with the United States Office of Strategic Services to prepare operations by KPG’s military units in Japaneseoccupied Korea. The sudden surrender of Japan came before KPG could play this military role 171

Jongsoo Lee

in defeating Japan. The Korean leaders such as Kim were worried, therefore, that the fate of Korea was now in the hands of the foreign powers that defeated Japan, not in the hands of the Koreans. Their worst fear was that Korea would once again become a playground for Great Power intrigue and rivalries and that the Koreans would be denied full restoration of sovereignty. True to the fears of these Korean leaders, the future of Korea in late 1945 was precarious indeed. The only officially announced wartime international agreement among the Allied leaders concerning Korea’s future upon Japan’s defeat was the so-called Cairo Declaration, a joint statement issued in 1943 by the leaders of the United States, Britain and nationalist China and later endorsed by the Soviet Union, which proclaimed Korea’s independence in due course. The Korean leaders welcomed this promise of independence but opposed the phrase “in due course,” as they wanted immediate independence. Indeed, the understanding reached among the wartime Allied leaders which underlay the “in due course” provision was that the Koreans were not ready for self-rule and that they needed a period of tutelage by the Allied Powers, who would administer an international trusteeship over Korea until such time as when the Koreans would be deemed capable of self-government. The concept of trusteeship as contemplated by the Allied leaders during World War II was itself based on the prior precedent of the League of Nations mandates, which was devised by the Western Powers as a transitional governance mechanism for the non-Western colonies of those Powers that were defeated in World War I, namely, imperial Germany and the Ottoman Empire. Examples of the League of Nations mandates that were implemented after World War I include Lebanon and Syria, both administered by France, and German Southwest Africa (presently Namibia), which was controlled by the Union of South Africa. Underlying both the League of Nations mandate system and the trusteeship idea was the assumption that the people living in the territories that would be subject to these governance mechanisms were not ready for self-rule and would need a period of tutelage in the arts of self-governance before being granted full independence. In line with this view that the Koreans were not capable of immediate self-rule, the Allied Powers during World War II, including the US, did not officially recognize any Korean group that claimed to represent the Korean people as the legitimate government of Korea. There were numerous Korean organizations of varying ideological and political persuasions that were agitating for Korean independence during the Japanese colonial rule over Korea (1910–1945), and many of these groups, including the aforementioned Korean Provisional Government, were based overseas given the harsh Japanese colonial rule in Korea, which effectively suppressed pro-independence movements within the peninsula especially after the March First Independence Movement in 1919, a peaceful nationwide grassroots demonstration that proclaimed Korean independence. However, later disunity among these various Korean groups that struggled for independence from Japan was a contributing factor in this Allied policy of non-recognition, as the Allied governments came to view the Korean independence movement as fragmented and considered no one group as broadly representative of the Korean people. When the surrender of the Japanese seemed imminent in the last days of World War II in August 1945, the United States was preoccupied with the future of Japan, a soon-to-be defeated Great Power, and the US policy was focused on ensuring that postwar Japan would become an ally of the United States and never again a threat. Korea, a colonial dependency of Japan, was at best an afterthought as a policy priority in the minds of the top US officials charged with planning the future postwar world order. If Korea possessed a strategic value, it was thought of mainly as an outpost for the future defense of US-occupied Japan. For the Soviet Union, whose entry into the war against Japan in August 1945 decisively contributed to Japan’s surrender, its leaders were also concerned with preventing a future Japan that would be hostile to the USSR. 172

Division of Korea and rise of two Koreas

After all, Japan had been an imperial rival of Russia, having won the Russo-Japanese War (1905), invaded the Russian Far East in the aftermath of the Bolshevik Revolution and threatened the security of the USSR as an ally of Nazi Germany. However, despite its efforts to secure a role in the postwar occupation of Japan, the USSR was denied any meaningful role there by the United States, which was determined to keep Japan in the capitalist world order and forestall a rise of communism there amid conditions of war-devastation and popular disaffection. Having been denied a role in postwar Japan, the Soviets apparently attached more importance than did the Americans to the postwar future of Korea, given the fact that the Korean peninsula was used by Japan in recent history as a platform for attacks on the Russian Far East and thus possessed an important strategic value. Therefore, when the US officials faced the question of what to do about Korea in the last days of World War II as Japan’s surrender seemed imminent, they apparently had no idea beyond a vague awareness of the wartime Allied agreement that the peninsula would be liberated from Japanese rule but would be subject to Allied occupation until such time as when the Koreans would be deemed capable of self-government.1 Given this, the officials in Washington, D.C., responsible for US policies towards East Asia could manage no better than to hurriedly entrust two colonels with the task of devising a formula acceptable to the Soviets for the Allied military occupation of the peninsula, which would, among other things, accept the surrender of the Japanese troops and maintain law and order until a further Allied agreement on the future of the peninsula could be worked out. When Dean Rusk and Charles Bonesteel took out a map of the Korean peninsula and studied it on the night of August 14, 1945, they knew that the Soviet troops were already advancing south in northern parts of the peninsula and that the US forces were not in a position to arrive in Korea anytime soon.2 Under time pressure to propose a formula before the Soviets occupied all of the peninsula and probably thinking that the US was militarily not in a position to ask the Soviets to withdraw their troops completely from the peninsula, they proposed the 38th parallel to the Soviets because it would divide the peninsula into roughly two equal-sized halves and leave Seoul, the capital, in the proposed US zone of occupation. The opinions of the Korean people were not consulted in this process, and neither did it seem to dawn on these two colonels that they could be fatally undermining the future of the Korean people by proposing a partition of the peninsula that could become permanent. Somewhat to the surprise of the US officials, the Soviets accepted this proposal. There are possible reasons as to why the Soviets accepted this US proposal of the division along the 38th parallel, one being that it reminded them of an old turn-of-the-century spheres of influence discussion between imperial Japan and czarist Russia to divide up the peninsula between themselves also at the 38th parallel.3 In this fashion, therefore, the peninsula was partitioned without the consent of the Korean people and definitely against their will. Although there were disagreements among the Koreans, it was clear that no Korean wanted their country to be arbitrarily divided in this manner, dealing a crippling blow to the organic unity of their country and economy, not to mention physically separating family members living on both sides of the dividing line and inviting the strong likelihood of a civil war to reunite the peninsula. The situation on the Korean peninsula in late 1945 became the following: the occupation forces of the Soviet Union that arrived in August and of the United States that arrived in September accepted the surrender of the Japanese and carried out their respective occupation policies in their zones of administration, while various Koreans groups of differing ideological and political orientations jockeyed for leadership and legitimacy among the Korean masses whom they purported to represent. These Korean groups and their leaders differed not only in terms of their ideological or general political orientations but also in terms such as their relationships with the occupation authorities and with one another. Some of these groups and leaders spent 173

Jongsoo Lee

the bulk of the Japanese colonial years living inside Korea (such as Yǒ Un-hyǒng, a moderate leftist, and Song Chin-u, Kim Song-su and Cho Man-sik, right-wing nationalists), while some spent those years in exile overseas, including the United States (such as Syngman Rhee [Yi Sŭng-man], a right-wing nationalist) and China (such as Kim Ku, a right-wing nationalist, Kim Kyu-sik, a moderate rightist, and Kim Il Sung, a leftist anti-Japanese partisan leader). Unfortunately for the future of Korea, these various Korean groups and their leaders could not form a united front vis-à-vis the foreign occupation powers. What drove these Korean groups and leaders even further apart was the decision reached at the Conference of Allied Foreign Ministers in Moscow in December 1945, which placed Korea under a United Nations Trusteeship for a period of up to five years. While almost all Korean groups initially opposed this decision, most leftist groups later changed their position in favor of it, and thereafter the rift between the left and the right in Korea grew irreparably large, as violence among the Koreans escalated, poisoning intra-Korean cooperation. It was in this atmosphere of escalating tensions between the left and the right in Korea and also between the USSR and the Anglo-American powers in the rising global Cold War that the US-USSR Joint Commissions in Korea were convened in 1946–1947 in order to carry out the trusteeship plan as announced at the Moscow Conference of Allied Foreign Ministers. A key element of the US-USSR Joint Commissions was the effort to form a left-right coalition among the Korean leaders as the nucleus of a future united Korean government that would work with the Allied trustee powers under the proposed UN Trusteeship. However, this effort failed, as the Americans and the Soviets could not agree on the composition of such a coalition body and their occupation policies in their respective zones of administration grew only more divergent as time went on.4 In the Soviet-occupied northern Korea, a radical transformation took place as a Soviet-style socialist regime and society was built there with sweeping changes such as land reform and nationalization of key industries. Kim Il Sung (Kim Il-sŏng), who returned to northern Korea in 1945 as an officer in the Soviet occupation forces, rose to power under Soviet support and managed to consolidate his power over rivals such as the nationalist leader Cho Man-sik, who was placed under house arrest in early 1946 for his strong opposition to the Moscow trusteeship decision. In the US-occupied southern Korea, the American military government made much less sweeping changes than those that were taking place in the north, and a main focus of the occupation became the preservation of the status quo against leftist agitation and subversion. As time wore on, Syngman Rhee managed to prevail over other leaders such as Yŏ Un-hyŏng, Song Chin-u, and Kim Ku (all of whom were assassinated). With the failure of the US-USSR Joint Commissions to implement the trusteeship, what followed next was the policy of the United States to refer the Korean question to the United Nations General Assembly while simultaneously making preparations for a separate South Korean state as a fallback option in case the U.N. also failed to resolve the problem. The United Nations, then under the sway of the United States and her allies, proceeded to set up the U.N. Temporary Commission on Korea (UNTCOK), which was charged with the task, among others, of observing the implementation of elections in both zones of occupation in Korea for the creation of a unified Korean government. This effort to refer the Korean question to the U.N., however, met the resolute opposition of the USSR, which protested against what it regarded as the illegal transfer of the Korean question onto the U.N. agenda and instead called for the simultaneous withdrawal of US and Soviet troops from Korea. Consequently, meeting the Soviet refusal to allow the entry of the UNTCOK into northern Korea, the U.N. proceeded to observe the implementation of elections in the US-occupied southern Korea only. In response, an important bloc of Korean leaders in southern Korea, 174

Division of Korea and rise of two Koreas

including not only leftists but also rightists such as Kim Ku and Kim Kyu-sik, sought to enter into talks with the leaders of northern Korea in order to prevent the impending permanent division of their country. They attended a conference in Pyongyang in April 1948, where they met with northern Korean leaders such as Kim Il Sung and issued statements opposing the separate southern elections and voicing support for the creation of a unified Korean government after withdrawal of all foreign troops from Korea. This effort by the Korean leaders, however, proved ineffective in preventing the elections for the National Assembly in southern Korea, which took place in May 1945 and led to the election of Syngman Rhee as the first president of the Republic of Korea, which was proclaimed in August 1948. The USSR and the northern Koreans then went ahead with their own elections for the Supreme People’s Assembly of Korea, which took place in September 1948 and led to the establishment of the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea under the leadership of Kim Il Sung. In retrospect, this emergence of the two rival states in the Korean peninsula seemingly became all but inevitable when the only framework for a unified Korean state that was agreed upon by the US and the USSR—namely, the transition to such a state under the proposed U.N. Trusteeship—failed in its implementation amid discord between the US and the USSR and between the various Korean groups themselves against the background of the rising global Cold War. The division of Korea after World War II, which led to the rise of the two rival Korean states in 1948 and the tragic outcome of the ensuing Korean War (1950–1953), was therefore a complex process that needs to be examined from a variety of angles, including international politics, domestic politics within the Korean peninsula and relationships among the various Korean groups in the context of World War II, postwar decolonization worldwide and the rise of the Cold War confrontations. While there have been numerous scholarly works in the English language on the Korean War and US-Korean relations in general, there has been a paucity of scholarship focused on examining Korea’s division in 1945–1948. Among the works that do deal with Korea in this period in one form or another, one observes a pattern similar to that discernible in works addressing other areas of early Cold War history: “traditionalists” of the 1950s–1970s who blame the USSR for the failure of Allied cooperation after World War II and for starting the Cold War; the “revisionists” of the 1970s–1990s who point to American “imperialists” as the culprits for starting the Cold War; and the “post-revisionists” since the 1990s, some of whose works can be characterized as “traditionalists plus archives.” Representative of the “traditionalists” or “Cold Warriors” is the monumental two-volume work by Scalapino and Lee (1972); seminal among the “revisionists” is the two-volume work by Cumings (1981, 1990); and examples of “post-revisionism” include Weathersby (1993). However, on the issue of the Korean division in 1945–1948, a lack of conceptual clarity exists in these scholarly works. Although the traditionalists and the revisionists differ sharply as to which side they blame for the Korean division, they have tended to assume that the division itself was inevitable and have not examined in depth the possibilities for alternatives to the division. In particular, scholars have paid insufficient attention to the issue of the trusteeship, namely, the wartime decision by Allied leaders to place Korea under a four-power trusteeship after Japan’s defeat and the subsequent agreement to implement this trusteeship reached at the Moscow Conference of Allied Foreign Ministers in December 1945. No work examined in detail how this trusteeship issue was central to causing both the military partition of Korea at the 38th parallel in August 1945 and the permanent division of Korea into the two Koreas in August–September 1948. Lee (2005) is a relatively recent work that helps to fill this gap in the scholarly literature. 175

Jongsoo Lee

Among the few works that address Soviet policy towards Korea in this period, the consensus view was that Stalin was intent on creating a Soviet satellite state in northern Korea and that he never took the trusteeship seriously, utilizing it at best as a propaganda ploy. Lee (2005), however, argues that this view obscures and oversimplifies what was a fluid and uncertain situation obtaining in Korea and the world during 1945–1948. Lee also argues that this view fails to capture the continent nature as well as the complexity and self-contradiction inherent in Soviet policy towards Korea and elsewhere in the early postwar years. According to Lee (2005), a work based on multilingual research including newly available archival materials from Moscow, Stalin apparently faced two basic alternatives in August 1945: Sovietizing northern Korea, which would create a buffer state in northern Korea presumably buttressing Soviet security but which would also lead the US and Japan to turn southern Korea into an outpost of a US-Japan security alliance directed against the USSR; or working with the Western powers to implement the trusteeship or some other mechanism for creating a unified independent Korea, which would be neutral or friendly in its foreign policy orientation to the USSR. Lee suggests that Stalin in 1945–1948 was at best ambivalent about either of these choices and that his preference, if he had one, was actually for the latter, given that a unified independent Korea on the USSR’s border would likely be more susceptible to dictates from Moscow than from Washington. Such a unified Korea, even if originally established as a capitalist state with a neutral foreign policy, would have been very susceptible to communist subversion and likely to have turned leftist. Therefore, Lee (2005) makes the prima facie case that, similar to how Stalin apparently approached the German problem after World War II, the Soviet dictator apparently pursued seemingly contradictory policies for a Korean settlement, at least in the initial stage of the Soviet occupation of Korea, and that he apparently never entirely gave up on the possibility of reaching an accommodation with the United States in Korea even after the failure of the Moscow agreement until the very eve of the establishment of South Korea in August 1948. Lee suggests the possibility that Stalin took the Korean trusteeship plan seriously, at least more seriously than did the Americans, and that the trusteeship was actually Stalin’s preferred policy for a Korean settlement. Based on a consideration of both international and domestic factors, Lee (2005) attempts to answer the question of why such alternative settlements for Korea’s future were not adopted and why the Korean nation-building effort in 1945–1948 failed, leading not to peaceful reunification but instead to war. In terms of future agenda for research on Korea’s division after World War II, the following observations, among others, may be made. First is that, as already alluded, there is a dire lack of scholarship in any language devoted to this issue, especially in comparison to the larger body of scholarship on the Korean War or the much larger body of works that examine other cases of national division and partition, such as Germany’s division after World War II. This calls for more research on the Korean division, especially by scholars based in the English-speaking world. Second is that there is a need for more works that place the Korean division in a broader comparative context, making an effort to draw comparisons with simultaneous developments elsewhere in the world (Japan, Vietnam, Germany, Austria, Finland, etc.) and with prior examples drawn from world history. Third is related to the second, namely the need for works that overcome the limitations of conventional national history and diplomatic history. Too often, scholars specializing in a national history have focused their energies on examining developments internal to a nation or a people while paying insufficient attention to broader international forces or at worst engaging in a nationalistic bifurcation of “us” vs. “the foreign” as a driving force in a national history. On the other hand, Western scholars of diplomatic history involving nonWestern peoples have sometimes focused their energies on the broader international forces and Great Power politics while paying insufficient attention or according insufficient agency to the 176

Division of Korea and rise of two Koreas

domestic actors and developments inside the non-Western countries they address. This situation calls for more balanced and nuanced works that rectify and transcend these limitations of conventional national history and diplomatic history. Fourth is related to the third but going further, namely the need for works that are in line with a current trend in historical scholarship towards “international” or “transnational” history and “global history,” that is, works that make an effort to address broader themes and forces in global history, such as global economy, geography and factor endowments and transnational interactions including trade and migrations, as well as empire and decolonization, war and peace and nationalism and nation-building. In the case of the Korean division, more research is thus needed that examines, for example, the division as a case study in worldwide decolonization, Third World nationalism and nation-building and the rising Cold War worldwide. Also welcome is more research that focuses on issues such as the economic and social dimension of the division (for example, Korea’s economic and strategic value to the Great Powers, including the US and USSR with their respective capitalist and socialist world orders; the cost of the division in terms of damage to the integrated Korean national economy, the loss of lives and materials arising from the subsequent Korean War; the human tragedy of family members separated by the division and the subsequent fratricide of the Korean War; etc.). Finally, there is an overall need for more multi-lingual, multi-archival scholarship that utilizes new evidence from Russia, Eastern Europe, Japan, China, the United States, Korea and elsewhere. If and when North Korea opens up and archival and other materials from there become available to researchers, this will be a boon for scholarship. Beyond the broader research agenda as outlined above, the following specific sub-areas, among others, call for more research. First is the need for more multi-archival research on the wartime Allied planning, including behind-the-scenes Allied deliberations, regarding Korea’s postwar future and, in particular, concerning the trusteeship issue, especially why and how the trusteeship idea was applied towards Korea. In addition to unearthing any new evidence from the United States, more evidence from the British, Russian, and Chinese archives would contribute to a more complete understanding of the respective Allied positions, including the US position, on this issue. Second is a fuller examination of how and why the “in due course” phrase was included in the Cairo Declaration on the postwar future of Korea, including the question of who was the “real author” of this phrase. Again, more evidence from the British, Russian and Chinese archives, as well as a more in-depth look at the evolution of the US position papers on this issue from the initial draft proposal to the final version approved by Franklin Roosevelt, would contribute to a more complete understanding of the respective Allied positions, including the US position. Third is a comprehensive analysis based on more evidence of how the United States came to propose the 38th parallel as the dividing line and why the Soviets accepted. At present, the standard account of this event is based on the recollections of Dean Rusk, a direct participant in the event, as preserved in the US government records and in his own published memoir. Researchers would benefit from access to more first-hand evidence from the US side and also any direct evidence from the Russian side that can shed light on this bargain struck between the United States and the USSR. Fourth is the need for more research on how the United States and the USSR, during 1945–1948, related to the various Korean leaders, including right-wing nationalists like Kim Ku and left-wing leaders like Kim Il Sung, and how the relationships between the US and Soviet occupation authorities and these Korean leaders helped shape the course of events in postwar Korea. Fifth is an in-depth analysis of the interactions during 1945–1948 between the US-occupied south and the Soviet-occupied north, such as trails of migrants, spies, political and religious refugees and official delegations of political figures, as well as flows of goods, 177

Jongsoo Lee

commodities and raw materials including electricity. Sixth is more research on the return or repatriation of ethnic Koreans to the Korean peninsula from the overseas Korean diaspora after World War II, including those who had been relocated to various parts of the Japanese empire as soldiers, forced laborers and “comfort women” (i.e. those forced into sexual slavery). The return of large numbers of these ethnic Koreans to Korea after World War II, whether from China, Japan, Russia, the United States or elsewhere, had a big impact on the developments in the Korean peninsula leading to the national division and the subsequent Korean War. As is the case in the first three sub-areas of research outlined in the previous paragraph, progress in these sub-areas of research outlined in this paragraph will depend in part on the availability of new evidence, archival and otherwise.

Notes 1

2

3

4

This assessment is based on the official US documents that are heretofore accessible to researchers. No effort is made here to speculate on the possibility of a “secret understanding” reached between the US and the USSR prior to Japan’s surrender concerning the future of the Korean peninsula. The existence of any such behind-the-scenes agreement, even if real, is not supported by these official documents, which, by their nature, document official deliberations and actions of the policymakers. There is some uncertainty about the exact date of this event, as an alternative account of this same event states it took place the night of August 10–11, 1945. The account of this event narrated here is largely based on the recollections of Dean Rusk as preserved in the official US documents and also included in his published memoirs. For a fuller discussion of the possible reasons why the Soviets accepted this US proposal of the division along the 38th parallel, see Jongsoo Lee, The Partition of Korea after World War II: A Global History (New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan, 2005), pp. 39–45. For a fuller discussion of the failure of the US and the USSR to cooperate in Korea in 1946–1948, including the failure of the effort to form a left-right coalition among the Korean leaders, see Lee (ibid.), pp. 86–126, 147–154.

References Armstrong, Charles K. (2003) The North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Bunche, Ralph J. (1945) “Trusteeship and Non-Self-Governing Territories in the Charter of the United Nations,” The Department of State Bulletin, December 30, 1945, vol. VIII, no. 340, Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office: 1037–1044. Byrnes, James F. (1947) Speaking Frankly. New York, NY: Harper & Brothers. Churchill, Winston and Franklin D. Roosevelt (1984) Churchill and Roosevelt: The Complete Correspondence, Volumes I–III, Warren F. Kimball, editor. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Cumings, Bruce (1981) The Origins of the Korean War, Volume I: Liberation and the Emergence of Separate Regimes, 1945–1947. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. –––– . (1990) The Origins of the Korean War, Volume II: The Roaring of the Cataract, 1947–1950. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Gaddis, John Lewis (1997) We Now Know: Rethinking Cold War History. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. –––– . (2005) The Cold War: A New History. New York, NY: Penguin. Hasegawa, Tsuyoshi (2006) Racing the Enemy: Stalin, Truman and the Surrender of Japan. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press. Ku, Kim (2000) Paekpom Ilchi: The Autobiography of Kim Ku, Jongsoo Lee, translator and annotator. Lanham, MD: University Press of America. Kovalenko, I. (1985) “The Rout of Japanese Militarism and the National Liberation Revolutions in Asia,” Far Eastern Affairs, no. 4. Lankov, Andrei (2002) From Stalin to Kim Il Sung: The Formation of North Korea, 1945–1960. London: Hurst & Company. 178

Division of Korea and rise of two Koreas

Leffler, Melvyn P. (1992) A Preponderance of Power: National Security, the Truman Administration, and the Cold War. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. –––– . (2007) For the Soul of Mankind: The United States, the Soviet Union, and the Cold War. New York, NY: Hill and Wang. Lee, Jongsoo (2005) The Partition of Korea after World War II: A Global History. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan. Matray, James I. (1985) The Reluctant Crusade: American Foreign Policy in Korea, 1941–1950. Honolulu, HI: University of Hawaii Press. McCune, George M. (1947) “Korea: The First Year of Liberation,” Pacific Affairs, vol. 20, no. 1: 3–7. Plokhy, S. M. (2011) Yalta: The Price of Peace. New York, NY: Penguin. Rusk, Dean (1990) As I Saw It, Daniel S. Papp, editor. New York, NY: W. W. Norton & Co. Scalapino, Robert and Chong-sik Lee (1972) Communism in Korea. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Truman, Harry S. (1955) Memoirs, Volume One: Year of Decisions. New York, NY: Doubleday & Co. Van Ree, Erik (1989) Socialism in One Zone: Stalin’s Policy in Korea, 1945–1947, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Weathersby, Kathryn (1993) Soviet Aims in Korea and the Origins of the Korean War, 1945–1950: New Evidence from Russian Archives, Cold War International History Project, Working Paper No. 8. Washington, D.C.: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars.

179

13 The Korean War and its politics Grace J. Chae

Remembering a war notoriously referred to as one that is “unknown” or “forgotten” carries with it a hefty burden to restore honor to the lives lost and affected by such devastating violence. However, as this war erupted during a volatile and uncertain climate of postcolonial liberation from Japan and escalating Cold War tensions—a time when local and international parties violently clashed over differing political ideologies, motivations, and expectations—its telling is fraught with both complexity and controversy. Restricted or unopened archives, changing memories, and still politically sensitive debates exacerbate attempts to accurately comprehend this moment. There is no one history of the Korean War. Thus, this chapter not only provides a historical overview of general events and significant themes, but also a conscious recognition of how this history has been and continues to be told. In this way, the Korean War’s place in history becomes more than just a historical episode, but one that provides a lasting lesson on how history, politics, and scholarship intersect.

Historiography A general review of Korean War historiography, specifically Western and East Asian scholarship, not only reflects academic trends across various disciplines and areas of study (e.g. critical shifts in postcolonial and postmodern studies), but also changing political climates in both the United States and East Asia that often influenced the kinds of narratives and tones that emerged. South Korean-language studies on the Korean War, for example, were largely unformed during the 1950s and 1960s due to the chaos of war, dictatorships, censorship, and postwar reconstruction. What little was produced by Koreans remained, over the course of decades, consistent with the official view of the Republic of Korea (ROK) Government that the war was an unprovoked aggression coordinated by the Soviet Union, China, and North Korea. Many scholars were not only inhibited by the state, which fostered and propagated conservative viewpoints and an overwhlemingly anti-communist culture, but also by the mere fact that they were witnesses to the brutality of the war and were weary of lenient considerations of North Korean intentions (C.B. Kim 1996: 158). It was the 1970s that produced a significant shift among Korean War scholarship produced in South Korea. Largely due to new funding initiatives and partnerships between the United 180

The Korean War and its politics

States and the Republic of Korea (e.g. via the Ford Foundation, the 1961 Fulbright-Hays Act, etc.), some students were able to study abroad in the United States and Europe (Cumings 1999: 180). These scholars gained exposure to critical and progressive viewpoints like world-systems analysis and Marxism, which were restricted under Korea’s authoritarian regimes. However, many of these students, as Kim Chull Baum has found in his study of Korean War historiography, were scholars of international politics and tended to remain somewhat conservative in their understanding of the war by insisting that responsibility for the devastation remained at the feet of foreign powers. It was not until Korean historians began to take up the mantle with the release of US and British military and state documents, along with captured North Korean documents, during the 1970s and 1980s that critical analyses began to emerge that considered the war as an internal conflict exacerbated by imperialist policies (C.B. Kim 1996: 158). For example, Kim Hak-joon’s Korean Affairs and International Politics (1975) was not only the first Korean-language study to use military archival documents, but it was also the first to explore controversial issues surrounding the Korean War, despite heavy censorship under the Chun regime. In his later work on the history of the Korean War (1989), Kim more freely reveals that there was a split in the North Korean leadership regarding whether to continue the fight beyond 1951. Pak Myung-lim (1996) examined captured North Korean documents alongside South Korean documents to provide a closer study of the internal conditions that led to the pursuit of unification by force, adding complexity to our understanding of the decision-making process to go to war. After South Korea’s democratization in the late 1980s, historical study of the Korean War has grown more diverse and more inclusive of what were once regarded as radical viewpoints. By the 1990s, the release of Chinese and Russian documents, partly aided by normalized relations between Seoul and Moscow and Seoul and Beijing, began to lend support to the traditionalist view that the war was an international conflict and instigated by North Korea. Much like the debate among English-language scholars, an exploration of which follows, the debate amongst Korean scholars has taken a similar turn based on the availability of archival documents from all sides and changing political climates. Attempting to bridge the gap, much of today’s scholarship seeks to explore the Korean War as a combination of domestic and international factors both in its origins and outcome. In addition, current Korean-language scholarship has now begun to incorporate interdisciplinary studies to examine the sociological, psychological, and cultural impact of the war (C.B. Kim 1996: 164–165). English-language studies published in the 1950s and 1960s suffered from their own lack of access to declassified documents and the vociferous tide of anti-communist sentiments that swept across the country. As a result, early works exhibited an almost formulaic depiction of the Korean War as a United Nations “police action” against an unprovoked 25 June 1950 North Korean invasion designed by the Soviet Union. This toed the Truman administration’s containment policy line, originally suggested by George F. Kennan in his “Long Telegram” (1947), arguing intervention as a necessary action for collective security against communist aggression, a view presented before the American public and the world.1 Meanwhile, Soviet and North Korean officials cast the United States and South Korea as solely responsible for instigating hostilities with the aim to ignite a civil war, invoking a defensive response from their side. Thus, as historian Steven Hugh Lee writes, “The issue [regarding the origins of the Korean War] was drawn into the vortex of superpower attempts to justify their respective positions in their international rivalry” (Lee 2001: 6). It was regarded as a proxy war between international superpowers. I.F. Stone’s original 1952 publication, The Hidden History of the Korean War, was the earliest monograph to gather available documents and reports to swim against this current in its consideration of internal/domestic factors in the origins of the war and its critique of the US 181

Grace J. Chae

government’s handling of the United Nations. It was, of course, met with disdain and was pushed into the shadows until the release of declassified government documents in the 1970s gave credence to some of his findings. In the meantime, orthodox works like those by David Rees (Korea: The Limited War [1964]) remained authoritative sources. However, as information became more available, scholars began to explore other dimensions of the war. The release of The Foreign Relations of the United States 1950 in 1976 enabled William Stueck, for example, to explore shifts in American policies towards China as a result of the war in his own 1981 book The Road to Confrontation. James Matray’s The Reluctant Crusade (1985) examined US State Department records to trace shifts in American foreign policy from restraint to global intervention in Korea, while also acknowledging that the origins of the conflict perhaps bore deeper than 1950. Growing disillusionment in the mid- to late 1960s with the Vietnam War, along with mounting unease with the relationship between US academia and the government that had developed out of state-funded “area” and “national character studies” during World War II, led to the emergence of a new crop of Western scholars willing to critically explore US policies in East Asia.2 This signified an important shift in Korean War historiography. Rather than 25 June 1950 marking the beginning of the Korean War, scholars—many of whom had developed sympathies towards their countries of study from their experiences as Fulbright Scholars and Peace Corps volunteers, something Vincente Rafael refers to as “sentimental imperialism”— began to more closely study the colonial and post-liberation history of Korea to reveal more multidimensional factors (Rafael 1999: 1214). Their work exhibited a break from orthodox scholarship in the United States that framed Korean history in terms of a linear development that justified US intervention in the language of assistance. Furthermore, exploration of military documents began to shed light on some of the more brutal tactics used by the US military against North Korean targets, as explored by English diplomatic and military historian Callum MacDonald in his Korea: The War Before Vietnam (1986). Australian historian Gavan McCormack’s Cold War, Hot War (1983) also raised questions regarding whether the US Air Force (USAF) might have used biological weapons against the North Koreans, in addition to positing that the South had instigated the war. Drawing extensively from newly declassified documents released during the 1970s, Bruce Cumings’ two-volume work (1981, 1990), as noted by many scholars of Korean studies (e.g. Lee 2001, Yuh 2010), boldly critiqued the pervading Cold War narrative of the origins of the Korean War, arguing instead that the US military occupation and foreign policy had in fact obfuscated a domestic revolution that had roots long before liberation and might have been in the Korean people’s best interests. Cumings’ publications challenged, and continue to chafe against, orthodox and conservative viewpoints that still contend that North Korea’s invasion of the South was a product of Soviet and Chinese machinations or that the war was largely an international conflict. At the same time, his work profoundly resonated with many Korean and American researchers by inaugurating critical scholarship into Korean studies while still mildly supporting “internal development” positions through his recognition of Korea’s inherent dynamism through the rise of peasant resistance and nationalism during the precolonial period (Shin 2003: 168). Cumings’ critique of American military occupation, in particular, was powerful among Korean students suffering under the rule of the US-supported Park Chung-hee and Chun Doo-hwan dictatorships, whereby the oppressive National Security Laws gave the regimes carte blanche to indefinitely detain and torture students for expressing leftist sympathy or criticism against the ROK government or the United States. Although arguments over the domestic versus international origins of the war have dominated debates within Korean War scholarship, the increased availability, albeit still limited, of Chinese and Russian documents beginning in the 1990s has provided researchers with new opportunities 182

The Korean War and its politics

to better assess the complexities of the war. Evidence from US, Korean, Japanese, Chinese, and Russian materials, most comprehensively brought together by Wada Haruki’s recently translated The Korean War: An International History (2013), which examines in great detail the war as a regional conflict, demonstrates that the decision to invade South Korea on that fateful June day was indeed a result of close coordination between North Korea and the Soviet Union. However, unlike the one-dimensional Cold War assessments of Soviet domination over decisions to launch an offensive across the 38th parallel, top-secret correspondences between North Korean and Soviet officials reveal that North Korean leaders were in fact active campaigners for invasion over a more reluctant Stalin. This level of agency paralleled what we have long known about South Korea’s President Syngman Rhee’s own aggressive campaign to launch a military campaign to reunite the peninsula. The final act was also achieved in close coordination with the Chinese, demonstrating a growing Sino-North Korean partnership. This complements Chen Jian’s findings in his China’s Road to the Korean War (1994), which examines China’s post-revolutionary internal political development and its impact on the decision to enter the war as a vanguard against Western imperialism in Asia. In balance with the colonial, post-liberation, and domestic circumstances of both Koreas, alongside the emerging Cold War climate of contending superpowers, including China’s ascendance, we can now better appreciate the multidimensional, or what Lee regards as the “symbiotic,” relationship between civil and international factors that not only led to the Korean War, but also impacted how it was carried out (Lee 2001: 7).

Colonial origins While responsibility for Korea’s geographic division could be placed at the feet of American military planners in 1945, its political division could be attributed to its colonial experience. As American and European imperial powers focused much of their attention on opening China to global trade during the mid-nineteenth century, Korea remained relatively marginal until Japan’s own imperial aspirations turned towards the tiny peninsular country. This began with the 1876 Kanghwa Treaty, which led to other unequal treaties with the United States, France, etc. Despite resistance from Confucian conservatives, some yangban (literati) and government officials in Korea’s Chosŏn Dynasty (1492–1910) began to seek political, ideological, and material solutions to meet the onslaught of Japanese and Western colonial ambitions. Out of various self-strengthening approaches emerged early forms of modern Korean nationalism (Eckert et al. 1990: 201–214). Alas, in spite of such efforts, Korea became Japan’s colony in 1910. Over nearly four decades of colonial rule, underground and exiled nationalist groups fervently sought independence through various means. Kim Il-sung and Syngman Rhee shared a common history as fighters for Korean independence with deep and long-lasting contempt for Korea’s colonial subjugation. Their experiences and divergent ideologies during this formative period greatly impacted their respective leadership approaches of a later divided Korea. Rhee, a descendant of a modest family of aristocratic lineage, was educated in both the traditional Confucian system and, later, at an American Christian school. He developed into a conservative political activist who joined the reform movement of the Independence Club in the mid-1890s that sought to adopt Western approaches to modernize the Chosŏn state. After falling out of favor with the king, he spent several years in prison before leaving for Hawaii and the US mainland, where he received his doctorate from Princeton University. There, he began to aggressively campaign for a Korean-American partnership by appealing to US officials and the American public for Korean independence (Oliver 1954: 1–114). 183

Grace J. Chae

At the close of World War I, the United States, Great Britain, France, Italy, and Japan convened in Paris as the principal powers in charge of formulating a plan for peace. In his “Fourteen Points” speech at the Paris Peace Conference in January 1919, President Woodrow Wilson insisted upon the fundamental importance of preserving and defending liberty through a union of nations. His fourteenth point spoke to the principle of “self-determination” in his appeal for “mutual guarantees of political independence and territorial integrity,” even for “small states,” emboldening Koreans like Rhee.3 In Korea, on 1 March 1919, over one million Koreans participated in a nonviolent, popular protest called the “March 1st Movement,” or Samil Undong, that lasted for several weeks against Japanese colonial occupation. They were met with brutal repression. Despite American missionary pleas for international sympathy for the tens of thousands of civilian victims, no Western nations stepped forward to intervene (Eckert et al. 1990: 276–279). As one of many exiled nationalists responding to this crisis, Rhee helped form the Korean Provisional Government (KPG) in Shanghai for which he temporarily served as President. In September, the New York Times published an article citing his proclamation for Korea’s independence from Japan titled “‘President’ Rhee Renounces Japanese Sovereignty and Asks for Recognition.” In it, he stated, “We accept and agree to the American principles of democracy and self-government enunciated by President Wilson during the Great War, the principles of a liberated mankind, of equal justice for all nations alike, be they weak or strong, and of the derivation of their just powers by governments from the consent of the governed.”4 However, despite such declarations that were rooted in the language of Wilson’s own speeches, those principal powers in Paris did little to respond to Korea’s pleas. After relinquishing the KPG presidency to Kim Ku, an advocate for organized violence against the empire, Rhee focused on his diplomatic efforts and became widely recognized in Korea as a Christian, anti-communist, conservative defender for Korean independence despite continued ambivalence, indifference, or, in some cases, irritation amongst American officials (Oliver 1954: 142–144). For other Korean independence fighters, continued rebuffs by Western nations convinced them of the weakness of diplomatic approaches. The 1917 Russian Revolution inspired many to look to guerrilla warfare and Marxist revolution as an alternative. While communist movements within Korea experienced brutal suppression by the colonial police, others were able to gain footholds in Siberia, China, and elsewhere, reflecting a scattered Korean diaspora during the colonial period. Many of these exiled nationalists served in the Soviet Army and the Chinese Communist Party during the 1920s through the 1950s. Among these participants, Kim Il-sung ascended as a junior revolutionary who joined the Northeast Anti-Japanese United Army and led raids against Japanese officials and Korean collaborators in Manchuria. He later served with the Soviet Army and returned to Pyongyang (P’yŏngyang) after the US bombing of Hiroshima on 6 August 1945 (Lee 2001: 14–16). It was the attack on Pearl Harbor that brought the United States into the maelstrom of World War II and squarely into Japan’s colonial territory and into Korea. And, it was during this subsequent decade that Korea’s geographic division took root. It began in November 1943 when President Franklin D. Roosevelt, Generalissimo Chiang Kai-shek, and Prime Minister Winston Churchill met in Cairo to outline their plan to defeat Japan. In their December radio release, the Allied leaders expressed their sympathies for the “enslavement of the people of Korea,” but asserted that self-rule would come “in due course.”5 This reflected Roosevelt’s gradualist vision of a new liberal world order of reconfigured economic and political relationships that would replace the old colonial economy and, ultimately, achieve American hegemony. In his private letters, Roosevelt reflected on the future of former colonies like Korea, French Indochina, British India, and the Dutch East Indies: “there are many minor children among the peoples of the 184

The Korean War and its politics

world who need trustees, [especially] the brown people of the East” (as cited in Hunt 1987: 162). Only under a paternalistic policy of trusteeship could these “many minor children” achieve a level of preparedness for self-rule. After Roosevelt’s death on 12 April 1945, American officials continued to pursue modified versions of his trusteeship idea. A few days before the Enola Gay was to drop “Little Boy” on Japan, Colonels Dean Rusk and Charles H. Bonesteel selected the 38th parallel to demarcate Soviet and American zones in Korea. In US policy formulations, Korea would factor as a key component to containing communism and reviving Japan’s industrial economy. Shortly thereafter, Korean leaders began to prepare for self-government. People’s committees also sprang up in rural areas with aims to dismantle the colonial apparatus, including rounding up individuals who served in the colonial police and landowners who preyed on vulnerable Koreans and profited from collaboration with the Japanese. Predictably, American officials disapproved of such efforts, viewing them as radical leftist extensions of Soviet influence (Cumings 1997: 185–187). Ignorant to key historical factors, like the centuries-long impact of class divisions between landed, educated elites and a large peasant population that regarded wealthy landowners as having continually benefited from the colonial period and with the Americans (e.g. brothers Kim Sŏngsu and Kim Yŏn-su, Song Chin-u, etc., who established the Korean Democratic Party [Eckert 1991: 30–32]), American officials failed to recognize that “the political fault line was not right versus left, but patriot versus collaborator” (Cumings 1997: 198). As American and Korean conservative leadership worked together to suppress local efforts to purge colonial vestiges, eruptions of violence began to mount throughout the peninsula. This rending apart of the country, between left and right factions, peasants and proprietors, resistant fighters and collaborators (though the lines were not always so clear or divisive), is powerfully portrayed in Im Kwon-t’aek’s dramatic film entitled Taebaek Sanmaek (Taebaek Mountains) (1994). By 1948, partisan and guerrilla fighters in southeast Kyŏngsang and the agriculturally rich, and traditionally rebellious, southwest Chŏlla provinces turned their vitriol against the repressive Korean National Police (KNP) and the Republic of Korea Army (ROKA), a majority of which was made up of Koreans who had served the colonial machinery. The two most infamous events were the bloody 1948 Yŏsu and Cheju Rebellions (Cumings 1997: 217–224). In that same year, the Republic of Korea was proclaimed on 15 August with Syngman Rhee as president. Meanwhile, Koreans in the north had a different trusteeship experience (we know this from North Korean documents captured by US military forces during the Korean War).6 After liberation, People’s Committees appeared throughout northern Korea with the approval of the Soviets. During the trusteeship period, Soviets worked rather loosely with communists and nationalists, as compared to American-directed efforts to build a centralized administration in South Korea. Out of an emerging coalition of leaders, Kim Il-sung began to maneuver into a position of leadership, surpassing communists who had cut their teeth surviving in Korea during the colonial period and those who had worked with the Soviets or Chinese abroad. By February 1946, a central administration was in the works and land reform measures began, which included purging state institutions of “reactionary” Koreans and those who served the colonial apparatus (Cumings 1981: 414). By late summer, the North Korean Workers’ Party (NKWP) overshadowed other political groups, and economic planning began along the lines of the Soviet model. At this juncture, Kim and his allies successfully removed a majority of political threats, including Christians and nationalists, through social, economic, and political alienation and exclusion. Meanwhile, they encouraged people with peasant backgrounds to join the NKWP. Self-criticism sessions were routinized and surveillance was in full force. By the end of 1946, the press was under tight 185

Grace J. Chae

control and all non-leftist opposition was eliminated (Cumings 1997: 226–235). On 9 September 1948, the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea (DPRK) was formed and Kim Il-sung was named its premier.

Storm rising Although the early Sunday morning of 25 June 1950 has been seared in American memories as the start date of the conflict in Korea, it was rather a coalescence of rising tensions and skirmishes between two competing factions that had been taking place for some time along the 38th parallel. By the summer of 1949, both North and South Korean leaders saw war as the only means to unification. In May, fights along the border began to escalate between North and South Korean forces. As early as June, heavy fighting on the Ongjin Peninsula alerted American intelligence officials of the possibility that a civil war could break out at any moment and by either side. While both sides were guilty of igniting violent confrontations, both were also hoping that the other would be the first to commit a full breach so as to force their respective reluctant largepower holders to come to their aid. The compulsion to reunite a country that had never been divided in its thousands-year history, nor ever should have been, was considerably strong on both sides. But, neither was in a position to launch a war. For Rhee, despite his persistent efforts to convince his American advisors of the imperative to invade the North and unite the country under the ROK flag, he failed to rally the necessary support and approval as the US government began to draw down its troop presence. Ambassador John J. Muccio, explicitly warned President Rhee that the United States would not provide any military support should the South engage in provocative actions, even threatening to withdraw economic aid (at the time, around $100 million per year) (Lowe 1997: 71). Kim Il-sung faced his own difficulties obtaining guarantees of Soviet support (Weathersby 1993: 28). The summer of 1949 was also too early; tens of thousands of his troops were still in Manchuria assisting Mao’s People’s Liberation Army against Chiang’s Kuomintang (KMT) troops since 1947. This move would prove to be a savvy one. By lending his support, Kim not only secured an “I-O-U” from Mao that would come into play in the next couple of years, he also gained battle-seasoned troops. After a period of relative quiet brought on by Korea’s harsh winter, war came, and with Stalin’s tacit approval, it came at the hands of Kim Il-sung in June 1950 (Cumings 1997: 239). While evidence shows that Stalin’s reluctant approval for Kim to invade was accompanied by equally ambivalent material support, for which payment was expected, Mao was making preparations to make good on his promise to return Kim’s favor with troops (Wada 2014: 20). Fighting erupted on the Ongjin Peninsula; both sides claimed one provoked the other in the early morning hours of 25 June 1950. By 5 a.m., it had moved eastward across the 38th parallel. The North Korean People’s Army (NKPA) dealt a heavy and concerted blow against the Republic of Korea Army and advanced, for the first time, towards Seoul, the South’s capital city (Lee 2001: 44). The NKPA, consisting of many veterans of anti-colonial struggles against the Japanese and volunteers who backed the communists against the KMT in China, met comparatively little resistance against the greener ROK forces. US Secretary of State Dean Acheson heard about the fighting while at his Maryland country house on Saturday; President Truman was at home in Missouri. Acheson and Assistant Secretary of State Dean Rusk decided to bring the Korea question before the United Nations, a more amenable body than the US Congress. They also planned to argue for increased military aid to the Republic of Korea, American air support for evacuation, and orders to move the Seventh 186

The Korean War and its politics

Fleet into the Taiwan Straits to stave off any possible acts of aggression between the communist Chinese and the nationalist government that had fled to Taiwan. Truman declared US actions in Korea a “police action,” thereby avoiding a formal declaration of war that would require legislation by Congress (Edwards 1998: 3). The United Nations passed “Resolution 84” on 27 June recommending that “the members of the United Nations furnish such assistance to the Republic of Korea as may be necessary to repel the armed attack and to restore international peace and security to the area.”7 In the absence of the Soviet Union’s representative Jacob Malik at the Security Council, in protest of the UN’s refusal to admit China as a member, the UN approved military action in Korea. By the night of 28 June, Seoul had fallen and South Korean forces were in disarray, an event witnessed by famous political cartoonist Kim Song-hwan, or “Gobau,” during his adolescence and recorded in vivid pen and watercolors (Salmon 2009: 1–13). Many Korean refugees fled ahead of the NKPA’s march into Seoul, while others welcomed their arrival. After a week in Seoul, likely waiting for supplies from the rear, the NKPA continued its southward move and rooted out “reactionaries” on the way. Local guerrilla forces, which had led campaigns against the KNP and US military before being shut down in years prior, emerged out of hiding to help reorganize the countryside. Focused on the redistribution of rice stocks and land, the return of people’s committees speaks strongly to the anti-feudal and anti-colonial roots of this conflict (Cumings 1990: 666–690). Interestingly, even surrender leaflets aimed at enemy forces produced by both the North Koreans and the Americans speak to the multifaceted nature of the conflict. For North Koreanproduced leaflets, South Korea is depicted as returning to colonial dependency as a puppet of Japan and the United States; for American-produced leaflets, North Korea is drawn as a political stooge of China and the Soviet Union (Chae 2010: 34). Chŏng Yong-uk, Professor of Korean History at Seoul National University, argues North Korea’s depiction of a subordinate South Korea speaks more to the question of legitimacy and which of the two governments rightfully represented the new, postcolonial Korean nation: the anti-colonial struggle being a constitutive force in the establishment of the North Korean state (2004: 217–226). For example, one NK leaflet caption reads: “The American invaders and the weak Rhee Syngman are dragging the Korean people’s Japanese enemies back to our homeland and are rushing to make our people into American slaves. If the spilled ancestral blood in the war against them is precious, then rise up against the American invaders and the Rhee Syngman traitorous gang” (as cited in Chae 2010: 69). For the American-produced leaflets, however, Chŏng identifies how the US government insisted on the ideological and global dimensions of the war, with North Korean soldiers serving as fodder for Soviet and Chinese aims. Even the divergent leaflet themes underscore the dualism of the Korean conflict as one that was both domestic and international. As the People’s Army continued to press against ROK and UN troops, American intelligence personnel discovered more than met the eye with regards to the makeup of enemy forces. Early reports found that enemy soldiers were slipping through the front lines as civilians to gain a forward position behind ROK and US troops. The Counter Intelligence Corps reported seeing “[h]undreds of North Korean soldiers [. . .] wearing civilian clothing and mingling with refugees.”8 Although the NKPA recruited willing South Koreans into their units as they swept south, losses incurred by contact with US and ROK forces also resulted in forcible conscription of civilians. According to a Seoul Sinmun report, the NKPA “increased indiscriminate forced recruiting of all youth” to fill their dwindling armies.9 As a result of the military’s inability to distinguish enemy troops from civilians, men, women, and children alike were swept into POW camps. Growing fear of disguised North Korean combat troops also led to horrific policy decisions for indiscriminate strafing of populations by air, leaving thousands of innocents dead. 187

Grace J. Chae

One particularly dreadful case took place at No Gun Ri, as accounted in Charles Hanley et al.’s The Bridge at No Gun Ri (2001). By the end of July, the North Koreans had pushed the ROK and UN forces to the southeast corner of the peninsula forming the Pusan Perimeter (delineated by P’ohang to the north, ChinjuMasan to the south, and Taegu in the center). In late August, the fighting along the Nakdong River reached its climax as the NKPA tried to break through the Pusan Perimeter to finish the war. However, by September, the NKPA felt the strains of weak supply lines, dwindling forces, and growing American and ROK resistance and was unable to penetrate further.

Turning tides It was not until General Douglas MacArthur’s famed Inchon (Inch’ŏn) landing on 15 September 1950 that the tides turned, so to speak.10 It was a massive amphibious counterattack against North Korean forces that brought with it a large number of captured enemy soldiers. In just one month, prisoner-of-war counts increased from several dozen to over 100,000 (Chae 2010: 2–3). They quickly gained control of Inchon and cut North Korean supply lines. Meanwhile the U.S. Eighth Army and ROK forces broke out of the Pusan Perimeter and chased the retreating enemy north. On 27 September, after Washington had consulted with its allies regarding war aims, MacArthur, commander of the UN forces, received permission to pursue the enemy into North Korea as long as he did not cross into Manchuria and there were no signs that the Chinese and Soviets would intervene. After retaking Seoul and handing it back to Rhee on 29 September, ROK forces crossed the 38th parallel on 1 October and pursued the US military’s new strategy of “rollback,” forgoing the original goals of containment toward a UN-sponsored goal of unification (Lee 2001: 47–50). By early to mid-October, ROK troops penetrated twenty-five miles north of the parallel. They reported no resistance and believed that they had the People’s Army on the run. What American commanders did not realize was that the NKPA’s withdrawal was also a strategic one; they hid in tunnels, mountains, and within villages above the 38th parallel as UN and ROK troops thinned out across the territory in their march north, becoming increasingly vulnerable to attacks from the rear. This was a conventional and guerrilla war, reflecting Kim Il-sung’s “hit and run” training developed against the Japanese during the colonial period (Cumings 1990: 729–733). As ROK and US troops charged north, rightist groups and the KNP began their work in villages in the rear. Focused on the political reorganization of northern villages, they systematically rooted out communists and collaborators, and they punished family members associated with “red sympathizers.” Reports of mass executions by the South were rampant, underscoring the brutality of a war that was civil and international in nature (Cumings 1997: 281–282). Early American intelligence reports showed no firm indication that the Chinese would intervene, with MacArthur giving Truman his assurances during their 15 October Wake Island meeting (Foot 1985: 78–80). However, recent evidence shows that Mao, owing much to Kim’s assistance during the Chinese civil war, had already made preparations to send “volunteers” (called Chinese Communist Forces [CCF] by the Americans or Chinese People’s Volunteers [CPV] by the Chinese) to assist North Korea should their campaign falter (Lowe 1997: 219). On 3 October, the Chinese premier warned the United States that if they crossed the 38th parallel, Chinese forces would be compelled to enter the war. When MacArthur pressed his troops across the parallel, Mao informed Stalin that he would begin preparations for intervention by providing, in total, 200,000 troops (Lee 2001: 51). The Soviet Union prepared to provide limited cover in aircrafts disguised with Chinese markers along the south Manchurian border. 188

The Korean War and its politics

On 26 October, the Korean Military Advisory Group, a US military unit charged with the logistical support of ROK troops, reported that Sino-North Korean troops were counterattacking UN units along the frontlines at Unsan, just below the Yalu River (Wada 2014: 144). This marked China’s first intervention. By this time, UN forces were pinned down and fell into disarray as Chinese and North Korean troops began to attack from the front and the rear. On 14 November, MacArthur launched a general offensive to trap NKPA forces and, for a few days, appeared to have succeeded until the enemy began to retaliate on 25 November and China launched the second phase with its 200–300,000 “volunteers.” North Korean guerrillas also began enveloping UN troops from behind in coordination with the North Koreans People’s Army, trapping them at the Chosin Reservoir. On 6 December, communist forces regained Pyongyang and by the end of the month, Seoul was at risk of falling, again (Lowe 1997: 235). Although the Chinese intervention was not the first time American military planners considered using the atomic bombs during the Korean conflict (MacArthur first suggested it to the Joint Chiefs of Staff in July 1950), it did bring them close to resolute action. Reintroducing the idea, MacArthur wanted to create a cordon sanitaire along the border between Manchuria and North Korea by dropping 30 to 50 bombs. Truman also began to hint at the potential use of atomic bombs in order to avoid the possibility of a third World War. In the end, with no indication of further Soviet involvement or advancement by Chinese troops beyond the parallel, Truman set aside his plans (Cumings 1997: 288–292).11 General Matthew B. Ridgway, who assumed command of the Eighth Army in December 1950, launched an aggressive campaign called “Operation Thunderbolt,” which involved heavy bombing campaigns against the Chinese and North Koreans. After fighting back China’s third intervention, he retook Seoul and established the “Kansas Line.” This brought the fighting back to the area just north of the 38th parallel. After MacArthur was dismissed on 11 April 1951 due to continued insubordination, Ridgway took over command of UN forces and stabilized fighting. Recognizing a possible ceasefire opportunity, George Kennan and Jacob Malik met at the end of May and agreed to begin discussions on how to end the conflict (Edwards 1998: 6).

Stalemate and politics of choice The armistice negotiations originally commenced in Kaesong on 10 July 1951, much to the chagrin of both Kim and Rhee, who wanted to continue their respective campaigns to unite the country by force. However, the talks halted when the communist side charged the UN Command with violating the neutral zone. In October, the talks were moved to Panmunjom (P’anmunjŏm) with a new demarcation line. After settling a majority of the agenda items within the first few months, the final question of prisoner of war repatriation, originally thought to be straightforward, posed the greatest obstacle. After sixteen months of negotiations, when the US side first put forward its contentious proposal of “voluntary repatriation” in January 1952, representatives finally resolved the matter on 8 June 1953 and signed the ceasefire agreement on 27 July 1953 (Foot 1990: xiii–xv). In original discussions regarding the treatment of POWs during the 1949 Geneva Convention, the US delegation disregarded exceptions to the “automatic repatriation” rule when the Austrian delegation first introduced possible conditions for it. As the Under Secretary of State at the time, Dean Acheson recalled Soviet concerns about whether “a prisoner of war might not be able to express himself with complete freedom when he was in captivity” (as cited in Foot 1990: 88). As a result, the final language in Article 118 dictated that the repatriation of all captured soldiers take place “without delay after the cessation of active hostilities.”12 However, the 189

Grace J. Chae

realization that approximately 40,000 captured POWs were South Koreans impressed into the North Korean Army raised immediate doubts for the United States as to whether it was prudent to proceed with automatic repatriation of all POWs under UN custody (Foot 1990: 103). In the most basic sense, this problem points to the overarching reality of the Korean War that is often pushed out of our minds when studying it from the perspective of how US foreign policies emerged during the beginning of the Cold War—that it was also a civil war. In a nation divided as part of post-World War II reordering, many Koreans confronted, for the first time, the harrowing and defining question of whether their futures lay in the North or the South. In this uncertainty, many were caught on the wrong side of that artificial latitudinal line and found themselves in the hands of the US military as captured enemy soldiers. American officials, reminded of the horrors that millions of Soviet soldiers faced when they were automatically repatriated at the close of World War II and working under the assumption that North Korea and China were communist puppet regimes under the stranglehold of the Soviet Union, began to regard automatic repatriation as a probable death sentence for many of the prisoners in its custody. In addition, as psychological warfare emerged as another means to subvert the legitimacy of communists, the prospect of using voluntary repatriation in the propaganda war seemed convincingly more promising. On 2 January 1952, the United States presented the position of “voluntary repatriation” to the negotiators at Panmunjom (Chae 2010: 241). According to Rosemary Foot’s account of the armistice negotiations in A Substitute for Victory (1990), an important diplomatic history of American strategies that had to balance political and military objectives at the negotiating table, the army’s chief of psychological warfare General Robert McClure advocated voluntary repatriation as an ideological opportunity to position the United States in a humanitarian posture vis-à-vis the communists (Foot 1990: 87). Gradually convinced of the ideological benefits, Dean Acheson contended that a forced return of prisoners “would be repugnant in our most fundamental moral and humanitarian principles of the importance of the individual, and would seriously jeopardize the psychological warfare position of the United States in its opposition to Communist tyranny” (as cited in Foot 1990: 91). It was a new moment of how the rights of foreign prisoners of war were to be negotiated during wartime, at a time when the principles of human rights were just beginning to gain currency in a postcolonial world. The communists immediately rejected this idea as a clear violation of the 1949 Geneva Convention. The American side argued that its humanitarian concerns for the welfare of the individual remained in line with the spirit of the Convention. Though neither side was an official signer, both sides insisted that they were compelled by its intentions. Meanwhile, inside the UN-run POW camps, emerging power struggles, basic in their initial nature, succumbed to more ideologically driven parties, particularly after NKPA agents and southern Anti-Communist Youth League members infiltrated the camps (Chae 2010: 131).13 Reports of violent clashes between groups of supposedly “pro-” and “anti-” communist factions (although most prisoners were less ideologically driven than motivated by diverse personal circumstances that reflected the chaos of a nation abruptly split in two), as well as between prisoners and ROK and US Army guards, grew. Coupled with the intensifying political contest at Panmunjom (P’anmunjŏm) and rising prisoner protests regarding voluntary repatriation policies enacted in the camps, the dam burst when communist prisoners captured the camp commander, Brigadier General Francis T. Dodd. In response, combat units armed with tanks, flamethrowers, machine guns, concussion grenades, and tear gas faced rock-throwing, Molotov cocktail-hurling, barbed-wire-swinging prisoners. During the seven-month crackdown, 577 prisoners of war were killed (Chae 2010: 261). In the 16 December 1952 issue of the New York Times, the communists, again, submitted to the world stage their protests against voluntary repatriation as attempting to manipulate 190

The Korean War and its politics

prisoners into refusing repatriation. In the article, Chinese representatives argued against the American insistence for voluntary repatriation “because it recognizes the ‘desire’ of the prisoners of war to ‘refuse repatriation,’ a ‘desire’ created by the United States side.” Through education and screening programs designed to orient prisoners towards the benefits of one political system (liberal democratic societies) over another (socialist and communist societies), in conjunction with growing violence in the camps, the notion of a “free choice” was a fallacy.14 The communists were not without contradiction or malefaction in their own treatment of UN and ROK prisoners of war. Just as many North Korean captives were tortured or executed by ROK soldiers upon capture, South Korean prisoners were also vulnerable to vengeful forms of cruelty by their enemy counterparts. Many UN prisoners were found dead, some executed with hands bound, others due to starvation or illness, along treacherous “death marches” to POW camps beyond the frontlines. Both sides were guilty of atrocities. For those UN soldiers that made it alive to the permanent camps established along the Yalu River, they gradually met improved conditions as the Chinese communists took responsibility for their care (see Carlson 2002). The Chinese and North Koreans jointly handled approximately 13,000 prisoners, a substantially lower number compared to the 160,000 prisoners (at its highest) managed by the Americans. Drawing from their experience during the Cultural Revolution, the Chinese embarked on programs to educate UN captives in communist ideology. Contrary to sensationalist depictions of UN prisoners being “brainwashed” and reprogrammed through Pavlovian conditioning, as dramatized in John Frankenheimer’s iconic film “The Manchurian Candidate” (1962), communist educators utilized films, literature, lectures, discussions, and criticism sessions to persuade prisoners of the benefits of communism.15 Those who participated in the programs did so for various reasons, namely due to: 1) genuine interest in communism; 2) boredom; or 3) they wanted to better their situation in the camps. Black soldiers, who had been integrated into the US Army for the first time, reflecting important shifts in US domestic race relations, were especially targeted by communist educators to reflect upon the inequities perpetrated by capitalist societies, as depicted in Hubert Bailey’s autobiography Black Boy, What Are You Fighting For? (1966). Interestingly, the infamous twenty-one American POWs who refused to return to the United States, which included three African-Americans, ignited a national crisis regarding the duties of American servicemen captured by enemy forces (see Pasley 1955), as well as cultural debates regarding diminished American masculinity (see Carruthers 2009). This led to the formation of the 1955 U.S. Military Code of Conduct, famously tested during the Vietnam War by captured Navy pilots like Everett Alvarez, Jr. and John McCain.

Conclusion As a so-called “limited war,” both sides violently engaged one another along the front lines without any clear strategies for victory; meanwhile, the political battles continued at Panmunjom and on the world stage. During the nearly two years of negotiations and stalemate over the issue of voluntary repatriation, tens of thousands of soldiers were killed on the front lines, and civilian causalities numbered in the millions. It was during these months that the US military launched its most protracted aerial campaigns from bases in Japan and Okinawa, smothering the North with napalm. In spring 1953, the USAF destroyed dams and reservoirs that would not only devastate newly planted rice paddies, but would starve out the northern population in the coming months. In the end, the combat death toll reached approximately 33,000 Americans; 115,000 Chinese; 215,000 North Koreans; 58,000 South Koreans; and one to two million civilians. With Dwight D. Eisenhower as the newly elected American president and the death 191

Grace J. Chae

of Stalin in March 1953, new UN forces Commander General Mark W. Clark signed the armistice agreement on 27 July 1953. But, the ceasefire was not a peace treaty. While general fighting has been suspended, one visit to the Demilitarized Zone (DMZ) or a review of today’s world headlines renders palpable the still-volatile tensions between the Koreas and the parties that fought on either side. Of such a suspension to the Korean War, historian Bruce Cumings sadly reminds us that “the terrible tragedy was that the war solved nothing: only the status quo ante was restored, only an armistice held the peace” (Cumings 1997: 298).

Notes 1 2 3 4

5 6 7 8 9 10

11

12 13

14 15

Kennan, G.F. (1947) ‘The Sources of Soviet Conduct,’ Foreign Affairs 25, No. 4: 566–582. See, Committee of Concerned Asian Scholars. Wilson, W. ‘Fourteen Points’, presented at Paris Peace Conference, Paris, January 1919. ‘“President” Rhee Renounces Japanese Sovereignty and Asks for Recognition; Plans Government Based on Principles Expressed by Wilson, Lincoln, and Washington’, New York Times 1 September 1919: p. 2. ‘Cairo Communique,’ from the United States Department of State/Foreign Relations of the United States diplomatic papers, The Conferences at Cairo and Tehran, 1943. For an in-depth view into “everyday life” accounts, see Kim 2013. ‘UN Security Council Resolution 84’ ‘Monthly Report of Counter Intelligence Corps Activities, 1 October 1950 for Month Reported’. ‘Doraol ŭiyonggun’ (‘Returning Righteous Army), Seoul Sinmun, National Library, South Korea 15 November 1950. What made the landing possible was a small window of time during which the tides were high enough to accommodate the battleships. During low tide, the water was known to drop as much as 32 feet, revealing a mosaic of darkly carved, almost alien-looking muddy flats that can be seen today from bridges heading towards Seoul in one direction, and Inchon International Airport in the other. Although there was no concrete plan to launch atomic weapons against the Chinese or North Koreans, the US Air Force ran bombing simulations in September and October 1951 under Operation Hudson Harbor, sending bombers into the north to drop empty atomic casings (Cumings 1997). United Nations, Geneva Convention Relative to the Treatment of Prisoners of War, 1949, II. Art. 118. Only a small percentage of prisoners actually grappled with ideological issues. Most wondered about their families, while others were drawn into certain groups due to generational, class, regional, and/or religious affiliations. ‘Chinese Communist and U.S. Statements on Korea,’ New York Times, 16 December 1952: p. 8. During the August and September months of 1953, Edgar Schein, a psychologist at MIT and with the US Army’s Operations Research Office, interviewed American repatriates processed at Inchon and on US naval ship General Black. In his article entitled ‘The Chinese indoctrination program for prisoners of war: a study of attempted “brainwashing”’ in Psychiatry (1956), he confirmed that there was nothing new or menacing to the Chinese techniques. The so-called mental erasure of American soldiers was accomplished through a typical collection of “group discussion, self-criticism, interrogation, rewards and punishments, forced confessions, exposure to propaganda and information control” (as cited in Winn 2000: 7).

References Bailey, H. (1966) Black Boy, What Are You Fighting For?, New York: Pageant Press. ‘Cairo Communique.’ (1943) From the United States Department of State/Foreign Relations of the United States Diplomatic Papers, The Conferences at Cairo and Tehran. Available at: http:// digicoll.library.wisc.edu/cgi-bin/FRUS/FRUS-idx?type=turn&entity=FRUS.FRUS1943Cairo Tehran.p0551&id=FRUS.FRUS1943CairoTehran&isize=text. Accessed 16 July 2014. Carlson, L.H. (2002) Remembered Prisoners of a Forgotten War: An Oral History of the Korean War POWs, New York: St. Martin’s Press. 192

The Korean War and its politics

Carruthers, S. (2009) Cold War Captives: Imprisonment, Escape, and Brainwashing, Berkeley: University of California Press. Chae, G. (2010) ‘Captive Minds: Race, War and the Education of Korean War POWs in U.S. Custody, 1950–1953’ (unpublished thesis), Chicago: The University of Chicago. Chen, J. (1994) China’s Road to the Korean War: The Making of the Sino-American Confrontation, New York: Columbia University Press. ‘Chinese Communist and U.S. Statements on Korea,’ New York Times, 16 December 1952. Chŏng, Y.-U. (2004), ‘6.25 Jŏnjaenggi ppirae natanan jŏkŭi imiji,’ (‘The Image of the Leaflet Enemy during the Korean War’), Naeilŭl yŏnŭn yŏksa (History of Tomorrow) 16 (Summer): 217–226. Counter Intelligence Corp. (1950). ‘Monthly Report of Counter Intelligence Corps Activities, 1 October 1950 for Month Reported September, to HQ 441 CIC Team, EUSAK,’ Folder ‘32.2 CIC Inter September 1950 to Jan 1951,’ Box 51, RG 338, National Archives. Cumings, B. (1981) Origins of the Korean War, Vol. 1, Seoul: Yuksabipyungsa. Cumings, B. (1990) Origins of the Korean War, Vol. 2, Seoul: Yuksabipyungsa. Cumings, B. (1997) Korea’s Place in the Sun: A Modern History, New York: W.W. Norton & Company. Cumings, B. (1999) ‘Boundary Displacement: The State, The Foundations, and International and Area Studies During and After the Cold War,’ in B. Cumings Parallax Visions: Making Sense of AmericanEast Asian Relations at the End of the Century (pp. 173–204), Durham, NC: Duke University Press. ‘Doraol ŭiyonggun’ (Returning Righteous Army). (1950) Seoul Sinmun, National Library, South Korea, 15 November. Eckert, C., Lee, K.B., Lew, Y.I., Robinson, M., Wagner, E.W. (1990) Korea Old and New: A History, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Eckert, C. (1991) Offspring of Empire: The Koch’ang Kims and the Colonial Origins of Korean Capitalism, 1876–1945, Seattle: University of Washington Press. Edwards, Paul (1998) The Korean War: An Annotated Bibliography, Westport: Greenwood Press. Foot, R. (1990) A Substitute for Victory: The Politics of Peacemaking at the Korean Armistice Talks, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Foot, R. (1985) The Wrong War: American Policy and the Dimensions of the Korean Conflict, 1950–1953, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Hanley, C.J., Choe, S.H., and Mendoza, M. (2001) The Bridge at No Gun Ri, New York: Henry Holt & Company. Hunt, M. (1987) Ideology and U.S. Foreign Policy, New Haven: Yale University Press. Kennan, G.F. (1947) ‘The Sources of Soviet Conduct,’ Foreign Affairs 25, 4: 566–582. Kim, C.B. (1996) ‘The Korean Scholars on the Korean War’, in L. Brune (ed.) The Korean War: Handbook of the Literature and Research (pp. 157–172), Westport: Greenwood Press. Kim, H.-J. (1975) Korean Affairs and International Politics, Seoul: Park Yong Sa Publishing. Kim, H.-J. (1989) The Korean War: Origins, Process, Truce and Influence, Seoul: Park Yong Sa Publishing. Kim, S. (2013) Everyday Life in the North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Lee, S.H. (2001) The Korean War, Harlow: Longman. Lowe, P. (1997) The Origins of the Korean War (2nd ed.), London: Longman. MacDonald, C.A. (1986) Korea: The War Before Vietnam, New York: Free Press. The Manchurian Candidate (1962), motion picture, MGM, United States. Matray, J.I. (1985) The Reluctant Crusade: American Foreign Policy in Korea, 1941–1950, Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. McCormack, G. (1983) Cold War, Hot War: An Australian Perspective of the Korean War, Sydney: Hale & Iremonger. Oliver, R.T. (1954) Syngman Rhee: The Man Behind the Myth, New York: Dodd Mead & Company. Pak, M.-L. (1996, 2nd edn. 2006) The Origins and Coming of the Korean War, Vols. 1 and 2, Paju: Nanam Chulpan. Pasley, V. (1955) 21 Stayed: The Story of the American GI’s Who Chose Communist China: Who They Were and Why They Stayed, New York: Farrar, Straus & Cudahy. ‘“President” Rhee Renounces Japanese Sovereignty and Asks for Recognition; Plans Government Based on Principles Expressed by Wilson, Lincoln, and Washington’, New York Times 1 September 1919. Rafael, V.L. (1999) ‘Regionalism, Area Studies, and the Accidents of Agency’, The American Historical Review 104, 4 (October): 1208–1220. Rees, D. (1964) Korea: The Limited War, Baltimore: Penguin Books. 193

Grace J. Chae

Salmon, Andrew. (2009) ‘A Cartoonist at War: “Gobau’s” Korea, 1950’, The Asia-Pacific Journal 28–3-09 (13 July) pp. 1–13. http://japanfocus.org/site/make_pdf/3186. Accessed 23 July 2014. Stone, I.F. (1952) The Hidden History of the Korean War, New York: Monthly Review Press. Stueck, W.W. (1981) The Road to Confrontation: American Policy towards China and Korea, 1947–1950, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina. Shin, M. (2003) ‘Major Trends of Korean Historiography in the US’, Sungkyun Journal of East Asian Studies 3, 1 (February): 151–175. T’aebaek Sanmaek (Taebaek Mountains) (1994), motion picture, Taehung Pictures, South Korea. United Nations. (1950) ‘UN Security Council Resolution 84’, available at: http://digitalarchive. wilsoncenter.org/document/117725. Accessed July 14, 2014. United Nations-Office of the High Commissioner for Human Rights. (1949) Geneva Convention Relative to the Treatment of Prisoners of War Adopted 12 August 1949 by the Diplomatic Conference for the Establishment of International Conventions for the Protection of Victims of War, II. Art. 118. Available at: https://www. icrc.org/applic/ihl/ihl.nsf/Article.xsp?action=openDocument&documentId=1F24D0C949FE1B83C125 63CD0051B48C. Accessed 10 September 2015. Wada, H. (2014) The Korean War: An International History, trans. F. Baldwin, Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield. Weathersby, K. (1993) ‘Soviet Aims in Korea and the Origins of the Korean War, 1945–1950: New Evidence from the Russian Archives,’ Working Paper No. 8 (November), Cold War International History Project (CWIHP), Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center. Wilson, W. (1919) ‘Fourteen Points’. Presented at Paris Peace Conference, Paris, January 1919. http:// avalon.law.yale.edu/20th_century/wilson14.asp. Accessed 16 July 2014. Winn, D. (2000) The Manipulated Mind: Brainwashing, Conditioning and Indoctrination, Cambridge: Malor Press. Yuh, L. (2010) ‘The Historiography of Korea in the United States’, International Journal of Korean History, 15, 2 (August): 127–144.

194

Part IV

North Korea

This page intentionally left blank

14 North Korean state-making Process and characteristics Shin Jongdae

Introduction Understanding North Korea’s present and future requires an awareness of the country’s statemaking process. The end of World War II, the division of the Korean Peninsula, and the start of the Cold War created a sort of special “critical juncture” where the state and its institutions were able to exist on a continuous basis. The focus of historical institutionalism centers on the fact that an institution has a certain degree of “path dependence” and can continue to exist if that institution is decided by the choices of a special period under decisive conditions. The institutional formation and characteristics of the central elements of North Korea’s political system—the Party, military, and central government—that were formed in the compressed period between 1945 and the establishment of the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea in 1948 have remained almost unchanged up to this day. As a result, a clear understanding of the Kim Jong Un regime requires grasping the origins and characteristics of North Korea’s state-making process.1 Studies on North Korea’s state-making process have viewed it with a wide range of perspectives. One perspective argues that the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR) held considerable influence on North Korea’s state-making process. (Scalapino and Lee, 1972) According to this view, the establishment of the North Korean government was a series of political processes that occurred in line with a pre-planned program by the USSR, while the political, economic, social and cultural aspects of those areas under Soviet military influence were transformed by Korea’s communist party, in line with Stalin’s wishes. This analysis is based on the idea that the handling of important issues concerning North Korea from August 1945 to a certain period required the permission of Stalin and other high-ranking Soviet officials in Moscow. The Soviet military did in fact establish a central government institution and police offices in each region and worked hard to lead North Korea’s state construction by sometimes intervening in the minute details of the state-building process. Yet another perspective is that North Korea’s leaders themselves led the formation of their power structure (Cumings, 1990). This perspective argues that North Korea’s communists were not closely linked with the Soviet-led international communist movement, but were rather more autonomous and nationalistic in nature. Proponents of this argument say that not only 197

Shin Jongdae

did Kim Il Sung and other North Korean leaders have experience fighting against the Japanese, but the USSR also had to watch their own actions in North Korea in consideration of their relationship with the US. As such, in contrast with the Soviet satellites in Eastern Europe, the North Korean government had a certain degree of independence from the Soviets. Bruce Cumings, for example, argues that North Korea developed its own autonomous political system in the late 1940s under the influence of the Soviet Union and the People’s Republic of China, and that its political system had internal characteristics as a “revolutionary nationalist corporative.” Cumings argues that North Korea’s state-making process was a “uniquely North Korean phenomenon” and argues this likely was based on influence from traditional Confucianism. However, Charles Armstrong recently went one step further and argued that the origins of North Korea could be found in North Korea’s geographical situation and recent historical legacy rather than simply due to a revolution from the outside. In essence, Armstrong argues that the tradition of Choson Dynasty-era Confucian ideology, which emphasizes ideological awareness rather than physical conditions, influenced North Korea’s political leadership and that the North Korean system was formed through a combination of top-down communist planning and bottomup geographical conditions (Armstrong, 2003). The question of how to measure Kim Il Sung and other anti-Japanese fighters’ influence during the state-making process, how to prescribe the military and party relationship during the state-making process, and even deciding on a period in time North Korea’s state-making process took place are all continuing academic disputes. The most significant reason these disputes are continuing is because North Korean documents are unavailable to scholars—despite the fact North Korea has been in existence for some 70 years. While scholars are able to view North Korean military documents captured during the Korean War, and Soviet-era documents released after the end of the Cold War, the documents in existence have not answered all the questions concerning the who, when, and how of North Korea’s state-making process. As a result, any study on North Korea’s state-making process must balance its analysis on two broad areas of thought: the external factory theory (Soviet influence) and the internal factory theory (autonomous revolution). If too much focus is placed on the former perspective, there is no way to explain North Korea’s unique characteristics or autonomy. Likewise, if too much emphasis is placed on the latter, then the historical fact that the USSR had a decisive role in the state-making process may be overlooked. North Korean documents—when they are released—will likely reflect this complex understanding of the period. Understanding the mutual relationship between the “internal” and “external” factors inherent in the diplomatic policy decision process is required for a complete understanding of the era. As such, this paper aims to examine the characteristics of North Korea’s state-making process with a focus on the establishment of the Korean Workers’ Party (KWP), the North Korean People’s Committee (NKPC), and the Korean People’s Army (KPA) from liberation in August 1945 to the proclamation of the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea on 9 September 1948.

Establishment of the Korean Workers’ Party (KWP) As the Korean Peninsula found itself liberated after World War II, there were a wide range of leftist forces with experience fighting the Japanese in the northern part of the peninsula. This environment ensured that the early power structure of the KWP was composed of a wide range of political forces. The KWP began as a simple political association but gradually became a party centered on the leadership of Kim Il Sung, until ultimately it became the cradle of a one-man leadership system. There were, of course, several power conflicts during this progression that were coupled with changes in the Party’s structure. 198

North Korean state-making

After liberation, communists in northern Korea moved to establish a political party that would have a monopoly over power in the northern part of the country. The real formation of the KWP started with the establishment of the North Korean Branch Bureau of the KWP. From 5–8 October 1945, before the holding of the Conference of Responsible Leaders and Enthusiasts of Five Northwest Provinces of the Korean Communist Party, a preliminary meeting between the two groups was held in secret in Pyongyang. During this meeting, the establishment of an implementation department and central party leadership institution was discussed and a decision to create the North Korean Branch Bureau of the KWP was made. Following this, Kim Il Sung and some 70 other well-known communists from northern Korea held a meeting on 13 October 1945, in Pyongyang and decided to create a North Korean Branch Bureau of the KWP independent of the pre-existing Central Party in Seoul. Then, in accordance with the 13 October meeting’s decision, the North Korean Branch Bureau of the KWP was established on 20 October. The First Secretary was Kim Yong-bŏm, who represented the communist party in South Pyongan province, and the Second Secretary was O Ki-sŏp. Another 17 Executive Committee members were also elected. This meeting allowed Kim Il Sung to analyze the political situation both at home and abroad, make the establishment of the Democratic People’s Republic a fundamental political duty, and raise the question of holding a National Party Representative Meeting to deal with the Party construction project. Kim then proclaimed a new Party organization platform and political platform and presented the “Four National Objectives.” These “Four National Objectives” included the thorough formation of a democratic national unification platform to establish a Democratic People’s Republic; the cleansing of remaining supporters of Japanese colonialism, international anti-communist forces, and all other anti-socialist forces; the establishment of a basis for the construction of an independent democratic nation through the organization of a people’s committee and democratic reforms; and the expansion of the Party (I.S. Kim, 1947: 26–27). Of course, due to the existence of a Central Party in Seoul and the dynamic relationship between communist forces, the North Korean Central Communist Organization Committee was never established. Even at that time, Kim Il Sung had not yet won complete hegemony over the North Korean communists. Despite these restrictions, however, the Seoul Central Party’s General Secretary Pak Hŏnyŏng had no choice but to accept the establishment of the North Korean Branch Bureau of the KWP ten days after it was established on 23 October 1945. This moved the leadership of the North Korean communist movement from Seoul to Pyongyang. The North Korean Branch Bureau (NKBB) of the KWP held a series of Expanded Executive Committees (EEC) and increased its hegemony through the reestablishment of its political platform and refining its organizational system. During the 2nd EEC on 15 November 1945, Kim Il Sung argued that a discussion must take place on establishing a National Unification Platform Committee and Central Government Institution for the establishment of a Democratic People’s Republic. Given that Kim Il Sung was calling for the establishment of such institutions after a People’s Republic of Korea had already been proclaimed in Seoul, this meant that the North Korean Branch Bureau had become independent of the Central Party in Seoul. Following this, during the 3rd EEC from 17 to 18 December 1945, as the independent activities of the provincial and local parties continued, the question of reorganizing the Party organization and placing it under a central authority was discussed. This meeting adopted measures to make farmers Party members, issue a one-party-pass system, and improve procedures for entering the Party. Moreover, Kim Il Sung, who had become the NKBB Secretary, strongly moved forward with centralizing the authority of the Party, strengthening the central party’s control over local parties, and proposing new policy platforms. 199

Shin Jongdae

During the 4th EEC on 15 February 1946, Kim Il Sung called for the destruction of factions, strengthening of organizational life, promotion of the North Korean People’s Committee, and expansion of campaigns to support the committee. These proposals soon led the North Korean Central Party to fall under Kim Il Sung’s control. Ultimately, as Kim Il Sung strengthened and solidified his singular position, the NKBB changed its name to the North Korean Communist Party in April 1946 in order to heighten its status. As Kim Il Sung’s NKKB progressed in its activities, political changes on the Korean Peninsula accelerated the establishment of the KWP. After the suspension of the First Joint USUSSR Commission in Korea on 8 May 1946, the North Korean communists began mobilizing their forces to establish a national people’s government under the foundation of “revolutionary democratic base theory.” In short, this meant that the creation of the KWP would establish a strong, independent communist movement in North Korea, and would lead to the use of a wide range of neutral forces in both North and South Korea to expand communist influence on political events in South Korea. Importantly, Kim Il Sung aimed to increase his power both qualitatively and quantitatively through this process. The 7th EEC, held from 22–23 June 1946, decided to move forward with merging political parties in order to “establish a strong democratic independent nation” in northern Korea. On 26 June the North-South Communist Party High Official Committee was held and called for the successful joining of the three parties and the establishment of a “united front” of political parties. Of those parties within the Choson Independence Alliance, the North Korean Communist Party’s (NKCP) Friendship Party, which had changed its name to the Korean New Democratic Party (KNDP), was a target for alliance. The KNDP was led by Kim Tu-bong, Ch’oe Ch’angik and others, and had been established to see the creation of a Korean Democratic Republic. The reason the KNDP was a target for a merger was to allow the KWP to expand its popular base of support to allow the smooth advance of the national unification movement. On 23 July 1946, the KNDP sent a letter to the NKCP proposing the merger, and at the 8th EEC on 27 July 1946, the new political party was named the North Korean Workers’ Party (NKWP). At the Expanded Joint Party Central Committee on 29 July 1946, the “Two Party Merger Decision” and “Proclamation” were adopted. With this as a basis, a ceremony to establish the NKWP was held on 28 August 1946 and was attended by representatives from each province. In a speech during the ceremony, Kim Il Sung called for the Provisional People’s Committee to gradually become a People’s Committee in order to construct a democratic independent country, and called for the nationwide acceleration of the land reform, labor laws, nationalization of important industry, and democratic reform of the people’s education system. Moreover, the preliminary steps proposed by the Expanded Joint Party Central Committee formed the basis of the adoption of the five-article, 41-clause “Party Rules.” This committee also elected 43 Central Party members including Kim Tu-bong, Kim Il Sung, and Chu Yong-ha. Following this, the 1st Central Committee of the NKWP was held on 31 August 1946, and was presided over by Kim Il Sung. This committee formed the Political Committee and elected Kim Tu-bong as chairman, Kim Il Sung and Chu Yong-ha as vice chairmen, and Hŏ Ka-i and Ch’oe Ch’ang-Ik as committee members. It also established the Standing Committee, which provided leadership and carried out Party-related projects. The NKWP was a political party for people because it stated in the first clause of its regulations that its duties were to “construct a democratic independent Korean nation” and, in the second clause of its Party Rules, that it was to “be the representative and supporter for the benefit of Korean laborers, construct a strong democratic independent Korean nation that can preserve the democratic freedom of the labor masses, and improve the political, economic and cultural standards of the labor masses.” While 200

North Korean state-making

Table 14.1 Dates of KWP meetings and main topics of discussion Meeting title

Meeting date

Main topics of discussion

Korean Communist Northern Regional Office Establishment Rally

1945.10.10–13

Proposed the Four National Objectives

1st Expanded Executive Committee (EEC) of the North Korean Branch Bureau (NKBB)

1945.10.16

Discussed land, industry, education and culture issues

2nd EEC of the NKBB

1945.11.15–17

Discussed the establishment of the National Unification Association and Central Government Institution

3rd EEC of the NKBB

1945.12.17–18

Discussed laborers, farmers becoming Party members, issuing a single-partypass, improvement of Party entry rules

4th EEC of the North Korean Communist Party (NKCP)

1946.2.15

Discussed cleansing of factions, strengthening of organizational life, promoting the North Korean People’s Committee, and starting promotional movements

5th EEC of the NKCP

1946.3.4

Discussed implementation of land reform, creation of police force

6th EEC of the NKCP

1946.4.10

Discussed end of land reform and future objectives

7th EEC of the NKCP

1946.6.22–23

Implemented the Labor Law

8th EEC of the NKCP

1946.7.27

Merger between NKCP and KNDP

North Korean Workers Party 1946.8.28–30 (NKWP) Establishment Ceremony

Establishment of NKWP and election of Central Party members

the Party held to some degree of Marxist-Leninism doctrine, Kim Il Sung in October 1945 said that the duty of the Party was to construct a “democratic people’s republic” and construction of a communist nation was the ultimate goal. He further said that the Party should gradually move forward with the required and appropriate moves and doctrine. The NKWP started to establish itself as the highest leadership institution in North Korea, as it was connected loosely with other labor and popular organizations. Figures who were in charge of the Party’s major positions like Kim Il Sung and Kim Tu-bong held multiple positions within the People’s Committee. Furthermore, as the military and political organizations undergirding the Party and nation fell under the leadership of Kim Il Sung, North Korea’s power structure became one centered on Kim Il Sung. The NKWP’s establishment led to the creation of a Standing Committee and Political Committee inside the Central Party Committee, and this gave its members a small degree of authority, which led naturally to the strengthening of Kim Il Sung’s status within the Party and leadership system. Kim Il Sung moved to strengthen his leadership system and place his own supporters inside the Party by moving forward with the one-party-pass initiative, and decisions related to cadre placement and movement. Simultaneously, while Pak Hŏn-yŏng’s defection to the North in October 1946 led to some activities by the northern branch of the South Korean Workers’ Party (SKWP), Park and his party’s real influence had fallen drastically following the establishment of the NKWP and its expansion of power. As a result, the significance of the NKWP being established was that it 201

Shin Jongdae

was the only strong leftist party that held leadership over all communist movements in the country. While the NKWP’s Central Committee and other central institutions were somewhat of a political alliance, in reality they formed the basis for a single leadership system under Kim Il Sung.

Establishment of the North Korean People’s Committee (NKPC) In order to examine the establishment of the North Korean People’s Committee that followed the launch of the NKPC in November 1946 (Ryu, 2004:41–92) there is a need to examine the activities of the Soviet Army based in northern Korea after liberation and the how the local people’s committees were established.(S.B. Kim, 2011:28–29) Following liberation, people’s committees sprouted up in each of North Korea’s provinces and they formed a variety of departments to deal with cleansing Japanese colonialism supporters and managing local affairs. For example, in North Hamgyong Province—even before the Soviet Army entered the area— the Communist Association and North Hamgyŏng Province National Building Preparation Committee (NBPC) was recognized by the Soviet Army and became the North Hamgyong Province People’s Committee on 30 August with Cho Man-sik as chairman. Soon the Soviet Army reformed this group into the South Pyongan Province People’s Political Committee and kept Cho as its chairman. As this shows, in general the people’s committees were established under an alliance between nationalist and socialist forces, and this fell into the Soviet plan of created forces that were friendly to the Soviets. The Soviets were well aware that they could not handle the Korean question all by themselves and had plans to consider the interests of the US and other countries. In short, in the beginning of the Soviet presence, they supported the establishment of local people’s committees and tried to use them to manage the affairs of state, but also made efforts to stay in the background (Ryu, 2004:55). However, the local people’s committees, as they became more centralized, ultimately moved toward becoming the NKPC. The Conference of Responsible Leaders and Enthusiasts of Five Northwest Provinces of the Korean Communist Party from 8–10 October 1945, was hosted by the Soviet Army Command and led to the regional people’s committees becoming more unified. In people’s committee meetings held in each province on 19 November 1945, the Soviet military government and North Korean leadership succeeded in establishing the ten administrative departments for the unified management of North Korea’s five provinces. This process led to the completion of a unified tax system and creation of a police force. That being said, the activities of the ten departments were independent of each other in each province, the activities did not last long, and other reasons, including the lack of Korean experience and lack of communication between the central and regional institutions, led the Soviet Army Command to view the whole project as a failure. However, the establishment of the ten administrative departments overcame the complexity managing the once disparate local people’s committees and their establishment ensured the efficiency and unification of managing local affairs. Given that the later North Korean Provisional People’s Committee and its central department inherited the system of the ten administrative departments, the experiment had some impact on the establishment of the future North Korean government. As the people’s committees became more centralized, the international political situation gradually led to the establishment of an independent government within North Korea. Before the opening of the First US-USSR Joint Committee, the North Koreans and Soviets had two goals: 1) apply the format of the government established in North Korea into the provisional Korean government; 2) secure the North Korean system as a response to the establishment of 202

North Korean state-making

an independent government in South Korea. In February 1946, political parties including the NKBB of the KWP established a committee to construct a central institution in North Korea and appointed Kim Chae as chairman, and Kang Yang-uk and Chu Yong-ha as vice chairmen. On 7 February a preliminary meeting by the political parties was held to establish the NKPC, and on the 8th, an expanded meeting of provincial, city and gun people’s committee representatives was held to establish the North Korean Temporary People’s Committee (NKTPC) with Kim Il Sung as chairman, and Kim Tu-bong and Kang Yang-uk as vice chairmen. The NKTPC was considered the highest administrative institution in North Korea and had judicial and legislative authority. According to the regulations concerning the establishment of the NKTPC, it “has the authority to legislate and announce temporary laws for the people, social groups and national institutions (Clause 3); correct incorrect decisions by each department and provincial people’s committees; and is the highest administrative sovereign unit in North Korea (Clause 4).” The NKTPC had to “conduct the laws and decisions announced by the Soviet Military Command” so North Korea’s authority was shared between the NKTPC and the Soviet Military. The 11 national objectives solidified arguments for the NKWP’s democratic base theory in preparation for the US-USSR Joint Commission. On 23 March 1946, the 20 platforms, which solidified the 11 objectives even more, included the cleansing of Japanese colonialist elements, a guarantee of democratic freedom, the establishment of democratic elections, the securing of democratic rights of the people, the nationalization of industry, land reform, and democratic reform as the fundamental tasks for the provisional democratic government. The various policies that were implemented immediately after the establishment of the NKTPC not only set the basic direction of North Korea’s state-making process but formed the basis for North Korean communists to organize and solidify North Korean society in a way that was favorable to themselves. The land reform project was completed thoroughly and swiftly under the basic principle of free forfeit and free distribution. Land reform was swiftly completed due to the mobilization of the people by local political parties and social groups, and the project reflected directly the enthusiasm of the farmers at the time, thus increasing the authority of the government. Beginning with land reform, the government implemented taxes of agricultural goods, a labor law, a gender equality law, the nationalization of important industry, education reform, the systemization of local people’s committees, and the reorganization of administrative units. The measure to nationalize important industries was significant because it aimed to destroy the colonial-era ownership system and both restore and secure a planned economy. As the industrial sector came under the control of the communist party and people’s committees, communist party cadres were not only able to grow their power, but establish themselves as a both economic and social leaders. As the NKTPC began its activities and the basis of state-building commenced, the halt of the US-USSR Joint Commission on 8 May 1946, allowed the North Korean communists to place more emphasis on establishing a national people’s government in accordance with the revolutionary democratic base theory. By November 1946, the North Korean communists believed that the results of the democratic reforms had been shown, and the systemic framework of the North Korean government had been formed. As such, they attempted to create legal government institutions. In August 1946, citizen passes were issued to facilitate the holding of an election. During the 2nd EEC of the Provisional People’s Committee on 5 September 1946, it was proposed that each people’s committee be confirmed through an election. Through these preliminary preparations, the TPC held an election on 3 November 1946, where 3,459 provincial, municipal and local people’s committee members were elected. The 203

Shin Jongdae

Table 14.2 Establishment of the NKPC Major event

Date

Details

Conference of the Five Provincial People’s Committees

1945.10.8–10

Discussion on the new government organ system

Creation of the North Korean 10 Administrative Departments

1945.11.19

Implementation of a central administrative unit by sector to for economic linkage between each province

Establishment of North Korean Provisional People’s Committee

1946.2.7–8

Role of North Korea’s highest administrative unit decided, nationalization of important industry, land reform and democratic reform conducted

Election of North Korean People’s Committee members

1946.11.3

Election of provincial, municipal, and local People’s Committee members

Establishment of North Korean People’s Committee

1947.2.22

NKPC becomes country’s highest executive unit through regular election with Kim Il Sung as chairman

NKWP received the highest support of all the parties with 32% of the vote. In February 1947, provincial, municipal and other local PC meetings were held, and the land reform law, industry nationalization law, labor law, gender equality law and other laws that had formed the basis of democratic reform over the past year were officially approved. Finally, on 20 February, the NKPC was created and became recognized as North Korea’s highest governmental organ. The establishment of the NKPC was approved under the precondition of “until the establishment of a unified temporary government by the US-USSR Joint Commission.” Ch’oe Yong-gŏn, who chaired the Central Committee of the North Korean Democratic National Unification Front, proposed Kim Il Sung as the chairman of the NKPC and the body adopted this proposal. On 22 February, the NKPC became the country’s highest executive institution with Kim Il Sung as its chair, and along with the Pyongyang Special City People’s Committee (PC), six provincial PCs, 12 municipal PCs, and 90 local PCs were established. Discussions on passing a constitution were held during the NKPC’s third meeting, 18–19 November 1947. During the meeting, 31 temporary constitution legislation members were delegated to discuss the issue, and the group’s first meeting was held on 20 November. On 29 April 1948, this special committee unanimously adopted a draft of a constitution. The draft upheld sovereignty for the people with the people’s committees as the basis, and focused on “people’s democracy” due the fact in the economic sphere it recognized state ownership, cooperative ownership and individual ownership. The characteristics and significance of the NKPC are as follows. First, the NKPC was an extension of North Korea’s People’s Committees and the ten administrative departments and was significant for having gained legitimacy through an election. Second, the NKPC was created as the highest executive organ separate from the NKPM, where the NKPC held executive functions while the NKPM held sovereignty. Third, while the NKPC did succeed with the TPC’s democratic reforms, it moved to bring socialist change to the country. Fourth, the establishment of the NKPC meant that the influence the Soviet military had on North Korean politics had decreased. 204

North Korean state-making

Establishment of the Korean People’s Army (KPA) The creation of the Korean People’s Army on 9 February 1948 occurred within the mutual relationship between the Party and military. In short, the creation of the Party and military were closely related to each other. The major turning point in the establishment of the KPA was due to the Soviet military. On 12 October 1945, the Soviet military ordered the disarmament of all organizations in northern Korea and the creation of a new police force. At the 5th EEC of the KWP, the decision to officially create a regular military force was made. The NKTPC led the creation of a security force to protect the border, the 38th parallel and railways. In June 1946 in Kaech’on, South P’yŏngan province, a security cadre training camp, which would serve as the central base for the future regular military, was established, and on 8 July the North Korean Central Security Cadre School was opened to train military cadres. The security force, which would become the basis for the army, navy and air force, was also created. In early October 1945, marine security divisions were established along the coasts, and in December 1946, these were expanded to form the coast guard. In October 1945, civilians led the formation of the Sinuiju Airbase in Sinuiju, and in August 1947, a regular plane division was formed, which later become the air force. On 15 August 1946, the cadre training division, as the managing organ of all armed forces, was newly created. This institution was led by the regular military’s chiefs of staff, with Ch’oe Yong-gŏn as commander, Kim Il Sung as deputy commander, and Mu Chŏng as artillery commander. These former guerrilla fighters took the highest-ranking positions in the military, which strengthened Kim Il Sung’s and the guerrilla faction’s control over the regular armed forces. In September 1946, a Soviet military advisor group arrived in North Korea and was stationed at each training camp and military school to accelerate the creation of the armed forces. This process brought once disparate armed forces to unite under the single authority of the cadre training division, and this division was headed by former guerrilla fighters like Ch’oe Yong-gŏn, An Kil, and Kim Il Sung. On 15 April 1947, Kim Il Sung sent a message to the Soviets requesting weapons and other material for the North Korean military, and the Soviets responded by sending weapons and equipment. This allowed the NK forces to expand to 6–7 divisions and two army groups. On 17 May 1947, Kim Il Sung instituted a new hierarchy system and the base was renamed to the “People’s Group Army” (PGA). Ch’oe Yong-gŏn was kept as head of the PGA, along with the other chiefs of staff. Following decisions made by the KWP Central Committee on 2 February 1948 and the NKPC on 4 February, the National Security Department was established as the North Korean military’s administrative headquarters and Kim Ch’aek was named its head. This allowed fluid management between the government and military. On 9 February 1948, the KPA was officially established. Kim Il Sung emphasized that the KWP was “a Korean people’s army made by the Korean people,” and not for the Party. Ch’oe Yong-gŏn was named head of the KPA Central Command, Kim Il the deputy commander and cultural commander, and Mu Chŏng the artillery commander. The KPA First Division commander was Kim Ung, Second Division Commander Yi Lee Chong-song, and the head of the Third Hongsong Infantry Brigade was Kim Kwang-hyŏp. After the KPA was officially established, the number of soldiers in each division increased due to cooperation with Party organizations. Moreover, the KPA’s fighting power decisively increased as the Chinese-Korean soldiers returned to North Korea following their participation in China’s civil war. This led to an increase from 27,000 soldiers in 1948 to 120,000 soldiers in 1950. 205

Shin Jongdae

Table 14.3 Establishment of the KWP Major event

Date

Details

Soviet Commander Order

1945.10.12

All armed groups must disband and establishment of new police force

5th EEC of the Central NKCP

1946.3.4

Decision to establish police force

Establishment of Defense Officers Training School (DOTD)

1946.6

Cultivation of officers for national defense

Establishment of Defense Officers Training Division

1946.8.15

Acts as highest unit of the regular military

DOTD is expanded and renamed the People’s Group Army

1947.5.17

Ch’oe Yong-go ˘ n is maintained as head of PGA

KPA (Korean People’s Army) established

1948.2.8

KPA Central Command establishment and Chae Yong-go ˘ n named as Supreme Commander

In summary, former guerrilla fighters centered-around Kim Il Sung became the central force in solidifying social forces under the cooperation of the SAC. During the vacuum period (May 1946 to May 1947) until the 2nd US-USSR Joint Commission was held, they created and expanded their military power. As the possibility of establishing a unified North-South government faded, a regular army called the People’s Group Army was created on 17 May 1947, and this was made official on 9 February 1948. The establishment of the KWP was an inherently developmental process and, along with the Party and people’s committees, formed the material basis of North Korea’s state-building.

Characteristics of North Korea’s state-building process The influence of the anti-Japanese guerrilla faction and Kim Il Sung’s autonomy The anti-Japanese guerrilla faction played an important role in the North Korean state-building process and allowed Kim Il Sung to have decisive influence within the Party and military2 (H.S. Paek, 1994:396–398). The guerrilla faction, which was more or less Kim Il Sung’s political capital, had been relatively weaker than other forces but had an outstanding ability to be cohesive. Kim Il Sung, through the anti-Japanese campaigns and “Arduous March” had a unique identity and confidence that was distinguished even among other Korean communists. During the campaigns against the Japanese, the experience of political training he received allowed him to demonstrate a high degree of political influence among the many forces that existed in North Korea following liberation (K.U. Kim, 2003:106–110). The guerrilla faction began appearing in Pyongyang in early September 1945 and expanded its influence. The faction was able to carry influence for several reasons. First, Kim Il Sung was already well known to Koreans due to his armed campaigns against the Japanese in the 1930s. Second, even though he was under the control of the Soviet army, he displayed a high degree of independence (Seo, 1998:269). Third, he displayed a strong sense of uniformity compared with other political forces. Fourth, he made the armed struggle against the Japanese a central 206

North Korean state-making

platform while placing priority on personally dominating the military. Moreover, because there was no legitimate platform as important as having the experience of fighting against the Japanese, Kim was able to emphasize his experience and expand his influence domestically while retaining a certain degree of autonomy from the Soviets. As we examined in the process of establishing North Korea’s regular army, the emphasis on the military strength of the guerrilla faction, its strong cohesiveness, and legitimacy all played a major role in its domination of the country’s military forces. Following the establishment of the North Korean government, the guerrilla faction became the generational cradle of the North Korean power elite and became the central symbol in strengthening the justification for Kim and his successors.

Soviet influence While there was some degree of academic discussion on the influence of the Soviets during North Korea’s state-building process, generally it is understood the Soviets had considerable impact on the period. Soviet policies had a major impact on important phases of the statebuilding process and tremendous influence of the creation of regular military forces (Wada, Seo and Nam, 2003:72–73). First is the impact Stalin’s orders had on overall Soviet policy. After the Soviets occupied northern Korea on 20 September 1945, Stalin ordered that the Soviets should “support all of northern Korea’s anti-Japanese democratic parties and organizational blocks in order to establishing a proletariat democratic power,” and that the Soviets should “not interrupt the formation of anti-Japanese democratic organizations and parties, and instead support them.” Then on 12 October 1945, the Soviet military permitted the establishment of anti-Japanese democratic organizations and activities. Given that the NKBB of the KWP was created the very next day on 13 October means there is a high possibility that the Soviet military cleared the way for it. (K.U. Kim, 2003:152) As a result, socialist forces were able to expand significant political influence due to Stalin’s orders for support of their activities. The orders Stalin made in July 1946 also became the procedures for creating the Party and military. Stalin appeared to have decided to just turn North Korea into a socialist country after the failure of the First US-USSR Joint Commission at the end of June 1946. In the middle of July 1947, Stalin proposed during a meeting with Kim Il Sung and Pak Hŏn-yŏng the merger of the Communist and New Democratic Parties to create a new party. This led to the merger of the two parties and a drastic increase in members and increased influence (Wada, Seo, Nam, 2002:83–84). Moreover, during the creation of the People’s Committee, the Soviets did not get involved in the specifics of its establishment or composition, but they did manage, to some degree, the establishment of the Department of Civil Administration (DCA) and its political issues. The head of the DCA, Andrey Romanenko, took over the administration work managed by the local people’s committee and placed advisors in each province (Ryu, 2004:58). Additionally, the Soviets played a decisive role in the establishment and train of the KPA. Following the return of the Korean volunteer army, they received Soviet-style basic training as they were integrated into the regular army. There were at least three Soviet advisors for each regiment, and training plans followed Soviet military principles. This allowed soldiers who had experience fighting against the Nationalists in China to complete 2–4 months of training before being integrated into the North Korean army (K.U. Kim, 2003:577).

207

Shin Jongdae

Relationship between the Party and military While the Party and military were somewhat separate organizations, the experience of building the Party was used in creating the military and this led to the KWP being created in a short period (Jang, 2012:169). The creation of education programs was required for establishing the Party, military and government. One area in which the relationship between the Party and military was prominently displayed was in how the educational system used during the creation of the Party was the same as the political education system used in the military. Another point showing how the establishment of the Party and military was similar was that the Pyongyang School Political Class was turned into the North Korean Communist Central Officers Training School, while the military class became the Central Defense Officials Training School. Moreover, a cultural department was formed and a Soviet political committee member system was adopted in order to establish a culture and political department. As a result, the Party had some degree of influence over the military.

Beginning of “nation approval diplomacy” by the Soviet Union and China The North Korean leadership’s goal was to create a socialist country, and as such the country’s diplomacy was focused on creating a favorable international environment. As such, North Korean policymakers placed as their diplomatic policies’ major goals: 1) creation of a favorable international environment for establishment of their government and implementation of socialism; 2) establishment of a united provisional government that would prevent national division; and 3) after the creation of the government, build the basis for activities on the international stage. (Park, 1985:60) In accordance with these goals, North Korea created a host of organizations that conducted exchanges with the various international organizations and formed the basis to enter the international stage through Party-to-Party exchanges rather than nation-to-nation diplomacy. After the government was proclaimed on 9 September 1948, it began establishing diplomatic relations with socialist countries like the Mongolian People’s Republic, Poland, Czechoslovakia, and Romania. Of course, while diplomatic relations with Eastern European countries were established and cooperation began with third-world countries, the most important relationships North Korea had were with the USSR and China. North Korea understood the USSR to be a proactive supporter of the Korean National Liberation Movement and the only ally to protect and support the country and revolution. During the country’s state-building process, Soviet authorities’ and the military’s influence was absolute. While North Korea received proactive guidance and support from the USSR during its statebuilding process, it also actively moved to establish relations with China. The North Korean government supported the Chinese Communist Party during the course of the Chinese Civil War, including sending a volunteer army of some 100,000 men led by Ch’oe Kwang and other former guerrilla fighters; large numbers of artillery and ammunition; permission for Chinese soldiers to move through the Korean Peninsula to enter China’s northeastern provinces; and permission for Chinese soldiers to use the North Korean region as a rear base. As a result, the solidarity between Kim Il Sung and the Chinese Communist Party grew, and the return of soldiers who fought in the Chinese Civil War to North Korea greatly assisted the construction of the country’s regular military forces. The relationship with China was strengthened even more through the Korean War and the relationship became a major pillar of North Korean diplomacy. 208

North Korean state-making

Conclusion To understand present-day North Korea it is important to first understand how the country was established. As the above shows, Kim Il Sung and North Korea’s leadership built the basis for North Korea’s system by dominating the Party, government organs, and military. We must focus on this state-making period because the framework of Kim Il Sung’s system was built during this period and was maintained, strengthened, and continually institutionalized, even after the Korean War. While the Kim Il Sung one-man leadership model was not fully institutionalized until the 1960s and 1970s, we are able to examine the KWP’s domination during the state-making period and the fluid relationship between the Party and State systems. This framework requires close examination because it has continued even today with the thirdgeneration succession to Kim Jong Un. This paper’s main points can be summarized into the following. First, the KWP’s origins can be found in the establishment of the KCP NKNF. On 13 October 1945, around 70 of the most famous communists in northern Korea met to form an organization that would be separate from the Central Party in Seoul. During the 2nd EEC of the NKNF on 14 November 1945, a discussion was held concerning the organization of a central government organ. Through a series of expanded plenums, the Party’s control over the central system and local parties occurred, along with a merger with the Korean New Democratic Party. The KWP was formed between 28 and 30 August 1946. Along with the establishment of the KWP, the NKPC was established. After liberation, each people’s committee in the provinces became part of a new government organ system following the Five Provincial People’s Committees and later as the ten administrative departments were established. As the NKTPC was established between 7 and 8 February 1946, it became North Korea’s most powerful administrative unit and began nationalizing important industries and implementing land reform and democratic reforms. Following this, a people’s committee election was held and on 22 February 1947, the North Korean People’s Committee was established with Kim Il Sung as its head. Finally, the establishment of the KWP was established, similarly to the Party and government organs. The Soviets released an order to disband all armed organizations and created a new police force. This was followed by the establishment of the Defense Officers Training Facility and training cadres began. On 15 August 1946, the Central Defense Officers Facility was established, and military power increased. It is a fact there have been a wide variety of discussions concerning North Korea’s statemaking process. It is unquestionable that the Soviets, including their aid and guidance, played a decisive role in the early stages of state-building and in the KWP’s establishment. However, it is also true that internal factors like Kim Il Sung and the partisan faction’s leadership also played an important role. Moreover, factors such as the Confucian tradition and unique socialcultural environment also made North Korea’s state-making process different than those in Eastern Europe. The special succession structure between Kim Il Sung, Kim Jong Il, and Kim Jong Un originated from these social and cultural factors. As a result, future research on North Korea’s state-making process will have to explain how these social-cultural factors combined to impact North Korea’s state-making process.

209

Shin Jongdae

Notes 1

2

For more on historical institutionalism please see S. Steinmo, K. Thelen, and F. Longstreth, eds., Structuring Politics: Historical institutionalism in comparative analysis (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992). For more on this see Han H.K., “Wounded Nationalism: The Minsaengdan Incident and Kim Il Sung in Eastern Manchuria” (Ph.D. diss., 1999). University of Washington.

References North Korean References (in Korean) Kim, I. S., (1947) The One Year Anniversary of the North Korean Workers’ Party, Pyongyang: Korean Workers’ Party Publishing. Park, T.H. (1985) Diplomatic History of the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea Vol.1, Pyongyang: SocialScience Publishing.

South Korean References (in Korean) Jang, S. J. (2012) ‘The Formation and Significance of the Party-Military Relationship During the Establishment Period of the North Korean Military,’ Modern North Korean Research, 15. 3, pp. 169–196. Kim, K.U. (2003) North Korean Political History Research 1: History of the Party, State and Military Establishment, Seoul: Seonin. Kim, S.B. (2011) 20th Century Korean History: North Korean History 1, Seoul: Critical History. Paek, H.S. (1994) ‘Kim Il Sung’s Autonomy Issue During the Formation of the North Korean State.’ International Political Review, 28. 2, pp. 396–399. Paek, S.H. (2005) ‘Research into Characteristics of North Korean Diplomacy During the StateEstablishment Period,’ North Korean Research Academic Review, 9. 2, pp 233-254. Ryu, G.J. (2004) The Formation Process of the North Korean State: Research on the Organization and Activities of People’s Committees, Seoul: Kyungnam University Press. Seo, D.M. (1998) ‘The Historical Formation of North Korea’s Party-Military Relationship: Focus on the Period of Establishment to Right Before the Korean War’ Diplomatic-Security Research 3. Wada, H., Seo, D.M., and Nam, G.J. (2002) North Korea, Seoul: Dolbaegae.

English-Language References Armstrong, C.K. (2003) The North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Cumings, B. (1990) The Origins of the Korean War, Vol. II, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Paik, H.S. (1993) ‘North Korean State Formation, 1945–1950,’ (Ph.D. diss.), University of Pennsylvania. Scalapino, R.A. and Lee, C.K. (1972) Communism in Korea, Berkeley: University of California Press. Seiler, S.A. (1994) Kim Il-song, 1941–1948: The Creation of a Legend, the Building and a Regime, Lanham, Md.: University Press of America. Strong, A.L. (1950) Inside North Korea: An Eyewitness Account, Montrose, CA. Suh, D.S. (1988) Kim Il Sung: The North Korean Leader, New York: Columbia University Press. Yang S.C. (1994) The North and South Korean Political Systems: a Comparative Analysis, Boulder CO: Westview Press.

210

15 North Korea’s chuch’e philosophy James F. Person

The Democratic People’s Republic of Korea (DPRK or North Korea) upholds the concept of chuch’e (also spelled Juche) as the nation’s official political philosophy. North Korea today maintains that chuch’e, often translated as “self-reliance,” is an idea that has “clarified the philosophical principle that the man [sic] is the master of everything and that he decides everything and, on this basis, illuminated the absolutely correct way of shaping man’s destiny.”1 In this respect, chuch’e turns Marxism-Leninism, which places material conditions as the driving force in historical progress, upside down. Establishing chuch’e, according to official website of the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea, means “adopting the attitude of a master towards the revolution and construction of one’s country. It means maintaining an independent and creative standpoint in finding solutions to the problems which arise in the revolution and construction. It implies solving those problems mainly by one’s own efforts and in conformity with the actual conditions of one’s own country.”2 In practice, chuch’e has meant many things over the years and was later transformed into an instrument of autocratic rule, but at the basis of the idea is an effort to promote and sustain an autonomous national subjectivity. North Korea claims that the concept of chuch’e was original to the country’s founding leader, the anti-Japanese guerrilla fighter Kim Il Sung, who led the country from its founding in 1948 until his death in 1993. This claim is inaccurate, as chuch’e as an expression of national subjectivity had been part of nationalist discourse in East Asia since the late nineteenth century. Following the imposition of the Western nation-state system and post-Westphalian concept of sovereign equality in the late nineteenth century, Japanese scholars, starting with Fukuzawa Yukichi, first imported, translated, and assimilated the term.3 In Korea, the term emerged as part of a project to produce an autonomous Korean subjectivity by nationalists of every political persuasion concerned with safeguarding, and later restoring, Korea’s national sovereignty. Such individuals included the anarchist historian Sin Chaeho (Sin Ch’ae-ho), conservative Kim Ku, progressive activist Yeo Unhyeong (Yŏ Un-hyŏng), and Marxist historian Paek Namun (Paek Nam-un). Kim Il Sung reportedly used terms expressing an autonomous Korean subjectivity throughout the 1940s and early 1950s. However, his earliest known use of the term chuch’e was in April 1955, though he is best known for having used the term more extensively in a speech in December of the same year. The speech, entitled “On Eliminating Dogmatism and Formalism 211

James F. Person

and Establishing Juche in Ideological Work,” was delivered on December 28 to propaganda and agitation workers following the conclusion of an enlarged plenary session of the Central Committee (CC) of the ruling Korean Worker’s Party (KWP). The speech focused primarily on perceived mistakes in the fields of ideology, literature, and education, but also touched upon problems with North Korea’s foreign relations. The speech bore a distinctive postcolonial nationalist character as Kim called for the formation of a national subject after centuries of Korean leaders willfully subordinated the country to China, followed by decades of Japanese colonial rule. He criticized the work of party propagandists for dogmatism and formalism and a lack of chuch’e, i.e. a lack of national subjectivity, through their mechanical replication and celebration of foreign cultural, economic, and political practices. Examples he gave of these shortcomings included the celebration of foreign literature while ignoring the achievements of Korean writers, not teaching Korean history while teaching Soviet history, and promoting Soviet economic achievements while ignoring the accomplishments of Korea’s own postwar economic transformation. “In our propaganda and agitation work,” Kim noted, “there are numerous examples where only things foreign are extolled while our own are slighted.”4 Kim complained of seeing displayed in a democratic hall of culture diagrams illustrating the Soviet Union’s Five-Year Plan, but nothing on North Korea’s own Three-Year Plan; images of the Siberian steppe in a People’s Army rest home; and portraits of only foreign cultural figures, including Mayakovsky and Pushkin, in primary schools. The imitation and glorification of foreign cultural, political, and economic practices conveyed a message to the Korean people that Korea had little of value to celebrate. It was a speech fundamentally concerned with instilling national pride in the Korean people. Analysts of North Korea have long treated Kim’s use of the term chuch’e in the December 1955 speech as a declaration of a singularly Korean ideology of “self-reliance” and, as such, as a declaration of independence from the Soviet Union and China.5 It is also treated as the opening salvo in a major attack on Kim Il Sung’s political opponents. The speech has therefore been portrayed as a watershed moment in the ideological history of North Korea. These analyses in many ways reflect the later status chuch’e was given by the North Koreans, but it does not reflect the reality of the period. For one, these interpretations ignore the fact that Kim Il Sung did not use the term chuch’e again until the early 1960s. Moreover, by the time North Korea began to treat chuch’e as an official governing ideology, the idea had transformed significantly. In December 1955, Kim’s use of the term chuch’e was not an expression of a unique and fully-formed North Korean ideology. What is missing from many analyses of the speech is the context in which it was delivered. Two contemporary developments in particular are necessary to consider. First, following the death of Soviet leader Joseph Stalin in March 1953, the socialist camp, which had become much more diverse after the Second World War, had many problems with which to grapple. The new Kremlin leadership recognized that the differing national perspectives and interests of other socialist countries could not be indefinitely suppressed as they had been under Stalin. Moscow’s relations with Josip Broz Tito’s Yugoslavia epitomized many of the challenges facing the Soviet leadership. Tito had liberated his country from Axis powers with limited direct support of the Soviet Red Army, and therefore felt less compelled to subordinate Yugoslavia’s interests to those of Stalin’s Soviet Union after the war. From 1948, Tito faced the very real prospect of Soviet aggression because of his independence. However, starting in 1955, Nikita Khrushchev lessened tensions with Tito, and began softening the Soviet line on issues such as the universality of the Soviet experience and the Soviet model, and how to account for historical and national peculiarities. This is a process that started in the summer of 1955 with a Soviet-Yugoslav summit. But there were limits to the degree of autonomy and national 212

North Korea’s chuch’e philosophy

distinctiveness Moscow would tolerate. Just over a year after the process of reconciliation with Tito’s Yugoslavia began, Soviet tanks rolled into Hungary to protect socialism against so-called “reactionary elements” of the Hungarian party. Kim Il Sung, like Tito, believed in the need for greater autonomy and the need to account for national peculiarities. However, when he delivered his speech in December 1955, Moscow was still reconciling with Yugoslavia and continued to struggle with these questions. Accepting differences had not fully become the norm in the socialist camp. It is therefore important not to place too much emphasis on Kim exercising more autonomy and expressing national distinctiveness as part of a Soviet-sanctioned, bloc-wide trend.6 This is particularly the case because in 1955 Moscow had not been accepting of—and actively sought to thwart—North Korean policies that did not follow the Soviet model. Therefore, Kim’s December 1955 speech was in part an attempt by Kim to minimize Moscow’s ability to impose on North Korea Soviet experiences and models in economic development and culture. He did this by discouraging officials in the ruling Korean Worker’s Party from mechanically replicating Soviet practices. This is the critical context missing from most analyses of the December 1955 speech in which Kim Il Sung used the term “chuch’e.” Over the previous two years, ever since the Korean War armistice, Kim Il Sung had been engaged in a protracted debate over postwar economic development strategies within the ruling Korean Worker’s Party (KWP). His vision for postwar reconstruction was also directly challenged by the patron allies financing national reconstruction. At stake were principled positions on the vision for a postwar North Korea. On one side of the debate inside the KWP was Kim Il Sung, who did not wish to simply reconstruct the factories destroyed during the war but promoted a policy of general industrialization in an effort to rectify colonial-era distortions to the national economy and to strengthen national security. Kim Il Sung sought to maximize the use of the massive amounts of aid given to North Korea after the war to replace the country’s poorly integrated industrial structure with complementary industries. Through a short-term dependence on foreign aid, Kim sought to establish an independent national economy and prevent future dependency relationships. On the other hand were officials who considered the restoration and expansion of light industry, consumer goods, and agriculture to be the priority for reconstruction in order to rapidly elevate standards of living. This position was inspired by the Soviet “New Course,” the short-lived post-Stalin policy of increasing the production of consumer goods and further developing light industry and agriculture. Those advocating this position were SovietKoreans and China-returned Koreans, ethnic Koreans who returned to northern Korea from the Soviet Union and China after the country’s liberation from Japan in 1945. Having spent considerable segments of their lives outside Korea in either the Soviet Union or China, these officials were strong advocates for the economic policies advanced by the more established Soviet and Chinese communist parties. Soviet-Koreans and China-returned Koreans were also guilty of other forms of foreign emulation that frustrated North Korea’s postcolonial nationalist leader Kim Il Sung. In addition to the portraits of Russian cultural icons in classrooms and murals of Soviet landscapes in resorts for the Korean People’s Army, Soviet-Korean officials in charge of textbook production simply translated Soviet textbooks into Korean without any revisions, even when they contained basic mistakes about Korean geography and history. Kim Il Sung was also under pressure from his patron allies, particularly the Soviet Union, to modify his postwar economic development strategy. Moscow, which gave one billion rubles in aid to North Korea in 1953, earmarked all but three percent of the aid for specific projects. These included the reconstruction of Japanese-built factories that had been destroyed during the war, but were not located near resources (the Japanese had constructed factories in locations 213

James F. Person

convenient for shipping resources to the metropole, but not close to resources). Other projects were focused on the construction of factories that would lead to the improvement of living standards, including textile mills and canneries. The Soviet restrictions on aid to North Korea limited Kim Il Sung’s ability to achieve the goals of his development strategy and eliminate future dependency relationships since Korea would still not be able to produce finished goods. During his frequent meetings with Soviet officials, Kim was encouraged to modify his pro-industry policies. More than the internal KWP debate, Soviet efforts to influence North Korean development strategies reduced Kim Il Sung’s freedom of action and ability to achieve his goals. However, it was the perceived collusion of his domestic opponents with Moscow that likely frustrated the North Korean leader the most. In December 1955, therefore, Kim Il Sung used the term chuch’e in the speech to admonish Soviet-Koreans and China-returned Koreans for formalistically imitating the policies of larger socialist countries without developing their knowledge of Korean history and customs or familiarizing themselves with local conditions. While there was little he could do about restrictions placed on Soviet aid to North Korea, it was within his power to discourage KWP members who were originally from the Soviet Union and China from mechanically replicating and promoting foreign practices. Kim Il Sung perceived the emulation of Soviet cultural, political, and economic practices as part of a broader problem that was a remnant of Korea’s long history of glorifying the cultures, traditions, and political practices of more advanced neighboring countries, including China, Japan, and from 1945, the Soviet Union. The speech might therefore be interpreted as an attempt by Kim Il Sung to decolonize the Korean mind. For Kim, establishing an autonomous Korean subjectivity meant abandoning sadae, the practice of “serving the great,” observed for centuries toward China, the “middle Kingdom.” His intent was national subject formation and instilling a sense of national pride. This was the start of a campaign to form a unified national will, or subject, which would motivate the behavior of all Koreans, particularly the Soviet-Koreans and China-returned Koreans, in support of national goals. While Kim Il Sung cannot be credited with introducing the idea of chuch’e as an expression of an autonomous national subjectivity, he can be credited for giving it saliency starting with the December 1955 speech and later when he introduced other terms expressing an autonomous Korean subjectivity in politics, economics, and national defense. Chuch’e would serve as the binding ideology with the practical applications of chaju (independence in politics), charip (selfsustenance in economy), and chawi (self-defense in national defense). The introduction of these ideas transformed chuch’e into a complete set of practical policy applications designed to minimize Soviet and Chinese influence on North Korea. Chaju, the first of the practical applications of chuch’e Kim introduced, was formally announced in December 1957, though it developed in response to an event that occurred in the summer of 1956. Despite having introduced chuch’e in December 1955 as a way of discouraging Soviet-Koreans and China-returned Koreans from mechanically replicating the political practices of other socialist countries, it was only a matter of months before they once again took inspiration from events unfolding in Moscow and called for political reform in the DPRK. Following the February 1956 Twentieth Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union, scene to Soviet leader Nikita Khrushchev’s famed “secret speech” that launched the policy of de-Stalinization, Soviet-Koreans and China-returned Koreans campaigned to limit the cult of personality in North Korea. They did so by directly criticizing the practices of Kim Il Sung and other leading KWP officials, and by encouraging foreign leaders to challenge the North Korean leader directly in meetings during the summer of 1956. When Kim Il Sung failed to respond to these pressures and even dismissed the idea that the DPRK had a problem with the cult of personality, Soviet-Koreans and China-returned Koreans attempted to force 214

North Korea’s chuch’e philosophy

change by raising the matters in a meeting of the KWP CC in August 1956. This political challenge, while never perilous for Kim Il Sung, was greater than the previous economic challenge and demonstrated that these critics would continue to act as conduits of foreign influence as long as they remained in influential posts in the Party. The chief critics were immediately purged from the KWP after the August Plenum. This included four individuals who fled to China, where they informed the leadership of the Chinese Communist Party of the developments in North Korea. The following month, China and the Soviet Union dispatched a joint party delegation to Pyongyang to investigate the actions of Kim Il Sung. The joint Sino-Soviet delegation directly interfered in North Korean politics by ordering the North Koreans to publish accounts of the August meeting and demanding the reinstatement of those purged and the release of other individuals from prison. These actions greatly disturbed Kim Il Sung, demonstrating the tremendous influence of North Korea’s putative allies over the trajectory of political developments. With Soviet and Chinese officials distracted by anti-communist uprisings in Poland and Hungary in late 1956, Kim Il Sung took measures to minimize the influence of Moscow and Beijing by purging most remaining Soviet-Koreans and China-returned Koreans, as well as those who took their orders directly from them. The following year, after Moscow issued a statement on sovereign equality and respect for the internal affairs of all countries of the socialist camp in November 1957, Kim Il Sung declared chaju to be the official policy of the KWP. This measure was designed to impress upon Moscow and Beijing the reality of North Korea’s sovereignty and to minimize their impact on the trajectory of political developments. The second practical application of chuch’e, charip, or self-sustenance in economics, was developed by virtue of necessity. In the years after the Korean War, North Korea was utterly dependent on the Soviet Union, China, and other countries in the socialist camp for economic support. Pyongyang was forced to develop self-reliance in economics for two reasons. First, by the time the DPRK was launching its Five-Year Plan in 1957, socialist countries had begun to reduce their post-Korean War aid. This was in part a result of disagreements over the use of aid, but also due to worsening relations after the political events of August and September 1956. The second, and perhaps greater reason, was that North Korea had come under increasing pressure from the Soviet Union and other socialist countries to coordinate production and industrial development through the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECON). Since the DPRK had not yet rectified colonial-era distortions to its economy, Kim Il Sung resisted pressure to coordinate production with more advanced socialist countries, recognizing that Korea would be discouraged from developing industries already existing in other countries and would instead serve as a source of raw materials. The country would forever remain dependent on foreign countries for finished goods. Just as Joseph Stalin had adopted the autarkic policy of socialism in one country when the Soviet Union was isolated, weak, and vulnerable in the 1920s, Kim Il Sung adopted autarky to prevent the exploitation of North Korean resources. To compensate for the reduced amounts of assistance, the North Korean leadership mobilized indigenous human and material resources. This was achieved through mass campaigns, such as the Cheonlima (Ch’ǒllima) Movement, which promoted Kim Il Sung’s voluntaristic vision for achieving the goals of the North Korean revolution, which demanded maximum sacrifice for minimal reward. Through these measures, despite reductions in foreign aid, North Korea achieved the goals of its Five-Year Plan well over one year ahead of schedule. Selfsustenance in economy did not mean self-sufficiency. North Korean leaders understood that they could not produce everything needed. While never integrating into or coordinating development with COMECON, North Korea nonetheless maintained robust bilateral trade relationships with COMECON member countries. 215

James F. Person

The development of the third practical application of chuch’e, chawi, or self-defense in national defense, was also by virtue of necessity. North Korea’s security was put in jeopardy following the May 1961 coup d’état in South Korea that brought to power the anti-communist military junta of Park Chung Hee. Despite having signed a Treaty of Friendship, Cooperation and Mutual Assistance with the Soviet Union in July 1961 (and another with China one week later), North Korea became suspicious of Moscow’s credibility as a patron ally following the October 1962 Cuban Missile Crisis, which Kim viewed as capitulation to the United States. Kim Il Sung believed his suspicions about Moscow’s credibility and commitment to the security of its ally was confirmed when the Soviets refused to supply the DPRK with 100 million rubles’ worth of military equipment in December 1962. Therefore, from December 1962, North Korea developed autonomous defense capabilities by adopting a so-called equal emphasis policy (p’yǒngjin) line, whereby heavy industry and national defense capabilities would be developed simultaneously, at the expense of consumer goods and light industry. Starting in early 1963, North Korea also began to explore the possibility of developing an indigenous nuclear deterrent. By 1965, the share of expenditures from the national budget allotted to national defense was approximately 30 percent, up from 4.3 percent in 1956.7 Even after relations with Moscow improved in late 1964, and the Soviets resumed providing North Korea with military assistance, Pyongyang never abandoned its policy of self-defense in national defense, refusing to fully entrust national security to a foreign nation. In April 1965, Kim Il Sung traveled to Indonesia on the occasion of the tenth anniversary of the first Bandung Conference of African and Asian countries. This was the first and only trip he made outside of the socialist camp. While in Jakarta, Kim delivered a lecture at the Ali Archam Academy of Social Sciences entitled “On Socialist Construction in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea and the South Korean Revolution,” where he gave full articulation to chuch’e as a complete set of practical policy applications. He described chuch’e as a “unique and creative stand which opposes dogmatism and applies the universal truth of Marxism-Leninism and the experience of the international revolutionary movement to one’s country in conformity with its historical conditions and national peculiarities. This represents an independent stand of discarding the spirit of relying on others, of displaying the spirit of self-reliance and solving one’s own affairs on one’s own responsibility under all circumstances.”8 He similarly described each of the practical applications of chuch’e in politics, economics, and in national defense. Within two years, however, the chuch’e again underwent a transformation. Starting with the military coup in South Korea in May 1961, North Korea faced multiple threats to its national security. In 1965, South Korea and Japan, both strong allies of the United States, normalized relations as Washington pushed for the creation of a Northeast Asian Treaty Organization. Also, the Sino-Soviet split, which became open in the early 1960s, divided the socialist camp and placed North Korea, which bordered both countries, between a rock and a hard place. As Moscow and Beijing quarreled, from the mid-1960s, the United States rapidly escalated its presence in Southeast Asia. Finally, from 1966, China launched the Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution and relations between Beijing and Pyongyang deteriorated to the point of armed clashes along their shared border. North Korea’s status quo had never been more unfavorable. Yet, starting after the Second Party Conference of the KWP in October 1966—precisely at a time when North Korea faced such perilous security challenges—members of Kim Il Sung’s inner circle began to challenge the continued emphasis on simultaneously developing the heavy industry and national defense sectors of the national economy. They advocated for more investment in light industry and the production of consumer goods to elevate standards of living in the DPRK. To be sure, this was a very sensitive subject. After nearly fifteen years of ambitious back-to-back economic plans and near constant mobilization, North Korea was transformed 216

North Korea’s chuch’e philosophy

from a country devastated by the Korean War to one that was moderately industrialized. It remained far more developed than South Korea until the early 1970s. However, the North Korean people still did not enjoy a quality of life commensurate to the labor they had invested in recovery and industrialization. While there had been plans to focus on improving living standards for the North Korean people at the start of the Seven-Year Plan (originally scheduled for 1961–1967), those plans were indefinitely shelved after the 1961 military coup in South Korea. Critics of the continued focus on heavy industry and national defense, including Pak Geumcheol (Park Kǔm-ch’ǒl) who had been among the most influential officials in the DPRK, engaged in economic populism by traveling throughout the country, delivering speeches declaring the need to drastically improve the lives of the masses after years of sacrifice. Because of the numerous threats facing the country, Kim Il Sung undoubtedly perceived this as a direct challenge to his national security imperatives. Starting in March 1967, Kim Il Sung took steps to eliminate pluralism in the KWP. He delivered a speech entitled “On Improving Party Work and Implementing the Decisions of the Party Conference,” in which he advocated for enshrining chuch’e as the official ideology of North Korea and for transforming it into a monolithic ideological system (yuil sasang ch’egye).9 Unless this system was fully established, Kim warned, “it is not possible to ensure the unity of ideology and will.” The establishment of the monolithic ideological system was necessary, Kim argued, to ensure that the KWP would be turned into a “militant organization” that would be capable of “lead[ing] the revolution and construction with success.” He gave examples of disunity in the KWP, such as in 1956, at a time when “Juche was not firmly established.” Kim placed great emphasis in the speech on accepting the orders of the KWP and the leader unconditionally.10 In May 1967, Pak and his associates were purged from the KWP during the Fifteenth Plenum of the Fourth KWP CC.11 Pak’s challenge in 1966 and 1967 in many ways resembled that of the Soviet-Koreans and China-returned Koreans from 1953 to 1956, though Pak did not have foreign backing. Kim took steps to eliminate the possibility of future challenges by transforming chuch’e into a tool for suppressing pluralism. This process was central to the establishment of the Kim Il Sung autocracy. In December 1967, Kim delivered a speech entitled “Let Us Embody the Revolutionary Spirit of Independence, Self-Sustenance, and Self-Defense More Thoroughly in all Branches of State Activity” to North Korea’s rubber-stamp legislative body, the Supreme People’s Assembly. In the speech, he presented a ten-point platform for establishing the monolithic ideological system in North Korea. This required, above all, absolute loyalty to Kim. It also provided specific guidelines for applying the principles of chuch’e to all fields of governance, including politics, economics, and national defense, and also to national reunification, international trade, science and technology, and international affairs. The ten points of the monolithic ideological system eliminated pluralism in the KWP, mandated ideological purity, and made the word of the sovereign, i.e. Kim Il Sung, absolute. This platform became the foundation for idolization of Kim, and turned him into an absolutist, supreme leader. Kim was thenceforth referred to by the title Suryǒng, or “Great Leader,” who would shepherd the masses. Further turning Marxism-Leninism on its head, according to North Korean theorists, it is the Suryǒng who is the leading force of the working class in historical development. The cult of personality surrounding Kim Il Sung was extended to members of his family, including to his son and also to his ancestors. Extreme forms of veneration, including the displaying of lapel pins bearing Kim’s image, became mandatory. Moreover, North Korean authorities took a series of measures to eliminate foreign influences, including banning foreign books and music. With the introduction of the monolithic ideological system in 1967, chuch’e ceased to become the practical set of policy applications designed to safeguard Korean sovereignty by minimizing 217

James F. Person

the influence of Moscow and Beijing on the trajectory of political, economic, and cultural developments. It became, for all intents and purposes, a tool of suppression and autocratic rule. North Korea elevated chuch’e to the level of a philosophy or ideology. This was likely, at least in part, to elevate Kim Il Sung to be on par with Mao Zedong, whose own eponymous ideology was being discredited through the tumult of the Cultural Revolution. North Korean propagandists began to refer to chuch’e as “Kimilsungism.” Instrumental in the transformation of chuch’e was Kim Il Sung’s son and future successor, Kim Jong Il. The junior Kim was aided in his efforts to utilize chuch’e to establish dictatorial powers even Stalin would envy by a philosophy professor at Kim Il Sung University named Hwang Jang-yop (Hwang Chang-yǒp). For his role in this process, Hwang, who in 1997 defected to South Korea, was known as an architect of chuch’e. In 1972, chuch’e was enshrined in the national constitution as the official ideology of North Korea. In 1974, the ten points of the monolithic ideological system were updated when Kim Jong Il was internally designated successor to his father. The updated ten points established more control over every aspect of life in North Korea. Every point was subdivided, with each demanding absolute loyalty to Kim Il Sung and Kim Jong Il. Every member of society was expected to memorize and live by these rules. From the late 1960s, North Korea began to assert that Kimilsungism was a model of politics, economic development, and foreign relations to be emulated in other former colonial and semicolonial countries. Pyongyang began to support so-called chuch’e study groups around the globe, constructed chuch’e farms in developing countries, and dispatched officials to teach North Korean methods of industrial and agricultural development. North Korea even dispatched instructors to Ethiopia in order to teach the techniques for “mass games,” the synchronized social-realist spectacles that in North Korea glorify the achievements of the Kim family.12 This experiment to bring chuch’e to the world ultimately failed as the North Korean model itself began to falter in the 1980s. Moreover, the ideas behind chuch’e were so uniquely suited to the particularities of North Korea that even with adaptation, it was difficult to export. Kim Jong Il’s credentials to lead North Korea after Kim Il Sung were in part established by portraying himself as the individual most qualified to interpret his father’s idea. In 1982, the book On the Juche Idea was published in Kim Jong Il’s name, establishing him as the final authority over the interpretation of the official state ideology. The same year On the Juche Idea was published, the junior Kim oversaw the construction of the 558-foot Juche Tower (three feet taller than the Washington Monument) in the center of Pyongyang to celebrate his father’s philosophical contribution to the world. Following the death of Kim Il Sung in 1993, Kim Jong Il added to chuch’e by incorporating, in 1996, sǒngun chǒngch’i, or military-first politics. Sǒngun, according to Kim Jong Il, was a system of politics which “solves all problems arising in the revolution and construction on the principle of giving priority to the military affair and advances the overall cause of socialism relying on the army as the pillar of the revolution.”13 The need for a military-first policy, according to North Korean propagandists, was the collapse of the socialist camp and the threat posed by US hegemony. Chuch’e and the North Korean founding leader Kim Il Sung are still central features in the everyday lives of North Koreans. In 1997, North Korea introduced the chuch’e calendar, a variation of the Gregorian calendar starting with the date 15 April 1912, Kim’s date of birth, as year one. Chuch’e today remains the official ideology of North Korea, though, it has been transformed significantly since Kim Il Sung first used the term in 1955. The idea started as an expression of an autonomous Korean subjectivity, developed into a set of practical policy applications to minimize foreign influence on the DPRK, and was subsequently distorted into a tool of 218

North Korea’s chuch’e philosophy

suppression and autocratic rule. Nonetheless, many of the very postcolonial nationalist ideas inherent to chuch’e early in its evolution in North Korea, including the desire to minimize the impact of larger countries on the trajectory of political, cultural, and economic developments, continue to inform North Korean policies.

Notes 1 Kim Jong Il, “The Juche Philosophy is an Original Revolutionary Philosophy” Kulloja, 26 July 1996. www.korea-dpr.com/lib/108.pdf. Accessed 17 June 2015. 2 “Juche Ideology,” Democratic People’s Republic of Korea, Official Website of the DPR of Korea. http:// www.korea-dpr.com/juche_ideology.html. Accessed 17 June 2015. 3 See Fukuzawa Yukichi, An Outline of a Theory of Civilization (New York: Columbia University Press, 2008). 4 Kim Il Sung, “On Eliminating Dogmatism and Formalism and Establishing Juche in Ideological Work” in Yongho Choe, Peter H. Lee, et al., Sources of Korean Tradition: From the Sixteenth to the Twentieth Centuries (New York: Columbia University Press, 2001), p. 422. 5 Andrei Lankov claims that the speech was “the first authentic statement to enunciate explicitly the juche principle.” Bradley K. Martin argues that in the speech, “Kim gave full voice to his arguments for juche” See Andrei Lankov, Crisis in Korea: The Failure of De-Stalinization, 1956 (Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press, 2004), p. 40, and Bradley K. Martin, Under the Loving Care of the Fatherly Leader: North Korea and the Kim Dynasty (New York: Thomas Dunne Books, 2004), p. 174. 6 Brian R. Myers argues that discussion of the creative application of Marxism-Leninism was in fact very common throughout the Soviet bloc, and interprets Kim’s speech as an expression of this effort to indigenize. He argues that it was, therefore, not an expression of Korean nationalism. See Brian R. Myers, “The Watershed that Wasn’t: Re-Evaluating Kim Il Sung’s ‘Juche Speech’ of 1955,” Acta Koreana, Vol. 9, No. 1, January 2006: pp. 89–115. 7 Record of a conversation with the Soviet Ambassador in the DPRK, Comrade V.P. Moskovsky, about the negotiations between the Soviet delegation, led by the USSR Council of Ministers, Chairman Kosygin, and the governing body of the Korean Workers’ Party, which took place at the USSR Embassy in the DPRK on 16 February 1965, Central Committee of the Communist Party of Czechoslovakia. Fond 02/1, folder 96/101, pp. 1–26. 8 Kim Il Sung, “On Socialist Construction in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea and the South Korean Revolution” in On Juche in our Revolution, Vol. 1 (New York: Weekly Guardian Associates, 1977) pp. 427–437. 9 Kim Il Sung, “On improving party work and implementing the decisions of the party conference,” in Kim Il Sung Works (Pyongyang: Foreign Languages Publishing House, 1985), p. 21. 10 Ibid., pp. 116–119. 11 See “Telegram from Pyongyang to Bucharest, No. 76.279,” 3 August 1967, History and Public Policy Program Digital Archive, Archive of the Romanian Ministry of Foreign Affairs, http://digitalarchive. wilsoncenter.org/document/116713. 12 Charles K. Armstrong, “Juche and North Korea’s Global Aspirations,” NKIDP Working Paper No. 1 (Washington: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars, 2009), p. 18. 13 “The Songun idea, the Songun politics viewed by the South Korean press,” National Democratic Front South Korea Website, accessed 17 July 2015, http://ndfsk.dyndns.org/kuguk8/pym/Nr0311/ s-2.htm.

References Armstrong, C.K. (2009) “Juche and North Korea’s Global Aspirations,” NKIDP Working Paper No. 1 (Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars). “Juche Ideology.” (n.d.) Democratic People’s Republic of Korea, Official Website of the DPR of Korea. http://www.korea-dpr.com/juche_ideology.html. Accessed 17 June 2015. Kim, I.S. (1985) “On improving party work and implementing the decisions of the party conference,” Kim Il Sung Works (Pyongyang: Foreign Languages Publishing House). 219

James F. Person

Kim, I.S. (1977) “On Socialist Construction in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea and the South Korean Revolution,” On Juche in Our Revolution, Vol. 1 (New York: Weekly Guardian Associates) pp. 427–437. Kim, I.S. (1977) “On Eliminating Dogmatism and Formalism and Establishing Juche in Ideological Work,” in Yongho Choe, Peter H. Lee, et al., Sources of Korean Tradition: From the Sixteenth to the Twentieth Centuries (New York: Columbia University Press, 2001). Kim, J.I. (1996) “The Juche Philosophy is an Original Revolutionary Philosophy,” Kulloja, 26 July. www.korea-dpr.com/lib/108.pdf. Accessed 17 June 2015. Lankov, A. (2004) Crisis in Korea: The Failure of De-Stalinization, 1956 (Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press). Martin, B.K. (2004) Under the Loving Care of the Fatherly Leader: North Korea and the Kim Dynasty (New York: Thomas Dunne Books). Myers, B.R. (2006) “The Watershed that Wasn’t: Re-Evaluating Kim Il Sung’s ‘Juche Speech’ of 1955,” Acta Koreana, Vol. 9, No. 1, January: pp. 89–115. Record of a conversation with the Soviet Ambassador in the DPRK, Comrade V.P. Moskovsky, about the negotiations between the Soviet delegation, led by the USSR Council of Ministers, Chairman Kosygin, and the governing body of the Korean Workers Party, which took place at the USSR Embassy in the DPRK on 16 February 1965, Central Committee of the Communist Party of Czechoslovakia. Fond 02/1, folder 96/101, pp. 1–26. http://digitalarchive.wilsoncenter.org/document/114980. Accessed 15 June 2015. “Telegram from Pyongyang to Bucharest, No. 76.279,” (1967) 3 August, History and Public Policy Program Digital Archive, Archive of the Romanian Ministry of Foreign Affairs, http://digitalarchive.wilson center.org/document/116713. Accessed 15 June 2015. “The Songun idea, the Songun Politics Viewed By the South Korean Press” (n.d.) National Democratic Front South Korea Website. http://ndfsk.dyndns.org/kuguk8/pym/Nr0311/s-2.htm. Accessed 17 July 2015. Yukichi, F. (2008) An Outline of a Theory of Civilization (New York: Columbia University Press).

220

16 A dynastic polity in economic stagnation and decline Andrei Lankov

In 1965, having visited East Asia, Joan Robinson, a Cambridge professor and world-renowned economist, relayed her recent experiences in an article under the telling title “Korean miracle.” Reflecting on what she had just seen, Joan Robinson stated: “All the economic miracles of the post-war world are put in the shade by these achievements” (Robinson, 1965: 542). It does not sound particularly surprising nowadays, since it has long since become a cliché to describe the recent economic history of South Korea as a ‘miracle.’ However, in 1965, Joan Robinson was talking a different Korea—the Leninist state of the north. Her eulogy might reflect her own ideological tastes, which were very peculiar indeed, but it did not look completely unfounded to many contemporaries. It has been almost forgotten, but from the mid1950s until the mid-1960s, people who spoke of the ‘Korean miracle’ usually meant not ‘the miracle on the Han River’ of later fame, but rather the ‘miracle on the Taedong River.’ Indeed, North Korea’s start was impressive, but this cannot be said about the subsequent economic performance of the country. It is difficult to study and describe North Korean economic history. It is widely assumed nowadays that any meaningful discourse on economics has to be based on the large quantities of the statistical data, but such data is sadly absent when we discuss North Korea of the 1953– 1990 period. In the beginning of this period, the published data was incomplete and poorly collected, but then things moved from bad to worse: the North Korean government essentially ceased to publish any meaningful economic data in the early 1960s and soon became an exceptionally elusive and secretive place, even if measured by the standards of the communist bloc. The situation is made more complicated by the very nature of a centrally planned economy, which in many regards makes the application of standard economic indicators difficult or misleading. So, one should not be surprised that there are significant differences between available estimates of North Korea’s economic performance in 1960–1990. Nonetheless, these figures still present a similar picture: a short period of quick recovery, followed by stagnation and, perhaps, decline towards the late 1980s. Table 1 presents the reader with some estimates, even though it is important to keep in mind that these estimates are not particularly reliable and are useful only for reference purposes. In spite of some differences, most scholars agree that until a certain point, either in the late 1960s or perhaps even in the very early 1970s, North Korea was ahead of the South in terms 221

Andrei Lankov

Table 16.1 Alternative estimates of the North Korean per capita GNP 1956 Bank of Korea Taik-Young Hamm

1960

1970

1980

1990

67

137

286

758

1064

108

172

303

927

1124

Source: Hamm 1999: 128.

of per capita GDP, even though by the mid-1970s, the South was pulling away fast (Eberstadt, 2010). A caveat is necessary: higher per capita GDP and other economic indicators did not necessarily mean that the average North Koreans had a more comfortable existence than their South Korean contemporaries did. At least some diplomats from North Korea’s allies, including the Soviet Union, presumed that North Korean living standards were lagging behind those of the South—obviously, this is what they believed strongly since they were ready to present such politically dangerous conclusions to their respective governments in highly confidential communications. To a large extent, North Korea’s initial economic superiority was the result of a massive colonial endowment it inherited at the time of division. The 1930s industrialization progressed largely in areas that eventually would come under the control of the government in Pyongyang. It has been estimated that in the early 1940s, the northern part of Korea, in spite of being home to merely one-third of the total population, had produced 86 percent of the entire heavy industry output (McCune, 1950: 57). Apart from the state-of-art steel mills and railways, North Korea inherited a significant amount of social capital and skills, being home to a vast majority of Korea’s skilled and semi-skilled industrial workers. While the massive US bombardment of North Korea during the Korean War destroyed a significant part of North Korea’s industries, much of North Korea’s human capital did survive. When this was all combined with generous developmental aid from the Soviet Union, China and other Eastern bloc countries, a speedy economic recovery ensued. Soviet aid was largely aimed at promoting the industrial revival of North Korea—in line with the then orthodox Leninist view that machine tools and steel should come first, and food and consumer goods as a distant second. The actual scale of Soviet, Chinese and Eastern European aid to North Korea cannot be estimated with much precision due to manifold problem. To start with, the aid was provided in roubles and other non-convertible currencies that cannot to be translated into the US dollars with any precision (due to the artificial nature of the official exchange rate and great difference in price structure). Things were made further complicated by the existence of indirect aid. It was the governments in communist countries that decided which goods should be exported, and in the case of intra-bloc trade, prices were often set at artificially lower levels, thus North Korea often received goods at prices far below the then current international market level, while being allowed to overcharge for its products. Nonetheless, a rough estimate of the combined Soviet and Chinese aid in 1945–1970 put the figure at the vicinity of $1.7 billion current dollars— a very significant amount for such a small and relatively underdeveloped country (Bazhanova, 1993: 460). It is possible that by the early 1960s, the spectacular post-war recovery of the economy made North Korea’s leaders remarkably confident (read: complacent) about the country’s economic prospects. It is important, however, to emphasize that their expectations and promises were quite moderate by our present standards. In an oft-cited 1962 speech, Kim Il Sung outlined the coming prosperity of North Koreans. He promised that North Koreans would soon be 222

A dynastic polity in economic decline

eating meat and rice, not corn gruel, and living in tile-roofed houses, not in the thatched huts that still ‘blighted’ the North Korean landscape at that time. This was a rather modest view of affluence—Kim Il Sung promised his subjects a lifestyle that had been the embodiment of affordable luxury by the average Korean peasant for centuries, no more, no less. However, much later, in 2010, the major North Korean newspaper, Rodong sinmun, admitted that the aforementioned moderate promise of then long-dead Generalissimo Kim Il Sung had yet to be realized (9 January 2010). Indeed, from the 1960s onward, things went wrong with the North Korean economy. Within a couple of decades, it went from being a miracle to being a basket case. To the great chagrin of the North Korean elite, this happened at the very same time as the economy in its southern arch-rival began to surge toward prosperity with truly unprecedented speed. To a large extent, the sorry fate of the North Korean economy resulted from its very nature. It was a highly centralized command economy, and the history of the twentieth century has demonstrated well that such economic systems are incapable of competing with market capitalist economies. The general reasons for their failures have been studied by some of the leading lights of twentieth century economics, such great names as Janos Kornai and Fredrick von Hayek—and their earlier insights were eventually proven right by the disintegration and collapse of the centrally planned economies. However, in the case of North Korea, this failure was more spectacular than the decline of centrally planned economies in Eastern Europe or the Soviet Union. To a large extent, this was a result of peculiarities of North Korea’s particular situation, as well as by some of the decisions of the North Korean leadership. The Soviet-style command economy includes a combination of state-run industry and collectivized (read: staterun) agriculture. In the case of North Korea, nationalization of industry began in 1946. While the 1946 law technically envisioned that only the property of Japanese collaborators would be confiscated, in real life nearly all Korean entrepreneurs of earlier era could be plausibly described as collaborators with the colonial authorities. Thus, for all practical purposes, almost all North Korean industry became state property by the end of 1946. Small workshops, retail markets, and individual handicraftsmen were allowed to continue their trade until 1957, whereupon, their property was also nationalized as well.1 At the same time, from 1955, the North Korean government stepped up its agriculture collectivization campaign, which ended in late 1957. Farmers were herded into agricultural collectives. Technically, these collectives were considered to be the joint property of their employees, but this was merely a legal fiction: for all practical purposes, these huge farms were state-owned and state-managed from the outset. While the official media reported inflated harvest figures, the collectivization’s immediate impact was a decrease in productivity and output.2 While forced collectivization of agriculture was an almost universal feature of socialist state building, done by nearly all Leninist regimes, North Korea was rather unique in its intensely negative attitude toward small, individual kitchen plots, which played such a significant role in the agricultural output of the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. Since the mid-1970s, the maximum size of plots was limited to 30 p’yǒng, or roughly 100 square meters—and even such size was by no means guaranteed. This was well below the private plot size which was allowed in nearly all other Leninist economies (Yim, 2000). In order to attain self-sufficiency in grain production, the North Korean government was prepared to make significant investments in agriculture. As a result, they created a system that indeed provided enough grain to meet the basic physiological needs of every North Korean, even though this system heavily relied on direct and indirect subsidies from the Soviet Union and other communist countries (this fact was not widely understood at the time). In order to produce the amount of grain required, the North Korean agricultural system had to be unusually 223

Andrei Lankov

capital intensive for such a poor country. It heavily relied on chemical fertilizer and also on irrigation systems, which were themselves dependent on electricity-driven pumps—hence the system required a substantial amount of electricity. Since spare parts for the power plants and raw materials for fertilizer production came from overseas at subsidized ‘friendship prices,’ this system was vulnerable to external shocks. Amid this charge to collectivize the countryside, North Korea’s industrial policy continued to follow Stalinist prototypes: emphasizing heavy industry at the expense of everything else. In the Soviet Union of the time, this model came under sustained attack and was partially revised soon after Stalin’s death in 1953. Around the same time, certain factions in the North Korean leadership also attempted to change their country’s course and make its economy more consumer-oriented. Pak Ch’angok, a head of the State Planning Committee (a former Soviet Korean) advocated in 1954 and 1955 that the government should take a new course and focus on consumer goods and agriculture. However, though Pak was supported by some elements in the leadership, Kim Il Sung and his ex-guerrilla comrades managed to win the ensuing factional struggle.3 Thus, Kim and his comrades came to dominate economic policy making until the last of them—Kim himself—died in 1994. Being indoctrinated in the Soviet-style Leninism, the ex-guerrillas obviously believed that heavy industry was the foundation of all economic success. They also saw significant industrial inheritance from the colonial era as the major asset the country had and they wanted to make the most of it. Their intense nationalism, as well as their deep (if hidden) mistrust of the Soviet Union and China, may have played a role as well. They hoped that speedy development of heavy industry would make them more independent from Moscow and Beijing when it came to making political decisions—including the possible decision to intervene by force into a future South Korean internal crisis and thus finally unify the country. This is why their policy implied that heavy industry should be as independent from the outside influences as possible. This approach was expressed by Kim Il Sung himself, who in 1965 said: “Our Party’s line in regard to the building of heavy industry was to create our own base of heavy industry which would be equipped with new technology and would develop relying mainly on domestic natural resources and sources of raw material” (Kim Il Sung, 1976: 219). Indeed, the possibility of another war was a major concern of the North Korean elite at this time. It is arguable as to whether their military preparations were primarily defensive or offensive in nature. However, it is clear that Kim Il Sung and his advisers were prepared to dedicate an unusually large share of their economic resources to military. As Noland and Haggard noticed, “By standard statistical measures, [. . .] North Korea is the world’s most militarized society” (Haggard and Noland, 2007: 5). The militarization became especially apparent after 1966, when the Second Party Conference officially declared a line of “simultaneous development” of the military power and civilian economy. This policy change, which actually became obvious few years earlier in 1962 and 1963, probably reflected Kim Il Sung’s revitalized hopes for a communist revolution erupting in South Korea—an opportunity not to be missed. The growing influence and popularity of the communist movement in Asia, as well as the success of Vietnamese guerrillas influenced Pyongyang strategic thinking as well.4 Their hopes proved to be unrealistic, and excessive militarization became a great and ever-increasing burden for the country’s economy.5 According to official North Korean budget reports, the share of military spending in the state budget increased from 7.5 percent in 1964 to an astonishing 32.4 percent in 1968 (Eberstadt, 2007: 139). These figures, like all North Korean official statistics, have to be taken with a generous measure of 224

A dynastic polity in economic decline

scepticism, but the visibly dramatic build-up of military forces clearly confirms the same trend. By the mid-1980s, some 6 percent of all North Koreans were in the military—a share roughly equal to that of the USA in 1943.6 Apart from the intense military spending, the government also pursued a number of expensive prestige projects that created additional pressure on the economy. One should mention large-scale (and hugely expensive) construction projects in Pyongyang that were undertaken almost exclusively for propaganda purposes—the aim was to make the capital into a showcase of “Juche socialism.” These construction projects culminated around 1980 and produced the Pyongyang we know today: a city of broad streets, which are almost devoid of car traffic, a city of high-rise buildings where the inhabitants of higher floors can get water a few hours a day at most, a city of mammoth, sometimes impressive, but usually kitschy political monuments. Of course, the prestige projects were not limited to Pyongyang alone. In the early 1980s, simultaneously with the large facelift of Pyongyang, the North Korean government undertook a massive project on the Yellow Sea, where a massive barrage was built to reclaim land and control the floods of the Taedong River. As officially claimed by the North Korean media, the barrage costs approximated $400 million. As usual, the figure should be taken with some caution: it seems to be based on the grossly unrealistic official exchange rate. However, the size of the mobilized workforce leaves little doubt about the scale of this grandiose project: some 30,000 people were sent to Nampo to complete the barrage.7 Another example of expensive prestige-boosting activities was the support given to the overseas Juche study movement in the 1970s, when for a brief while North Korean diplomats and ideologues hoped to make this peculiar North Korean mix of nationalism and Leninism into one of the Third World’s leading ideologies. The large sums that were spent on such activities clearly did the North Korean economy no good, while also producing little in the way of actual diplomatic results. The Sino-Soviet split was another factor that aggravated North Korea’s economic decline. The split surfaced around 1960, and soon afterwards, North Korea made a fateful decision to distance itself from the Soviet Union, which for some 15 years had been its major sponsor. On the one hand, the dramatic deterioration in Sino-Soviet relations provided Kim Il Sung and his government with a great opportunity: he was able to assert his country’s autonomy visà-vis the two great communist powers—the overbearing control of which Kim Il Sung and his deeply nationalist entourage had only ever accepted reluctantly. For a few years in the early 1960s, North Korea chose to side with China and was suspicious about the USSR. In 1963 a lengthy editorial in the Rodong sinmun openly criticized the “socialist division of labour,” Khrushchev’s favourite idea, as a grave threat to the economic independence of the ‘fraternal countries.’ Predictably, North Korea did not participate in the assorted joint economic projects, which had become common in the communist bloc since the mid-1960s, and never joined COMECON, an intra-government body which was created to coordinate such projects (Armstrong 2013: 128). However, the period of pro-Chinese orientation was short. Pyongyang was soon disappointed with pitiful amount of economic aid the Chinese were prepared to provide—it was well below of what the Soviet had provided hitherto. As a result, from 1965–1966, North Korea began its switch to a policy of equidistance between Moscow and Beijing, which continued with only minor variation until the collapse of the Soviet Union.8 From a purely state-centred and nationalist point of view, the North Korea made the most of the ‘complex’ international situation (a standard euphemism the North Korean media used 225

Andrei Lankov

to hint at the quarrel between Moscow and Beijing). North Korea was to become one of the most autonomous countries within the socialist bloc. Compared to the other autonomous communist regimes of the era—Yugoslavia and Albania, and then Romania—it was able to squeeze developmental assistance from the great power patrons at a smaller political cost. However, compared to the avalanche of aid that North Korea received in the 1950s, the post-1960 aid remained modest. Thus, the North Korea’s economy began to slow down in the 1960s. Curiously, the first reaction of the North Korean government was to cease publishing potentially damaging statistics. The North Korean government attempted to replace material incentives with appeals to the ideological better nature of its subjects. To an extent, this might have stemmed from changes simultaneously occurring in China—Kim Il Sung was fluent in Chinese and by all accounts was an lifelong avid reader of the Chinese press, so he might have been influenced by the Maoists’ firebrand rhetoric as well as by Chairman Mao’s unwavering belief in the power of persuasion and ideology. However, we should discount the importance of the worldview of those in charge in Pyongyang. The guerrilla past of the top North Korean decision-makers was one of hardships, danger and extreme sacrifice in cause of national liberation, and this made them firm believers in the power of mobilization and ideological purity premised upon ceaseless indoctrination. The first massive ideology-driven labour mobilization campaign was the Ch’ǒllima movement launched in 1958.9 This was to be followed by an endless number of similar campaigns including the notorious ‘speed battles’ (‘70-day battle,’ ‘100-day battle for’ and so on). The first of these shock-labour campaigns, which have few if any analogues elsewhere, was launched in 1974, that is, at the time when slowdown of North Korean economy began to be felt.10 During the said ‘battles,’ workers were treated like soldiers on the frontline and were expected to stay at their workplaces as long as possible, frequently even sleeping on the premise, with days off being cancelled. The intense propaganda campaigns, with content often being delivered straight to the workers through specially designed vans with loudspeakers, were designed to push workers to ever higher feats of productive labour. Even in normal times, though, the amount of ideological indoctrination was all but unprecedented even by the remarkably high standards of the socialist bloc. Kim Il Sung once said that the North Korean worker should spend eight hours working, eight hours studying and eight hours resting (Kim Il Sung, 1988: 452). This might sound rather edifying, but we should not forget that Marshal Kim in this case was not talking about the study of classical philosophy, art or even foreign languages. Rather the word ‘study’ in this context was supposed to mean that the average North Korean worker should spend eight hours of her/his day attending ideological indoctrination sessions or reading official propaganda. Probably, the stated ideal was never met, but the average North Korean still had to spend an astonishing amount of time attending various indoctrination and political studies sessions. In the 1980s, after the government had decided to reduce the time allocated to the political studies, every North Korean employee was still expected to attend three such sessions a week, each session lasting some two hours (of course, it was done after the end of the official work day). On top of that, every morning he or she was exposed to short indoctrination sessions where the attendees were required to listen to the articles from the official media being read aloud for some 15 minutes. While these efforts were largely aimed at ensuring the docility of the populace, the authorities also believed that heavy indoctrination would produce economic benefits, since it should make the masses work harder and better, while demanding little material rewards for themselves (Lankov et al., 2012). 226

A dynastic polity in economic decline

Since the late 1950s, endless labour mobilizations have been a recurrent feature of North Korean economic management. For example, in autumn during harvesting and in spring during rice planting, the state mobilized and sent to the fields pretty much all urban workers who were engaged in what the state deemed to be ‘non-essential’ industrial activities (like the production of consumer goods) as well as middle and high school students. Even housewives were not excepted from such duties: every ward was told how many women it was to dispatch to the countryside for unpaid agricultural work. It was difficult or even impossible to avoid such mobilizations, and they remained an important part of North Korean daily life until recently. Mobilized workforce received their regular salaries and rations issued by their permanent employees, but got no additional payments for physically demanding and sometimes dangerous work. In some cases, large-scale construction projects were also done with large-scale mobilization of ‘non-essential’ workers. In the late 1950s, and again in the late 1970s, extensive construction campaigns in Pyongyang led the authorities to close the city’s universities so that students could be mobilized in the renovation of the city—as a former students of Kim Il Sung University recalled while talking to me, “in 1958 we studied, perhaps, for merely two months, and spent the rest at the constructions site.” While this system was adept at increasing ideological cohesion, economy wise it did not work so well. Indeed, these efforts largely failed to revive North Korea’s slowly worsening economic fortunes. Partially driven by their own ideological inclinations and partially reacting to the economic slowdown, from the late 1950s the North Korean government came to increasingly rely on rationing and distribution when it came to meeting the demands of the country’s population. All command economies gravitated towards rationing to some extent, but in North Korea, this trend was taken to the extremes, and by the early 1970s, North Korea arguably had the most comprehensive and elaborate rationing system in the entire Soviet bloc (with the probable exception of Albania). Rationing was first introduced by the North Korean authorities in 1946. Initially it was only the employees of the country’s state-owned enterprises who were eligible for subsidized food rations. At this early stage, access to such rations was actually a privilege, allowing the lucky minority the right to cheaper food and other consumer goods. However, in 1957, grain and cereal products were subject to universal and mandatory rationing. Thus, the private sale of grain was criminalized: cereals could not be sold and bought. All cereal output of state-run farms was first harvested by workers of the state-run ‘collective farms,’ who were then allotted their own rations. The remainder was dispatched to state-run granaries for the eventual distribution in towns and cities, as well as among the military. Grain-rationing norms were universal nationwide: 800- or 900-gram rations were issued to the workers who were doing hard manual labour, 700 grams was a standard ration for other employees, while high school students received 500 grams, and so on. The lowest allowance, merely 100 grams, was reserved for the infants. The rice rations were paid every fifteenth day. On a designated day, a family representative, usually a housewife, went to the assigned graindistribution centre. She produced the ID and the coupons for her entire family, then paid the token price and took home the cereals for the next two weeks. The farmers, being employed in the state-managed cooperative farms, were also subjected to rationing, the only difference being that their rations were issued only once a year, soon after harvesting was complete (obviously, on assumption that they should take responsibility for storing the grain). Rations consisted of a mix of different grains. In the 1970s, in Pyongyang, rice represented as much as 60 percent of the allowance; but even in those relatively prosperous times, in more 227

Andrei Lankov

remote areas, rations consisted entirely of corn and barley, which have fewer calories than rice and was generally seen as an inferior subsistence food. The proportions between rice and other less valuable kinds of grains depended largely on one’s place of residence, with Pyongyang and other major cities being most privileged. As time went by, both the quantity and quality of the rations decreased. In 1972 the first nationwide cuts of the ration size were introduced, being presented as necessitated by the mounting threat of the imperialist aggression against North Korea. In the late 1980s, more cuts were introduced, and soon, in the early 1990s, the entire elaborate system collapsed.11 In terms of nutrition, almost all calories in the North Korean diet came from rice and other cereals, with other foodstuff seen as secondary. Such ‘additional’ items like soy sauce, cabbage, and fish, as well as consumption goods like soap, socks were also rationed. Such items were distributed by the local authorities, with distribution quotas set locally, largely depending on how economically fortunate and politically powerful the given local authority was. The shops were superseded by a variety of direct distribution systems, each targeting different segments of the population. Officials had their distribution systems, which provided them with luxury items normally beyond the reach of the common population as well as delicacies. The size and quality of these special rations depended on the official’s position within the state and party hierarchy.12 One of more curious forms this distribution would take was the so-called ‘presents from the Great Leader’ (later, with the rise of Kim Jong Il, ‘presents from the Dear Leader’ appeared too). Such presents were usually given to select individuals as a sign of their special contribution to the realization of the state’s lofty aims. In most cases, the presents were rather expensive: televisions, radio sets, wristwatches, cooking utensils and the like. In other cases, presents were distributed far more widely—for example, nearly all children were normally given fresh fruits and assorted sweets as presents from the Leaders Great and Dear on days of especial national significance. It is noteworthy that distributed items were sold at generously subsidized prices, essentially for free. For decades, North Koreans would pay 0.08 won per kilo of rice, and less for a kilo of corn—while the average monthly salary in the 1970s was about 50–60 won. Indeed, the relative marginality of money became another important feature of the North Korean economy as it emerged in the 1960s. Nicholas Eberstadt once noted: “[T]he medium of domestic currency was almost marginal to the operation of the DPRK economy by that point. In this respect, the DPRK is an extreme outlier from the modern economic experience. The only other economy to come close would be Cambodia’s in the late 1970s, under the dark days of the Khmer Rouge, when the Pol Pot leadership simply abolished money for a time” (Eberstadt 2002). One cannot help but agree: indeed, money would not buy much in Kim Il Sung’s era North Korea. Food and basic goods were strictly rationed, while moderate luxuries were issued as a reward for labour and loyalty by the state, free of charge—and it was almost impossible to get around the regulations and bans. Markets never ceased to exist in North Korea, and in 1969, Kim Il Sung himself admitted that, for the time being at any rate, the existence of markets were a necessary evil. But in most cases, markets only opened three days a month. There were also long lists of items, the sale of which was prohibited in these markets—though these lists were increasingly disregarded as time went by.13 Be that as it may, market prices were prohibitively expensive because farmers were only able to sell what they had grown themselves in their very small private plots. For example, in the mid-1980s, in Pyongyang’s main market, a single chicken would cost thirty-five won (this was equivalent to roughly half the average monthly salary), while one apple would cost five won (roughly equivalent to two days wages).14 Theoretically, garments, footwear and other non-food items were banned from sale at the markets, but the ban came to be neglected by 228

A dynastic polity in economic decline

1980—the author remembers that in the mid-1980s at least half of the merchants in the major Pyongyang market were trading in the non-food items. Another notable feature of Kim Il Sung’s economic policy, as it emerged in the 1960s, was a strong emphasis on self-reliance (otherwise known as economic autarky), both in the international economic relations and domestically. The North Korean government made the principle of charyk kaengsaeng—which can roughly be translated as self-reliance—into the major slogan describing its economic policy. As a matter of fact, this slogan, Sino-Korean in origin, was borrowed from Mao’s China verbatim (the Mandarin pronunciation of these four characters is zili gengsheng), though few North Koreans were aware of this.15 Indeed, Mao’s experiments of the period resonated remarkably well with what the North Korean leaders saw as an ideal model of economy. The emphasis on autarky was not merely inspired by Chinese experiments of the era, but also reflected the deep-rooted beliefs of the North Korean political elite. Their ideal economic model implied that every industrial enterprise and administrative unit would normally produce most of what it needs without having to ask for funds and assistance from the central government. Until the late 1980s, the North Korean official media extolled the achievements of those enterprises and regions where the self-reliance had been actualized. For example, when workers in Pyongyang’s main granary needed a small railway locomotive to move grain, instead of asking the central government for this piece of transportation machinery, they allegedly produced for themselves. This is but one of a litany of examples to be found in the North Korean media of the 1960s and 1970s. Obviously, North Korea’s economic planners hoped that an emphasis on regional selfsufficiency would decrease the pressure on the central government to provide scarce industrial equipment and raw materials. It was also expected that a conglomeration of self-sufficient regions would ultimately help to reduce economic and hence political dependence on other countries (above all, the Soviet Union and China). Such emphasis on self-reliance was quite popular in the developing world of the period, and incidentally, in South Korea in the late 1960s some opposition politicians and public intellectuals promoted similar schemes as an alternative to Park Chung Hee’s export-oriented industrialization policy. At the end of the day, though, North Korea’s approach proved to be unsuccessful, and probably led to greater inefficiency and wastage, since modern economies are necessarily premised upon division of labour and specialization. Paradoxically, in spite of the much trumpeted self-reliance, North Korea remained one of the most economically dependent countries of the socialist bloc. As events of the late 1990s painfully demonstrated, it was kept afloat largely by direct and indirect subsidies from the Soviet Union, China and other relatively affluent socialist states. As the socialist bloc disintegrated around 1990, aid to North Korea dried up and the North Korean economy imploded in a matter of years. In the early 1970s, though, there was a short period when the North Korean government seemingly discarded the emphasis on the autarky and attempted to use the favourable international climate at the time in order to acquire foreign loans. It was assumed that these loans would be used to buy modern factories, thus reviving their country’s increasingly stagnant economy. The world’s banking institutions were prepared to loan North Korea significant sums, partially because at the time, the communist countries were believed to be trustworthy and reliable borrowers, but also because in the early 1970s, after the first oil crisis, the world’s financial system was flush with petro-dollars (Armstrong, 2013: 178). These loans were indeed used by the North Korean government to purchase industrial equipment and sometimes even entire factories, like, say, a watch factory from Switzerland or large batches of mining and metal-working equipment from Sweden. At the same time, the 229

Andrei Lankov

North Korean authorities showed remarkably little interest in the acquisition of technical knowhow. They obviously assumed that money should not be wasted in such way, since the requisite technology would be independently mastered by North Korea’s own engineers and technicians. It is debatable how North Koreans expected to be able to pay these loans and even whether actually planned to repay this money at all. At any rate, this investment boom proved to be short-lived. In the late 1970s, North Korea became the first state in the socialist bloc to default on its loans. By the late 1980s the accumulated debt to the Western private creditors was estimated to be at some $900 million (Noland, 2000: 95). In the mid-1970s, obviously under the pressure of default and feeling the increasing need to acquire foreign currency, the North Korean authorities began to engage in a number of illicit money-making activities. These included the production and sale of drugs, the manufacture and use of counterfeit US dollars, as well as engagement in a number of insurance fraud schemes and the abuse of diplomatic immunity to smuggle alcohol, tobacco, and other contraband goods like ivory and wristwatches. Contrary to what is often assumed, such illicit activities seemingly never yielded significant income, but rather led to a large number of high-profile diplomatic scandals that seriously damaged the country’s image on the world stage (Noland, 2000: 95). Apart from such illicit activities, the North Korean economic planners, increasingly hungry for dollars, yens and francs, began to utilize a number of less controversial schemes to earn income overseas. From the late 1970s, North Korea de facto abandoned the state’s hitherto monopoly on foreign trade (this was a typical feature of all planned economies of the Soviet type). Larger industrial embassies, but also party and government agencies (like the central committee) and even larger military units were allowed (and, indeed, encouraged) to establish their own, autonomous foreign-currency earning enterprises. These enterprises were given rights to export some types of resources—like coal, medical herbs, ginseng and seafood. As just stated, these organizations enjoyed what was at that time an unprecedented level of autonomy and managerial freedom. They were allowed to pay commercial wages to workers engaged in the extraction/ harvesting of resources for export, they were permitted to seek out their own commercial partners overseas and sell their produce at the international going rate—as long as they made required hard-currency contribution to their agencies’ budget. As time passed, the managers of such enterprises increasingly came to behave as if they were private entrepreneurs. They began to pocket a significant amount of their foreign-currency earnings (Greitens, 2014). Another source of income was a large ethnic-Korean community in Japan. In the mid-1950s, pro-Pyongyang activists created Ch’ongryǒn (known as Chosen Soren in Japanese), a powerful Korean émigré organization to which most of the émigré community initially belonged to. Facing serious discrimination in Japanese society, ethnic Koreans were inclined to create a closely knit organization that came to look upon Pyongyang as its political benefactor and protector. Some 95,000 ethnic Koreans moved from Japan to North Korea in the 1960s. For the subsequent few decades, most of these people relied on monetary remittances from their relatives in Japan (Morris-Suzuki, 2007). Additionally, from the 1960s, more successful ethnic Koreans in Japan were encouraged to make donations to the North Korean government’s budget. Often, the most important donors were rewarded for their generosity by the regime: for example, their relatives could be granted the right to reside in Pyongyang or study in a prestigious college. Also, from the late 1970s, the government opened a number of the hard-currency shops, where the receivers of the remittances could shop for high-quality goods that were unavailable to the vast majority of the North Koreans. Since the money was usually sent illegally, it is impossible to estimate the scale of transfers with any precision, but there is little doubt that from the early 1960s and until the late 1980s 230

A dynastic polity in economic decline

these remittances constituted a major source of revenue for the North Korean state. For example, in 1994 the director-general of the Japanese Agency for Public Security and Investigation stated that Ch’ongryǒn, its affiliated groups and individuals annually sent to North Korea between $650 million and $850 million a year. However, in 1996, Nicholas Eberstadt, having studied the available sources, concluded that by the mid-1990s the figure was lower, in the region of $100 million a year—even though in the 1960s and 1970s, the amount of remittances had been significantly higher (Eberstadt, 1996). Given that the total foreign trade volume of North Korea in the 1980s oscillated between one and two billion dollars, a few hundred million dollars a year made very important a contribution indeed. * In general, the history of North Korean economy in 1945–1990 can be seen as a short period of success followed by long stagnation and then accelerating decline. The success was, to a large extent, made possible by the large endowment the northern part of Korea inherited from imperial Japan: prior to 1945, it was the area which attracted a remarkable amount of investment. Nonetheless, a significant role was also played by the new government’s ability to mobilize the labour and resources while also attracting large-scale foreign aid. However, the inner inefficiency of the Leninist centrally planned economy was exacerbated by the excessive militarization (perhaps, partially unavoidable, given the international environment and political priorities of the regime), as well as by the ideological peculiarities of the decision-makers’ worldview. Thus, the economy soon slowed down and slowly moved to stagnation. While the foreign assistance allowed North Korea to stay afloat and provide the population with a basic food supply, the country began to lag behind its major rival. The growing gap between two Korean states was to have significant impact on the strategic thinking in Pyongyang, essentially determining the fate of the North Korean state in the long run. The fateful decisions of the 1950s and 1960s made the 1990s disasters nearly unavoidable—but nobody, including the decision-makers themselves, could foresee such an outcome.

Notes 1 The relevant North Korean laws and regulations have been studied well. For a short description, see: Kim Hak-chun, Pukhan 50 nyŏn sa [Fifty Years of North Korean History] (Seoul: Tonga, 1995), pp. 108–110, 179–182. 2 이주철, “1950년대 북한 농업협동화의 곡물 생산성과 연구” // 고려사학회 31, 2008.5, pp. 205–240. 3 For a review of the discussion and subsequent events, see: Andrei Lankov, Crisis in North Korea: Failure of de-Stalinization, 1956 (Honolulu: Hawaii University Press, 2004). James F. Person, “We Need Help from Outside”: The North Korean Opposition Movement of 1956 (Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center, 2006). 4 On the tension-building policy of the late 1960s, see: Mitchell Lerner, “Mostly Propaganda in Nature”: Kim Il Sung, the Juche Ideology, and the Second Korean War (Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson International Center, 2010). 5 For a review of the “simultaneous development” policy, see: 한모니까, “1960년대 북한의 경제· 국방병 진노선의 채택과 대남정책.” 역사와현실 50, 2003.12, pp. 133–164. 6 Ibid., p. 146. 7 A typically uncritical reiteration of the Pyongyang official narrative can be found in: 정태웅, “남포: 인 천-남포 뱃길 통해 물자 오가는 서해갑문의 항구도시” // 민족 21 86, 2008.5, pp. 52–55. 8 On the details of this remarkable diplomatic balancing act, see: Charles Armstrong, Tyranny of the Weak: North Korea and the World, 1950–1992 (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2013). 9 See: 이문청, 서정민, 북한과 중국의 사회주의 대중동원운동 비교연구 : 천리마운동과 대약진운동 // 한국정치학 회보 47(4), 2013.9, pp. 157–183. 231

Andrei Lankov

10 A review of the ‘battles’, see: 차문석, 북한150일 전투 개시 – 새 건설은 흙 살림집 뿐? // 통일한국 27(6), 2009.6, pp. 81–83. 11 For a comprehensive overview of the PDS since its inception and until its collapse in the 1990s, see: No Yong-hwan and Yŏn Ha-ch’ŏng, Pukhan-ŭi chumin saenghwal pochang chŏngch’aek p’yŏngka [Evaluation of the Welfare Policies in North Korea] (Seoul: Hankuk pokŏnsahoeyŏnkuwŏn, 1997), pp. 47–62. 12 For the description of the special rationing system for officials, see: 서동익. 인민이 사는 모습 (서울: 자 료원 , Seoul: Saryowŏn1995), vol. 2, p. 212. 13 For a review of the North Korean government’s policy on markets, see: 정형곤 [김병연, 이 석, “북한의 시장화 현황과 경제체제의 변화 전망”서울: 대외경제정책연구원 2012, pp. 54–61. 14 Author’s own notes from his stay in Pyongyang. 15 For a brief review of the Chinese origin and Mao-era usage of the slogan, see: Lawrence R. Sullivan, Historical dictionary of the People’s Republic of China, 2nd ed. (Lanham, MD: Scarecrow Press, 2007), pp. 444–445.

References Armstrong, Charles (2013) Tyranny of the weak: North Korea and the world, 1950–1992, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Bazhanova, Natalia (1993) Vneshneekonomicheskie sviazi KNDR [Overseas Economic Connections of the DPRK], Moscow: Vostochnaia literatura. Ch’a, Mun-sŏk (2009) ‘Pukhan 150 il chŏnt’u kaesi [The beginning of the 150 days battle]’, T’ongil hankuk [Unified Korea], 27–6: 81–83. Chŏng T’ae-ung, ‘Namp’o: Inch’ŏn-Namp’o paeskil t’onghae mulcha okanŭn sŏhae kapmun-ŭi hangkutosi [Nampo: The City of the West Sea Barrage Where Good Come through the Inch’ŏn-Namp’o Searoute]’, Minchok 21 [Nation 21], 86: 52–55. Chŏng, Hyŏng-kon, Kim, Pyŏng-yŏn and Yi, Sŏk (2012) Pukhan-ŭi sichanghwa hyŏnhwang-kwa kyŏngche ch’eche-ŭi pyŏnhwa chŏnmang [The Current State of North Korea’s Marketization and the Prospects of the Changes in the Economic System], Seoul: Taeoe kyŏngche chŏngch’aek yŏnkuwŏn. Eberstadt, Nicholas (1996) ‘Financial Transfers from Japan to North Korea: Estimating the Unreported Flows’, Asian Survey, 36–5: 523–542. Eberstadt, Nicholas (2002) Humanity, Peace, and Security. Presentation at the ICAS 2002 Fall Symposium. Retrieved from: http://www.aei.org/article/foreign-and-defense-policy/regional/asia/humanity-peaceand-security/. Accessed 27 August 2014. Eberstadt, Nicholas (2007) The North Korean Economy: Between Crisis and Catastrophe, New Brunswick and London: Transaction Publishers. Eberstadt, Nicholas (2010) Policy and economic performance in divided Korea during the Cold War era: 1945–91, Washington, DC: AEI Press. Greitens, Chestnut (2014) Sheena Illicit: North Korea’s Evolving Operations to Earn Hard Currency, Washington, DC: Committee for Human Rights in North Korea. Haggard, Stephan and Noland, Marcus (2007) Famine in North Korea: Markets, Aid, and Reform, New York: Columbia University Press. Hamm, Taik-young (1999) Arming the Two Koreas: State, Capital, and Military Power, London and New York: Routledge. Han, Monikka (2003) ‘1960 nyŏntae Pukhan-ŭi kyŏngche kukpang pyŏngchin nosŏn-ŭi ch’aet’aek-kwa taenam chŏngch’aek [North Korea’s Choice of the Simultaneous Economic-Military Strengthening Strategy and Its Policy Towards South Korea]’, Yŏksa-wa hyŏnsil [History and Reality], 50: 133–164. Kim, Hak-chun (1995) Pukhan 50 nyŏn sa [Fifty years of North Korean History], Seoul: Tonga. Kim, Il Sung (1976) ‘On Socialist Construction and the South Korean Revolution in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea’, in Kim Il Sung Selected Works, Volume 4, Pyongyang: Foreign Languages Publishing House. Lankov, Andrei (2004) Crisis in North Korea: Failure of de-Stalinization, 1956, Honolulu: Hawaii University Press. Lankov, Andrei, Kwak, In-ok and Cho, Choong-Bin (2012) ‘The Organizational Life: Daily Surveillance and Daily Resistance in North Korea’, Journal of East Asian Studies, 12–2: 193–214. Lerner, Mitchell (2010) “Mostly Propaganda in Nature”: Kim Il Sung, the Juche Ideology, and the Second Korean War, Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson International Center. 232

A dynastic polity in economic decline

McCune, George (1950) Korea Today, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Morris-Suzuki, Tessa (2007) Exodus to North Korea: Shadows from Japan’s Cold War, Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. No, Yong-hwan and Yŏn, Ha-ch’ŏng (1997) Pukhan-ŭi chumin saenghwal pochang chŏngch’aek p’yŏngka [Evaluation of the Welfare Policies in North Korea], Seoul: Hankuk pokŏn sahoe yŏnkuwŏn. Noland, Marcus (2000) Avoiding the Apocalypse: The Future of Two Koreas, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. North Korean Research Institute (1988) Pukhan sasip nyŏn [40 Years of North Korea], Seoul: Ŭryu munhwasa. Person, James (2006) “We Need Help from Outside”: The North Korean Opposition Movement of 1956, Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center. Robinson, Joan (1965) ‘Korean Miracle’, Monthly Review, January: 541–549. Rodong sinmun (2010) ‘Saeroun sŭngli-e-ro purŭnŭn chŏntu chŏkki (The battle banner which calls for new victories)’ (Editorial). 9 January. Sŏ Tong-ik. Inmini sanŭn mosŭp [How People Live], Volume 2, Sŏul: Charyowŏn. Sullivan, Lawrence (2007) Historical dictionary of the People’s Republic of China, Second edition, Lanham, MD: Scarecrow Press. Yang, Mun-su (2010) Pukhan kyŏngche-ŭi sichanghwa [The Marketization of North Korean Economy], Seoul: Hanul. Yi, Chuch’ŏl (2008) ‘1950 nyŏntae pukhan nongŏp hyŏptonghwa-ŭi kokmul saengsansŏng-kwa yŏnku [Study of the Grain Production during the 1950s’ Collectivization of Agriculture in North Korea]’, Hankuk sa hakpo [Korean History Journal], 31: 205–240. Yi, Mun-ch’ŏng and Sŏ, Chŏng-min (2013), Pukhan-kwa Chungkuk-ŭi sahoechuŭi taechung tongwŏn untong pikyo yŏnku: ch’ŏnrima untongk-wa taeyakchin untong [The Comparative Study of Mass Socialist Mobilization Movements in China and North Korea: Cheonlima movement and Great Leap Forward]’, Hankuk chŏngch’ihak hoepo [Korean journal of political studies], 47: 157–183. Yim, Sang-chŏl (2000) Pukhan nongŏp [North Korean Agriculture], Seoul.

233

17 The North Korean famine Marcus Noland

During the 1990s, North Korea experienced one of the worst famines of the twentieth century. The disaster represented the culmination of decades of economic mismanagement and was abetted by the country’s authoritarian political system which allowed the government to act in a callous and unaccountable fashion. Indeed the actions of the North Korean authorities before, during, and after the famine, were cited by the United Nations Commission of Inquiry on North Korean Human Rights investigation as egregious human rights violations constituting crimes against humanity (UN 2014). Although the worst of the famine has passed, food shortages and malnutrition remain a chronic problem for some segments of the population. Apart from the enormous human costs measured in deaths, splintered families, and permanently blighted lives, the famine accelerated the breakdown of the country’s centrally planned economy. The failure of the state to fulfil its obligations under the existing socialist compact necessitated entrepreneurial coping responses, often technically illegal, by small-scale social organizations— household, enterprises, local party organs, military units—to secure food. The associated transactions, which began as barter, eventually were monetized and spread to a wider range of goods and services, contributing to a grassroots marketization of the economy. North Korea’s economic transition over the past two decades can best be understood not as a top-down attempt by the governing authorities to marketize or improve efficiency, but rather as bottom-up coping in the face of state failure. The world community responded to this tragedy with considerable generosity, committing more than two billion dollars in food aid. The United States alone contributed more than $600 million, equivalent to two million metric tons of grain, and at times North Korea was the largest recipient of US aid in Asia, despite the manifest political differences between the countries. Yet the famine also tested public and private sector relief agencies, which were frustrated by the North Korean government’s refusal to accept international norms and which still struggle to implement high-quality humanitarian operations to ameliorate North Korea’s chronic food insecurity. Today the United Nations World Food Program effort in North Korea is woefully underfunded, reflecting donor fatigue. These changes that the famine provoked—greater openness to the outside world, less direct state control over the economy, and a sustained presence by more savvy humanitarian 234

The North Korean famine

organizations means that a trauma like the famine of the 1990s is less likely to occur today. The North Korean populace is more genuinely self-reliant and less prone to passively follow the government’s lead than it was twenty years ago; the spread of information continues, the economy is more flexible, and the outside world is more aware. In this essay, I assess the North Korean famine, examining its context, its basic characteristics, the competing estimates of famine deaths, the international community’s response to this calamity, and conclude with some observations about how the outside world should address the ongoing issue of food insecurity in North Korea.

Historical context Under Soviet tutelage, North Korea established a thoroughly orthodox centrally planned economy, notable only for the rigour with which markets were suppressed. Under the ideology of juche (or chuch’e), normally translated as “self-reliance,” North Korea never joined the Council of Mutual Economic Assistance, the Soviet-led grouping of planned socialist economies, and the authorities went so far as to time their economic plans to frustrate linkages with other socialist states. Under relatively autarkic conditions, agriculture was collectivized, quantitative planning in production was introduced, state marketing and distribution of grain was established, and private production and trade were prohibited. North Korea made a fateful decision to pursue the understandable goal of national food security through a misguided strategy of national selfsufficiency. Natural conditions, including a high ratio of population to arable land, short growing seasons and limited opportunities for double cropping, were inauspicious. To compensate, a highly industrial input-intensive system of agricultural production was developed to maximize yields, involving, for example, the heavy application of chemical fertilizers and the extensive use of electrically driven irrigation—both of which were dependent on imported oil (Noland 2000). The crisis had its origins in a multifaceted set of developments in the late-1980s, though the precise causal relationships are unclear. In 1987, frustrated by North Korean unwillingness to repay accumulated debts, the Soviets withdrew support. (Despite its juche-inspired declarations of self-reliance, North Korea has been dependent on outside assistance throughout its entire history, with first the Soviet Union, later China, then South Korea, and most recently China again in the role of chief benefactor.) That same year, the North Koreans initiated policy changes in the agricultural sector, including the expansion of grain-sown areas, transformation of crop composition in favour of high-yield items, maximization of industrial inputs subject to availability, and the intensification of double-cropping and dense planting. Continuous cropping led to soil depletion, and the overuse of chemical fertilizers contributed to acidification of the soil and eventually a reduction in yields. Testimonies by refugees and diplomats, the emergence of a “let’s eat two meals a day campaign,” as well as implicit evidence derived from the stature of defecting North Korean troops, and the delayed onset of menarche uncovered in a survey of North Korean refugees in South Korea, all indicate the emergence of significant food insecurity by the late 1980s, at least among some socioeconomic groups (Haggard and Noland 2007; Shin and Lee 2013). The economy was hit by massive trade shocks beginning in 1990, as the Eastern Bloc disintegrated. Trade with the Soviet Union had accounted for more than half of North Korean two-way trade, including most of its fuel imports. For reasons that remain a mystery, the North Korean leadership appears not to have grasped the epochal nature of the changes occurring around them. Unlike Vietnam, which suffered a similar pattern of shocks, North Korea proved incapable of reorienting its commercial relations, and its industrial economy imploded. Deprived 235

Marcus Noland

of industrial inputs—most importantly imported oil, used not only to power irrigation systems and agricultural machinery, but as the feedstock for the production of chemical fertilizers— agricultural yields and output fell dramatically. As yields declined, hillsides were denuded to bring more and more marginal land into production. This contributed to soil erosion and the silting of rivers, canals, and most importantly, reservoirs. The result was the exacerbation of the usual pattern of flooding associated with monsoon-type rain during the summer, as the land simply could not carry as much water as it once had. China initially stepped into the breach, offsetting some of the fall in trade with the Soviet Union and emerging as North Korea’s primary supplier of imported food, most of it reportedly on concessional terms. But in 1994 and 1995, responding to growing internal discontent over rising grain prices caused by tight global market conditions, China reduced its exports to North Korea in an effort to dampen internal price increases. If there was a single proximate trigger to the North Korean famine, this was it.1

Famine response At this juncture the government of North Korea could have relieved emerging shortages by relaxing the supply constraint, either by increasing exports to finance imports or appealing for aid. (Borrowing was not an option: sovereign defaults in the 1970s—the only communist country to do so—left it effectively excluded from international capital markets.) Instead, it chose to further suppress consumption, cutting rations delivered by the public distribution system (PDS), the quantity rationing system from which urban residents, roughly two-thirds of the country, obtained their food. It was not until the spring of 1995, with a famine underway, that North Korea appealed for external assistance, initially approaching Japan, its former colonial master, whose contributions could be portrayed as a kind of reparation, then later requesting assistance from rival South Korea, and ultimately, the United Nations system. Floods that summer (and the following summer as well) played an important political role insofar as they facilitated the depiction of the famine as the product of natural disasters. The North Korean government even went so far as to rename the unit charged with managing the aid relationships as the Flood Damage Rehabilitation Committee. The onset of the famine preceded the floods; the floods did not cause the famine, and indeed appear to have been a relatively minor contributing factor (Noland, Robinson and Wang 2001). Aid was forthcoming, but the government impeded the normal assessment, monitoring, and evaluation functions of the relief organizations—for example, prohibiting the use of Korean speakers and banning access and relief to certain geographic areas, including ones suspected to be the worst affected. Critically, with assistance ramping up, the government cut commercial grain imports, in essence using humanitarian aid as a form of balance of payments support, and freeing up resources for other expenditure priorities, most notably the importation of advanced weaponry (Figure 17.1). While it is true that aid often crowds out commercial grain imports in famines, it is important to underscore that in the North Korean context, the outcomes depicted in Figure 1 are the product of policy, not decentralized decision-makers responding to price signals. Indeed, even after the economy began recovering in 1999 and overall imports began rising, commercial food imports remained minimal (Figure 17.2). If North Korea had simply maintained its imports, normal human demand could have been met throughout this period (Figure 17.3). But from 1995 on, the public distribution system did not deliver the minimum needs, even on paper, averaging around 300 grams daily (Figure 17.4). Even at the famine’s peak, the resources 236

The North Korean famine

Percent

Metric Tons (millions) 1.8

100

1.6

90 80

1.4

70 1.2 60 1.0 50 0.8 40 0.6 30 0.4

20

0.2

10

0.0

0

Imports on Commercial Terms

Volume of Aid

Aid, % of Total Imports (RHS)

Figure 17.1 Food imports and aid, 1990-2010

Index (1993 = 100) 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

Total Commercial Food Imports

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

Total Commercial Merchandise Imports

Figure 17.2 Total imports and commercial food imports, 1993-2010

237

Marcus Noland

Metric tons (millions) 6.0 Production, Imports, and Aid

5.5

Production and Counterfactual Imports

5.0

4.5

Production, Counterfactual Imports, and Aid

4.0

Minimum Human Need

3.5

Minimum Human Need (Adjusted 20%)

3.0

2.5

Normal Human Demand

2.0 1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

Figure 17.3 Scenarios of food supply and minimum human need, 1990-2004

Grams per day 700

600

600

600

600

575 550 500

500 Minimum human need (457g) 427

400

400

395

400

353 300 300

300

293

271 250 200

100

200

208 196

100

319

296

300

300

250

250

225

200

100 25

0 Nov. 1995 - Nov. 1996 - Nov. 1997 - Nov. 1998 - Nov. 1999 - Nov. 2000 - Nov. 2001 - Nov. 2002 - Nov. 2003 - Nov. 2004 Oct. 1996 Oct. 1997 Oct. 1998 Oct. 1999 Oct. 2000 Oct. 2001 Oct. 2002 Oct. 2003 Oct. 2004 Oct. 2005 Max

Average Average

Figure 17.4 Estimates of daily per capita PDS rations

238

Min

Farmers Farmers

The North Korean famine

needed to close the gap were relatively modest, only on the order of $100–$200 million dollars, or about five to twenty percent of revenues from exported goods and services or one to two percent of contemporaneous national income (Noland 2013).2 That gap could have been closed with modest expenditure switching. Instead, the government of North Korea did not act expeditiously: it waited years between the emergence of a food crisis and making appeals for aid, and once the famine was underway, it did not use the maximum of its available resources to ensure access to adequate food.

Famine deaths controversy The result was a famine with pronounced geographic, socioeconomic, and demographic components (Haggard and Noland 2007: Chapter 7). The worst affected being the young and old, those in the four provinces of the northeast, and those deemed politically unreliable. Given the secrecy of the North Korean regime, it is unsurprising that the timing and impact of the resulting famine are still not well understood. The onset of the famine is conventionally dated 1994, though there is some argument that mortality rates were already significantly elevated in 1993. Either date would mean that the famine was already underway when the country experienced floods in 1995. This chronology is critical insofar as it undermines the politically convenient depiction of the famine as a product of natural disasters. The famine is generally acknowledged to have ended in 1998. There have been essentially three waves of estimates of famine deaths. Contemporaneous estimates were sometimes quite high—3.5 million or more were provided by a variety of observers and NGOs, often with detailed knowledge of the situation on the ground, but lacking professional training in demography or related disciplines. One important exception was the testimony of Hwang Jang-yop (Hwang Chang-yŏp), former member of the Standing Committee of the Supreme People’s Assembly, who defected to the South in 1997. Hwang testified repeatedly and in public3 up until his death in 2010 on the basis of internal Party discussions and documents that “According to the Organization Guidance Bureau official, more than 500 thousand people, including fifty thousand party members, had starved to death in 1995. And as of mid-November 1996, almost 1 million people had already starved to death. . . That more than 1.5 million people died of hunger from 1995 to 1996 is an irrefutable fact. We do not have accurate data about the situation from 1997 to 1998, but since the food supply did not improved [sic] much, it can be deduced that at least a million people have met their deaths every year. According to reports that Chinese press company Xinhua claims it received from officials of the Agricultural Committee in North Korea, a total of 2.8 million people have starved to death at last count at the end of 1997. From this and the irrefutable fact that 1.5 million had died by the end of 1996, we can deduce that another 1.3 million people died in 1997 to add up to a total of 2.8 million deaths by starvation. We have consistently said that more than 1.5 million died between 1995 and 1996 and that 1 million more probably died every year from 1997 to 1998. We never resorted to exaggerating the situation” (Hwang 2002). Of course, there is no way of verifying Hwang’s claims and one can speculate on his motives. Nevertheless, it would be a mistake to dismiss his allegations out of hand. The next generation of estimates was done by analysts with greater formal training and more rigorous methodologies. Prominent was work done by Courtland Robinson and colleagues, who analysed retrospective refugee testimony collected between September 1998 and June 2000 on deaths from selected villages in North Hamgyong (Hamgyŏng) province (Robinson et al. 1999; Robinson et al. 2001). They concluded that between 1995 and 1997, twelve percent of the province’s population, or 245,000 people, had died. Projected onto the whole country 239

Marcus Noland

(something that Robinson et al. were careful not to do), that baseline would yield an estimate of 2.64 million excess deaths. This simple extrapolation would be inappropriate for a variety of reasons, and as a consequence, two million excess deaths would seem to be an absolute ceiling, and the actual number was probably much lower (Haggard and Noland 2007). Demographers Daniel Goodkind and Loraine West, working off the Robinson et al. surveys, produced estimates on the range of 605,000 to 1 million deaths (Goodkind and West 2001). In his dissertation, Lee Suk (2003), unaware of the Goodkind-West work and using a different methodology, came up with estimates also in the 600,000 to 1 million range. J. Stanton (2007) argued that this estimate may have been excessively conservative insofar as death rates may have been higher in South Hamgyong than North Hamgyong. (This argument is not implausible: according to the latest UNICEF nutritional survey, South Hamgyong generally scores worse than North Hamgyong—it appears that it is better to be closer to China than to Pyongyang [UNICEF 2013]). “Up to a million deaths” seems to have remained the academic consensus until a series of contributions appeared in the last several years, a paper by Goodkind, West, and Johnson (2011), one produced by South Korean government demographers4, another by Spoorenberg and Schwekendiek (2012), and a paper by Lee Suk (2011), all using variants on the same methodology. They take the controversial 1993 census as a starting point, posit a model of population growth, and then compare the projections from that exercise to data from the 2008 census. The shortfall in the actual population numbers from the projections is then allocated over the period 1993–2008, and from that process, one obtains estimates of excess deaths during the famine period. A key point that comes out most clearly in the paper by Spoorenberg and Schwekendiek, is that if one allocates few deaths to the famine period, then by implication, one is allocating more deaths to the post-famine period. On the basis of various assumptions, they generate estimates ranging from 237,000 to 420,000 excess deaths. But if these estimates are accepted, then they imply a greater human toll during the twelve years following the famine than during the famine itself! This result comes from some combination of the aftermath of the famine—the long-lived results of chronic malnutrition—and the fact that the economy failed to grow over this period, resulting in a stagnation of life expectancy. This particular result may not be persuasive, but the paper does provide a useful service in reminding us that while the famine may have ended in 1998, its effects continue to reverberate. Lee (2011) is the paper that appears to be most informed by actual knowledge of North Korea. Somewhat like Spoorenberg and Schwekendiek, Lee treats the entire period as a “slow motion” famine occurring over the whole fifteen-year sample period, so that his estimates of excess deaths are not directly comparable to the earlier work (including his own) that examined to a more limited period in the 1990s. Unlike the other papers, Lee takes the problematic nature of the North Korean data seriously, observing that problems of counting males (first identified by Eberstadt and Banister [1992] as the “missing male” problem associated with military service) creates anomalies in the apparent cohort-specific survival rates in the two censuses. Lee’s response is to focus on females, where this distortion is likely to be less severe. He calculates excess deaths in 1993–2008 among the female population who were over thirty years old in 1993, and finds that deaths were 196,307 higher than expected, or 3.8 percent. If one extrapolates this percentage to the entire population, one generates a baseline estimate of 815,000 excess deaths. Lee produces other variants on this calculation which produce estimates ranging from 506,000 to 1,125,000. So where does this leave us? Well, much where we started. Excess deaths during the famine were probably on the order of 600,000 to 1 million people, or three to five percent of the pre-crisis population, making the North Korean famine one of the worst of the twentieth century. 240

The North Korean famine

Humanitarian dilemmas In trying to ameliorate this disaster, the humanitarian community faced a fundamentally hostile environment (Haggard and Noland 2007). The North Korean government would not permit normal assessment and monitoring activities, so aid agencies were forced into adopting a secondbest solution of targeting institutions such as orphanages, schools, and hospitals, where particularly vulnerable populations were thought to be present. But food was not delivered directly to these institutions—it went through the PDS system where it was comingled with other sources of supply intended for different recipients. Initially the World Food Program (WFP) was not permitted to use Korean speakers or employ ethnic Koreans; it was not until 2004 that the government allowed WFP resident staff to take Korean lessons; today the use of Korean speakers remains restricted, though not entirely prohibited. Pre-notification, generally one week, was required for site visits; not until 2002 were two teams allowed to visit a single province at the same time. Pre-notification is still required, but the pre-notification period is now down to twenty-four hours. The WFP and other relief groups have consistently been denied access to markets where, for almost twenty years, most non-elite households have actually obtained their food. In short, during the famine period and its immediate aftermath, the WFP was restricted to using fifty non-Korean speakers to monitor 40,000 end-user institutions of which the North Korean government never furnished a complete list. Such conditions were imposed despite the fact that at its peak, the aid program was targeting roughly one-third of the population. Weak monitoring meant ample opportunity for diversion of aid away from its intended recipients, as well as enabling discrimination in the provision of aid. The extent of diversion depends in part on how rigorously diversion is defined, either as aid not reaching its intended recipients, or as aid not reaching its intended recipients on the gratis terms on which it was donated. Haggard and Noland (2007) use several methodologies to examine the first question and conclude that perhaps thirty percent of aid was diverted. If a more rigorous definition of diversion is applied—the intended recipients did not receive the aid without paying—then the figure would be vastly higher. Concerns over the effectiveness of the aid operation were subsequently reinforced by results obtained from refugee surveys. Haggard and Noland (2011) report results from two surveys of refugees, one conducted in China and the other in South Korea. In both the China-based and South Korea–based surveys, an astonishing share of respondents, roughly half of those surveyed, revealed that they were unaware of the longstanding, large-scale program (Haggard and Noland 2011: Table 3.1). Moreover, among respondents who indicated knowledge of the effort, thirty-three percent of the South Korea survey respondents and only four percent of the China survey respondents believed that they had been recipients. Looking only at urban residents (those on the agricultural cooperatives would have been less likely to receive aid), only three percent in the China survey and fourteen percent of the later South Korea survey reported being recipients. The refugees overwhelmingly believed that the aid went primarily to the military (Haggard and Noland 2011: Table 3.2). The question and possible responses were posed slightly differently in the two surveys, but the results are consistent. When asked who received food aid, and allowing multiple responses, eighty-nine percent of the refugees in China who were aware of the program believed that it went to the military and twenty-seven percent said that it went to government officials; less than three percent said it went to common citizens or others. When asked in the South Korea survey who the primary recipient of aid was—not allowing multiple responses— sixty-seven percent said the military, twenty-seven percent said high-level government or party 241

Marcus Noland

officials, two percent said local government or party officials, and two percent said the general public. Similar results were obtained in a subsequent survey of 500 refugees in South Korea conducted by the Network for North Korean Democracy and Human Rights. Seventy-eight percent of the respondents reported not receiving international food aid while in North Korea. However, the more survey reports something even more astonishing: “Of 106 respondents who did receive such aid, 29 said they returned whole or part of the aid,” apparently after international monitors had departed.5 When asked where the aid went, few of the respondents in any of these surveys thought that the common people had benefitted; large majorities thought that the aid went to the military or other connected groups. According to the Chosun Ilbo, “some 73.6 percent believed that food aid went to the military, followed by party leaders (69 percent), government agencies (48.8 percent) and the privileged (38.8 percent). Only 2 percent believed it went to vulnerable children. Multiple answers were allowed.” The issue of diversion is a complex one: if aid is diverted, it does not disappear into the ether. Obviously, it would be best if the aid reached its targeted beneficiaries. Yet in the North Korean case, the diversion of aid had an oddly positive side-effect, encouraging the development of markets. During a famine, aid is extremely valuable, and there is an enormous incentive to sell it in the market—if such markets exist. In North Korea, however, markets were thoroughly suppressed under the communist system. Ironically, the inflow of aid acted as a lubricant, encouraging the development of markets, a desirable development in the long run. The lack of monitoring and apparent lack of understanding of the North Korean system by the aid agencies may have also enabled the authorities to discriminate in the provision of aid. North Korea maintains a classification system called the sŏngbun system of fifty-two categories based on family background and perceived political loyalty (Collins 2012). There are three broad categories: the core, wavering, and hostile classes. The sŏngbun system strongly influences educational opportunities, job assignments, and location of residence. It appears to have also played a role in relief activities. Between 1998 and 2000 a number of private NGOs (nongovernmental organization) terminated operations in North Korea due to the inability to operate effectively as a result of North Korean government interference (Noland 2000; Schloms 2003). In explaining their withdrawal Medicins Sans Frontieres (MSF) (1998), then the largest private relief operation in the DPRK, made specific allegations with regard to North Korean practices: •



That they were denied access to the so-called 9/27 camps that they had learned of via children’s medical records and discreet comments by local staff, and where they believed patients—particularly starving, orphaned children needing assistance were being held, and MSF specifically claimed that the North Korean government had denied access to sick and malnourished children and channelled relief supplies to the children of the politically wellconnected.

Other NGOs made similar claims. More broadly, aid supplies flow through the PDS system, which is used as a mechanism of social control. Clearly some of the worst-affected areas—mainly in the northeast of the country—were not prioritized in terms of PDS shipments, and these areas also happened to be locations where the share of people classified as wavering and hostile is believed to be particularly high due to a history of forced internal deportations. 242

The North Korean famine

And then, of course, there is the extensive penal system for which I know of no aid shipments ever being delivered.

Conclusion The famine and its aftermath are inseparable from the nature of the political regime. Only a regime that systematically restricts all human, civil, and political rights, preventing the spread of information, debate over policy, and criticism of public officials—and hence is completely insulated from the demands of the populace—could have acted with such culpable slowness and maintained such disastrous policies in the face of a humanitarian catastrophe. Yet reoccurrence of a famine on the scale of the one that occurred during the 1990s is unlikely: North Korea’s economy is more flexible than it was two decades ago, and the North Korean public is unlikely to react to adverse development with the same degree of passivity that some exhibited in the 1990s. Nevertheless, parts of the North Korean population remain chronically food insecure. The ultimate solution to North Korea’s food problems is to be found not in humanitarian aid or even in development assistance, but in economic reform and opening and the revitalization of the industrial economy that would allow North Korea to earn foreign exchange and finance food imports—just as its neighbours China, South Korea, and Japan do. That development, in turn, hinges on North Korea’s willingness to embrace economic reform, something that it has until now eschewed. Until that occurs, the outside world has little ethical choice other than to engage. But that engagement can be done more effectively than it is now. One of the positive things done by the United States government has been to insist that a large share of its contribution should be routed through ports in the extreme northeast of the country where problems are the worst: even if the aid is stolen and sold in the markets, it will still be circulating in the region where malnutrition is most severe. Under such tenuous conditions, providing aid in the form of poor people’s food— such as barley or millet rather than rice, the preferred staple of the elite—is another way of trying to maintain the humanitarian effectiveness of the program. Similarly, providing aid in cooked form would make it less susceptible to hoarding and diversion. However, a policy of providing aid in the form of barley or millet rather than rice or corn would encounter resistance in both Washington and Seoul, where the local political economy of aid reflects the parochial interests of domestic political lobbies, encouraging the inefficient provision of inappropriate products (i.e. shipping American-grown grain on United States-flagged ships). In short, the problems are not located solely in Pyongyang. The UN agencies should be encouraged to adopt a less supine posture with respect to the issues of discrimination in the provision of relief. To my knowledge, the UN specialized agencies have never even mentioned the songbun system in their reports, much less proactively addressed how their practices may interact with this system. Donors should insist on improved monitoring and assessment. Specifically follow-up evaluations of targeted populations should be mandatory: if we cannot observe measurable improvements, then clearly there are problems with the implementation of the relief policy. In short, we should provide assistance. But we should be clear-eyed about the terms of that engagement and seek to provide aid in ways consistent with our values and our obligations under international law.

243

Marcus Noland

Glossary Juche: ideology of national self-reliance Public Distribution System (PDS): system of monthly quantity rationing through which urban residents traditionally obtained their consumer goods, including food. Excess deaths: premature deaths, or ones that occur before the average life expectancy for a person of a particular demographic group. Songbun system: socio-political classification system in which all citizens are placed into one of fifty-two categories based largely on family origin.

Notes 1 2

3

4

5

This would not be the last time that China would respond to rising internal discontent over food prices by embargoing grain exports. It did the same thing in 2009 (Haggard and Noland 2009). For these calculations, famine peak years are considered 1996–1998. Annual commodity prices (in constant 2005 USD) for rice and maize between 1996–1998 taken from World Bank Global Economic Monitor (GEM) figures. North Korea grain deficit estimates taken from FAO/WFP. GDP figures 1996–1998 taken from UN National Accounts Main Aggregates Database. Licit merchandise export figures taken from author estimates. See, for example, audio clip from point 1:12 of Center for Strategic and International Studies (2010) ‘Korea Platform Special Session with Mr. Hwang Jang-yop’ 31 March. Available from http://csis.org/event/korea-platform-special-session-mr-hwang-jang-yop. Accessed 22 July 2014. For an overview, see Noland, M. (2011) ‘Yet Another Estimate of Famine Deaths’. North Korea: Witness to Transformation. 19 October. Available from http://blogs.piie.com/nk/?p=3202. Accessed 22 July 2014. For survey result summary, see ‘78% of N. Korean Defectors Never Saw Foreign Food Aid’ (2011), Chosun Ilbo. 6 April. Available from http://english.chosun.com/site/data/html_dir/2011/04/06/ 2011040600985.html. Accessed 22 July 2014.

References ‘78% of N. Korean Defectors Never Saw Foreign Food Aid.’ (2011). Chosun Ilbo. 6 April. Available from http://english.chosun.com/site/data/html_dir/2011/04/06/2011040600985.html. Accessed 22 July 2014. Center for Strategic and International Studies. (2010). ‘Korea Platform Special Session with Mr. Hwang Jang-yop.’ 31 March. [Audio File]. Available from http://csis.org/event/ korea-platform-specialsession-mr-hwang-jang-yop. Accessed 22 July 2014. Collins, R. (2012). Marked for Life: Songbun North Korea’s Social Classification System. Washington, DC: Committee for Human Rights in North Korea. Eberstadt, N. and Banister, J. (1992). The Population of North Korea. Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies. Goodkind, D. and West, L. (2001). ‘The North Korean Famine and Its Demographic Impact.’ Population and Development Review, 27(2): 219–38. Goodkind, D., West, L. and Johnson, P. (2011). ‘A Reassessment of Mortality in North Korea, 1993–2008.’ Presented at Annual Meeting of the Population Association of America, Washington, DC. March 31–April 2. Available from http://paa2011.princeton.edu/papers/111030. Accessed 22 July 2014. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2007). Famine in North Korea: Markets, Aid and Reform. New York: Columbia University Press. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2009). ‘Famine in North Korea Redux?’ Journal of Asian Economics, 20(4): 384–395. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2011). Witness to Transformation: Refugee Insights into North Korea. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute of International Economics. Hwang, J. (2002). ‘The Problems of Human Rights in North Korea (III).’ Daily NK. Available from http://www.dailynk.com/english/keys/2002/9/04.php. Accessed 22 July 2014. 244

The North Korean famine

Lee, S. (2003). Food Shortages and Economic Institutions in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea. [Ph.D diss.]. Department of Economics, University of Warwick. Coventry, UK. Lee, S. (2011). ‘Analysis on 2008 Census of North Korea and Problems.’ Korea Development Institute. Available from http://www.kdi.re.kr/report/report_class_etc.jsp? pub_no=12403. Accessed 22 July 2014. Medecins Sans Frontieres. (1998). ‘MSF Calls on Donors to Review Their Policy in DPRK.’ [Press release]. 30 September. Available from http://www.doctorswithoutborders.org/press/release.cfm?id=460. Accessed 2 December 2013. Noland, M. (2000). Avoiding the Apocalypse: The Future of the Two Koreas. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. Noland, M. (2011). ‘Yet Another Estimate of Famine Deaths.’ North Korea: Witness to Transformation. 19 October. Available from http://blogs.piie.com/nk/?p=3202. Accessed 22 July 2014. Noland, M. (2013). ‘North Korea and the Right to Food.’ Essay adapted from testimony before the United Nations’ Commission of Inquiry on Human Rights in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea Public Hearings. 30 October. Available from http://www.iie.com/publications/testimony/noland2013 1030.pdf. Accessed 22 July 2014. Noland, M., Robinson, S. and Wang, T. (2001). ‘Famine in North Korea: Causes and Cures.’ Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(4): 741–67. Robinson, W.C., Lee, M.K., Hill, K. and Burnham, G. (1999). ‘Mortality in North Korean Migrant Households: A Retrospective Study.’ Lancet, 354: 291–95. Robinson, W.C., Lee, M.K., Hill, K., Hsu, E. and Burnham, G. (2001). ‘Demographic Methods to Assess Food Insecurity.’ Prehospital and Disaster Medicine, 16(4): 286–92. Schloms, M. (2003). ‘The European NGO Experience in North Korea.’ In L.G. Flake and S. Snyder (eds.) Paved with Good Intentions: The NGO Experience in North Korea (pp. 47–79). Westport: Praeger. Shin, G. and Lee, S.J. (2013). ‘Mental Health and PTSD in Female North Korean Refugees.’ Health Care for Women International. 10 September. Available from http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/ 10.1080/07399332.2013.817412#.U87cG-NdV8E. Accessed 22 July 2014. Spoorenberg, T. and Schwekendiek, D. (2012). ‘Demographic Changes in North Korea: 1993–2008.’ Population and Development Review, 38(1): 133–58. Stanton, J. (2007). ‘“Famine in North Korea:” An Interactive Review (1 of 3).’ One Free Korea. 22 August. Available from http://freekorea.us/2007/08/22/famine-in-north-korea-an-interactive-review-1-of3/. Accessed 22 July 2014. UNICEF. (2013). ‘Democratic People’s Republic of Korea Final Report of the National Nutrition Survey 2012 September 17th to October 17th 2012.’ Available from http://www. unicef.org/eapro/DPRK_ National_Nutrition_Survey_2012.pdf. Accessed 23 July 2014. United Nations. (2014). ‘Report of the commission of inquiry on human rights in the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea.’ UN Human Rights Council Report A/HRC/25/63.

245

18 North Korea under Kim Jong Il Adrian Buzo

Introduction Kim Jong Il became the supreme leader of the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea (DPRK) upon the death of his father, Kim Il Sung, in July 1994, and ruled for seventeen years until he died on 17 December 2011 at the age of seventy. While the influence of Kim Il Sung in shaping the DPRK is self-evident, the role played by the younger Kim remains more obscure. In what ways, then, was the DPRK in 2011 different from the DPRK in 1994, how might we usefully assess these differences, and what role did Kim Jong Il play in bringing them about? Current assessments of Kim Jong Il are deeply coloured by a number of factors, ranging from the trivialities of media imagery to the profoundly serious dimensions of both the DPRK’s nuclear weapons program and its human rights record. The non-Korean media has been especially influential in shaping perceptions, such that upon his death, the outside world wasted little time in passing harsh judgement on Kim, generally acknowledging his skilful manoeuvring toward despised ends, but mainly highlighting his admittedly singular private life and habits, liberally bestowing upon him the epithets of ‘tyrant’ and ‘despot’, and also highlighting what were presented as the consequence of all this folly – an impoverished, starving, isolated, brutalised, failing state. And yet, now we are well into the reign of his son and chosen successor, Kim Jong Un, and the DPRK’s nuclear weapons and payload delivery programs are continuing to make steady progress, seemingly impervious to outside pressure, while the long-predicted collapse of the economy has not occurred. Nor has the recurrence of famine-like conditions, although the food situation remains serious. Given Pyongyang’s basic goals of survival and control of its destiny, such achievements present as indices of success – paradoxical though this may seem to many. The regime that Kim Jong Il has bequeathed to his son still believes it is able to pursue its quixotic chosen destiny, albeit with what looks like substantially reduced effectiveness in some areas, and while this state of affairs is of course subject to abrupt and unforeseen change, most commentators continue to base predictions of such change – if not the outright demise of the DPRK state – on extrapolations which often seem little removed from hunches. This present outcome clearly warrants a much more careful assessment of Kim Jong Il than many currently seem prepared to offer. 246

North Korea under Kim Jong Il

What were Kim Jong Il’s goals? Given the opaque nature of formal government rhetoric, and the clearly self-serving, subtly dissembling content of Kim’s recorded conversations with outsiders, we are very much reliant on both historical perspective and on the accumulated pattern of state behaviour over time. We are certainly safe, though, in accepting the dominant regime slogan ‘Let’s live in our own way’ as a core goal, to be defended on the level of, say, ‘life, liberty and the pursuit of happiness’. For those in the DPRK who still either count themselves as true believers, or else feel they have no other option, this remains the polestar. The definition of ‘our own way’, means, of course, the ‘own way’ determined by the Kimist elite with next to no input from outside. It used to mean active mobilisation of the entire resources of the state to achieve Korean reunification on the North’s terms, but it has increasingly come to mean survival of the way of life they have ended up with, and control of their own destiny in order to keep it that way. Rhetoric on the theme of creating a strong, modern state abounds, but the goal of building a modern socialist Korean state has faded into the past. To what issues, then, should we look in order to assess Kim Jong Il’s leadership? Under Kim the country made substantial progress toward the acquisition of nuclear weapons, it suffered serious and endemic food shortages, including the catastrophic 1994–96 Arduous March famine, and it accepted significant private market activities as part of its consumer economy. These constituted what we might term Kim’s ‘three crises’, and an assessment of his handling of them, based on current outcomes, will obviously tell us much about his effectiveness as a leader.1

Background At the outset, it is important to remind ourselves of some key aspects of Kim Jong Il’s background, route to power and personality. His formative influences were not nearly as dramatic as his father’s, who moulded the DPRK in accordance with a diverse array of early experiences, including exposure to Japanese militarism, a decade of guerrilla warfare, and training as part of the Soviet Red Army during World War Two. By contrast, the younger Kim, who was born in the Soviet Union in 1941 and was eight years old at the outbreak of the Korean War in 1950, grew to maturity during what were tumultuous years for the Workers’ Party of Korea, but as a princeling he was cocooned from such events. After graduating from Kim Il Sung University in 1964, at age 22 he entered the Party organisation – by now thoroughly dominated by his father – where for the next thirty years, his major field of activity was agitprop, with a focus on the subordination of art and culture to Kimist ideology.2 In this capacity he secured his position as his father’s successor, further strengthening the foundations of Kimist rule through Maoist-like mass mobilization campaigns during the 1970s, most notably the Three Revolutions Team Movement, an insurgency movement whose activities further hobbled a faltering economy and effectively completed the destruction of the Workers’ Party of Korea as a functioning collective. Kim then began assuming public positions commensurate with his behind-the-scenes power, first emerging at the apex of the Workers’ Party of Korea at the Sixth Party Conference in 1980. Election to the Supreme People’s Assembly followed in 1982, and he became Supreme Commander of the Korean People’s Army in 1992. Kim Jong Il came to power as a genius-leader surrounded by the cult of personality established by his father and, of course, derived from Josef Stalin, the great avatar of this form of leadership. Observers have speculated to what extent Kim Jong Il ruled by terror, stealth, consultation or committee, but no convincing evidence exists to contradict the widely prevailing belief that he chose to rule with few internal political constraints in determining policy. From time to time, people take issue with what they perceive to be a misleading, monolithic perception of government in the DPRK, and posit the existence of factions and sectional interest 247

Adrian Buzo

groups, ranging from ‘hard line’ to ‘moderate’, with Kim somehow required to balance interests and ‘tilt’ between these entities. However, this is just a posit, and a dubious one at that, because we lack hard evidence for the belief that policy formulation and execution is accompanied by any significant degree of internal policy debate, and even the high-level defector Hwang Jang Yop did not provide persuasive evidence to the contrary. High-ranking officials have occasionally been purged, but their transgressions appear to have been individual, taking place in the context of court politics, rather than as the result of substantive views they may have expressed on ideological or policy issues. Meanwhile when it came to making basic strategic decisions, whatever problems and constraints Kim Jong Il suffered in their aftermath, the evidence drawn from protracted observation of the DPRK’s political culture is that he faced few constraints; if he chose to consult, or even defer, then well and good, but he was under no pressure to do so, as his was a personal autocracy. As such, it was Kim’s leadership which shaped his country’s response to the various challenges it faced, not those challenges which shaped Kim’s leadership. And what of Kim Jong Il the man? The international media dined out for years on lurid accounts of his lifestyle – debauchery, sadism, prodigious alcohol consumption, gourmandism, jaw-dropping extravagance. These images were usually attached to political behaviour which favoured descriptions such as ‘brutal’, ‘ruthless’, ‘erratic’ or ‘capricious’, producing a total effect that prompted strings of seasoned foreign politicians, envoys and negotiators to feel obliged to register surprise when they encountered Kim’s evenness, his strong grasp of state affairs, detailed knowledge of the outside world and adroit negotiating skills. In her memoirs, former US Secretary of State Madeleine Albright noted that during her missile negotiations with Kim in 2000 he was ‘an intelligent man who knew what he wanted. He was isolated, not uniformed’ (2003: 467). The comment was amplified by one of her staff members, who found him ‘smart and a quick problem-solver . . . very different from the way he was known to the outside world . . . he knew a lot more than most leaders would – and he was a conceptual thinker’.3 Chris Patten, EU Commissioner for External Relations, remarked several months later, ‘He was very articulate, spoke without notes. The talks were surprisingly open and freeflowing.’4 ROK, Russian and Japanese officials have been quoted in a similar vein. This suggests, then, that Kim’s lifestyle is largely irrelevant in the broader scheme of things, since no credible observer has ever advanced the case that his private pursuits impacted on either his decisionmaking ability or the coherence of state policy. A further revelation to Kim’s interlocutors was his often detailed knowledge of the world outside North Korea, albeit acquired second-hand and captive to an unusual world view. Somehow, people assumed that the quality of this knowledge implied a potential for engagement, but Kim’s record shows that he did not see anything in the international order that North Korea might wish to attach itself to. Like all leaders, in his home environment he naturally acquired his share of distortions and lacunae, his probably being severer than most, and these, combined with Kimist political tradition and inheritance caused him to draw rather different conclusions to those that many somehow expected of him, with the result that the DPRK remained in selfimposed isolation. Nevertheless, within the Kimist world view these conclusions were far from invalid: for Kim the greater the knowledge, the greater the threat perception, and the more he felt he had to fear as he pursued the basic set of policies he had inherited for the preservation of the Kimist state. A further significant side to Kim Jong Il was his deep absorption in the performing arts North Korean style, especially cinema, and this is often cited by those assembling a comic or disparaging portrait of Kim. We could speculate that his obvious intelligence, his enclosed world, and his status as a princeling might have influenced him to build up a rich, extensive alternative universe 248

North Korea under Kim Jong Il

in which he was in charge of more than what his father decided he would be in charge of, and that the resources available to him allowed him to indulge himself to a rather spectacular degree. Given the stifling pressures of life, first as a princeling and then as designated heir and successor, perhaps these pursuits were a judicious choice. And given the hallmarks and conventions of this genre, it is no wonder that he seems to have masterminded the production of an oeuvre of appalling, disturbing spectacles. But again, there are no grounds for assuming that these pursuits in some way indicated an unbalanced, eccentric or frivolous disposition. In sum, then, as we turn from what Kim Jong Il was to what he did, we find that he was rigorously trained and initiated into a well-defined career path within a well-defined system, which, furthermore, he was profoundly accepting of. He appears to have approached business in a well-informed, self-disciplined, consistent manner, seeking to preserve as much as he could of the system he had played such a key role in shaping. Even the liberal resort to state terror and the scale of human rights abuse under his watch did not appear to issue from any streak of psychopathy, as was the case with Stalin. Rather, such callousness was part – sadly, an accepted, integral part – of the broader Kimist system.

The DPRK’s nuclear weapons program The first issue in any examination of Kim Jong Il’s performance must, of course, be the DPRK’s nuclear weapons program. This is because it was not only the DPRK’s primary chosen means of state survival, but also the matter of greatest concern to the international community. The DPRK’s nuclear weapons program began in earnest toward the end of the 1970s as hopes of waging successful conventional warfare against the South faded. By the late 1980s it faced concerted international pressure to ratify its 1985 accession to the Nuclear Non-Proliferation Treaty (NPT), sign a safeguards agreement with the International Atomic Energy Agreement (IAEA) and submit to inspections. In the early 1990s, suspicions about DPRK intentions grew, culminating in a major standoff with the United States in July 1994, brought about by the DPRK’s unsanctioned removal of plutonium rods from its (Yŏngbyŏn) reactor. By the early 1990s, the DPRK of course faced a heavily degraded strategic and economic situation. The end of the Cold War had deprived Pyongyang of the protection of its mutual defence treaty with the Soviet Union, and had greatly expanded the global possibilities of US military power and deployment. The demands of basic reunification strategy, domestic political mobilisation, and the singular Kimist world view had historically constituted powerful drivers for the direction of extraordinary levels of hostility and abuse toward the US, and we have no reason to doubt the DPRK’s sincerity in this. Thus, the DPRK’s US-centred threat perception, elevated at the best of times, became further pronounced in this, the worst of times. The equation was simple: poor and rapidly losing further economic ground, almost friendless with the partial exception of China, and with nothing but the anathematised option of systemic reform on the table, the achievement of a credible nuclear threat presented the best, and some would have argued the only, option for preserving the Kimist system. Debate on the nature of this threat tends to begin at this point and focuses on whether the DPRK can or cannot be persuaded by the US and other adversaries to abandon its weapons program and embrace any alternative means of guaranteeing state survival. This can be a rather complex debate at times, beset in the first place by almost total ignorance of the true dimensions of the DPRK weapons program, and extremely limited perceptions of DPRK mindset, goals and strategy. This in turn fuels a rich debate on the tactics, strategies and goals of all parties, which is largely beyond our present scope. However, what may be said with confidence after 249

Adrian Buzo

observing the record of the past twenty years is that Pyongyang has not lurched from crisis to crisis, tactic to tactic, but has followed a consistent strategy that links nuclear weapons capability to the very identity of the Kimist state. In the process, the DPRK has carefully laid the groundwork for the successful pursuit of its chosen path by thinking through likely consequences. The first consequence was obviously the economic impact of pursuing a series of major, expensive, technologically advanced projects as rapidly as possible, and with minimal outside interference. Personnel needed to be trained, facilities created, sufficient amounts of plutonium needed to be produced and weaponized, and a means of delivery developed, and all of this would have to rest on a very fragile economic base. The result was the continuing absolute priority accorded to the country’s proportionally huge military economy, which meant that no serious attempt could be made to resurrect the collapsed nonmilitary economy; somehow, figures convinced the leadership that the country could do this.5 A collateral consequence was that the DPRK quickly proceeded to utilize the threat potential of its program in order to extract economic resources from an anxious international community, but it makes no sense to regard this as a major objective of the program per se. One does not make commitments on this scale for such returns, nor, for that matter, for the purpose of some nebulous form of ‘leverage’ in negotiations, or indeed for any other merely tactical objective. The second strategic consequence was that the DPRK would have to live in an almost permanent state of conflict with a wide range of international actors over this matter, and this would involve withstanding an array of pressures. Diplomatically, only minimal achievement towards weaponisation could be achieved before precipitating confrontation with the IAEA. Moreover, as soon as anything like the true dimensions of the progress the DPRK had achieved in its nuclear weapons program became open knowledge, the DPRK would invite a broad range of international sanctions and forfeit a great deal of leverage in other areas of negotiation, especially with the Republic of Korea (ROK). In short, the dividend for the Kimists of such doomsday weaponry was survival on their own terms, while the price was that they could go no further than limited, tactical engagement with the international community and had to accept forms of pressure such as sanctions along the way. Since the DPRK was already alienated from the international order, almost as an article of faith, this did not present as a major challenge, but it helps us to account for the DPRK’s unflinching set against reform, since it assessed any meaningful reform process as compromising their nuclear program and thus conceding leverage to outside forces. The DPRK received an early dividend in November 1994 when the Yongbyon crisis was resolved through the Geneva Framework Agreement (GFA) with the US, and essentially it got to keep the unknown amount of plutonium it had already extracted and agreed to a dual track, whereby it would come back under the IAEA inspection regime in return for receiving major quantities of heavy fuel oil and two light-water nuclear reactors, ostensibly to compensate for lost power generation capacity. It is idle to spend time apportioning precise measures of blame for the rather predictable demise a decade later of a complex, flawed agreement, but the GFA did at least meet the short-term needs of the US, which had overreached itself, and the DPRK, which had bought time to carry forward its program. Disdainful of the economic advantages it had garnered as ends in themselves, Pyongyang no doubt valued the fact that the fuel assistance freed up resources elsewhere in the economy, while the reactors never proceeded beyond the initial construction phase. By 1998, despite the surrounding economic chaos and human distress, the DPRK had also advanced its missile development program to the point where in August that year, it test-fired its first substantial missile. This prompted a flurry of diplomacy in the last months of the Clinton Administration which aimed at curtailing the DPRK’s missile exports, but which ultimately 250

North Korea under Kim Jong Il

failed to produce tangible results. Relations with the US then quickly deteriorated under the Bush Administration as deep and genuine concern over the DPRK’s nuclear program, abiding scepticism of the efficacy of any form of conciliatory negotiation such as the ROK’s Sunshine Policy6, and belief that the North was in fact a failing state. This, plus the bedrock of neoconservative ideology, led the US into increasingly rigid stances, characterised by the use of extreme – and to the North Koreans insulting – public language, especially in referring to Kim Jong Il, and culminating in the inclusion of the DPRK along with Iran and Iraq in the administration’s self-defined ‘axis of evil’ in Bush’s State of the Union address in January 2002. In any case, by now the DPRK’s policy matrix was firmly set. They had avoided outright economic collapse and, despite international pressure, had secured adequate resources to continue the pursuit of its nuclear and missile programs. How far they had actually come was revealed in October 2002 when the DPRK effectively acknowledged to US negotiators that they had been pursuing a parallel, secret highly enriched uranium production program for some time. This finally terminated the life of the already-moribund GFA, and unleashed a further round of nuclear diplomacy, characterised by the fruitless cat-and-mouse Six Party Talks format, involving the US, the ROK, China, Japan, Russia and the DPRK. These talks tried to project a semblance of management of the situation during six rounds between 2003 and 2009 before being suspended. Only Pyongyang knows if indeed it suffered any inhibition by agreeing to these talks, but meanwhile, the milestones passed swiftly by. In December 2002 it expelled the last IAEA inspectors, and in April 2003 it withdrew from the NPT. In February 2005 it officially announced that it had developed nuclear weapons; in July 2006 it test-fired a number of missiles into the Eastern Sea and then in October conducted its first low-yield underground nuclear test. Significant negotiations took place in the last months of the Bush Administration without result, and since then more bomb and missile tests have occurred. The extent to which this pursuit has been determined by the behaviour of the DPRK’s adversaries and the extent to which it has been dictated by Kimist ideology constitute rather enduring polarities of interpretation, and is likely to continue to be the case. However, one does not need to reach any resolution of this debate in order to note the combination of tactical acumen and strategic focus and consistency demonstrated by the DPRK in pursuing this goal over a long period of time under enormous pressure. This should be taken into account in any assessment of Kim Jong Il’s leadership, especially as he himself displayed a close command of the issues during the brief periods in which he was personally present during negotiations.

The famine Progress in the DPRK’s nuclear weapons program was achieved against the background of a catastrophic famine, known in the DPRK as the period of the Arduous March, which claimed upwards of one million lives during 1994–96, roughly 5% of the population. Clear food supply distress signals had already emerged in 1993 while Kim Il Sung was still in charge. The older Kim’s mistrust of the agricultural sector and his ideologically rigid policy of subjecting it to industrial norms of production had entrenched inefficiency and under-performance for many years, but now as inputs collapsed in the broader economy – ranging from maintenance and spare parts to fuel and fertilizer supply – flood conditions in August 1994 – which were serious, but not biblical – caused tragedy. The enormous loss of life had as much to do with the DPRK’s policies as with the availability or non-availability of food. The problems began with a highly centralised, inefficient decisionmaking structure and with lines of communication which were rigorously ordered on top-down 251

Adrian Buzo

principles, with the reverse flow almost totally reserved for conveying military-security information or else concealing unfavourable developments from the leadership. In a manner that recalls the crisis management performance of the Soviet leadership in the face of the Chernobyl disaster, having operated for decades without the need to seriously consider the claims of a civil society, and essentially viewing the entire population as a military asset, the DPRK authorities were simply not tooled, conceptually as much as systemically, to gather, process, and react to data on disasters or emergencies. This meant in turn that international donors were themselves unable to respond quickly, and this further compounded the disaster. In addition, a major bottleneck existed in the form of the Public Distribution System (PDS). Modelled on the delivery of rations to a field army, this long-standing food rationing mechanism was the means by which government controlled who got what and how much. This was a cornerstone state policy and practice, not to mention an arbiter of life or death for the general population, and the government could not countenance people going outside it. Food was to come to the people, and due to rigid internal controls on human movement, the people could not go to the food. Thus when nothing came to them, people died in huge numbers where they lived – especially in the major industrial cities of the northeast such as Hamhung and Chongjin (Demick 2009). All the while, in fact, there was a considerable amount of food in the country, and the expansion of commercial imports, which as recently as 1993 had exceeded one million tonnes, was also an option. However, domestic stocks were chiefly in the form of stockpiles reserved in case of military action, or else earmarked for the Pyongyang-based elite, and hence were sacrosanct, while only a modest increase in the level of foreign purchases took place during 1994–95. As the famine took hold, and as foreign humanitarian workers were allowed into the country, many were surprised, if not confounded, by the behaviour of the DPRK authorities. They encountered a pattern of obstructive behaviour, involving rigorous efforts to isolate aid workers from the populace, denial of access to many of the most-affected areas, and the diversion of food aid away from the most needy, all of which spoke of reactions governed by self-interest and heightened threat perception, but certainly not humanitarian impulse (Haggard & Noland 2005). Essentially, amid the understandable confusion, what they were encountering was an emerging policy comprising three major elements. First, Party-Army demands would consistently be given priority over the most at-risk groups who were the primary targets of the food aid. Second, the DPRK would not attempt any meaningful reform of now-dysfunctional Kimist agricultural policies. To do so might, of course, invite questioning of the content the widely circulated ‘infallible’ pronouncements of Kim Il Sung on this topic, with the danger that this might spread to other policy areas. This option therefore remained anathema – a typical example of the way in which the Eternal President of the Republic continued to rule the country from his mausoleum. However this was not an entirely illogical stance, because the option of both more or less meeting food requirements from international donors and maintaining ideological sanctity – that is, conditions of minimum disturbance to the existing system – was available, and this constituted the third element in the DPRK’s food strategy: international food aid would be allowed to become a fixture in the DPRK economy, though of course it would be tightly controlled to prevent the concession of any leverage. Once the food aid began to flow, commercial food imports were minimised as the government, long schooled in external predatory behaviour, essentially identified the economic dividend in using international aid to subsidise other priorities. Food aid sources also fluctuated with a pronounced linkage to the political calculations of both donor and recipient. In general, the DPRK benefited from this process, and as levels of food aid from initial large-scale donors such the US and the EU levelled off, 252

North Korea under Kim Jong Il

and even fell post-2000, this slack was taken up by China and, during 2001–2008, the ROK. With their non-intrusive, undemanding ways, these two were in fact more desirable partners, and had the effect of increasing DPRK leverage against the monitoring requirements of the World Food Program and others (Haggard & Noland 2007:7). What, then, is the present outcome of all this? The DPRK’s actions, strategies and their outcomes should leave no one in any doubt as to its determination and effectiveness, nor should it surprise that in applying triage measures, Kim chose to sacrifice the lives of so many people in order to defend the pursuit of broader objectives, for this is consistent with the core values of the regime. Meaningful agricultural reform has not occurred, and food production levels still approximate the levels of the early 1990s. Famine conditions have not yet recurred, though further significant deaths occurred in 2008 after a bad harvest in 2007, and vulnerability levels remain high. However, with some twenty years of experience in food aid politics now behind it, the DPRK has good reason to believe that it will be able to get by without significant compromise to its system. Thus, while Kim Jong Il did not direct a timely response to the famine, nor did he preside over any real amelioration of the food supply situation, these were not objectives in themselves. In the desperate calculus of the time, and within the constraints of the Kimist system, he achieved the more important objective of containing the threat potential of this situation.

Market economics If there is one area where the DPRK of today looks and feels different from the DPRK of 1994, it is in the growth of an officially-tolerated private consumer market sector. Governmentadministered marketplaces now operate in many localities, and a broad range of legal, semilegal and illegal economic activity proceeds, frequently involving official resources, and accompanied by escalating levels of bribery and corruption. This is mostly a Pyongyang phenomenon, of course, and from the changing, neon-sign-dotted skyline of the capital come rich anecdotes of the scale and variety of small (and some not-so-small) businesses, the ubiquity of mobile phones, growing volumes of vehicular traffic and the like. Such anecdotes will have to speak for themselves amid the on-going statistical blackout, but while they testify to the scale of Chinese involvement in the DPRK consumer economy, more importantly they reflect nearly twenty years of private enterprise activity. This phenomenon has its origins in the Arduous March famine, where the clear message of the leadership to both state-owned enterprises and ordinary citizens became ‘Fend for yourselves – we’ll be back’. In this process it permitted the previously impermissible – namely, a role for autonomous economic activity by state-owned enterprises, and a role for citizens in informal, grey and black market activities. This development marked the beginning of a significant shift in the structure of some sectors in the DPRK economy, beginning at the tactical level, but gradually expanding as the inability of the government to organize any alternative inputs became clear. In fact, the cart began to lead the horse as the authorities discovered they could extract new dividends from these new forms of economic activity, for they greatly expanded the opportunities for rent-seeking, such as the extracting of bribes and pay-offs in connection with a wide range of technically illegal activities, not to mention outright confiscatory behaviour. After deaths peaked and began to subside in 1997, the leadership became convinced that the worst of the famine was over and the process of reasserting control began, first through propaganda campaigns and then through policy measures. The government had been forced to live with a situation in which most of the population had slipped outside the PDS net, with defector surveys 253

Adrian Buzo

suggesting many people earned upwards of 80% of their income from private sources during the period 1998–2003 (Lankov 2009: 53), and this posed a potential threat to their authority. The genie was out of the bottle, and henceforth, success in meeting this ideological and political challenge would be measured in terms of how far the regime could go in restoring the status quo ante. As with the handling of negotiations with the US and the ROK during this period, the DPRK authorities met this initial challenge with tactical flexibility, but with no hint of strategic uncertainty. The first major step toward management and control of market activities was taken with the self-described 7.1 Measures for the Improvement of Economic Management announced on 1 July 2002. Since a total reversion to the system that existed before the famine, however ideologically attractive, appeared to be beyond the government’s means at this point, after seven years of monitoring the practices that had sprung up, the government now sought to define what it could live with for the moment. In the first place, it could definitely live with the greater autonomy now exercised by state-owned enterprises, for those which had survived had demonstrated some flair in raising foreign currency through a variety of means, some of them legal, and their remittances were useful. Secondly, it could extend some measure of acceptance and recognition to private markets as this enabled greater control. These markets now became more substantial, regulated and permanent (Lankov & Kim 2008; Everard 2011). Thirdly, with the demise of the PDS system, cash transactions for daily necessities had expanded, and since the government still lacked the means of re-introducing this system, it brought official currency and prices – which historically had been set at highly artificial levels – more into line with actual traded values, which meant a steep devaluation of the won, a steep rise in commodity prices, and differentiated increases in wages and rations. This had the collateral advantage of drastically reducing the acquired wealth of market operators, which was denominated in won. Some observations flow from this. First and foremost, the 2002 measures were seven years or so in contemplation and formulation, and so while they proved problematic, they were in no way half-hearted, hasty or ill-conceived. Rather, they should be treated as a carefully considered response to the government’s underlying agenda of restoring as far as possible its traditional control of the economy. Secondly, while the label ‘reform measures’ has been widely and frequently attached to these measures by outside observers and analysts, the DPRK government itself did not use this label (Lankov 2009). As an aside, we should observe that the DPRK detests the word ‘reform’ because it carries the implication that its canonic, revelatory system has shortcomings and is in need of some kind of overhaul.7 Thus it is not surprising that the measures were directed toward curbing and channelling what was still seen as – almost quite literally – a necessary evil. Thirdly, changes of any significance cannot simply come from pronouncements, but need to be backed up by, and mirrored in, follow-up measures such as on-going policy oversight and fine-tuning, as well as changes to the themes and the tone of public commentary, to institutions and to personnel. None of these was in evidence here, nor have defector interviews revealed much awareness of the 7.1 measures – where indeed people had actually heard of them (Lankov 2009: 57). And so again we are faced with the age-old paradox of observers expecting change to come from within the parameters that had so resolutely kept these changes at bay at tremendous material cost in the past. The economic results of these measures were as broad as intended. The state-owned enterprises derived little or no benefit since they merely continued to do what they had already been doing for a considerable period of time, the measures did not extend to intra-enterprise transactions, and the government maintained tight control over the commanding heights of the economy. The same applied to the private markets, where on the one hand, traders continued 254

North Korea under Kim Jong Il

to operate and probably benefitted from the more substantial, settled markets they began to inhabit, but where the confiscatory monetization measures deeply affected many. Overnight, market traders saw the value of their won holdings tumble, and with their private capital vastly diminished they were once more rendered more dependent on the state. Moreover, these moves unleashed a strong, sustained surge of inflation, the only real defence against which was access to foreign currency. The message for the marketeers on both scores was that if they hoped to stay in business then they needed partnerships with those who had access to foreign currency, a privilege mainly confined to the elite. In this way, the elite began to seize control of the newly marketised areas of the economy from the new entrants. The state was back, and it continued to assert increasing control over the economic lives of its citizens in the years that followed. This was not always a one-way procession, and some decisions showed a tactical preparedness to accept and abet private economic activity, but the essence lay in pull-back. The China-North Korea border became more tightly patrolled, in 2004 the use of mobile phones was drastically restricted, campaigns against ‘anti-socialist activities’ were again emphasised, and in late 2005 this process led to the reinstatement of a country-wide ban on the private sale of grains and the partial reinstitution of a PDS. These, plus an ensuing raft of regulations limiting private market vendor activities, were only partially effective because of the extent to which the markets had grown, but they left no doubt as to what the leadership regarded as a desirable economic direction. Any doubt on this score was removed with the announcement on 30 November 2009 of a further series of market-controlling measures in the form of the overnight replacement of the currency by a newly denominated won, accompanied by a number of wages and price adjustments. By this stage, Kim Jong Il had been debilitated to an unknown degree by a stroke in August 2008, but there is no particular reason to blame this for a singularly maladroit policy measure which caused widespread confusion and was speedily countermanded, because in any case, the root cause of what even the Kimists conceded was bad policy in this instance was clear: the government was unsure how far was too far to go in reasserting its prerogatives. In terms of the regime’s long-established policies and goals, Kim Jong Il cannot be counted as successful in this area, though given the dilemmas involved, it is hard to say what success would have looked like. The government has continued to apply a raft of controlling measures to market activities, but appears to have tacitly acknowledged that since it cannot itself generate the inputs needed to replace those generated by private economic activity, it will have to continue to tolerate them. Haggard and Noland see the 2009 measures as part of a longer-term trend towards the criminalization of market activity and the stripping it of protection from predatory officialdom (Haggard & Noland 2010c), but such discouragement is probably not enough to maintain Kimist economic control in the longer term. The major problem which continues to this day is that, as is so often the case in such circumstances, the ‘wrong sort of people’ are conducting market activities, and they are living substantially outside the parameters of government control, whether in the form of workplace or neighbourhood mobilisation, or else through enforcement of the social classification (sŏngbun) system. In Lankov and Kim’s terse description, ‘They present a vital and attractive alternative to the officially promoted life strategy which, as many Koreans came to understand, leads nowhere’ (Lankov & Kim 2008: 71). And here again, since ideologically the government cannot truly debate, or perhaps even properly comprehend, this phenomenon except in terms of the threat it poses, it has remained tooled only for suppression, and apart from allowing more ‘suitable’ people – that is, people with the appropriate social and political status – to gain measures of control over the market, seems otherwise uncertain in its thinking on co-optive strategies. 255

Adrian Buzo

Discussion In theory, at least, in 1994 Kim Jong Il had three broad policy options in front of him: abandon the proudly self-avowed monolithic system he himself had devoted his life to building up, significantly modify this system or else defend it. He may also have opted for a course intermediate of these three. But even if we somehow reprogram him as a closet pragmatist, there were powerful arguments against opting for either of the first two, or any intermediate position between them, for if somehow he were attracted to tinkering with the loosening of Party hegemony, then still-recent events in the former Soviet Bloc, Romania and Albania, were powerful disincentives: there was no future for him or for the Party if he chose that path. Historical timing was crucial here, for without delving too far into counterfactuals, the DPRK would clearly have faced a much less threatening path to modifying its system had it decided to do so in, say, the early 1980s, when the economic tide was clearly turning and differentials with its neighbours were more favourable. But now those differentials had blown out to the extent that this option was far more daunting. Thus we find that Kim chose the option that in any case his whole life’s experience would have pressed him to choose: he opted to seek survival by defending by any means necessary the essentials of the Kim Il Sung system. Despite its obvious weaknesses, this system still had in place an effective police state apparatus which had always been equal to the task of isolating and controlling the population, while it also had extensive military assets, developed with offensive intent, but also of course serviceable in the survivalist cause. Moreover, the option of playing for time, while not always distinguishable from attempting to delay the inevitable, should not automatically be dismissed as a poor option – it is a time-honoured practice in statecraft. Thus it is not surprising that we seem unable to identify distinctive Kim Jong Il strategies and policies which depart from those pursued while Kim Il Sung was alive. Like his father, he energetically pursued and sustained the country’s drive to secure a nuclear weapons arsenal and payload delivery system, and essentially organised the state economy around the pursuit of this objective. Likewise, the tenor and tempo of inter-Korean talks in 2000 and 2007 conformed to the pattern followed by his father in 1972–73, 1984–86 and 1990–93 of tactical engagement, quick assessment of prospects for even trivial gains at the South’s expense, the signing of wideranging agreements, and then a staged retreat amid accusations of bad faith to avoid unwanted implementation measures. Moreover, Kim Jong Il’s military-first reorganization of government simply carried forward a trend that had already become marked in the last years of his father’s rule (Buzo 1999: 211ff). The single area of arguable discontinuity was in permitting space for private market activities – arguable because we do not know what Kim Il Sung might have done if he had faced a comparable disastrous famine, though we are safe in surmising from his record that the elder Kim would have demonstrated a similar brand of threat analysis and ruthless response. The Kim Jong Il era is also noteworthy for what did not occur. No meaningful systemic reform measures were put in place, but nor did the much-predicted economic collapse of the DPRK occur. And despite the enormous pressures that the system was operating under, no significant purges took place, nor did other signs of disarray appear in leadership circles, in itself a somewhat remarkable reflection on the resilience of the Kimist system, but also one toward which we must assume Kim Jong Il made a significant contribution. One cannot just walk in and assume power in Pyongyang. The rules of the game are complicated and obscure, institutional rules and procedures are seriously degraded to facilitate leadership intervention, and this leadership is in turn exercised in a ruthless, personalised fashion in the setting of lip-service to an exacting, anachronistic ideology. It is not a game for dilettantes. Amid all this, beyond 256

North Korea under Kim Jong Il

the odd public execution, not only do we have little credible evidence of major purges or internal disputes, but in government too, cabinet ministers, essentially bureaucrats whose task it was to find ways and means of implementing the instructions of the leadership, came and went, occasionally suffering demotion, dismissal or worse, and the rubber-stamp Supreme People’s Assembly continued to meet. New institutions, such as the National Defence Committee, nominally under the SPA but in fact the supreme decision-making body, flourished, while other institutions with their roots in the regime’s receding Marxist-Leninist past, such as the Workers’ Party of Korea, atrophied. Allowing for ideological distortions, and with the partial exception of the November 2009 measures, the overall impression remains of steady, orderly strategic assertion and, where necessary, tactical retreat in policy. By this we are also saying that statedirected violence, principally through the extensive gulag system, proceeded in an organised, controlled and effective manner. Significant pockets of dysfunctionality and incoherence obviously exist throughout the DPRK government and bureaucracy, but observations over time suggest that a lot of what the leadership believes it has to do well it tends to do well, while chaos, inefficiency and counter-productivity often seem to indicate lower priorities. Similarly, Kim’s handling of his cult of personality is rarely analysed, but it also suggests careful calculation. Cult of personality serves a number of needs and ends. To Stalin, its originator, it was foremost an effective political weapon for subverting the Party and consolidating his authority, and the personal gratification he may have derived from it appears to have been secondary. As an avid Stalinist, Kim Il Sung also adopted this weapon, but the element of ego gratification seemed far more pronounced, as anyone who got to witness firsthand the manner in which Kim received such adulation probably observed. But with Kim Jong Il one appears to return to the purer Stalinist cult-as-political-asset model. He accepted the adulation – indeed, he could do no less as son of the Great Leader, but he did not appear to relish it, and remained a remote leader. More important, he astutely identified wherein his chief asset lay, and so the cult remained essentially the cult of Kim Il Sung, which continued to be energetically propagated on many fronts, ranging from statuary (a form of tribute his son deliberately and pointedly avoided) and portraiture to apotheosis as Eternal President, and the inception of the new Juche Calendar in 1997, which designated the year of the older Kim’s birth (1912) as Juche 1. Assessing how much of Kim Jong Il’s achievement is likely to endure also sheds light on his effectiveness. Comparing the DPRK of 1994 with the DPRK of today, the external perception is of the same isolated, pariah status, the same reprehensible commitment to nuclear weapons, the same appalling human rights record, and, with the partial exception of China, the same set of shadowy economic relations with shadowy states on the fringes of the international system, based primarily on the arms trade. Within North Korea, we see a malnourished, terrorized general population which, outside the privileged enclave of Pyongyang and its environs, mainly conducts a daily struggle for survival. The government applies the same dogmatic, dysfunctional ideology, informed by Stalinist methods, if no longer by strict Stalinist practice, and modifies these only in the name of tactical expediency. Most tellingly, there is no end in sight. Some may therefore suggest that in stripping away the false and misleading images of Kim that abound, all we are doing is revealing the real tyranny underneath. How, then, can we call such leadership effective? And yet, from a Kimist perspective, ‘positives’ are present, even if they sometimes look like the mere dividends of persistence. The political, social and economic challenges posed by free market activities continue to be contained, even though the scale and variety of these challenges must make this seem like a daunting task, for it is true to say that since the 1990s, people have increasingly departed from the previous collectivist model, and through economic necessity have 257

Adrian Buzo

had to make individual and family-focused judgements on how to survive and even make a living. For the many who now engage in some form of market activity, this involves a change from passive acceptance of the status quo to proactive planning and execution, aided by the authorities’ retreat from active oversight in many areas of its citizen’s lives, a consequence of its own lack of economic means, and the dependence of mainly lower level officials on bribery and corruption for their livelihood. However, so far these trends have not led to any great flowering of civil society above the level of mainly petty economic activity and the sampling of forbidden fruits of consumerism for those who can afford them. The porous border with China is regularly breeched by contraband such as South Korean videos, and this has of course exacerbated cognitive dissonance as more and more people see the gap between the daily realities they experience and the official version of that reality. On some abstract plane this may well shorten the life of the regime but, for the moment, while people may know far more about their predicament and may be more aware of the true dimensions of their rulers’ mendacity, they are none the wiser about possible ways out of it, and so as yet, we cannot yet detect any signs of a dissident movement; the state control apparatus still clearly remains too strong, too motivated, and too ruthless. Thus one can still only speculate on the role this nascent civil society will play in future political events. International trends are not uniformly negative, especially if one sees them through ideology glasses. China has remained a consistent, if at times reluctant, supporter in some crucial areas, less hindered by moral scruple, responsive to growing economic involvement, seeking to contain the situation, probably hoping for the best but certainly fearful the worst. In the area of food aid, its intervention was crucial in helping the DPRK to withstand international pressure and maintain control over the aid donation process. Moreover, broader trends such as the overall fraying of the international order, the increasing propensity of states such as China, Russia and Iran to challenge elements of that order, the continuing fallout from the Arab Spring, the growth of the Shiite-Sunni divide, and the increase in the number of states suffering from varying degrees of serious dysfunctionality are all trends which are opening up economic opportunities for the DPRK and its chief cash crop – serious weaponry – and this trend may well expand, rather than diminish in coming years. In addition, whether from fatigue, impatience or frustration, a curious tolerance of the DPRK seems to have grown as outside observers become more and more inured to its behaviour. One finds a case being put for DPRK exceptionalism – that is, negotiating with the DPRK, which of course usually means granting concessions, on the grounds (well appreciated by DPRK strategists) that some form of dialogue is better than no dialogue. This is despite DPRK policies and practices that pose a fundamental challenge to key elements of the international order, ranging from the NPT to the Universal Declaration of Human Rights, and it keeps avenues open for a whole range of consequence-free behavior. One facet of this is the tendency of influential people, and even leaders, in adversarial nations, whether for reasons laudable, less than laudable or just plain obscure, to go to considerable lengths in order to secure what they seem to believe to be an important place in history by achieving some sort of breakthrough in Korea. This has been especially true in the ROK in the past, but it has also influenced the thinking of other main actors. Again, the DPRK is well attuned to this phenomenon and has adroitly harvested the significant tactical and material advantages this tendency has brought. How effective, then, was Kim Jong Il in pursuing the goals of the DPRK leadership and elite? As we consider the crises of the last twenty years, space limitations prevent us from discussing the DPRK in the full range of its complexities, and in the full range of the evidentiary and methodological challenges it presents, but it is probably obvious where all this is headed: unless 258

North Korea under Kim Jong Il

we dismiss much of the accumulated historical record, unless we attach minimal importance to the role of leadership in the Kimist system, and unless we insert our own a priori judgements based on what we believe the leader should have done, could have done, or might have done, we find that Kim Jong Il was a convinced, effective Kimist who achieved considerable success in pursuing a difficult and demanding set of goals. The fact these goals are almost entirely despised by the international community, just as he himself appears to be despised by many North Koreans, should not distract us from absorbing the implications of this achievement. It is now twenty years since he first assumed full power, and the same policies are essentially still in place with little sign of strategic confusion or doubt. They have therefore stood a reasonable test of time, even though some might question how much more success of this type the DPRK can stand. While Kim Jong-un was less prepared for leadership, and may possibly be less able than Kim Jong Il, his father left an important legacy by enforcing Kimist parameters in a disciplined manner over an extended period of time. Kim Jong Il may not conform to many people’s concept of a Dear Leader, but he certainly performed as a significant consolidator.

Notes 1

2

3 4 5

6

7

Kim also conducted significant negotiations, including two leadership summits, with the ROK in response to Seoul’s Sunshine Policy, and effected major changes to the structure of government, institutionalising the central role of the military and further marginalising the Workers’ Party of Korea. They are important issues, but space does not permit their discussion here. Kimism must be defined not from theory, but from the body of practice we see in the DPRK. It draws on the essentials of Stalinism, such as a mass (as opposed to an elite) communist party; an intensive coercion and control apparatus; a high degree of political mobilisation; cult of personality; reliance on canonical pronouncements of a genius-leader; adherence to the doctrine of the intensification of class struggle; economic autarky; the collectivisation and industrialization of agriculture; rapid heavy industrialisation through mass economic mobilisation; Stakhanovite work practices (‘speed battles’ in a DPRK context); and a heavy reliance on ideological motivation. To this mix Kim Il Sung brought little in the way of innovation, but emphasised elements drawn more directly from his own experience, most notably pervasive militarism; a rigid, hereditary class system based on assessments of political reliability (songbun); a pronounced hostile, predatory attitude toward external transactions; strong intervention in the traditionally self-regulatory areas of Korean family and clan affairs – perhaps the most salient of the many reasons why applying the term ‘Confucianist’ to this system is grossly misleading; indifference to the norms of civil society; and moral puritanism. For more on this see Buzo (1999). Wendy Sherman, quoted in Rogin (2011). http://thecable.foreignpolicy.com/posts/2011/12/19/ wendy_sherman_on_kim_jong_il_smart_witty_and_humorous, accessed 25 July 2014. ‘N. Korea to extend missile test moratorium, EU says’, http://usatoday30.usatoday.com/news/ world/2001–05–02-nkorea-eu.htm, accessed 25 July 2014. The complexities of the DPRK economy are a topic in themselves. A useful perspective here is Habib (2011), who argues that the disasters of the 1990s caused ‘the splintering of the old command system into parallel economies – the official, military, illicit, court and entrepreneurial economies – separated from the central planning matrix.’ This describes the curious amalgam of DPRK-style pragmatism and expediency, and helps us to understand the phenomenon of DPRK economic resilience. The inauguration of Kim Dae Jung as President of the Republic of Korea in February 1998 inaugurated the ten-year period of Seoul’s Sunshine Policy toward the North. This policy placed engagement at the centre of ROK policymaking, featuring disavowal of any moves to absorb the North and the active promotion of economic cooperation and exchange, while still emphasising that the ROK would not tolerate armed provocation. Hence Moon Chung In’s comment “You have to be careful about not using the word ‘reform’; they are sensitive about that and prefer ‘modernize.’” Quoted in Norimitsu (2008). http://www.nytimes. com/2008/06/28/world/asia/28nuke.html?pagewanted=print, accessed 27 July 2014.

259

Adrian Buzo

References Ahn, M.S. (2011) ‘What Is the Root Cause of the North Korean Nuclear Program?’, Asian Affairs, 38:4, 175–187. Albright, M. (2003) Madame Secretary: a memoir, London, England: Macmillan. Asher, David L. (2013) Testimony before the House Foreign Affairs Committee, Pressuring North Korea: The Need for a New Strategy, 5 March 2013. Available at http://www.cnas.org/files/documents/ publications/Asher%20Testimony%20HFAC%2003052013_0.pdf; accessed 24 July 2014. Bechtol Jr, B.E. (2013) The last days of Kim Jong Il: the North Korean threat in a changing era, Washington DC: Potomac Books. Buszynski, L. (2013) Negotiating with North Korea: The Six Party Talks and the Nuclear Issue, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge. Buzo, A. (1999) The Guerilla Dynasty: Politics and leadership in the DPRK, Sydney: Allen & Unwin. Cha, V. (2011) ‘The End of History: ‘Neojuche Revivalism’ and Korean Unification’, Orbis, 55:2, 290–297. Cha, V. (2013) The Impossible State: North Korea, Past and Future, New York: Ecco. Demick, B. (2009) Nothing to Envy: Ordinary Lives in North Korea, New York: Spiegel & Grau. Eberstadt, Nicolas (2007) The North Korean Economy: Between Crisis and Catastrophe, New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers. Everard, J. (2011) The Markets of Pyongyang, Korea Economic Institute Academic Paper Series, vol. 6, No. 1. Washington DC: Korea Economic Institute. Gause, K.E., (2012) North Korea – Coercion, control, surveillance and punishment: an examination of the North Korean police state, Washington, DC: Committee for Human Rights in Korea. Habib, B. (2011) ‘North Korea’s parallel economies: Systemic disaggregation following the Soviet collapse’, Communist and Post-Communist Studies, vol. 44, pp. 149–159. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2005), Hunger and Human Rights: The Politics of Famine in North Korea, Washington, DC: Committee on Human Rights in North Korea. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2007) Famine in North Korea: Markets, Aid, and Reform, New York: Columbia University Press. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2009c) Repression and Punishment in North Korea: Survey Evidence of Prison Camp Experiences. East-West Center Working Papers, Politics, Governance, and Security Series no. 20. Honolulu: East-West Center. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2009b), Reform from Below – Behavioral and Institutional Change in North Korea, Washington DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics. Haggard, S, and Noland, M. (2009a), ‘Famine in North Korea Redux?’, Journal of Asian Economics 20:4, 384–95. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2010c) ‘Winter of their Discontent: Pyongyang attacks the Market’, Washington DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2010b) ‘Sanctioning North Korea: The Political Economy of Denuclearization and Proliferation’, Asian Survey, 50:3, 539–568. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2008), ‘North Korea in 2007: Shuffling in from the Cold’, Asian Survey 48:1, 107–115. Haggard, S. and Noland, M. (2010a) ‘North Korea in 2008: Twilight of the God?’, Asian Survey 49:1, 98–106. Hassig, Ralph and Oh, Kongdan (2009) The Hidden People of North Korea: Everyday Life in the Hermit Kingdom, Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield. Hastings, Justin V. (2014): ‘The economic geography of North Korean drug trafficking networks’, Review of International Political Economy, DOI:10.1080/09692290.2014.880934. Joo, H.M. (2010), ‘Visualizing the invisible hands: the shadow economy in North Korea’, Economy and Society 39:1, 110–145, DOI:10.1080/03085140903424618. Kim, S. (ed.) (2001) The North Korean System in the Post-Cold War Era, New York: Palgrave. Lankov, A. (2007) “Staying Alive: Why North Korea Will Not Change,” Foreign Affairs 87:2, 9–16. Lankov, A. (2007) North of the DMZ: Essays on Daily Life in North Korea, Jefferson NC: McFarland & Company. Lankov, A. and Kim, S.H. (2008) “North Korean Market Vendors: The Rise of Grassroots Capitalists in a Post-Stalinist Society,” Pacific Affairs 81:1, 68–69. Lankov, A. (2009) “Pyongyang Strikes Back: North Korean Policies of 2002–08 and Attempts to Reverse De-Stalinization from Below,” Asia Policy 8:47–71. 260

North Korea under Kim Jong Il

Lankov, A. (2013) The Real North Korea: Life and Politics in the Failed Stalinist Utopia, New York: Oxford University Press. Martin, B.K. (2006) Under the loving care of the fatherly leader, New York: Thomas Dunne Books. Moon C.I. (2012) The Sunshine Policy: in defense of engagement as a path to peace in Korea, Seoul: Yonsei University Press. Park, K.A. & Snyder, S. (eds.) (2012) North Korea in transition: politics, economy and society, Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. Park, Y.S. (2009) The political economy of economic reform in North Korea, Australian Journal of International Affairs, 63:4, 529–549, DOI: 10.1080/10357710903312587. Rogin, J. (2011) ‘Wendy Sherman on Kim Jong Il; Smart, witty, and humorous’, The Cable. Available from: http://thecable.foreignpolicy.com/posts/2011/12/19/wendy_sherman_on_kim_jong_il_smart_ witty_and_humorous. Accessed 25 July 2014. Scobell, A. (2006) Kim Jong Il and North Korea: the Leader and the System, Carlisle PA: Strategic Studies Institute. Scobell, A. (2008) Projecting Pyongyang: the future of North Korea’s Kim Jong Il regime, Carlisle PA: Strategic Studies Institute. Suh, Jae Jean (2008) Economic Hardship and regime sustainability in North Korea, Seoul: Korea Institute for National Unification. USA Today, ‘N. Korea to extend missile test moratorium, EU says’. Available from: http://usatoday30. usatoday.com/news/world/2001–05–02-nkorea-eu.htm. Accessed 25 July 2014.

261

19 Marriage, family, and sexuality in North Korea Suzy Kim

On a visit to the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea (hereafter, North Korea) in 1977, two overseas visitors were told that sex before marriage ‘does not exist in our country’ (Halliday 1985: 50). This was in a meeting with the representatives of the Korean Democratic Women’s Union – the official women’s organization in North Korea – about the status of women and relations between the sexes. Other responses seemed just as implausible. The visitors were told that ‘[a]ll women in our country want children’ (Halliday 1985: 50) and ‘[t]here is nobody in the family who refuses to do something that should be done’ (Halliday 1985: 53). When asked about the availability of contraceptives and abortion, the representatives denied the existence of policies on birth control, rejecting that there could be instances of rape that might require an abortion. Such answers are difficult to take at face value, but they are significant, nonetheless, for what they reveal about North Korea’s official conceptualization of sexuality. Family is regarded as the building block of a deeply collective society, and marriage and sexuality are understood strictly within the confines of the heterosexual nuclear family. How can we make sense of such conservative policies and attitudes, especially in a country claiming to be one of the last bastions of existing socialism, a philosophy which traditionally attacked the family as an oppressive institution? The answer goes back to the years immediately after Korea’s liberation from colonial rule (1910–1945), when North Korea instituted the major reforms that were to shape its modern history. Japan was defeated at the end of the Pacific War on 15 August 1945, terminating its 35year rule over Korea. Despite the jubilance of liberation, Korea was compelled to take two divergent paths. The United States proposed (and the Soviet Union conceded) to divide the Korean peninsula at the 38th parallel into two separate occupation zones – the United States in the south and the Soviet Union in the north – to disarm the Japanese troops while preparing a provisional government in Korea. However, negotiations between Moscow and Washington toward a unified Korean government failed as the Cold War loomed. The American occupiers saw most Korean political movements as too radical and suppressed them in the south, while unprecedented social reforms were carried out swiftly in the north, aided by the Soviets (Cumings 1981). The two separate states were not officially founded until 1948, but both sides competed for legitimacy from the beginning, claiming to represent the entire country. Toward that end, a thorough land reform was instituted in the north in March 1946, confiscating the land from 262

Marriage, family, and sexuality

landlords without compensation and distributing it to the peasants who actually tilled the fields. Major industries, which in many cases had been owned by the Japanese, were nationalized in August 1946. Amidst these reforms, North Korea passed the Law of Equal Rights for Men and Women (Namnyŏ p’yŏngdŭnggwŏn pŏmnyŏng; hereafter, the Gender Equality Law) on 30 July 1946. It was a sweeping measure for its time, raising the ire of conservative patriarchs in both the North and the South, and became the basis for gender relations and the role of sexuality in post-liberation North Korea.

Marriage Throughout the Chosŏn Dynasty (1392–1910), Confucian ideology had defined marriage as a relationship forged between two families. In other words, a commitment of marriage signified an alliance between two families, whether as a strategy to expand influence in the region or to smooth relations between rival factions. Individuals were defined by their position in the family as fathers, sons, mothers, and daughters within the wider network of extended kinship relations. Individual preferences or romance had little relevance in this patriarchal system whether for women or men. The impact on women, however, was more severe because of patrilocal practices, which required a woman to move into her husband’s household after marriage in order to serve his extended family. As a new member of the household, she was placed at the bottom of the family hierarchy to spend ‘three years as if blind, three years as if deaf, and three years as if dumb’ (Ch’oe et al. 2001: 50). Only with the birth of a son who would continue the patrilineal line could she secure a solid position within the family. While the colonial period had introduced modern concepts of ‘love marriage’ based on freedom of choice in marriage and divorce, unwritten customary rules often trumped what was already a selective application of the civil code imposed by Japan (Yang 1998: 41). It was not until the systematic introduction and enforcement of new legislation after liberation in North Korea that there was a large-scale transformation in marriage practices. The Gender Equality Law of 1946 declared equal rights between men and women, including the freedom of marriage and divorce (Kim Y.-D. 1947). The full text of the law reads: Article 1: Women have equal rights to men economically, culturally, socially, and politically in all areas of life of the nation. Article 2: Women have the same rights as men to vote and be elected in the regional as well as the highest national organs. Article 3: Women have the same rights as men to worker rights, equal wages, social insurance, and education. Article 4: Women, like men, have the right to free marriage. Unfree and forced marriage without the consent of those marrying is prohibited. Article 5: When it becomes difficult to continue the married relationship, women have the same rights as men to free divorce. The right to litigation to demand child support payments from the ex-husband is acknowledged, and such cases shall be processed at the People’s Court. Article 6: The legal marriageable age shall begin at seventeen for women and eighteen for men. Article 7: Polygamy is a feudal practice from the Middle Ages and sales of women as wives or concubines are hereby prohibited as evil practices that violate women’s rights. Licensed prostitution, private prostitution, and the kisaeng [female entertainer] system— kisaeng licenses and schools—are prohibited. 263

Suzy Kim

Article 8: Women have the same rights as men to inherit property and land, and women have the right to be given their share of property and land in case of divorce. Article 9: All Japanese imperial laws and regulations pertaining to Korean women’s rights are null and void as of the promulgation of this law. This law takes effect as of the day of promulgation. Almost half of the entire legislation dealt with marriage and divorce in articles 4 to 8. It was the first indication that the family would continue to play a central role in North Korean society. More telling than the Gender Equality Law were the Regulations on the Implementation of the Gender Equality Law issued six weeks later, on 14 September 1946, stipulating that all marriages and divorces be registered with local authorities. Despite the principle of free marriage and divorce embodied in the Gender Equality Law, marriages had to be registered, and nonregistered marriages, including common law marriages, were not recognized. This was in stark contrast to other socialist revolutions in Russia and China, which initially liberalized marriage by doing away with the distinction between registered and non-registered marriages, while making divorce as simple as a unilateral declaration by the one seeking divorce without the consent of the spouse. By contrast, in North Korea, articles 10 to 22 of the Regulations contained detailed procedures for divorce (Pak 1989: 422). In cases of consent by both parties, divorce papers could be filed with the local people’s committee, but if either party disagreed the couple had to file for legal divorce proceedings with the appropriate People’s Court. Divorce would only be granted if the court concluded that continued married life was impossible due to adultery, health or political reasons. In addition, there was a hefty fine for those filing for divorce more than twice, acting as a disincentive to repeat divorces, although this could be waived at the court’s discretion. By March 1956, divorce required legal proceedings even in cases of mutual consent (Yun 1991: 75). Due to such legislative obstacles, as well as societal pressure, divorce had been relatively rare. Recent anecdotal evidence, however, indicates that divorce regulations have been liberalized since the late 1980s, allowing couples to divorce without court proceedings (Pak 2003: 305). As a result, the rate of divorce has reportedly been on the rise since the late 1990s. In 2002, the average number of divorces per year stood at 2,000, still a minuscule number for a population of 24 million (CEDAW 2002: 35). North Korea has held the family to be the basic unit of society and people were mobilized specifically around the idea of the nation as an extension of the family. Instead of regarding the family as something to be overthrown, certain ‘feudal’ marriage practices were targeted as ‘backward’ and in need of reform. On 24 January 1947, the Law to Eradicate Remnants of Feudal Practices was announced, consisting of four articles which all dealt with so-called ‘feudal’ marriage practices (Pak 1989: 425). Article 1 outlawed practices of dowry exchange, stipulating up to a year of forced labour or a substantial fine for exchanging money, animals, labour, or other valuables. Article 2 guaranteed freedom in marriage by providing up to two years in prison for those who forced a woman into marriage or into maintaining a marriage, as well as anyone who deceived a woman into marriage. Article 3 banned child marriage by imposing forced labour on anyone who married a person not yet of legal marriageable age: 17 for women and 18 for men. Finally, Article 4 prohibited polygamy by stipulating a fine or forced labour for up to a year for anyone who practiced polygamy. As a result, these practices were quickly eradicated within the first years of North Korea’s founding, and marriage customs were drastically simplified. While matchmaking through relatives, friends, and co-workers continued to be popular among the older generation with the added step of verifying individual consent, the younger generation has increasingly veered toward romantic relationships, finding their marriage partners on their 264

Marriage, family, and sexuality

own by dating since at least the 1980s (Pak 2003: 293). Recent reports estimate that about 70 per cent of marriages are ‘love’ marriages as opposed to arranged marriages (Jung 2006: 754). Instead of dowry exchange, the groom is responsible for providing housing while the bride prepares household items. Since housing is generally provided through the workplace under the socialist system, the bride’s family may have a greater financial burden in this regard (Pak 2003: 297). Traditional practices of elaborate wedding rituals involving gift exchange and multiple days of festivities have been replaced by simplified ceremonies. Twenty to fifty guests may gather at one of the families’ homes or a public hall to participate in a simple ceremony. The groom wears a suit or military uniform and the bride dresses in the traditional chosŏnot (or hanbok in South Korean terminology) – a long skirt and a high-waisted top (M.W. Lee 1976: 76; Halliday 1985: 54). With the simplified ceremony, weddings are no longer occasions to show off family wealth, a moot point in a supposedly classless society. While the legal minimum age of marriage was set at 18 for males and 17 for females, official policy has encouraged people to marry after they have finished their studies and military service, fulfilling their responsibilities to society. This was codified into law in article 9 of the Family Law promulgated in 1990 (Ch’oe 2010: 227). As a result, the majority of men reportedly marry in their late twenties to early thirties while women marry in their mid- to late twenties (Pak 2003: 301). The difference in the minimum marriage age has been noted by the UN Committee on the Elimination of Discrimination against Women (CEDAW) as a possible breach of gender equality. North Korea – a state party to the Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination against Women (CEDAW) since 2001 – does not, however, consider the age difference to be a form of discrimination, citing the trend of late marriages, women’s earlier ‘physiological maturity’, and most women ‘choosing’ to marry older men (CEDAW 2005a: 3; 2005b: 4). During the examination of its first report to the Committee in 2005, North Korea was reportedly reviewing the possibility of amending its laws to bring it in line with the Committee’s recommendations to equalize the marriage age. North Korea has not, however, engaged with the Committee since then. Although North Korea’s social revolution was meant to establish a classless society, family background continues to be one of the most important factors in selecting a spouse, as there is one class that is discriminated against: the descendants of former landlords, pro-Japanese collaborators during colonial rule, pro-American collaborators during the Korean War (1950–1953), and people with relatives who have fled to South Korea (M.W. Lee 1976: 73). Marriage with anyone associated with this ‘impure’ class is avoided, and most people marry those from similar family backgrounds (Pak 2003: 326). More recently, there are indications that economic capability has overtaken family background as the most important quality in a partner since the devastating famine of the mid-1990s, which killed an estimated one to two million people (Pak 2003: 295). Otherwise, the selection of marriage partners is much like elsewhere, involving a combination of factors including physical attraction, social standing, education, and compatibility – with an added emphasis on public service. Couples seek their parents’ blessing, although this is not required by law, and approval by the local party official is a must if they hope to climb the social ladder. Love and marriage continue to be communal affairs rather than private ones. While hierarchical relations between husband and wife seem to be particularly acute in the relatively conservative countryside, as often reflected in the testimony of refugees and defectors, working women with professional careers (who tend to be under-represented among these populations) seem to have relationships of equality and camaraderie with their spouses. Indeed, an ethnographic study of North Korea in the 1970s went so far as to conclude that the ‘relationship between husband and wife appears to be so greatly changed that it is no longer a relationship of clear cut authority and submission. Love and mutual understanding were now greatly 265

Suzy Kim

emphasized as desirable between husband and wife’ (M.W. Lee 1976: 82). Lee went on to state that ‘cooperation and solidarity between husband and wife are stronger than ever, and marital life based upon genuine “comradeship” is highly valued’ (1976: 83). Under the law, freedom of marriage and divorce were instituted early on in North Korea, but there are social pressures to marry and stay married, especially when there are children in the family. Consequently, there are few options for those who wish to be free from marriage by choosing not to marry at all. Likewise, there are no options for non-heterosexual unions as article 8 of the Family Law stipulates that ‘marriage shall be undertaken between a single male and a single female’ (CEDAW 2002: 34). As I discuss below, the heterosexual family has been the basic unit of North Korean society and those that reject this family are regarded as antisocial and abnormal.

Family In addition to the legislation pertaining to marriage, divorce, and gender equality, the Labour Law, promulgated on 24 June 1946, was also premised on the importance of protecting the integrity of the family. This law includes special stipulations for the protection of children and mothers, prohibiting them from ‘toilsome or harmful labour’, in addition to the basic clauses for an eight-hour workday, paid vacations, and equal pay for equal work. The clauses specific to women provide paid maternity leave for 35 days before and 42 days after delivery, extended to 60 days before and 90 days after delivery in 1986 (Jung 2006: 750); lighter work for expectant mothers beginning in the sixth month of pregnancy; and nursing breaks for thirty minutes twice a day for women with children under a year old (Pak 1989: 416–418). The law also prohibits pregnant and nursing women from working overtime at night. Maternity was carefully protected and indeed fostered since women were expected to work while also embracing motherhood. For instance, the government grants ‘special favours’ to families with twins, triplets, and quadruplets, supplying them with free clothes, blankets, milk goods, and other necessities until the children reach school age (CEDAW 2002: 26). While a number of studies have conflated North Korea’s authoritarian politics with patriarchy, a closer look at family dynamics in contemporary North Korean society challenges any easy equation between familism (that is, family-centrism) and patriarchy, no matter how hierarchical relations are between family members. Patriarchy can be defined as men’s domination over women and the older generations’ domination over the younger generations in a hierarchy of age and gender for the purposes of maintaining family lineage through the male line of descent. North Korea, however, does not entirely fit this model, despite its hierarchical organization of society. Extended family and kinship networks do not play a significant social role; the head of household need not be male; and gender roles are not as rigid since women have come to occupy positions that were traditionally reserved for men, even in the military. In fact, a high proportion of households were headed by women in the aftermath of the Korean War, as many of them were widowed (M.W. Lee 1976: 79). Much of the changes in North Korean family structure and marriage practices can be attributed to the incorporation of socialist principles, which in many instances directly challenged the core principles of patriarchy as shown in the following table. Certainly, reality on the ground is far from the ideal principles embodied by socialism. Multigenerational households still make up 20 per cent of North Korean society (Pak 2003: 62). In the predominant conceptualization of the family, the male head of household is still seen as the ‘master’ of the family, whom wives obey as they perform fixed gender roles – taking on most, if not all, childcare and household chores (Pak 2003: 122). Despite the principle of freedom of 266

Marriage, family, and sexuality

Table 19.1 Comparison of features in patriarchal family and socialist family Patriarchal family

Socialist family

Hierarchy Extended family Familism Marriage as union of two families; thus, no divorce Family as unit of production Male domination over women Father-son relations

Equality Nuclear family Collectivism Individual freedom of marriage and divorce Family as unit of consumption Gender equality Spousal relations

Source: Adapted from Pak, Hyo ˘n-so ˘n (2003)

divorce, it is prohibitively difficult. Moreover, the expectation that the eldest son will take care of his parents in old age reportedly continues to some degree since men generally earn more than women. The practice of performing ancestral rites also seems to have been maintained, although in simpler fashion. Despite the continuities in some aspects of the patriarchal family, the turn toward nuclear families freed women from serving multiple generations in one family as they were encouraged to work outside the home in service of the nation rather than the extended family. Acute labour shortages after the devastation of the Korean War prompted the government to decree greater female participation in the workforce. The unemployed were given only 300 grams of food a day through the public distribution system as opposed to the 700 grams for the fully employed, and large investments went into public childcare facilities to incentivize women to work (Yun 1991: 104–105). The hojŏk (household registry system), which required a male head of household, was eliminated with the introduction of the citizen registration card on 9 August 1946, thereby breaking down patriarchal kinship ties (Yun 1991: 76). South Korea did not abolish the household-head system until 2005. While the roles of mother and wife were still considered important, these roles were not meant to be limited to individual domestic concerns but expanded to take care of society in the spirit of collectivism (S. Kim 2010). Although filial piety was still lauded as a ‘beautiful custom’ to be preserved as part of a distinctly Korean cultural heritage, socialist youths were urged to stop blindly obeying their elders. The generational hierarchies that once existed in traditional patriarchal households, especially manifested in the conflict between the mother-inlaw and daughter-in-law, were replaced by an emphasis on the importance of a harmonious collective life, fostered through pressure exerted by groups such as the Women’s Union. Mothersin-law in multi-generational families were often reported to be helpful with household chores and childcare while their daughters-in-law worked outside the home (M.W. Lee 1976: 83). Furthermore, families tended to have closer relationships with the maternal side than the paternal side of the family (Pak 2003: 259). While relations with the paternal side often involved material and practical support when they were in close proximity, relations with the maternal side of the family involved both material and emotional support, regardless of geographical distance, thus challenging the patriarchal emphasis on father-son relations (Pak 2003: 259). Most importantly, the national collective took precedence over the family, and familism was frowned upon as selfish. The kind of familism that was pervasive in traditional patriarchal families was made obsolete with the elimination of property inheritance, which had formed the economic basis for maintaining large extended families. The strong kinship networks sustained 267

Suzy Kim

by members of the landholding yangban (scholar-official) élite were dispersed early on since such families were tainted as former landlords. Many of them fled to the South shortly after the land reform in 1946 or were relocated to other villages to sever them from their power base. The peasants who took up leadership positions, replacing the former landlords and local élites, lacked the yangban custom of maintaining detailed genealogical records or holding elaborate ancestor-worship rituals. As a result, immediate family relations may be close and simple ancestral rites for parents or grandparents may be performed, but traditional patriarchy involving extended family clans has been superseded in North Korea. Nonetheless, no legislation or political campaign in North Korea ever denounced tradition or Confucianism per se, as in other socialist revolutions where the traditional family was branded as the source of women’s oppression and condemned as counter-revolutionary (as in China’s Cultural Revolution). Rather than the family being held responsible for women’s subjugation, the family came to symbolize the Korean nation. As postcolonial studies have shown in other contexts, women in colonial societies were often seen to embody the nation, with special weight placed on family and gender roles in the construction of a national identity (Chatterjee 1993). North Korea’s Marxist-influenced official discourse targeted ‘feudal and colonial remnants’, and ‘feudal relations’ between men and women, but not tradition. The Gender Equality Law, for example, outlawed concubinage, early marriage, and prostitution as feudal and colonial practices, but nowhere was there any reference to Confucian tradition or the family as a source of social ills. The state maintained and built on the importance of the family as the building block of North Korean communism (Armstrong 2003: 94–98). Article 23 of the first North Korean Constitution of 1948 stipulated that ‘marriage and the family are under the protection of the state’. Almost a quarter of a century later, the revised 1972 Socialist Constitution again reiterated the importance of the family by stating that ‘the state pays great attention to consolidating the family, the cell (sep’o) of society’ (Yun 1991: 81). In lieu of the patriarchal family, the nuclear family became the basic ‘cell’ of North Korean society, and the leader’s family was exalted as the model family. The founding leader of North Korea, Kim Il Sung (1912–1994), and his nuclear family, consisting of Kim Jong Suk (1917–1949), his wife and comrade-in-arms during the anticolonial struggle of the 1930s, and their son Kim Jong Il (1941–2011), are often referred to as the ‘Three Generals of Mount Paektu’ in reference to the highest mountain on the Korean Peninsula bordering China. Long considered a sacred mountain by Koreans as the place of their ancestral origins, North Korea today venerates Mount Paektu as the heroic site of Kim Il Sung’s anticolonial guerrilla struggle and Kim Jong Il’s birthplace. The dynastic succession of the leader from Kim Il Sung to his son, Kim Jong Il, and most recently to the grandson, Kim Jong Un (1983–), presents a markedly patrilineal model of politics. In this regard, practices which jeopardized the family unit, including the open expression of sexuality or divorce, were thus strictly limited as a threat to the nation itself.

Sexuality Given the significance of marriage and family in North Korean society, it is easy to see why sexuality has become so austere – at least in official discourse. Not only are other concerns, such as national security and food insecurity, major preoccupations for a politically-isolated country with an ailing economy, but the normative value placed on the nuclear family as the basic unit of society officially limits the expression of sexuality to the reproduction of future generations within the confines of heterosexual marriage. Reproduction for the purposes of population growth has been particularly important because North Korea’s population has stood at less than half of 268

Marriage, family, and sexuality

South Korea’s since 1945, an imbalance that was further exacerbated by the Korean War, which killed 12 to 15 per cent of North Korea’s population (Halliday 1985: 47). Like other industrialized societies, however, there has been a steady decline in the fertility rate despite policies promoting population growth – the average number of children per woman decreased from 6.5 in 1966 to 2.5 in 1988 (Jung 2006: 754). The official promotion of reproduction notwithstanding, one must therefore assume that there is much that goes on behind closed doors whether in non-reproductive sexual practices or methods of birth control. Officially, family planning, including contraceptives and abortions, are available with a doctor’s prescription through the public health system, but the extent to which they are readily accessible remains unclear. According to one survey, more than 60 per cent of North Korean women used contraceptives, mainly the intrauterine device (CEDAW 2005b: 8). However, by North Korea’s own admission, abortion is restricted, only available in cases of medical complications (‘disease’ or ‘deformity’) or unwed ‘illegal’ pregnancies (CEDAW 2002: 27). There are reportedly no restrictions to women’s access to family planning services to decide on the number and spacing of children, but the language presumes the use of contraceptives within a family for the purposes of family planning (CEDAW 2002: 28). Similarly, a form of sex education is provided in secondary schools, as students are taught human anatomy, but the burden is on girls to attend additional lectures between the third and sixth grades on ‘female physiology’ and ‘common knowledge of female menstruation and nursing of children’ (CEDAW 2005a: 16). Family planning and reproductive health policies therefore target women in order to prevent ‘illegal abortion and premature pregnancy’, limiting sexual practices to the confines of marriage (CEDAW 2005a: 17). Although little is known about North Korean sexual practices, some information can be gleaned from North Korean refugees and defectors with the caveat that they represent a selfselected group of those who chose to leave North Korea, overwhelmingly from the border regions of North Hamgyŏng Province. They are often paid for their interviews, which leads to incentives to embellish their stories. On the surface, the stories gathered in the twenty-first century are surprisingly similar to the statements offered in the 1970s, leading one journalist to conclude, for example, that ‘the country doesn’t have a dating culture. Many marriages are still arranged . . . Couples are not supposed to make any public displays of affection. . . [and] there is no premarital sex’ (Demick 2009: 80). However, the reportage betrays hidden realities between the lines. For example, out of the six main personalities featured in Barbara Demick’s book on North Korea, three of them either have family members who divorced or had divorced themselves. One of the more rebellious sons had lived out of wedlock with an older woman (Demick 2009: 144) and the book itself revolves around the blossoming love affair between a young couple who manage to find time to date in the cover of night with the blackouts that became a regular feature of everyday life during the period of famine and economic collapse referred to as the ‘Arduous March’ (officially 1996–1997, but in reality 1994–1998). The famine and the subsequent disintegration of the family apparently weakened strict sexual norms with increases in extramarital relations, unwed pregnancies, abortions, and divorces (Jung 2006: 756). Moreover, in a rare survey of North Korean refugees about their sex lives, husbands on average were shown to be satisfied with their sex life, while wives generally answered that they had no thoughts on the matter or did not know (Pak 2003: 332). The only woman to express overt dissatisfaction was a woman in her mid-thirties with a college degree in a professional occupation. While most were embarrassed to speak about sex, the fact that an educated, professional woman was the only one to speak up suggests the extent to which much of the data coming from refugee testimony is skewed. Predictably, the vast majority of refugees tend to come from the border regions, having lived their lives in the periphery as low-level workers. 269

Suzy Kim

Their views and experiences are coloured by their lack of access to the relatively more cosmopolitan surroundings of places like Pyongyang, whose residents might have seen love affairs displayed on the silver screen or read about them in translated works such as Gone with the Wind (Demick 2009: 190). While the vast majority of films and literature are didactic in nature, some incorporate popular genres of entertainment such as science fiction and romance, including films such as Pulgasari (Shin 1985) about a creature resembling Godzilla, and Love, Love, My Love (Shin 1984). Based on the popular folktale of a beautiful courtesan of the Chosŏn Dynasty named Ch’unhyang, Love, Love, My Love featured heretofore unprecedented themes of romance and sexuality (H. Lee 2000: 89). Since 1987, the Pyongyang Film Festival has provided its residents with the opportunity to watch foreign films, and the state-run television stations also show films from the former Soviet bloc at least once a week (Schönherr 2011). Without a focused study on North Korean sexual practices and experiences, however, it is difficult to make any conclusive assessments about sexuality in North Korea. What is clear is that sexuality is no more difficult to discipline than other facets of life. Young people are encouraged to marry later in life, while public displays of affection are restrained. There are no acknowledgments of or provisions for homosexual relationships or transgendered identities. There seems to be very little awareness at all of any diversity in sexual orientation or identity, as one North Korean refugee claimed that he did not understand why he felt no desire for his wife for the nine years he was married until, after settling in South Korea, he saw a photograph of two men kissing, which ‘sent thrills throughout [his] body’ and he finally recognized his homosexuality (Chu 2004). Despite the limited forms of sexuality, there is little evidence of social issues that arise in other parts of the world, such as escalating rates of sexually transmitted diseases, teenage pregnancies, unwed mothers, or illegal abortions. No doubt such instances do exist (as intimated by more recent problems of prostitution and trafficking discussed below), but widespread occurrences would be difficult to hide, especially with the increases in the volume of visitors to the country in the form of aid workers and tourists. Rather than the ‘repression’ of sexuality, I have therefore inquired into the origins and mechanisms of the kind of puritan sexuality that has come to dominate North Korean society. A lasting factor has been the history of colonisation. Postcolonial societies in both the North and South have been plagued by the legacies of Japanese imperialism which simultaneously combined discriminatory policies targeting colonized women to serve as sexual slaves (so-called comfort women) for the Japanese Imperial Army while propounding the equality of all imperial subjects through a form of pan-Asianism in the call for the Greater East Asia Co-Prosperity Sphere. The result in North Korea has been an obsession with purity and a homogeneous national identity to expel the traumatic memory of discrimination and sexualized violence. In so far as Japanese domination of Korea – whether in the loss of sovereignty or the systematic rape of ‘comfort women’ – was thought to be the direct result of the lack of a strong state that could protect its independence and its people’s physical integrity, the state is now presented as the protector and guardian of sexuality and national identity. As noted above, the Gender Equality Law voided all Japanese imperial laws and regulations pertaining to Korean women, proceeding to define how marriage, family, and sexuality would be construed in a new Korea. Many communist states have attempted to solve the ‘woman question’ by enabling women to work outside the home and claim independence from male breadwinners. Sex would no longer be a commodity to be sold by destitute women nor would it be a form of servitude by women in wealthy families for the reproduction of heirs to pass on the inheritance. Guaranteed a basic minimum standard of living, women (and men) would now be able to choose their partners according to their true sentiments rather than for survival. North Korea was no different, as women were encouraged to join the workforce. By 1965, approximately 55 per cent of the 270

Marriage, family, and sexuality

workforce was made up of women (Jung 2006: 750). Social services and maternity benefits for women were accordingly expanded. Children were provided eleven years of free mandatory education; there were free childcare centres for infants between thirty days and three years old, and kindergartens for children of ages four to five; and women were provided five months of paid maternity leave (Pak 2003: 151–152). Even among disaffected North Koreans who have chosen to leave the country, free education and medical care have been regarded favourably as the greatest achievements of state socialism in North Korea. Still, the family was maintained as a social unit in which women were the main caretakers. Despite major strides enabling women to be economically independent and politically active, it remained largely women’s duty to take care of children and housework. North Korean women have the double burden of working outside the home while being in charge of domestic chores. Even with the socialization of childcare, the sexual division of labour has been difficult to overturn because gender roles within the family were reproduced in public institutions. Public canteens, laundries, orphanages and childcare centres were run by women who were often referred to as ‘mothers’ (S.-Y. Kim 1947: 55). Moreover, gender segregation in labour sidestepped the principle of equal pay for equal work, since women usually worked in occupations with lower pay: the service sector, light industries, primary school teaching, and nursing. Men dominated the higher-paid occupations in mining and heavy industries, taking the jobs with the highest status as managers, university professors, and doctors (Yun 1991: 203). In the 1970s, 70 per cent of women’s employment was concentrated in the light industries (Jung 2006: 751), and women continue to make up 70 per cent of workers in the light industries, 86 per cent of school teachers, and 100 per cent of nurses (K.A. Park 2011: 163). North Korea claims to have put in place a quota of over 30 per cent for the proportion of women among public officials, but women only make up 10 per cent of judges, 10 per cent of top officials in government ministries, and 20 per cent of representatives to the people’s assemblies at all levels (CEDAW 2005a: 6, 9). Despite the claim to gender equality, North Korean discourse emphasizes different ‘constitution and ability’ for different types of jobs (CEDAW 2005a: 12) with some work that deals with ‘poisonous matters’ or ‘harmful rays’ or excessive heat, cold, humidity, noise, or vibration deemed ‘harmful’ for women (CEDAW 2002: 24). However, in the aftermath of the crises of the 1990s, which dismantled the public distribution of food and most social services, women became the main income earners through private trading activities that ranged from peddling food and household items to providing services such as hair-cutting and needlework (K.A. Park 2011: 165). As already noted, strict sexual norms weakened, but gender roles were also undermined as women earned income through black markets with their relatively greater free time since housewives were not always expected to work outside the home. Unlike other socialist countries, an unusually high percentage of married women have chosen to be housewives. In the mid-1980s, 60 to 70 per cent of married women began quitting their jobs after marriage, although they often continued to work in neighborhood work units without remuneration (Jung 2006: 752). In contrast to other mass organizations such as the Socialist Youth League, open to all youths between the ages of 15 and 26, or the Occupational League for all workers, the Women’s Union – predominantly made up of housewives – was reportedly less strict about holding its members accountable for regularly attending its meetings since the organization was not tied to career advancement (Pak 2003: 280). As a result, housewives were able to take advantage of market activities, and some women began to question the sexual division of labour at home, demanding that their husbands share in domestic chores, while others opted out of marriage altogether (K.A. Park 2011: 171). 271

Suzy Kim

Subsequently, the revised 1998 Constitution deleted the clause that the state shall ‘liberate women from the heavy family chores’, which had been included in the 1972 Constitution (K.A. Park 2011: 167). The state’s withdrawal from its commitment to the protection of women’s rights came at the worst time as sexual trafficking has arguably become the single most pressing problem facing North Korean women in the border regions. As women look for opportunities to provide for their families, they are often kidnapped or lured, and sold as farmhands, restaurant workers, family servants, brides, or sex workers into China (Jung 2006: 757). The women’s illegal status exposes them to sexual violence, rape, and confinement without any recourse (Good Friends 2005: 8). Officially, North Korea disavows instances of trafficking in women or prostitution in the country, claiming that ‘there is no informal sector in the DPRK’ (CEDAW 2005a: 8, 12). However, independent research by humanitarian organizations confirms the existence of prostitution within the country, which spiked drastically after the onset of food shortages beginning in the mid-1990s. Women sold sex as a form of bribe to security personnel or in exchange for food (Good Friends 2005: 7). While the state has more often been viewed as an obstacle to sexual freedom, especially in places like North Korea, state intervention may be the only remedy to address the rising problem of trafficking and sexual violence against women. It is a sobering reminder of the potentially protective role of the state, rather than simply its intrusiveness, in the realm of sexuality.

Note *

I have used the McCune-Reischauer system for the transliteration of Korean names and terms. All translations are my own unless otherwise noted. This chapter is a revised version of a chapter included in the Routledge Handbook of Sexuality Studies in East Asia edited by Vera Mackie and Mark McLelland (2014).

References Armstrong, Charles (2003) The North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. CEDAW – U.N. Committee on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination against Women (2002) Consideration of reports submitted by States parties under article 18 of the Convention, Initial report of State Parties: Democratic People’s Republic of Korea, 11 September (CEDAW/C/PRK/1). CEDAW – U.N. Committee on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination against Women (2005a) Responses to the list of issues and questions for consideration of the initial report: Democratic People’s Republic of Korea, 15 April (CEDAW/PSWG/2005/II/CRP.2/Add.3). CEDAW – U.N. Committee on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination against Women (2005b) Summary record of the 699th meeting held at Headquarters, New York, on Monday, 18 July 2005, at 10 a.m., 8 September (CEDAW/C/SR.699). Chatterjee, Partha (1993) The Nation and Its Fragments: Colonial and Postcolonial Histories, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Ch’oe, Ŭn-pong and Pak Hyŏn-sŏn (2010) ‘Sŏngun sidae silhyŏn kwa sŏngun kajok’ [Realization of Military First era and Military First family] in Sŏngun sidae pukhan yŏsŏng ŭi sam [North Korean women’s lives in the Military First era] (pp. 220–250), Seoul: Ihwayŏjadaehakkyo ch’ulp’anbu. Ch’oe, Yŏng-ho, Peter H. Lee, and Wm. Theodore de Bary (eds.) (2001) Sources of Korean Tradition Volume Two: From the Sixteenth to the Twentieth Centuries, New York: Columbia University Press. Chu, Sŏng-ha (2004) ‘Tongsŏngae komin kkŭt nam on t’alpukcha tongsŏngaeja e soga pint’ŏlt’ŏri sinse’ [North Korean homosexual penniless after conned by another], Dong-A News (October 27) available at http://news.donga.com/Politics/NK/3/all/20041027/8121497/1, accessed January 27, 2013. Cumings, Bruce (1981) The Origins of the Korean War: Liberation and the Emergence of Separate Regimes 1945–1947, Vol. 1, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Demick, Barbara (2009) Nothing to Envy: Ordinary Lives in North Korea, New York: Spiegel & Grau. 272

Marriage, family, and sexuality

Good Friends: Centre for Peace, Human Rights and Refugees (2005) Alternative NGO Report on the Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination Against Women, First Periodic Report of the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea (June) Halliday, Jon (1985) ‘Women in North Korea: An Interview with the Korean Democratic Women’s Union’, Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars 17 (3): 46–56. Jung, Kyungja and Bronwen Dalton (2006) ‘Rhetoric versus Reality for the Women of North Korea: Mothers of the Revolution’, Asian Survey, 46 (5) (September/October): 741–760. Kim, Sŏk-yang (1947) ‘Yugawŏn Pangmun’gi’ [Visit to an orphanage] Chosŏn Yŏsŏng [Korean Women] (October): 55–57. Kim, Suzy (2010) ‘Revolutionary Mothers: Women in the North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950’, Comparative Studies in Society and History, 52 (4) (October): 742–767. Kim, Yun-dong (1947) ‘Pukchosŏn ŭi namnyŏ p’yŏngdŭnggwŏn pŏmnyŏng’ [The Law on the Equality of the Sexes in North Korea] Chosŏn Yŏsŏng [Korean Women] (July): 18–24. Lee, Hyangjin (2000) Contemporary Korean Cinema: Identity, Culture, Politics, Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press. Lee, Mun Woong (1976) ‘Rural North Korea under Communism: A Study of Sociocultural Change’, Rice University Studies 6 (1) (Winter): 1–176. Pak, Hyŏn-sŏn (1989) ‘Panje panbonggŏn minjujuŭi hyŏngmyŏnggi ŭi yŏsŏng chŏngch’aek’ [Policy on women during the anti-imperialist anti-feudal democratic revolution] in Kim Nam-sik (ed.) Haebang chŏnhusa ŭi insik [Understanding pre- and post-liberation history] (pp. 326–370), Seoul: Han’gilsa. Pak, Hyŏn-sŏn (2003) Hyŏndae pukhan sahoe wa kajok [Contemporary North Korean society and family], Seoul: Hanul. Park, Kyung-Ae (2011) ‘Economic crisis, women’s changing economic roles, and their implications for women’s status in North Korea’ The Pacific Review, 24 (2) (May): 159–177. Schönherr, Johannes (2011) ‘Permanent State of War: A Short History of North Korean Cinema’ Film International (March 31) available at http://filmint.nu/?p=1402, accessed November 28, 2012. Shin, Sang-ok (1985) Pulgasari. Pyongyang: Shin Films. Shin, Sang-ok (1984) Sarang sarang nae sarang [Love, Love, My Love]. Pyongyang: Shin Films. Yang, Hyunah (1998) ‘Envisioning Feminist Jurisprudence in Korean Family Law at the Crossroads of Tradition/Modernity’, unpublished doctoral dissertation, New School for Social Research. Yun, Mi-ryang (1991) Pukhan ŭi yŏsŏng chŏngch’aek [North Korea’s Policy on Women], Seoul: Hanul.

273

This page intentionally left blank

Part V

South Korea

This page intentionally left blank

20 Trade union movements in South Korea since 19451 Jooyeon Jeong

In capitalistic nations, the prevailing view regarding the relations between employers and workers is to assume the inevitable presence of conflicts arising naturally, not only from their different interests but from the inequality of power between the two sides. According to the pluralistic perspective, workers’ free and voluntary choices to organize, bargain, and strike legally could be a realistic solution to such problems in capitalistic industrial relations (Gospel and Palmer, 1993; Katz, Kochan, and Colvin, 2008). As a result, workers in advanced capitalistic nations are allowed to freely organize their trade unions, to conduct collective bargaining through democratic unions and to strike in order to urge their employers to meet their bargaining demands. In order to study unions and industrial relations in Asian ‘newly industrialized countries’ (NICs) (Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore) and developing nations (China and Indonesia) in comparison with their counterparts in advanced nations, the pressing and primary question to be addressed by researchers could be whether such a pluralistic prescription is similarly available to workers in those nations. According to the literature on unions in Asian NICs (Bean, 1994; Choi, 1989; Deyo, 1989; Martin, 1989; Poole, 1986), Korean workers could not freely exercise their collective rights through the formation of democratic unions for most of the economic developmental period from the early 1960s to 1986. This retarded pattern of union growth, which contrasts with the pattern in advanced nations during similar periods, is interpreted in the literature as having been constrained by the repressive state-led, political and economic environments at the national level—termed the macro politico-economic analytical framework in this chapter. In the distinct environments, the demands for the collective voices of unions to be heard was treated as detrimental both to the rapid growth of manufacturing firms in developing nations and to the required national political stability. As a result, unions in Korea and advanced nations were treated as ‘oranges and apples’ in terms of their representative capacities as well as their determinants. This chapter is critical of the incorrect presumption of a lack of representative capacity among Korean unions and calls for an analysis of those capacities at the industry and firm levels in Korea2. Above all, this chapter, based on several pieces of concrete evidences on union activities in several Korean industries, shows that Korean unions are not completely useless to workers, even though they are not completely independent from the state and possess only weak to intermediate representative capacities in their relations with employers. Even though Korean 277

Jooyeon Jeong

employers are in an advantageous position with regards to repressing and constraining normal union activities, the Korean democratic political and social system cannot allow its employers to either completely ignore the spontaneous desires of workers or block their attempts at building autonomous and independent unions. Thus, this chapter aims to explore the extent of the representative capacities that Korean unions possess in their relations with employers and the factors that account for incomplete capacities. The representative capacities are aggregately judged by (i) union organizational bases, defined as both the quantitative absolute sizes of unions and their sizes relative to the total workforce, or union density, (ii) union security, defined as the level of support offered by the employers in admitting union efforts to recruit and retain employees as union members, (iii) bargaining capacity, defined as union ability to achieve the right to represent the workers and its agendas, and (iv) dispute leverages, defined as the capability of unions to induce employers to agree to their demands either through the threat or realization of industrial action. In addition, except for a few traditional and manufacturing industries, unions in most Korean industries have maintained enterprise unionism as the prevailing structure (Jeong, 2001, 2007). Here, enterprise unionism is defined as a highly decentralized union and bargaining structure in which the initial union organization, and subsequent decisions related to collective bargaining and disputes, are primarily made by workers at enterprise levels interacting closely with employers who have diverse attitudes and policies toward accepting, or at least tolerating, unions. Given the decentralized structure, both workers and employers have tended to possess considerable discretion over the formation and acceptance of enterprise unions, respectively, which has concomitantly led to extraordinary diversity in representative capability among enterprise unions in different industries, as well as among enterprise unions across different firm sizes within the same industry. Accordingly, this chapter tries to illuminate different types of representative capacities of unions in three industries, as judged by (i), (ii), (iii), and (iv) above. The analysis of those types is beyond the coverage of this chapter; other works of this author (Jeong, 2005, 2007, and 2011) propose an alternative meso- (industry) and micro- (firm) socioeconomic analytical framework to emphasize that the phenomenon of enterprise union growth and decline chiefly depends on the capacity and determination of workers to form and retain unions as juxtaposed to the employers’ economic capacity and tolerance toward the presence and operation of unions, which closely interacts with several social and economic environments at the industry and firm levels. Those environments include the product market environment (the strategic significance of an industry in the national economy, the growth stages of an industry, the status of an industry in the national economy and the types of interventionist policies of the government, and the industrial structure), the industrial relations domain (historical growth paths of militant versus feeble union activities in formative periods of industrial relations at industry and firm levels, prevalent attitudes and strategies of firms toward unions), labor market environments (demographic features of workers in terms of education and skill levels, genders, and ages), and a firm’s managerial domain (corporate ownership and structure, management philosophy, management style, and pertinent labor and union policies). The remainder of this chapter is composed of two sections. The first provides a broad overview of the historical evolution of Korean labor markets and industrial relations during the last seven decades since 1945. The second section examines the representative capacities of unions in close interaction with the structural features of industrial relations in the chemical, city bus, and auto industries.

278

Trade union movements in South Korea

Historical development of industry-level labor markets and industrial relations This section aims to broadly examine the historical evolution of both the number of employees across sectors and industries in the Korean labor market and the extent of union memberships in industrial union federations during the approximately seven decades from 1945 to the early 2010s. Certain industries, which were experiencing growth stages during specific periods, contributed greatly to job creation in the Korean labor market and thus sometimes, but not always, led the national union movement by forming the bulk of the rank-and-files composing national union membership. In contrast, as industries entered into stages of decline, their leading statuses in the labor markets and in industrial relations gradually weakened and they were replaced by other newly growing industries. What, then, were the predominant industries in the Korean labor markets and industrial relations in different periods during the seven decades? Can we find any differences and similarities in a rough comparison between the Korean case and the British counterpart during the two-and-a-half centuries from the mid-18th century to the present day, and how can we analyze them? In Korea, the last seven decades can be divided into five distinct periods during which the predominant industries leading both the Korean labor markets and industrial relations have shifted. In 1963, roughly at the end of the first pre-industrialization period (1945–1961), about twothirds of the Korean workforce (63.2 percent) were employed in the agricultural, fishery, and forestry industries in contrast to 7.9 percent in the manufacturing sector, 9.8 percent in the wholesale, retail, food, and lodging sectors, and 13.9 percent in other social, public and individual service sectors (Table 20.1). Looking at the distribution of the rank-and-files across industries, the transport sector employed the largest proportion (34.5 percent) in comparison with 29.8 percent in the mining and manufacturing sector and 23.2 percent in the public sector in 1962 (Table 20.2). The comparison between the Korean labor markets and unions and their British counterparts during the first pre-industrialization period helps to illuminate three crucial features. First of all, the Korean industrialization pattern can be characterized by (1) the relatively retarded growth of the manufacturing industry, which generated only a small share of total employment in the labor market—7.9 percent in 1963 (Table 20.1)—and (2) the low proportion of rank-and-file workers among all Korean union memberships during the pre-industrialization period—29.8 percent in the mining and manufacturing sectors and 21.4 percent if mining is excluded in 1962 (Table 20.2). This contrasts with the British pattern of early growth in several craft manufacturing industries as national strongholds of unions such as the metals, engineering, shipbuilding, textile, clothing, printing and paper, woodworking and furnishing industries, which altogether employed 53.3 percent of all national union members in 1888 (Clegg, Fox, and Thompson, 1964: 1). Second, the Korean state in the state-led developmental process during the 1950s and 1960s was aimed at encouraging the rapid growth of public corporations in the railway, electricity, post office, ginseng and tobacco industries, and the transport sector, as those industries provided public goods and maintained the social infrastructures that would be essential for subsequent rapid industrialization. As a result, both public corporations and the transport sector formed union strongholds to which the bulk proportion of the rank-and-file belonged—23.2 percent of all Korean union members were employed in the public sector and 34.5 percent in the transport sector in 1962 (Table 20.2). In addition, the Korean state intervened heavily in the mining sector, as coal was the primary source of power. Accordingly, if we include the members of the Mining Union in the proportions of rank-and-files in both public and transport sectors—8.4 percent of all union members belonged to the Mining Union in 1962 in Table 20.2— the share of total 279

16,870 (112.3%)2

19,452

24,681

Wholesale, retail, food, and lodgings

785

3,646 (364.6%)

5,416

5,595

1988

1995

2010

Sectors

1963

1988

1995

2010





140

59

Mining

76

70

52

25

3,472

1,075

749



1,773

1,913

1,024 (412%)

200

Construction

6,038

3,042

2,285

1,108

Other social, public and individual services

Electricity, gas, and water

Finance, insurance, real estate, and business services

4,105

4,818

4,667 (640%)

631

Manufacturing

Notes: 1. Criteria for the classification of sectors were modified several times to exclude negligibly small sectors such as finance, insurance, real estate, and business services in 1963 and mining in 1995 and 2010. 2. Numbers in ( ) with two arrows < and > respectively shows the percentage increase and decrease in the number of employees in Korea and the relevant sectors from 1963 to 1988.

Source: Lee et al. (1990: 98) originally cited from The Survey of Economically Active Population (1963) and The Annual Report of Economically Active Population (1988) of the Economic Planning Board.; KLI (2013: 24–25).

2,080

1,075

823 (603%)

117

Transport, warehouse, and communication

1,528

2,403

3,483 (30.6%)

5,021

7,947

1963

Agriculture, forestry, and fishery

Total

Sectors1

Table 20.1 Annual shifts in the number and proportions of employees in various sectors in Korea (in thousands)

Trade union movements in South Korea

union members that were rank-and-file employees of public corporations, companies in the transport sector, and in the mining industry was 66.1 percent; thus, about two-thirds of the unionized workforce were employed in the public and transport sectors and mining industry, which were heavily intervened by the state at the end of the pre-industrialization period. Finally, in parallel with the weakness of the unions in the British agriculture and fishing industry—there were 10,000 rank-and-file union members from that industry among a total of 750,000 British union members in 1888 (Clegg, Fox, and Thompson, 1964: 1), the unions in Korea’s agriculture, forestry, and fishery industry are unpopular despite that industry having the highest proportion (63.2 percent) of the total Korean workforce in 1963 as shown in Table 20.1. During the second early (1962–1971) and third mature (1972–1992) industrialization periods, Korea recorded the rapid industrialization resulting from the growth in employment in the manufacturing sector. As seen in Table 20.1, between 1963 and 1988, while the total number of employees in Korea grew by 112.3 percent and that in the agriculture, forestry, and fishery sector fell considerably by 30.6 percent, there was rapid growth of 640 percent in the manufacturing sector; 603 percent in the transport, warehouse, and communication sector; 412 percent in the construction sector; and 364.6 percent in the wholesale, retail, food, and lodgings sector. Accordingly, in 1988, the highest proportion of all Korean employees was in the manufacturing sector (27.7 percent), followed by the retail, wholesale, food, and lodgings sector (21.6 percent) and the agriculture, forestry, and fishery sector (20.6 percent) (Table 20.1). However, we should note that the types of manufacturing industries that led to job creation in the Korean labor market, and thus occupied relatively large proportions of the national rank-and-file employees, differed between the early and mature industrialization periods. The national industrialization during the second early industrialization period (1962–1971) was chiefly led by the growth of light manufacturing industries such as the female-dominated textile (84.2 percent of females among all rank-and-file employees in 1971; Textile Union, 2004: 260), chemical (38.1 percent in 1971; Chemical Union, 1987: 151), and electronics industries. In contrast, during the third mature industrialization period (1972–1992), the growth of maledominated heavy manufacturing industries—machinery, automotive supply and assembly, and shipbuilding—led the Korean industrialization. Accordingly, the Metal Union’s share of the total manufacturing union membership, excluding the Mining Union, grew rapidly from 12.7 percent (= 5,336 / [58,385 – 16,446] x 100) in 1962, to 21.2 percent in 1972, to 26.1 percent in 1986, and to 51.5 percent in 1989 (Table 20.2). In contrast, the share of rank-and-file union members of the four public corporations in the public sector—railway, electricity, post office, and ginseng and tobacco—and the transport sector, respectively, fell from 23.2 percent and 34.5 percent in 1962 to 4.7 percent and 19.4 percent in 1989 (Table 20.2). During the fourth period of sluggish economic growth and economic crisis calling for the intervention of IMF (International Monetary Fund) for avoiding the national bankruptcy in 1997 (1993–1998), the size of the workforce in the manufacturing sector and its proportion of the overall national workforce shrank from a maximum of 4,986,000 and 26.2 percent in 1992 to 3,917,000 and 19.6 percent in 1998 (KLI, 2013: 24). As Table 20.1 shows, the proportion of employees in Korea’s manufacturing sector fell from 27.7 percent in 1988 to 23.6 percent in 1995, while the proportion in the wholesale, retail, food, and lodgings sector grew. In addition, the size of the manufacturing sector’s union membership and its proportion of national union membership fell considerably during this period, as seen in Table 20.2, from 914,114 and 48.2 percent in 1989 to 479,732 and 34.2 percent in 1998. In particular, the disadvantageous economic environment during the fourth period damaged the organizational bases of union membership in the light manufacturing industries more seriously than those in the heavy manufacturing industries as shown by the rapid declines in the textile union membership from 1989 to 1998 281

Subtotal

Transport Land transport1 Dock transport Seafaring Auto transport2 Taxi Luggage transport

Subtotal

Public Railway Electricity Post office Ginseng and tobacco Public (1) Public (2)

Subtotal

Mining and manufacturing Textile Chemical Metal Rubber Printing Mining Food

Sector/ Industrial union federation

67,670 (34.5%)

22,361 14,987 10,878 19,444

45,575 (23.2%)

21,756 8,178 7,041 8,600

168,787 (33.4%)

17,107 47,544 19,500 84,636

82,485 (16.3%)

33,419 10,465 24,569 14,032

163,340 (32.4%)

256,230 (24.7%)

36,430 79,574 140,226

125,612 (12.1%)

30,398 18,415 65,345 11,454

427,462 (41.3%)

5,815 54,538

4,202 33,867

16,446 58,385 (29.8%)

115,129 154,433 97,547

1986

54,165 43,551 27,555

1972

25,263 11,340 5,336

1962

Table 20.2 Numbers of union members of Korean industrial union federations

368,568 (19.4%)

46,668 83,455 121,161 117,284

89,885 (4.7%)

31,181 26,517 21,949 10,238

914,114 (48.2%)

155,331 206,429 448,583 32,579 26,887 44,305

1989

286,058 (20.4%)

36,037 38,083 82,261 124,037 5,640

157,789 (11.3%)

44,641 25,218 25,774 6,209 28,114 27,833

479,732 (34.2%)

44,751 122,146 291,867 9,729 3,580 7,659

1998

207,208 (11.6%)

22,749 26,719 83,722 74,018

232,587 (13.0%)

3,846 14,729 28,832 6,053 56,900 122,227

388,079 (21.7%)

12,528 78,832 272,210 9,677 1,086 2,852 10,894

2012

1,035,890

1,897,266

1,781,337

350,054 10,592 +19,524 17,914

554,839 (31.1%)

6,147

3,863 14,337 45,833

1,349

68,392 16,352

60,249 25,600 12,385 11,394 57,044 7,400

159,431 42,304 11.340 11,419

Notes: 1. Land transport was divided into dock transport and seafaring in 1980. 2. Auto transport was built in 1963 and 19,444 is the number of members in that year.

Source: FKTU (2002: 408, 524); Ministry of Labour (1987: 39); Ministry of Labour (2013: 23–25).

504,624

1,401,940

195,609

396,584 (28.3%)

4,036

4,627 1,286

17,244 17,188 77,624 4,419 7,267 16,420

170,512 35,634 11,306 20,671 8,350

Total

524,699 (27.7%)

24,107 237,597

38,416 50,366

174,213

81,777

291,931 (28.1%)

12,766

90,012 (17.8%)

8,676 59,835

2,661 39,874

23,979 (12.2%)

22,297 65,345

23,928

5,231

135,778

23,549

5,982

Nonaffiliated independent unions Directly affiliated to FKTU or KCTU People’s Trade Union

Subtotal

Private service Finance Hospital College administration U.S. military services Communication School teachers Part-time school teachers Newspaper and broadcasting Tour services Allied Medical services Commercial Construction workers Construction machine operators Apartment maintenance Building maintenance Apartment construction Female Private services Information and telecommunication clerical services Cleaning services

Jooyeon Jeong

of 71.1 percent (= (155,331 – 44,751) / 155,331 x 100), of 40.8 percent in the chemical sector, and 70.1 percent in the rubber sector, in contrast to 34.9 percent in the metal sector. The case of union decline in the chemical industries is examined below in the next section. Total national union membership in Korea fell notably from 1,897,266 in 1989 to 1,401,940 in 1998 (Table 20.2). Table 2 also shows that new unions were formed in the public sector and in several service industries in the private sector. However, these new unions do not seem to have compensated for the decline in other sectors or halted the decline in national union membership. The union movement in the public sector still faced serious limitations in bargaining and strikes due to the restrictive union policy of the state. On the other hand, several of the new small industrial union federations in the private service sector seem to have lacked the stable bargaining capacities and strike leverages needed for effective representation of the interests of their rank-and-file members, not to mention their precarious union organizational bases. To sum up, the poor organizational bases and representative capacities of Korean unions in the public sector and private service sector contrast with Britain, where the growth of union membership in the public sector and white-collar occupations led the growth of national union membership from the early 20th century to after World War II (Clegg, Fox, and Thompson, 1964: 466–471; Clegg, 1979: 174–186). Finally, during the fifth period of low economic growth (1999–present), national union membership grew, mainly due to the growth of industrial union associations in the public sector including public (1) and public (2), nonaffiliated independent unions and several small industrial union associations in the private service sector, as seen in Table 20.2. However, many new unions in those sectors do not seem to have possessed satisfactory levels of bargaining capacities and dispute leverages. In addition, union membership in the textile, chemical, and metal industries, and in dock transport, seafaring and taxi fell continuously from 1998 to 2012 (Table 20.2).

Three industrial cases of union growth and industrial relations This section aims to characterize the structural and functional features of unions and industrial relations in three industrial cases in Korea, the chemical industry, the city bus industry in the auto transport sector, and the auto assembly industry in the metal sector. The choice of the chemical industry is useful for considering the highly decentralized enterprise unionism typically observed in the Korean light manufacturing industries3. That industrial case typically shows weak representative capacity characterized by unstable and low security of enterprise unionism, which could be attributed to low union densities, weak bargaining capacity and weak dispute leverage confining to annual wage growth as typically observed in other female-dominated light manufacturing industries during the 1970s. The city bus branch of the Auto Transport Union exhibits the stable representative capacity typically observed in the Korean transport sector4. The union is comprised of several regional unions that organize enterprise union branches and are responsible for regionally centralized bargaining, which deals with broad issues of concern as well as workers’ wage increases at the regional levels. The union also differs from the Chemical Union through its high union densities, union shop rules and effective strike leverages. Jeong (2001) showed that identifying the determinants of the regionally centralized bargaining, as well as the bargaining outcomes for the city bus union, calls for the referring of previous literature in the contexts of Britain, Germany, and Japan (Bean, 1994: Clegg, 1976; Windmuller, 1987). Finally, unions in the metal industry have been the vanguard of the vigorous democratic enterprise union movement, and distinguished from their precedents by showing unprecedented and exemplary levels of militancy and autonomy during the political and social democratization 284

Trade union movements in South Korea

period that existed in Korea from 1987 to 19925. In particular, the strong representative capacities of enterprise unions in auto assembly firms are characterized by a stable growth of annual union memberships, high union densities, aggressive bargaining demands for wage increases and regulatory power over personnel and work organization policies in combination with frequent strikes.

Case 1: Weak but dissimilar representative capacities among enterprise unions in the chemical industry Case 1, part (a): Low union security and unstable union organizational bases In the chemical industry, enterprise unionism prevails in terms of union organization, bargaining, and strikes. In other words, union organizations have been initiated by spontaneous desires and efforts towards organization among workers within firms, which must be sufficiently powerful to overcome the resistance and opposition of the employers, while in one firm, bargaining and strikes have been led by the enterpriser union in order to deal with the complaints and demands of its organized employees. FKCU (Federation of Korean Chemical Unions; henceforth, the Chemical Union), which was the loose industrial union federation of enterprise unions in chemical industry and was affiliated to the national union confederation, FKTU (Federation of Korean Trade Unions), was not usually involved in organization, bargaining, and strikes at enterprise levels. Instead, it publishes annual activity reports that record union organization, bargaining, and strikes in its affiliated enterprise unions every year. The Chemical Union was comprised of 16 to 18 industrial union branches from 1973 to 2013. In 2013, these were cement, concrete and remicon; PVC; petrochemical; petroleum refining; petroleum gas; pharmaceutical and cosmetics; glass; dish manufacturing; shoe manufacturing; paint; chemical fertilizer; food; paper; stationery; and general chemicals (Chemical Union, 2013: 105). The industrial structure in the Chemical Union can roughly be judged as having a predominance of small- and medium-sized enterprises (henceforth, SMEs) and a small number of large-sized enterprises (henceforth, LEs), with the unions usually organized in the LEs. Accordingly, the unorganized chemical firms are smaller than the unionized ones. In 1978, the average number of rank-and-file members in any given chemical enterprise union was about 389 (142,000 / 365) while the average number of employees in chemical firms was approximately 54 (583,000 / 10,793) (Chemical Union, 1987: 393). The prevalent anti-union attitudes among employers and managers of chemical firms primarily resulted in instability and low union security. First of all, the fragile union security in Korean chemical firms was easily shown by the predominance of strikes resulting from unfair labor practices, including employers unfairly treating union leaders and repressing democratic union activities; for example, among 137 strikes between 1972 and 1979, the cause of 71 strikes (51.8 percent) was unfair labor practices which aimed to threaten union security (ibid.: 450). Such repressive behaviors by employers, which attempted to deny and eliminate unions in chemical firms, had always been the primary cause of strikes. These behaviors took the forms of the repression and elimination of democratic enterprise unions, retaliatory personnel policies for union leaders, physical harassment of union leaders and their followers, the hiring of workers to replace those on strike, and the denial of unions’ legitimate rights to engage in collective bargaining between 1984 and 1989 (Chemical Union, 2004: 300, 318–345). Similar causes of the strikes were cited between 1990 and 1999 (ibid., 490–523). In particular, such weak union security in chemical firms during economic recessions, in which the presence and representative roles of the unions were easily repressed and denied by employers, forced 285

Jooyeon Jeong

Table 20.3 Annual sizes of union membership (in thousands) and of enterprise unions in Chemical Union and its major industrial branches Industrial branches Food Petroleum refining Cement Paper Pharmaceutical and cosmetics Chemical Union

1973

1978

1990

1998

2013

9.9 1.3 3.1 0.8 0.1

19.0 1.6 6.1 5.3 3.8

34.0 7.1 7.5 15.2 17.5

20.0 3.9 5.3 8.1 7.6

8.7 2.7 2.9 4.2 5.2

142 (24.4%)1

182

88

45

42

Source: Chemical Union (1987: 425–427); Chemical Union (2004: 409); Chemical Union (2013: 99) Note: 1. It is the estimated union density in 1978.

numerous enterprise unions to disappear. From 1990 to 1999, after the Chemical Union had reached its largest organizational size in 1990, 535 enterprise unions, of which 45,732 rankand-file employees were members, were disaffiliated from the union (Chemical Union, 2004: 429). Such decisions by the enterprise unions primarily resulted either from formidable pressure from employers or from worsened business conditions for chemical firms, leading to bankruptcies and mergers. Case 1, part (b): Weak enterprise bargaining capacity and dispute leverage, confined to annual wage growths The proportion of all enterprise unions actually reaching collective bargaining agreements is one measure of the effectiveness of bargaining as the primary institutional mechanism for determining the employment conditions of unionized workers. A rate of 100 percent would mean that all unionized chemical firms reached bargaining agreements with their enterprise unions. In the Chemical Union, the rate was 71 percent in 1972; 74 percent in 1979 (Chemical Union, 1987: 440); and 93 percent in 1998 (Chemical Union, 1999: 99). However, rates fell noticeably in the 2000s to 67 percent in 2000 (Chemical Union, 2004: 168); 58 percent in 2003 (Chemical Union, 2004: 168); 41 percent in 2008 (Chemical Union, 2009: 160); and 47.9 percent in 2013 (Chemical Union, 2013: 137). In other words, the proportion of enterprise unions reaching bargaining agreements fell to about two-thirds of all unionized firms in 2000 and again to less than half of such firms after 2008. The plunge in the union organizational basis in the Chemical Union from 1990 to 2013 (Table 20.3) is also closely related to the noticeable collapse in the bargaining capacity of the existing unions. Another measure of the declining bargaining capacity of the chemical unions was the types of agendas chiefly dealt with in the bargaining. The agendas in chemical unions were mainly confined to annual wage growth rather than other fundamental issues of concern among workers such as unfair wage structure creating large wage differentials between female blue-collar workers and male white-collar workers or dirty, dangerous and demanding working conditions. The annual wage growth rates bargained for in the chemical unions, as shown in Table 20.4, mainly depended on several industry-specific business cycles and on the national economic environments. The two digits of growth rates in the 1970s reflect both the rapid-growth stage of the industry and the high growth in nominal wages to fit high inflation rates in that period. After the recovery from economic recession following the second oil shock in the early 1980s, the high annual wage growth rate in the chemical unions in 1987 reflect the unprecedented 286

Trade union movements in South Korea

economic boom (favorable economic environment) and the explosive growth in the unions’ organizational bases and bargaining capacity (favorable industrial relations environment) that started in that year. However, the annual wage growth rate in the chemical unions fell in 1995, at the end of the economic boom, and was frozen in 1998 after the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997. Finally, after the economic crisis, the wage bargaining capacity of unions in chemical firms started to recover but remained at one-digit growth during the 2000s. However, the decentralized wage bargaining of the enterprise unions in the chemical industry could not fix the large wage differentials between different chemical industries. Those wage differentials in 1973 (67,176 won in petroleum refining; 21,773 won in paper; 20,702 won in food; 16,328 won in rubber; and 16,168 won in leather) remained roughly constant in 1979 (244,069 won in petroleum refining; 104,595 won in paper; 88,029 won in food; 75,517 in rubber; and 66,610 won in leather) (Jeong, 2007: 46). In addition, the weak enterprise bargaining confined to annual wage growth could not fix the large wage differentials between (i) unionized manual and non-unionized clerical and managerial workers, (ii) male and female workers, and (iii) SMEs and LEs within the same chemical industry, even though those wage differentials were the primary complaints among the rank-and-files in chemical firms. Finally, according to the analysis of collective bargaining agreements from 124 unionized chemical firms in 1986, the prevailing form of regulatory voices for firms’ personnel policies regarding the rank-and-file was very weak; the large proportion (58.0 percent) of those agreements specified unilateral decision of firms, while others had either no agreements (19.3 percent) or weak forms of regulations like consultation between firms and unions (12.0 percent), notification to unions (8.0 percent), and consent with unions (2.7 percent) (Chemical Union, 2004: 279). Among 137 disputes in chemical unions from 1972 to 1979, the top four causes of the disputes were (i) demands for free union activities and opposition to the arbitrary dismissal of rank-andfile employees (71 disputes); (ii) annual wage growth (49); (iii) opposition to temporary closures and permanent shutdowns of firms (11); and (iv) improvement of working conditions (5) (ibid.: 449). The first cause shows that employers’ illegal practices aimed at suppressing union activities frequently lead to weak union security while the second cause shows that the annual wage growth was the primary bargaining agenda. In addition, more than two-thirds of the disputes during the 1970s (94 of those 137 disputes from 1972 to 1979, or 68 percent) took passive forms such as raising petitions or submitting complaints to the National or Regional Labor Committee and requesting mediation, rather than the active, threatening form of conducting strikes (ibid.). Table 20.4 Annual wage growth rates bargained for in the chemical industries Years

1975

1978

1985

1987

1995

1998

1999

2003

2006

2012

Rates

28.7

22.6

6.7

23.6

10.5

0

4.2

8.1

5.8

4.9

Source: Chemical Union (1987: 430–431); Chemical Union (2004: 279, 438); Chemical Union (2009: 160); Chemical Union (2013: 138).

Case 2. Stable representative capacities of regionally centralized bargaining in city bus unions Case 2, part (a): High union security and stable union organizational bases The proportion of rank-and-file employees in the transport sector among all Korean union memberships was 34.5 percent in 1962 and 33.4 percent in 1972 but fell to 24.7 percent in 1986, as seen in Table 20.2. In that sector, the auto transport industry became the largest, 287

Jooyeon Jeong

occupying more than half of the rank-and-file employees in 1972 and 1986 (Table 20.2). In the Auto Transport Union, the rank-and-file members of the city bus branch ranged from 52.4 percent in 1990 to 72.5 percent in 2013, as seen in Table 20.5, after the taxi branch was disaffiliated from the union and built its own Taxi Union in 1988. The city bus branch of the Auto Transport Union, rather than the enterprise unions in city bus firms, was mainly responsible for leading collective bargaining and strike activities at the city levels; such a regionally centralized bargaining structure gave them greater bargaining capacities than decentralized enterprise bargaining would have done, as examined below. In addition, the union shop rules— which required all of the large numbers of male drivers (17,696 drivers in city bus companies in December 1977 [Auto Transport Union, 2003: 132]) and female conductors (19,217 bus conductors in city bus companies in December 1977 [ibid.: 126]) and a small number of mechanics to join unions as soon as they were employed—was the chief institutional condition guaranteeing high union security. As a result, with the growth in economic development increasing the national demand for city bus services in newly formed and growing cities, the subsequent growth in the number of employed drivers and conductors automatically guaranteed an increase in union rank-and-file membership from 1980 to 2013 (Table 20.5). In the city, intercity, highway, and rental bus branches in the Auto Transport Union, the number of female conductors started to decline from 1982 as bus companies tried to reduce labor costs by discharging female conductors by enabling passengers to pay voluntarily when boarding buses. As a result, the number of female conductors in all bus companies fell from about 17,000 in 1982 to less than 100 by 1992 (ibid.: 261). However, the increase in male drivers resulting from the growing demand for city bus services in the 1980s offset this reduction as shown by the only slight reduction in union membership in the city bus branch of the Auto Transport Union from 1980 to 1990 (Table 20.5). Case 2, part (b): Strong centralized bargaining capacity and dispute leverage High union security and stable union organizational bases in city bus unions generated strong bargaining capacity and dispute leverage. During the last five decades, city bus unions have retained the regional collective bargaining structure in which regional unions and their regional employer associations bargain and determine wages and other working conditions for all rankand-file employees in their affiliated bus companies in the regions. For example, bargaining agreements over wages and other working conditions were separately reached in six large cities, namely Seoul, Pusan, Incheon, Daegu, Kwangju, and Daejeon. These centralized regional wage bargaining agreements achieved by the regional city bus unions won 11 percent growth rates in Seoul and Pusan, 25.6 percent in Incheon, 12 percent in Daegu, 25 percent in Kwangju, and 20.5 percent in Daejeon in 1987 (Auto Transport Union, 2003: 289). Leaders of the city bus branch of the Auto Transport Union were always involved in loose coordination in the determination of annual wage growth rates among six cities in the regional wage bargaining. What, then, were the industrial relations outcomes of the centralized regional wage bargaining structure in the city bus unions of Auto Transport Union? Above all, the centralized wage bargaining structure and loose coordination succeeded in generating similar wage levels in six cities. For example, the average wage level in city bus companies in Seoul during 1998 was 1,506,842 won, in comparison with 1,493,016 won (99 percent of the wage level in Seoul) in Daegu and 1,422,893 won (94.4 percent of the wage level in Seoul) while in 2013 the similar wage levels remained constant, respectively 1,910,507 won, 1,934,826 won (101.2 percent of the wage level in Seoul), and 1,724,598 won (90.2 percent of the wage level in Seoul) (ibid.: 417). In addition, wage levels at city bus companies in all cities stayed at similar levels under 288

Trade union movements in South Korea

Table 20.5 Union membership in the Auto Transport Union and its city bus branch 1973 City bus (estimated union density) Auto Transport Union

104,220

1980

1990

1998

2013

46,693 (71.8%)

45,555 (72.0%)

55,812

58,444

177,550

86,832

79,811

80,576

Source: Auto Transport Union (2003: 148, 265, 522–526 in); Auto Transport Union (2013: 473–474).

the city-level bargaining structure. In contrast to dissimilar wage levels between SMEs and LEs within several chemical industries as shown above, the similar wage levels across city bus companies within and among cities is a surprising bargaining outcome. Such bargaining outcomes of similar wage levels helped to enhance solidarity among rank-and-file employees in city bus companies and thus maintained their high credibility and commitment to their unions. In addition, the centralized regional bargaining structure enabled numerous enterprise unions in city bus companies to respond collectively at the city level to several issues of concerns commonly faced by those unions, and thus helped to enhance the bargaining power through the formidable threat of strikes that would paralyze the normal operation of the city buses, a major public transportation system. On the basis of stable union security and organizational bases in city bus branch in the Auto Transport Union, the centralized bargaining structure also allowed them to conduct vigorous policy activities to meet the demands of the workers; that activity relied on political lobbying to call for the building and implementing of policies by the relevant government agency, usually, the Ministry of Construction and Transportation. This shows that the mode of dealing with broader bargaining issues beyond the enterprise level through a centralized regional, industrial, and national bargaining structure, as observed in Germany and Sweden (Bean, 1994), also occurred in the Korean city bus unions. During the periods from 1987 to 1989, from 1990 to 1996, and from 1997 to 2002, the demands raised by city bus branches of the Auto Transport Union included several complaints of bus drivers, such as (i) in 1987 and 1992, suggestions for relevant policies to deal with unexpected problems of individual wage losses for city bus drivers resulting from traffic accidents, (ii) in 1996 and 2002, demands for compulsory purchase of aggregate insurance by bus companies to deal with the problem of several types of wage losses for bus drivers mentioned in (i), (iii) in 1987, demands calling for lengthening excessively short time intervals between buses in operation which increased the possibilities of traffic accidents, (iv) in 1992 and 2001, reforms for reducing long working hours of bus drivers, and (v) calls for prohibiting the employment of nonstandard or irregular bus drivers in city bus companies in order to guarantee stable jobs for regular rank-and-file drivers in 1998 (Auto Transport Union, 2003: 274–282, 315–326, 378–398). Even though all these policy activities of the Auto Transport Union failed to always generate the desired policy outcomes, some of them did succeed in building and implementing relevant policies.

Case 3. Strong but various representative capacities of enterprise unions in the auto industry Case 3, part (a): High union security and stable union organizational bases but varying across firms During the mature industrialization period (1976–1992), the growth of male-predominant heavy manufacturing industries such as the metal sector contributed to the rapid growth of their unions 289

Jooyeon Jeong

in Korea. In contrast to the union movements of the female-dominated textile, chemical, and electronics industries during the early industrialization period from 1962 to 1975, the maledominated metal sector’s unions showed a higher degree of militancy and autonomy in their relations with employers. Within the metal sector, unions in the auto industry were in the vanguard of the dramatic growth of the union movement after 1987. Considering three enterprise unions in the auto assembly industry and two unions in the auto supply industry is academically useful for showing the strong but complex and diverse patterns of union growth in those industries. Table 6 shows annual union memberships in five enterprise unions in two chaebol-affiliated firms: unions H and D in the auto assembly industry, one independent large-sized firm (union K in the auto assembly industry) and in two SMEs (unions S and T in the auto supply industry). A chaebol (chaebŏl) is a Korean conglomerate owned and managed by one family. Each enterprise union is comprised of several regional plant branches usually producing different sizes of cars; for example, the total membership (43,025) of enterprise union H in 2006 (Table 20.6) was comprised of (i) blue-collar manual workers (24,737 or 57.5 percent of all memberships in union H at the Ulsan plant, 2,655 or 6.2 percent at the Chunju plant, 2,590 or 6.0 percent at the Asan plant), (ii) 2,608 mechanic workers or 6.1 percent and 3,979 white-collar workers or 9.2 percent at the Namyang plant, and (iii) 6,456 white-collar sales staff or 15.0 percent in firm H (Lee, 2011: 37). High union densities in those five plants and a separate occupation of sales staff stayed about 90 percent ranging from the lowest 90 percent among mechanic workers to the highest 98 percent in Ulsan and 70 percent in sales staff in that year (ibid.). Similarly, the total number of rank-and-file employees in firm K in 2012 (30,356) (Table 20.6) was comprised of 5,605 at the Soha plant, 12,945 at the Hwasung plant, 6,594 at the Kwangju plant, 1,691 in the mechanics department, and 3,521 in the sales department (Hahm, 2013: 50). High union density in firm K was 83.6 percent in 2006. The total union membership in firm D was primarily comprised of rank-and-file employees at the Bupyong plant, which saw a notable decline of union membership from 1998 to 2009, as seen in Table 20.6. Finally, unions S and T in two auto supply SMEs experienced slight declines in their union membership from 1997 to 2001 as the table shows. Both high union densities in unions H, K, and D and great popularities of unions in the auto assembly industry helped their enterprise unions to possess stable union securities in combination with high bargaining capacities and dispute leverages. Table 20.6 Sizes of union membership in five enterprise unions Unions

1988

1995

1997

1998

1999 2004 2009

H

22,202

29,937

34,829

34,122

28,256

39,077 45,070

19,779

25,847

28,046

10,648 (8,012)

10,438 (7,450)

8,218 (4,524)

10,457 (6,100)

515

526

K D (Bupyo-ng plant) S

565

T

740

290

667

2013

28,098

Trade union movements in South Korea

Successful formation of democratic enterprise unions, which were either newly created or replaced previous employer-controlled undemocratic company unions, occurred in LEs in several metal industries in 1987. Given that those industries were strategically core to the Korean economy at that time, recording high growth and profits as leading industries of national exports, manual workers could confidently and boldly express their discontent over their low wages and poor working conditions from the early 1980s. Successful examples of enterprise unions’ struggles in some chaebol-affiliated metal LEs, which aimed to defeat employers’ stubborn resistance to admitting unions and the building of permanent union organizations, were emulated by those in other chaebol-affiliated LEs and in enterprise unions in LEs and SMEs in other manufacturing and white-collar industries5. In the face of unprecedentedly militant and autonomous demands for democratic unions, employers had no choice but to accept the presence of unions as legitimate representatives of workers rather than suppressing them and blocking their formation as they had in the past. However, the outbreak of the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis worsened the business performance of auto firms and led to massive dismissals. Employer-led enterprise restructuring led to the massive discharge of around 8,000 unionized workers from firm H in 1998 and 1999. In contrast, similar employer-led enterprise restructuring generated greater shocks and damages to unions’ organizational bases in firms D and K as those bankrupt firms were taken over by a U.S. auto assembly firm and firm H, respectively. The number of employees in the Bupyong plant of firm D fell from 8,012 in 1998 to 6,100 in 2009 (Table 6), while the union opposing the employer-led enterprise restructuring clashed with the police in 1999. Finally, unions in auto supply firms S and T also suffered a decline of their rank-and-file memberships between 1997 and 1999 after the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis. Case 3, part (b): Strong decentralized bargaining capacity and dispute leverage, but defensive shifts varied across firms in periods of union decline

In the auto industry, all of the enterprise unions in Table 20.6 showed a growth in bargaining capacity from 1987 to 1993, followed by a noticeable decline from 1998 to 2013. During the first period, enterprise unions were able to call aggressively for considerable improvements in wage levels and working conditions and actually achieved considerable progress. For example, the annual bargaining by union H in 1987, 1988, and 1989 gained significant growth in wages and improvements in working conditions: the 1989 agreement included 79,260 won in growth, 600 percent monthly bonuses, increases in family allowances, an increase in rest time, increases in paid national and family holidays, increases in paid holidays for female rank-and-file employees, and increases in long-service and hazard allowances (Union H, 2009: 82). In addition, that union was also involved in several coalitions with other newly formed enterprise unions in H-chaebol companies in a struggle against the owning family of H-chaebol, which was exhibiting authoritarian attitudes towards new unions. It finally formed the Union Association in H-Group to coordinate the separate bargaining and strike activities of individual enterprise unions in H-chaebol firms in 1987 because the major managerial decisions in those firms were all being made by the owning family (ibid.: 86–91).Given the unprecedented boom in the auto assembly industry in the late 1980s, the owning family exhibited a managerial style of reluctantly recognizing the union presence while maintaining an adversarial posture. In comparison with the case of enterprise union H, enterprise union K faced a different business environment and management style from its managers. Firm K was not owned by one family but maintained a separation of management and ownership. As a result, most of the financial fund in that firm was collected in the security market while a small portion of the firm’s equity— 291

Jooyeon Jeong

Table 20.7 Annual wage growth rates achieved in firm K during the period of its declining bargaining capacities Years

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

Rates

15.1%

13.7%

12.9%

11.3%

11.1%

10.5%

8.4%

Years

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

Average

Rates

9.1%

8.9%

8.9%

5.5%

8.0%

8.6%

8.2%

10.1%

Source: Hahm (2013: 90).

6.98 percent at the end of 1996—was owned by its employees (Hahm, 2013: 54). Due to the relatively loose managerial control of the firm, its top managers showed a relatively cooperative management style, accommodating the militant union K. However, firm K experienced bankruptcy due to its deteriorated business performance after the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis and was finally sold to firm H in 1998. The advent of unfavorable economic and firm business environments after the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis damaged the bargaining capacities of the enterprise unions in the metal industry but to different extents across firms. For example, the annual wage growth rates achieved in firm K showed a wage freeze in 1998 but positive rates from 1999 to 2005 (Table 20.7). This can be mainly explained by (i) firm-specific factors as the bankrupt firm K was merged into firm H in 1998 while the new mother firm H adopted an accommodative labor control policy until 2005 and (ii) the improved business performance of the Korean auto assembly industry. However, the opposite business performance and the adversarial labor control policy of firm H after 2006 led to a decline in annual wage growths achieved after 2006. After the outbreak of the crisis, enterprise unions in firms S and T also faced managerial demands for considerable concessions such as wage freezes and cuts and the removal of some favorable working conditions that had been agreed to through collective bargaining before the crisis. In the face of the unfavorable economic and firm business environment after the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis, the main stance of the auto industry’s enterprise unions in collective bargaining shifted from offensive to defensive as they tried to defend the job security of rank-and-file employees. However, the enterprise unions possessed different degrees of regulatory power to interfere in unilateral managerial decisions regarding such job security. For example, firms’ policies in hiring irregular and part-time workers, the transfer of jobs from unionized workers to unorganized workers in subcontracting firms, and massive dismissals could clearly undermine and threaten the employment security and working conditions of unionized full-time workers. The bargaining agreement achieved by union H succeeded in prohibiting the hiring of both irregular workers and workers in subcontracting firms without union consent. In contrast, the bargaining agreements made by union D did not impose such binding and regulatory clauses on the unilateral decisions regarding the hiring of additional irregular, part-time, and subcontracted workers and thus that union possessed weaker regulatory bargaining power. The bargaining agreement reached by union A also successfully prohibited massive dismissals unilaterally led by employers while requiring its managers to make sincere efforts to avoid dismissals by shifting workers among workplaces, not hiring new workers, and providing education and training. In contrast, union D had a weaker regulatory voice when it came to massive dismissals; if its managers decided on a curtailment of production leading to massive dismissals, its bargaining agreement required them only to give prior notice to the union. Finally, enterprise unions S and T had the weakest regulatory voices, as their bargaining agreements 292

Trade union movements in South Korea

did not have any regulatory bargaining clauses dealing with unilateral managerial decisions over the job security of rank-and-file employees. Strike leverages in four unions also shifted from an offensive posture to a defensive one between 1987 and the 2010s. Numerous strikes in the late 1980s and early 1990s were usually caused by offensive issues involving union demands over annual wage growth, the improvement of working conditions, and the elimination of unfair employer-led personnel policies. In contrast, the causes of strikes after the mid-1990s—and in particular, after the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis— were typically defensive in nature, such as the aforementioned job security of rank-and-file employees achieved through the regulation of employers’ unilateral power to change personnel and work organization policies, make massive dismissals and transfer jobs. In addition, the frequencies of strikes and the number of workers participating in them diminished significantly in most auto LEs during the second period.

Notes 1 2 3

4

5

6

This work was supported by the National Research Foundation of Korea Grant funded by the Korean Government (NRF-2010-411-B00028). For detailed expositions of these two critical arguments that appear in this chapter, refer to four recent works of the author (Jeong 2003, 2005, 2007, and 2011). The author intensively collected various sources of data regarding unions and industrial relations in the chemical industry between 2002 and 2004, from crucial annual activity reports of the Chemical Union, historical documents such as Chemical Union 1987 and 2004, and interviews with leaders of the Chemical Union in preparation for a book (Jeong, 2007: 44). The data and information were updated with more recent annual activity reports. Data on unions and industrial relations in the Auto Transport Union and its city bus branch were initially collected in 1998 through annual activity reports and interviews with union leaders in preparation for a previous paper (Jeong, 2001: 60). The author also led a research team that wrote a historical document about the union (Auto Transport Union, 2003), which gave him easy access to various data on the union and enabled him to interview several union leaders in 2000 and 2001. More recent data were gathered through the collection of a more recent historical document (Auto Transport Union, 2013) and more of the union’s annual activity reports. The author had several chances to collect data on unions and industrial relations among enterprise unions in the metal industry in the 2000s through the collection of annual activity reports and historical documents (Union H, 2009) and interviews with union leaders in preparation of a previous paper (Jeong, 2005) and book (Jeong, 2007). Recent data were collected similarly and through the supervision of master’s dissertations written by two union leaders in auto assembly firms H and K (Lee, 2011; Hahm, 2013). Jeong (2007) provides detailed descriptions of this emulation in both blue-collar enterprise union formation in numerous chaebol metal LEs (pp. 92–96) and SMEs in the manufacturing industry (pp. 96–98) and white-collar enterprise unions in secondary financial firms (pp. 98–101) from 1987 to 1990.

References Auto Transport Union (Federation of Korean Auto Transport Union, FKATU) (2003) Four Decades of History of Auto Transport Unions. Seoul: FKATU (in Korean). Auto Transport Union (2013) Five Decades of History of Auto Transport Unions. Seoul: FKATU (in Korean). Bean, R. (1994) Comparative Industrial Relations: An Introduction to Cross-national Perspectives. New York, NY: Routledge. Chemical Union (Federation of Korean Chemical Union, FKCU) (1987) Two Decades of History of Chemical Unions. Seoul: FKCU (in Korean). Chemical Union (2004) Four Decades of History of Chemical Unions. Seoul: FKCU (in Korean). Chemical Union (1999) Annual Activity Report. Seoul: FKCU (in Korean). Chemical Union (2009) Annual Activity Report. Seoul: FKCU (in Korean). 293

Jooyeon Jeong

Chemical Union (2013) Annual Activity Report. Seoul: FKCU (in Korean). Choi, J.J. (1989) Labor and the Authoritarian State: Labor Unions in South Korean Manufacturing Industries, 1961–1980. Seoul: Korea University Press. Clegg, H.A. (1976) Trade Unionism under Collective Bargaining: A Theory Based on Comparisons of Six Countries. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Clegg, H.A. (1979) The Changing System of Industrial Relations in Britain. London: Basil Blackwell. Clegg, H.A., Fox, A., and Thompson, A.F. (1964) A History of British Trade Unions since 1889: Volume I. 1889–1910.Oxford University Press. Deyo, F. (1989) Beneath the Miracle: Labor Subordination in the New Asian Industrialism. Berkeley: University of California Press. FKTU (Federation of Korean Trade Unions) (2002) Five Decades of History of FKTU. Seoul: FKTU (in Korean). Gospel, H.F. and Palmer, G. (1993) British Industrial Relations. London: Routledge. (2nd ed.). Hahm, J.K. (2013) A Study on Changes of Unions in the Period of Union Decline: The Case of Automobile Firm K. A Master’s Dissertation. Graduate School of Labor Studies, Korea University. Jeong, J.Y. (2001) “Pursuing centralized bargaining in an era of decentralization? A progressive union goal in Korea from a comparative perspective”, Industrial Relations Journal, 32: 55–57. Jeong, J.Y. (2003) “Is Korean enterprise bargaining a bona fide tool for employee representation?”, Journal of Industrial Relations, 45(1): 94–100. Jeong, J.Y. (2005) “Diversity in union security among enterprise unions: Cases of Korean metal firms from a micro-socioeconomic perspective”, Journal of Industrial Relations, 47(1): 43–61. Jeong, J.Y. (2007) Industrial Relations in Korea: Diversity and Dynamism of Korean Enterprise Unions from a Comparative Perspective. London: Routledge. Jeong, J.Y. (2011) “Can unions grow in authoritarian political and social environments?”, Journal of Industrial Relations, 53(4): 504–521. Katz, H.C., Kochan, T.A., and Colvin, A.J.S. (2008) An Introduction to Collective Bargaining and Industrial Relations. NY: McGraw-Hill. (4th ed.). KLI (Korea Labor Institute) (2013) Annual KLI Labor Statistics. Seoul: KLI. Lee, D.K., Park, D.J., Cho, W.H., and Kim, K.S. (1990) Industrialization and Labor Force in Korea: Summary and Analysis of Labor Statistics. Seoul: Korean Economic Research Institute (in Korean). Lee, S.H. (2011) A Study on Industrial Relations among White-Collar Workers: The Case of Research Institute in Automobile Firm H. A Master’s Dissertation. Graduate School of Labor Studies, Korea University. Martin, R.M. (1989) Trade Unionism: Purposes and Forms. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ministry of Labor (1987, 2013) A Report on Organization in National Unions. Seoul: Ministry of Labor (in Korean). Poole, M. (1986) Industrial Relations: Origins and Patterns of National Diversity. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. Textile Union (Federation of Korean Textile and Distribution Union, FKTDU) (2004) Five Decades of History of Textile and Distribution Unions. Seoul: FKTDU (in Korean). Union H (2009) Two Decades of History of Union H. Ulsan: Union H (in Korean). Windmuller, J.P. (1987) Collective Bargaining in Industrialized Market Economies: A Reappraisal. Geneva: ILO.

294

21 Economic miracle From post-war reconstruction to post-crisis affluence Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

Introduction Economic miracles are few and far between in modern human history, suggesting that world economic affairs have persistently upheld a biased division between a few haves and a majority have-nots. Over the post-World War years, the Cold War, an era of freer trade, and US hegemony, only eight countries have successfully ascended to the status of what the IMF calls ‘developed’ (i.e. countries exhibiting full political independence with a highly developed infrastructure, health care facilities, education, culture, strong middle class, and affluence as measured by national and per capita GDP). These countries are Israel in the Middle East; South Korea (hereafter, Korea), Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore in East Asia; and the Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Slovenia in the former Soviet bloc. In this short list of newly developed countries (two of them being city-states), only four are non-European, adding further bleakness to the already gloomy picture of north-south inequality. Among the four so-called East Asian tigers, Korea stands out because it is the only nonChinese country without prolonged interaction with European colonial forces. Hong Kong and Singapore were modernised by the British colonial administration, whereas Taiwan was first exposed to Portuguese and Dutch colonial, or long distance, explorers. Furthermore, while Korea has survived a massive civil war with North Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore have not fought any major wars during the post-war years. In addition, Korea is not a territorial part of China, whereas Hong Kong and Taiwan are under the constant threat of being annexed to the socialist regime. In fact, Korea has maintained that it plans to unify the peninsula in tandem with the expected collapse of the North’s communist rule. In contrast to Singapore, Korea is a fully democratised country that has faithfully conformed to the Lipsetian rule of democratisation through economic affluence, whereby we see a correlation between democratisation and economic growth. With regards to economic growth, Korea’s GDP per capita was just around twice that of Sub-Saharan Africa in 1960, but almost 24 times as high in 2005 (Pillay 2010). Finally, Korea underwent a long period of military dictatorship between 1961 and 1987 after Japanese colonial rule of a similar length (1910–1945). This pattern cannot be found in Hong Kong, Singapore, or Taiwan, where civilian dictatorship or UK-style colonial administration had been the norm. 295

Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

Table 21.1 Korean miracle: GDP growth Year

GDP ($)

Year

GDP ($)

Year

GDP ($)

1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979

156 91 104 142 120 105 129 156 193 237 292 317 339 426 589 646 875 1,106 1,468 1,858

1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

1,778 1,969 2,076 2,268 2,474 2,542 2,906 3,628 4,813 5,860 6,642 7,676 8,140 8,869 10,275 12,404 13,255 12,197 8,134 10,432

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

11,948 11,256 12,789 14,219 15,922 18,657 20,917 23,101 20,475 18,339 22,151 24,156 24,454 25,977

Source: World Bank Group, World Development Indicators. http://data.worldbank.org/country/korea-republic. Accessed: October 24, 2014

Qualifying the Korean economic miracle is therefore a complicated task, given its unique presence in East Asia on the one hand and its superficial resemblance to Japan, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore on the other. Koreans share similar physical features with the Chinese populace, elements of Chinese and Confucian culture, and use many Chinese expressions and terminologies in their language. On the surface, the Korean economic miracle seems to be Chinese in origin, as was much propagated by scholars who touted Confucian work ethic and Confucian capitalism (Rozman 1990; Lew et al. 2011; Bae and Form 1986). To others, however, Korea also resembles Japan. Koreans also share similarities with the Japanese and hold on to the Japanese cultural concept of senpai (senior) and kōhai (junior) in hierarchical human relations. Like the Japanese, Koreans have respected and followed the pre-war system of selecting public officials or kōmuin through national exams. Indeed, many precedent studies of the Korean and Japanese economic miracles have highlighted bureaucratic efficiency in a developmental state as a key factor for success (Johnson 1982; Hattori 1987; Lie 2000). Despite these cultural proximities between greater China and Korea as well as between Korea and Japan, the lynchpin of the Korean economic miracle was an idiosyncratic institutional and cultural framework that cannot be found in its neighbouring nations. For one thing, neither greater-Chinese (Hong Kong, Taiwan, Singapore) nor Japanese economic development necessitated the development of the chaebŏl, or family-owned and -controlled inter-market conglomerates that competed over a small domestic market during the heyday of post-war capitalism. The key aspect of the chaebŏls’ birth, development, and maturity involves monopolistic competition under the behest of military dictatorship (see inter alia Lie 2000; E.M. Kim 1997; Oh 1999; Cumings 1984). In East Asia and elsewhere, family conglomerates, which dominate 296

Economic miracle

Table 21.2 Changes of top five chaebo˘ls 2003

2013

Company

Assets Employees (KRW trillion)

Company

Assets Employees (KRW trillion)

Samsung LG SK Hyundai Motor KT

83.5 58.6 47.5 44.1 30.8

Samsung Hyundai Motor SK LG Lotte

306.1 166.7 140.6 102.4 87.5

130,750 92,283 29,127 98,706 48,344

257,091 147,714 78,593 141,722 85,010

Source: South Korea Fair Trade Commission. http://www.businessweek.com/articles/2013–09–26/for-south-koreas-topstudents-chaebol-are-the-place-to-be. Accessed: October 24, 2014

global export and Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) markets in addition to the domestic market, are rarely sustainable under military dictatorships unless they have blood ties with the military itself (Khanna and Yafeh 2007; Hattori 1997; Mo and Weingast 2013). For another, these chaebŏls have maintained their strong market position through both radical (i.e. either profit growth of more than thirty percent in one fiscal year or cost reduction by the same scale due to the introduction of new technology) and incremental innovation. While innovation occurs in all advanced and globally competitive firms in export markets, the kind of innovations that have occurred and are still occurring in the chaebŏl are considerably different from those found in the Japanese keiretsu (interlocked business groups) or in the guanxi firms based on personalized social networks in greater China. Briefly, Japanese innovations are process-based with institutional complementarity that emphasise a combination of malleable skills between management and shop-floor teams (Aoki 1990). In greater China, firms manage to innovate through collaboration between guanxi groups in the motherland and in North America through inter-faction competition (Saxenian 1999; Hsu and Saxenian 2000; Oh 1999; Wong 2005). But in the chaebŏl, innovation is more radical and patent/technology based than in Japan, while no chaebŏl groups maintain guanxi networks with Korean Americans for technological innovations (L. Kim 1997; Oh et al. 2005; Ghoshal 1988; Chang 2011). Innovative chaebŏls are, therefore, the fundamental institutional rubric of the Korean miracle before the 1997 Asian financial crisis. For another, no East or Southeast Asian country that underwent an economic miracle featured Korean-style macroeconomic policies of rapid industrial restructuring, which required forcible closure of old industrial sectors to bet on untested new alternatives in the global export market (Song 2003; World Bank 1993; Pirie 2008; Eichengreen et al. 2012). This means that largescale population displacement, massive unemployment between stages of restructuring, and geographical transfiguration involving landscape destruction and environmental pollution were far more rampant and disparaging in Korea than in Japan, Taiwan, Hong Kong, or Singapore. While predominantly agrarian in the 1950s and the 1960s, the political economy of Korea (or its peculiar state-business relations) managed a rapid, abrupt, and far-reaching movement of young people from the rural to urban areas to create the urban working class in the 1970s (Koo 2001; Lie 2000). Farmlands were converted into factory complexes in a matter of years, if not months, for light industries (e.g. textiles, wigs, toothpaste, soap), which were then bulldozed and replaced with new factories for heavy and chemical industries (e.g. oil refineries, automobiles, shipbuilding, electronics). In the 1980s and 1990s, employees of heavy and chemical industries were laid off in large numbers due to factory automation and robotics, while tertiary sector jobs (or what we call ‘McJobs’) were created in vast numbers to jumpstart a new service-sector 297

Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

economy era. As a consequence, geographical and environmental metamorphoses were most dramatic in Korea, while labour union movements were and still are the most militant among East Asian miracle economies (Lie 2000; Hart-Landsberg 1993; Cumings 1984; Pirie 2008). The net result of this peculiar Korean economic miracle is fourfold: (1) a mafia/predatory state that espoused GDP growth alongside escalating class polarisation; (2) chaebŏl groups that could not survive without political protection extended to them by the mafia/predatory state; (3) a social and institutional culture that could not maintain or organise human business and social relations without resorting to credible threats (real, thus credible, threat of using force by power-holders to someone who does not participate in economic activities or carry out contractual conditions), given rampant distrust among organisational members; and (4) semiworld-class process (institutional) and technological innovation via parodying. We will discuss these in turn before explaining the Korean economic miracle through the concept of ‘rentsharing’.

Four elements of the miracle The most peculiar institutional arrangement of the Korean economic miracle was based on the lack of credible commitment among economic actors and organisations to deliver a guaranteed quantity of goods and services at agreed-upon prices. Amid the absence of the most fundamental element of the Anglo-American concept of the free market and its mechanism of credible commitment, the latter of which is undertaken in support of alliances and to promote exchange (see Williamson 1983; North 1993), Korean economic actors and organisations had to rely on the credible threat, which appeared in the context of conflict and rivalry. In Korea, credible threats were realised only through what can be called the mafia/predatory state, which was willing to exercise either legitimate or illegitimate power to enforce agreements (for credible threats, see Konrad and Skaperdas 1997; Gambetta 2000; for Korean credible threats, see Oh 1999; Oh and Varcin 2002). The mafia state can take many forms, although the most distinctive property is its peculiar way of collecting revenue. While extortion is a typical mafia means of collecting revenue from street merchants in exchange for property protection, extortion by the mafia state can be institutionalised on an on-going basis through either rent-seeking or rent-sharing. Unlike rentseeking, where interest groups and individuals seek bigger rent in exchange for co-opting state actors (Buchanan et al. 1980; Krueger 1974), rent-sharing requires an opposite arrangement of state actors seeking a larger share of the rent than the one garnered by interest groups and individuals (Oh and Varcin 2010). In fact, throughout the miracle years, Korean state actors tried hard to raise the portion of rent they shared with the business sector. For example, in one year, total rent of 100 may be divided between the state and firms at a ratio of 20 and 80, respectively. If the state demands a greater portion of rent that exceeds rent generated for firms, firms would have to increase total output dramatically to meet state demands while maintaining an adequate share of the rent for themselves. As such, total rent may increase to 200 in the next period, with the state receiving 80 and firms receiving 120. What did the mafia state do to maximise its (legitimate or illegitimate) share of rent? First and foremost, dictators of the first military regime (1961–1979) pursued macroeconomic policies to boost economic growth rates via higher real interest rates. Savings ratios were high (i.e. the K effect) throughout the regime’s lifecycle, but the state quickly moved into the banking sector to own and control most Korean financial institutions. Savings went into state-controlled banks that lent money out to select clients, such as chaebŏl families. Unlike in Japan, where savings 298

Economic miracle

rates were also high, the Korean mafia state maintained high interest rates to induce savings from the working class. Although savings ratios were high, the absolute need for capital far exceeded what state banks could provide to chaebŏl groups. As such, the state had to underwrite most of the foreign loans and aid money to fund chaebŏl projects, which in turn promised paybacks to the state. Simultaneously, the state suppressed wages while improving labour productivity (i.e. the L effect). Firms subsidised night schools for workers while jailing thousands of union leaders and their supporters, and wholesale relocation of rural youth to urban factories progressed quickly thanks to government and factory buses and recruiters. Finally, the state actively subsidised firms that licensed foreign technologies, especially from Japan (i.e. the T effect). The K, L, and T effects combined, the Korean mafia state boasted GDP growth rates between eight and ten per cent during the 1960s and the 1970s (Eichengreen et al. 2012). On the other side of macroeconomic policies was the chaebŏl that contributed extorted money to the predatory mafia state. Chaebŏl literally means ‘families with enormous wealth’. How the families accrued and expanded their wealth may remain a family secret, although all top ten chaebŏl families were connected to each other and to key politicians through marriage (Hattori 1987; Chang 2003). The chaebŏl differs significantly from other East Asian conglomerates on several accounts. First, chaebŏl groups have a dual-ownership structure. On paper, owning families do not possess more than two to six per cent of total shares, but in reality, they own more than sixty per cent of total equity through a pseudo holding company system (Chang 2003; Campbell and Keys 2002; Kim et al. 2004; Trautvetter 2010). It is a pseudo holding company system because chaebŏl holding companies indirectly own shares of chaebŏl member firms without publicly listing the holding company itself. The reason behind a dual-ownership structure is the thorny issue of succession. Succession from the chaebŏl founder to his son was not seriously challenged during the military regime under the mafia-clientele arrangement. But since rapid democratisation since 1987, the civilian government began heavily taxing chaebŏl inheritances (e.g. shares) while concomitantly demanding ownership diffusion according to Anglo-American standards of corporate governance, particularly after the 1997 Asian financial crisis. In order to safeguard succession without paying massive taxes, chaebŏls have experimented with different varieties of dual-ownership structures (Chang 2003). Second, ownership and control are fused instead of separated, unlike in many guanxi corporations in greater China and in Japanese keiretsu groups. Although managerial professionalisation has progressed rapidly in Korea, chaebŏl families have actively educated male heirs in preparation to succeed their fathers as CEOs and/or chairmen and neutralise external criticism of nepotism, such as Samsung’s heir-apparent Lee Jaeyong’s education at Harvard University. Unlike in North American or European family businesses, it is not uncommon to see many chaebŏl heirs attending or having graduated from Ivy League schools in the United States, not to mention prestigious Korean and Japanese undergraduate programs. Third, chaebŏls have increased the market value of their companies through massive diversification and tunnelling. Diversification was a bulwark or insurance against state hostility to chaebŏls in the form of destruction or confiscation (i.e. no property right protection). In fact, chaebŏls such as Yulsan, Kukje, and Daewoo disappeared during the first and second military regimes and even under the civilian government, in addition to seven chaebŏls that were closed down after the inauguration of the first military regime. The chaebŏl logic was that the government would not confiscate their property if they were big in size and highly diversified into industries such as automobiles, textiles, and even military (E.M. Kim 1997). Tunnelling is an illegal means of manipulating the price of chaebŏl holding company stocks by actively buying out unrelated firms through mergers and acquisitions (M&As). If unrelated firms are bought 299

Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

out, chaebŏl’s stock prices go up artificially with market rumours about potential revenue growth through new acquisitions (Baek et al. 2006). These practices are either illegal or uncommon in other East Asian countries. Fourth, unlike other conglomerate groups in neighbouring countries, chaebŏl groups relied heavily on labour exploitation for profit, using both workplace patriarchy and police crackdowns on militant labour unrest. Labour unrest was an anticipated response to harsh working conditions. Often, these organisations functioned as sweatshops or prison labour camps, where workers from the countryside worked in often unhealthy and poorly ventilated workspaces, eating and sleeping on the same premises. Wages were twenty to forty cents an hour, far below recommended rates for factory workers in export processing zones of many developing countries (Hart-Landsberg 1993; Lie 2000; Pirie 2008). Workers in Korean chaebŏls were denied union rights, minimum wage laws, or lifetime employment during the military regime, while labour union movements instigated by the self-cremation of Jeon Taeil in 1970 were quashed by brute police force. What distinguished the chaebŏl from other family businesses in East Asia was the suppression of one of the world’s most militant labour movements, either unionised or unorganised, arguably resembling a massacre of one social class by another. To this point, labour strikes reached a record high of more than 3,600 incidents in 1987 (E.M. Kim 1997). Finally, the chaebŏl has maintained a huge network of interlocking ownership, where the financial firm in the secondary finance market (e.g. insurance, stock brokerage, leasing, credit cards) and former holding companies (i.e. holding companies before the 1961 military coup) in general trading, construction, and electronics (e.g. Samsung Mulsan, Hyundai Construction, Samsung Electronics) own one another’s stock to protect ownership of the chaebŏl group by one family. This system of mutual stock ownership is different from that of the keiretsu in Japan or guanxi firms in greater China; the use of financial and former holding firms within the chaebŏl is to protect the chaebŏl family, in contrast with the ban on owning keiretsu-style main banks or guanxi-style holding companies (Chang 2003; Oh and Park 2001). The birth of the mafia state and the chaebŏl after the 1961 military coup led by General Park Chung Hee created a new business culture of what we call ‘credible threats’, contrasting with the Anglo-American or Japanese culture of credible commitment (see Williamson 1983; North 1993). The culture of credible threats is the third element of the Korean post-war economic miracle. Credible commitment works in two ways. First, in the Anglo-American tradition, formal contractual relations in the market and between firms reduce room for opportunism. But given that contractual relations in the UK and the US cannot be institutionalised without administrative fiat or organisational (or sometimes legal) safeguarding, actual inclination to opportunism looms large. To offset opportunism rampant in the market, Anglo-American firms use institutions of administrative fiat to induce credible commitment between contractual parties. Second, in the Japanese tradition, room for opportunism is always very high given the relative absence of formal contractual relations in business practice. But given that Japanese business networks are based on long-term trust rather than short-term contracts, actual inclination to opportunism is surprisingly rare between business partners and firms, thus leading to credible commitment between liable business parties. Either system of inducing credible commitment, whether based on task or job specialization or structural stochasticity (e.g. shop-floor communication between blue- and white-collar workers), would be an acceptable institutional solution to the problem of transaction costs (Aoki 1994; Nooteboom 2001). But in post-coup Korea, neither system of prompting credible commitment worked. For one thing, Korean business and economic actors did not possess functional specificities to lead to high levels of organisational (both technological and procedural) standardisation. They also failed to build a business network that was based on a long-term trust. Structural stochasticity, 300

Economic miracle

or effective management-labour communication, did not exist within such networks because the actors lacked a sufficient level of tacit knowledge to run organisations constrained by qualitative, if not functional, standardisation. In a nutshell, Korean business firms were organised and run under the principle of informal solidarity and group norms, although they tried to quickly learn and apply American-style technological know-how and work procedures (see Oh and Varcin 2010). Amid the welter, both military rulers and chaebŏl owners agreed upon a new rule of using credible threats in the form of brute force to realise organisational goals. Between the state and the chaebŏl, credible threats worked to induce the chaebŏl’s commitment to economic growth and payments (both legal and illegal) to the state, and the punishment if either failed was to close down the chaebŏl (i.e. withdrawal of state protection of chaebŏl’s property rights). Between labour/suppliers and the chaebŏl, credible threats worked in a fashion to induce labour/supplier commitment to economic growth and sacrifice (e.g. supplier bribery to the chaebŏl, low salaries for workers) for the chaebŏl, and punishment in the case of failure, such as destroying the supplier firm or laying off workers in large numbers (Oh 1999). In order to institutionalise credible threats, both the state and the chaebŏl routinely punished inexorable partners. For example, 1,653 mergers and acquisitions (M&As) of small firms by the chaebŏl groups were reported throughout the 1980s. Although all these M&As were illegitimate under the M&A law, only one case was ruled illegal by the court (Chung and Yang 1992). The final element of the Korean economic miracle was technological and organisational innovation, a key feature of the economic success throughout the developmental period. In order for real GDP to grow quickly, developing states need to secure either momentous labour productivity or technological innovation, whether radical or incremental (see Tsuru 1996; Eichengreen et al. 2012). For Korea, labour productivity was not always something that the government could quickly increase due to various structural difficulties and constraints. Fundamentally, the state faced low levels of skill attainment among young rural boys and girls who were almost forcibly shifted from rice paddies to urban factories. Educating the new urban proletariat class required substantial investment in education and long-term training programs, and the military state had no intention of doing either. Instead, the state and the chaebŏl spent enormous effort on technological and organisational innovation (or the T factor of GDP growth). To many Anglo-American economists and innovation scholars, this option would have been more difficult for Korea than that of increasing labour productivity (the L factor of GDP growth). However, Korean firms had the option of copying to improve their T factor quickly. Copying and piracy had occurred widely from the 1960s to the 1990s before Korea joined the WTO (World Trade Organization). Korea was fortunate due to its close proximity to Japan, where highly sophisticated technologies, ranging from textiles and construction to shipbuilding, electronics, and automobiles, were available for either licensing or outright copying (L. Kim 1997). An anecdote regarding the effect of the T factor on Korean GDP growth includes that of Samsung Electronics during the 1970s. In the early days of electronics development at Samsung, the chaebŏl successfully garnered a loan from the Long Term Credit Bank of Japan. With the borrowed money, the firm rented a two-story house in the Tokyo neighbourhood of Akihabara, a well-known shopping district for the most advanced Japanese electronic goods. In the house, Samsung technicians bought and disassembled Japanese electronic goods (mostly household appliances such as refrigerators, washing machines, range ovens, and TVs) to uncover secrets behind Japanese electronic technology (i.e. reverse engineering). Although they were patented in Japan and elsewhere, that proved to be ineffective in Korea. In addition to outright piracy, the Korean chaebŏl also actively sought licensing opportunities with Japanese and American companies with the hopes of learning both standardised and 301

Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

tacit knowledge from advanced firms. Licensing is a fast way of learning advanced technologies in a legitimate way, although it is vulnerable to knowledge theft by licensees (Davis 2008). In return for chaebŏls’ active T-factor improvements, the state provided R&D subsidies in tandem with a silent negligence over patent infringement. In less than four decades since the 1960s, Korean chaebŏl firms defeated Japanese competitors in steel (POSCO became the fifth biggest global steel company by the 1980s), shipbuilding (Korean shipbuilders are the second largest shipbuilding country in the world), household appliances, electronic hardware and semiconductors (among the top ten global semiconductor suppliers, two are Korean – Samsung Electronics and SK Hynix – while just one is Japanese), and mobile phone markets. Electronics constitutes one of the most fascinating success cases of the chaebŏl, in that Samsung and LG Electronics alone make more annual revenue and profit than what all Japanese electronics firms generate combined (Chang 2011). The T-factor growth story is a secret formula for export-led development strategy and cannot be easily emulated by other developing nations that do not have neighbouring countries with advanced technologies for patent pirates. To this extent, China is a case in point. With Korea, Taiwan, and Japan right next to the mainland proper, it could easily emulate Korea’s development through its own version of export-led development schemes. This is also why countries like the Philippines could not develop as quickly as China or Korea, despite the fact that the island nation was under the US Cold War protection program: it simply didn’t have any neighbours that were technologically advanced. Be that as it may, Samsung now holds the second largest number of patents, second only to IBM in the US (US Patent and Trademark Office 2014). Despite its phenomenal track record of R&D and patenting, various rivals in the market, including Apple and Microsoft, have sued Samsung for patent infringement. While this indirectly illustrates how the chaebŏl is least innovative with its own Korean version of ingenuity, it remains an organisational structure that is extremely efficient in learning others’ technologies in a short period of time. In this sense, the chaebŏl is probably the most efficient learning organisation in the world.

Explaining and understanding the miracle: rent-sharing Having explained in detail the four elements of the Korean economic miracle, we now present our understanding of how the Korean economic institution achieved this miracle underpinned by the mafia state, the chaebŏl, an organisational culture of credible threats, and a miraculous record of technological and institutional innovation. The purpose of this explanation is not only to produce some generalisations, but also to help readers understand the Korean case for a broader interpretation of global capitalism since the 1500s. The central concept we employ is rent-sharing, or state-business relations that produce rent and concomitantly institutionalise the way rent is distributed between them. In other words, rent-sharing will explain why these four elements surfaced in Korea but not in other developing countries during the post-war years. The concept is particularly useful for this chapter because other competing concepts that attempt to explain the Korean miracle, such as the free market, crony capitalism with rent-seeking behaviour, authority structures, institutions (including transaction cost economics, failure of rationality and rational choice institutions, legitimacy and organisational isomorphism, endogenous institutional bases and outcomes of great transformations, and ideational factors of interest-based politics), and the developmental state, have neglected its dominant presence in Korean political economy. All these competing concepts can explain one or two elements of the miracle, but are unable to identify or explain all four, thus suggesting a lack of understanding rather than of explanations. 302

Economic miracle

All types of capitalist development begin from a state of absence: the absence of the free market; the absence of freedom of choice; and the absence of private property protection by the state. Korea’s economic development is no exception. Throughout the colonial period and the subsequent dictatorship by President Rhee and the military, private property protection was in the grey. During land reform during the early 1950s, for example, the state actively destroyed private ownership of land by a few wealthy cliques, allowing actual land tillers and peasants to claim ownership. The urban bourgeois class, epitomised by the chaebŏl families, who owned colonial properties that Japanese imperialists left behind after liberation, faced abrupt confiscation by the new state. During the Rhee regime and military dictatorship, the state’s forced extortion of private property in exchange for protection was also rampant (Mo and Weingast 2013). In the absence of institutionalised property protection, despite the fact that private property has been legitimised, protection still awaits either to be purchased from the market or institutionalised by the public sector. Throughout history, private property protection has never been privatised systematically on a long-term basis. Instead, the birth of the state that officially provides property protection services for fees (e.g. tax) has been common in most civilised societies (Weber 2013; North 1993; Konrad and Skaperdas 1997). But before modern politics was democratised, private property protection by the state has often been carried out in a predatory manner, reducing the overall welfare of an economic unit. Some economists argue that predatory means of providing protection to the private property increases community welfare, although total economic output will be still lower than capitalist democracies where the state acts as a representative of voters who are equally divided into property owners and non-owners (Moselle and Polak 2001). Commitment by threats and fear is always less productive than commitment by freedom of choice. However, the Korean path to development overturns this economic view because (a) the Korean predatory or mafia state not only exceeded growth rates of other developing countries during the same period, but (b) Korea also continues to use credible threats, such as incarceration and worker surveillance, in chaebŏl private property protection despite democratisation and people’s freedom of choice. As we will show in this chapter, the main thrust of relying on credible threats during and after development is its unprecedented utility in promoting learning among people and incremental innovation for sustainable development. In order to understand the concept of rent-sharing, we first propose to compare it with a more familiar common concept, rent-seeking. Unlike creating individual wealth without adding new wealth to GDP through both legitimate and illegitimate lobbying (i.e. rent-seeking), rentsharing increases both group wealth (e.g. monopolies) and GDP through extortion (or other illegitimate bribery) to promote and realise group interests. How this works is rather simple. Typical predatory states that maximise extortion (i.e. rent-seeking) would abandon one community for another when state revenues run out. If a new community they can conquer and extort money from has a bigger revenue basis than the previous one, they would abandon the latter for the former (e.g. migratory predatory states). They can also expand their territory to a new community (e.g. imperialistic states). If such options are absent, as in the Korean mafia state, the only possibility of sustaining the mafia state on a long-term basis without drying up its revenue basis is through endogenous GDP growth. If this were not possible, as was the case of the Rhee regime, the predatory state would be supplanted by another one via military coup (e.g. vicious cycles of coups as in Latin American and African developing states). The military is the backbone of the predatory state, which constantly demands more budget than previous fiscal years. If the system of extortion cannot satisfy this demand, military leaders will organise coups to overthrow the incumbent government. 303

Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

The only possibility of raising GDP through rent-seeking is increasing both labour productivity and introducing rapid technological innovation, while also pursuing monopolies by lobbying the mafia state. In other words, monopolies like chaebŏls had to create national wealth through both L and T factors and pay off exponentially growing amounts of extortions to the mafia state. As explained above, increasing the L factor takes a long time and requires both national and private-sector education reform. Therefore, the chaebŏl exploited the labour force while the mafia state banned all forms of company-, industrial-, or national-level union activities through government labour unions. However, we have also seen that the chaebŏl could easily ensure T factor growth through Japan and the US, either under licensing agreements or piracy. But why did the military junta in 1961 suddenly pursue rent-sharing instead of rent-seeking? Where did they spend the money that was extorted from chaebŏls? Introducing rentsharing, while stopping the vicious cycle of rent-seeking and coups, into the Korean system of development demanded several complicated processes. First and foremost, endogenous factors loomed large. Both predators (civilian and military dictators) and property holders (chaebŏl families) had no trust-based interactions, although they shared experiences and knowledge gained from Japanese imperialists (i.e. they knew how to operate their organisations using Japanese institutional norms and complementarities). Due to this lack of trust between the military and the chaebŏl, the only protection available was to make chaebŏls too big to collapse, or face punishment by the military. Diversification using borrowed money from the curb market at an extraordinarily high interest rate progressed frenetically during the 1970s (E.M. Kim 1997; Oh 1999). In addition, aligning with foreign (especially Japanese) firms through technological licensing also made selected chaebŏl firms look legitimate and strong in the eyes of the military (i.e. mimetic isomorphism). Chaebŏls could raise productivity rapidly through diversification using Japanese institutional norms and complementarities, including job rotation, functional versus malleable skills, and lifetime employment. On a shop-floor level, technological complementarity was achieved through Japanese-style technological complementarity (i.e. J equilibrium), whereas on a macro-institutional level, institutional complementarity was garnered through Japanesestyle complementarity between the state bureaucracy (including banks) and the chaebŏl. Lack of trust in Korean society, however, made the chaebŏl fundamentally different from the Japanese keiretsu, as the former intensified ownership and control concentration despite economic openness through export-oriented development. Second, exogenous factors were also critical. Unlike the previous predatory state led by Rhee, the 1961 military state had experienced devastating modern warfare and understood that the communist threat from North Korea, China, and the Soviet Union was credible and real. This means that the military regime in the South had to be able to compete with the North in terms of equal or better economic and military power. The Rhee state wrongfully believed that the US would always help its predatory state with massive military and economic aid, when in fact the US withdrew its forces from the South right before the war broke out. With US commitment to South Korean security questionable throughout the developmental period, the need for a self-subsistent military was a paramount priority for mafia-state leaders (Mo and Weingast 2013). Therefore, rent-sharing was a far better strategy than outright rent-seeking for the new mafia state to sustain itself, while it also suppressed other smaller groups of violence that could be mobilised toward another possible coup (e.g. the military, the police, guerrilla or terrorist groups, and local mafia). The US also understood the North Korean threat after losing more than 36,000 American lives and began applying the most favoured nation (MFN) status to South Korea in a similar fashion as it did to Western Europe and Japan following the Second World War (Cumings 1984; Woo 1991). Korea began export-led development only after the war, a timely 304

Economic miracle

plan of expansion for the chaebŏl, which copied much of the export-led developmental strategy of the Japanese keiretsu. In order to curb other groups of violence from mobilising into another coup, the military spent extorted money to either co-opt or extinguish them from the field of violence. The military regime executed leaders of the local mafia who were closely connected to the Rhee regime, disbanded the entire organisation, and later co-opted it into its new violence segment under the military and police control (Porteux 2013). Some key players in the military coup were also removed from government positions, jailed, or executed, such as Hyung-Wook Kim, a former KCIA (Korea Central Intelligence Agency) chief. Simultaneously, the government began spending huge amounts of money to manage the military. The total military budget during the first military regime remained close to five percent of GDP, or thirty-one percent of total government expenditure on average between 1974 and 1987 (Ministry of National Defense 2013). This may offer just a glimpse as to how much illicit money the military may have raised and spent during the same period for their own corporatist benefits and perks. Miraculously, rent-sharing in Korea worked as a combination of Japanese institutional norms and complementarities, lack of trust (or credible commitment), chaebŏl’s own pursuit of growth through diversification, technology/productivity assistance from Japan and the US, and exportled developmental strategies at the behest corporate buyers, and consumers to blockade communism from the Korean Peninsula. The winners of Korean style rent-sharing were the military rulers, government bureaucrats, chaebŏl families, chaebŏl professional managers, chaebŏl subcontractors, exporters, and rich, government-subsidised farmers; the losers were the peasants, urban workers, pro-democracy fighters, and labour union organisers who were massacred by state forces on 19 April 1960 (April Revolution), 16 October 1979, and 18 May 1980 (Gwangju Massacre), to list a few. Rent-sharing can be easily explained in economic terms, but understanding it requires different levels of cognitive and intellectual strength. Indeed, Korean rent-sharing has not always been negative. We see that it took the same path as that of European-style development and modernisation, which required upheavals in order to establish the successful political economic regime of capitalist democracy (Lie 2004).

Future of the miracle The second military regime (1979–1987) was unable to last longer than the first. Continuous economic development mobilised the masses more than ever toward nation-wide democratisation movements, which included intellectuals, university students, outlawed labour union organisers, and even white-collar workers at chaebŏl firms. Democratisation in 1987 and the subsequent election of the first civilian president in 1992 signified the victory of the capitalist market economy and its juggernaut, the chaebŏl, in Korea’s history of modernisation and economic development. The chaebŏl’s strategy of ‘too big to fail’ proved to outwit the brute force of the mafia state. Coase’s theorem gives us some clues to understand this seemingly ironic outcome. If there is a dog in the flat next door that barks early in the morning and wakes up all the residents on the same floor, complaints from building tenants would not stop the dog owner from disowning the dog, as no law has yet been institutionalised to penalise causing public nuisance (or perhaps the dog owner is a beloved daughter of a neighbourhood mafia boss who would send horse heads to those threatening to report his daughter to the police). Coase suggested that money would resolve this issue: a rich building tenant can offer a price for the dog that she cannot refuse. The rich neighbour can then safely put the dog away after buying it from the owner (Coase 1937; for the dog anecdote, see Mankiw 2014: 210). 305

Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

In a similar vein, the chaebŏl has technically put the menacing mafia state in Korea to death. The monopoly of violence by the capitalist democratic state is not complete unless its capitalist class buys out competing groups of violence (e.g. the military, the mafia, the police, bandits, rebels, terrorist groups) from state apparatuses (Mo and Weingast 2013). The chaebŏl has not only grown too big to fail, but they can now financially co-opt and manipulate holders of violence and power for their own benefit as well. It is not a shocking revelation in Korea that Samsung and other leading chaebŏl groups continuously hire ex-judges and state attorneys to protect the chaebŏl family from state indictments for any wrongdoing (Yonhap 2012). The end of the developmental state in Korea effectively opened up a new era of the instrumental state, whose biggest beneficiary is the chaebŏl. The chaebŏl derives its legitimacy from the mafia state itself, a crucial reason why it failed to garner legitimacy from the Korean people (e.g. workers, consumers, conscientious elements, intellectuals) despite the economic miracle. Although it was the chaebŏl that defeated the mafia state in the fight over control of the private property protection market, its lack of legitimacy within the new Korean democratic state has forced the chaebŏl to actively buy institutional raison d’être from civilian bureaucrats, their bosses, elected politicians, and intellectuals. Today, a new form of state-business collusion under the democratic government is not over the issue of property protection; it is over the question of the chaebŏl’s institutional legitimacy. Globalisation, the 1997 financial crisis, widening class polarisation, and increasing economic concentration by the few chaebŏl groups have combined to threaten chaebŏl legitimacy in Korea, especially from the perspective of disgruntled Korean voters over illegal ownership-succession plots by chaebŏls to turn over property to biological heirs (Ilyo Weekly 2014). Neoliberal policies forced upon the Korean government after the 1997 crisis also worked against the chaebŏl, the latter of which promotes concentration and monopoly more than free market competition, accounting transparency, and managerial professionalism (Kang 2002; Siegel 2007). Consequently, the Korean political economy still suffers from a lack of trust among business actors in the market. Rent-sharing is now replaced by rent-seeking as we do not have the creation of substantial GDP wealth. In fact, post-miracle Korean GDP annual growth rate has remained less than six per cent annually since 2003, and has fallen below the three per cent level in recent years. Rent-seeking is a means of prolonging chaebŏl corporate governance (i.e. family control) despite the democratic institution of guaranteed private property protection. Corrupt politicians, state bureaucrats, and chaebŏl owners have worked closely for this purpose. As such, we can argue that rent-seeking has been responsible for the lacklustre performance of Korean innovation (both technological and institutional) in the 2010s. Despite their splendid and sustained track records of radical innovation in the 1970s and 1980s, Korean chaebŏl groups do not own any world-class technology, although Samsung owns patents that are second only to IBM in quantity (Hankyung 2013). Although Korean scientists publish research and are ranked number six in the world in terms of citations, no Korean universities are ranked in the top thirty in terms of scientific reputation. Consequently, chaebŏl groups have been buying research results from North American, European, and Japanese scientists, while Korean scientists are rapidly forming a fourth group of rent-seekers who embezzle government research funding for their own personal use (Oh 2013). Even worse, Korean society has suffered from serial man-made disasters since the beginning of the rent-seeking era in 1987. Starting from the ferry sinking in 1993 that killed 292 passengers on board, democratic and civilian Korea witnessed annual disasters that have included the Seongsu bridge collapse which killed thirty-two people in 1994, the downfall of Sampung Department Store in which 502 perished in 1995, the gas explosion of the Daegu subway line that killed 101 people in 1995, and most recently, the 2014 Sewol ferry sinking that killed 213 passengers. 306

Economic miracle

All these accidents had roots in systematic corruption within bureaucratic supervision and regulation. Many bureaucrats and company owners were found guilty of receiving and offering bribes for bypassing strict safety inspections to maximise corporate profits (Han 1998; Yee 1998; Yadav 2014). As such tragedies have become more commonplace, the average Korean citizen has cast doubts regarding the capability of the civilian government to manage safety and security. The future of the Korean economic miracle is not as rosy as some may think. Although the mafia state has been dismantled either by pro-democracy movements by citizens and students or by the chaebŏl, which successfully bought out the mafia from the state, the Korean state is still hampered by rent-seeking behaviours of politicians, bureaucrats, and business leaders. Rentseeking in the post-miracle era disrupts the process of trust-building necessary to replace the culture of ‘credible threats’ with that of ‘credible commitment’. Why Korea, despite its global status as a developed democratic country and member of the OECD and the DAC (Development Assistance Committee), cannot establish a capitalist democratic culture of credible commitment is something that demands further exploration. It is for this very reason that Williamson and North’s new institutionalism cannot easily explain the Korean experience (cf. Mo and Weingast 2013). As credible threats no longer exist, moral hazard is rampant in Korean business organisations and bureaucracies (i.e. both room for and inclination to opportunism are high). This does not meant that threats no longer exist in Korea’s political economy. In fact, the state continuously uses the North Korean threat to crack down on dissidents and radical union leaders. However, the state can no longer wield formidable power over the chaebŏl, which now exercises more threats over its workers than ever. Although GDP growth has stalled at below three per cent, globalisation (i.e. integration with the world economy) has progressed at a high speed. The effect of rapid globalisation for the Korean economy is growing inequality and class polarisation among the populace, while ethnic enclaves and segregation are much more visible than before. Class polarisation and inequality partly derive from the failure of indigenous small businesses that could not compete with incoming foreign direct investment in the service sector (e.g. shopping malls, financial services, and ITrelated services). Ethnic segregation is a result of the decline of the manufacturing sector in the country, where blue-collar workers in the manufacturing sector and manual labourers in the service sector have discontinued economic participation due to the income effect. The issue of chaebŏl reform will continue to fetter the development of Korea’s political economy beyond the economic miracle. The chaebŏl no longer seem to generate national economic wealth through the T factor, while Korean labour productivity is not increasing as fast as it needs to. Korean corporate workers work the second-longest number of hours, whereas their income is the lowest among all OECD countries (OECD 2014). Creativity remains a central question to the future viability of the Korean economy. With current chaebŏl organisations, creativity remains sparse, although it was the most efficient form of learning and catch-up of all industrial organisations during the miracle years. This suggests that corporate Korea should experiment with varieties of organisational forms that allow for diversity, multiculturalism, and organisational freedom (i.e. freedom to pursue individual goals within organisations). As such, chaebŏl reform must include not only corporate governance reform, but organisational transformation as well.

Conclusion In this chapter, we identified four important elements of the Korean economic miracle that surfaced between 1965 and 1987. During this period, the Korean economy recorded annual GDP growth rates in excess of eight per cent. But unlike neoclassical explanations, we argued 307

Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

that the Korean miracle was marked by: (1) a mafia/predatory state that espoused GDP growth with escalating class polarisation; (2) chaebŏl groups that could not survive without political protection extended to them by the mafia/predatory state; (3) a social and institutional culture that could not maintain or organise human business and social relations without resorting to credible threats amid rampant distrust among organisational members; and (4) semi-world-class process (institutional) and technological innovations through parodying. We also argued that the theoretical principle of the country’s economic growth was rent-sharing, an institutional process of engendering phenomenal growth based on state-business collusion and credible threats. We showed that rent-sharing was fundamentally different from rent-seeking due to actual economic growth through corruption. However, we also noticed that credible threats had discouraged creativity and innovation in the Korean economy despite political democratisation and economic development, presenting a bleak picture for the future of Korea’s economic miracle. We also see that the Korean economy suffers from outright rent-seeking behaviour by economic and political actors despite democratisation and economic development. When the economy is in the hand of the chaebŏl, which remains too big to fail, economic development is hampered because credible threats are not replaced with credible commitment. We need to explore when and why credible commitments are made possible. The lesson of the Korean economic miracle is twofold: the global capitalist regime that started from the 1500s was critical in shaping the exogenous basis of industrial transformation, although the endogenous basis of an economic system that was founded on the principle of the credible threat was equally pivotal in bringing about the miracle. At the same time, globalisation in the same world system has substantially delimited the creative potential of the Korean miracle in much the same way it has curtailed Japan’s efforts to hammer out creative solutions to its prolonged recession, following a period of high-powered growth and mass consumption. Thus going forward, there will be great academic and practical interest in how to improve the relationship between credible threats and commitments via theory-building and empirical testing.

Glossary Chaebŏl: A South Korean business conglomerate that is owned and controlled by a single family. Chaebŏl literally means a family clique with colossal wealth. Although it originated from the pre-war Japanese zaibatsu, the post-war Korean chaebŏl is significantly different from the former, as its ownership and control structure are fused without a zaibatsu-style holding company. Nor is the chaebŏl allowed to maintain a main bank system, which was common within the Japanese zaibatsu and post-war Japanese keiretsu. Credible commitment: In all business transactions, no verbal commitment is credible, until such commitments to a preferred strategic move in business deals can be discerned as credible with additional safeguarding mechanisms. Business reputation, written contracts, burning bridges, hostage exchanges, building credibility through teamwork, and finally the institutionalisation of the commitment through state legislatures and legal enforcements are such safeguarding mechanisms. Among these, the institutionalisation of the commitment is the safest mechanism in the modern capitalist state. Credible threat: In all business transactions, no verbal commitment is credible, until such commitments to a preferred strategic move in business deals can be discerned as credible with additional threat mechanisms, such as the code of honour that is often employed by the mafia. The threat used in business transactions becomes credible if it is either informally or formally institutionalised as in the case of the mafia and the mafia state. 308

Economic miracle

Developmental state: The developmental state became a widely used and understood concept as a consequence of Chalmers Johnson’s seminal analysis of Japan’s post-war economic reconstruction. In Johnson’s original formulation the developmental state had a number of features, including competent state agencies and carefully calibrated industrial policies. The key quality that makes a state developmental is its capacity of planning a development process rather than relying on market forces to determine the optimal allocation of resources. Unlike “market rational” states, which are concerned with establishing the rules of the economic game, the “plan rational” state seeks to formulate and pursue substantive social and economic goals. Guanxi: Social networks in China that are established and maintained to nullify or bypass institutionalised credible threats directed against particular business transactions. Guanxi networks are created to neutralise such credible threats and defend private, individual, and group interests in business. Guanxi networks with the most social capital and financial resources will ultimately win business contracts despite legal and informal threats and difficulties. East Asian Tigers: Following the footsteps of the Japanese economic miracle that heavily relied on the state’s macroeconomic policies with its plan-rational developmental strategies and goals, South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore succeeded in bringing about rapid economic and social developments with their strong states, symbolised as tigers. These economies share similar cultural background, although they are geographically apart in Northeast and Southeast Asia. Economic miracle: If the gross domestic product (GDP) demonstrates a growth of more than eight per cent for more than ten consecutive years, the phenomenon becomes dramatic or unexpected. In modern economic history, the industrial revolution in the UK was the first good example of the miracle, while the post-war recovery in Germany and Japan was another. In recent years, the miracles in Asian Tigers and China are additional examples. However, continued macroeconomic expansions of eight per cent or more for more than two decades have not been witnessed in economic history. Institutional complementarity: All economic organizations face two kinds of uncertainties: localised technological uncertainties and institutional uncertainties. Technological uncertainties affect organisations within a sector in a given time period, while institutional uncertainties affect the entire industry and the economy. In Aoki’s original analysis of the Japanese keiretsu, the institutional uncertainty had three layers: the pattern of dependence of a member firm within a keiretsu on other member firms, member firms’ reliance on keiretsu main banks, and the main banks’ dependence on the state banks. If the method of resolving technological uncertainty (e.g. bottom-up communication in Japan) is complementary with keiretsu institutions with their main bank system, institutional complementarity is achieved within the keiretsu. The keiretsu institutional complementarity can be achieved with the state institutions to resolve various types of keiretsu-wide and nation-wide economic problems (e.g. state banking system with “window guidance”). Kereitsu: The post-war Japanese conglomerate business organisations that spearheaded the postwar economic miracle in Japan in tandem with the developmental state. The keiretsu has no owning family or holding company, unlike the pre-war Japanese zaibatsu. Instead, it is owned and controlled by institutions including member firms, main banks, and the presidential council (shachōkai). The keiretsu may be vertical (intra-market) or horizontal (inter-market) depending on their market position in the economy. Vertical keiretsus form a supply chain for one product in one market, whereas horizontal keiretsus serve different markets. During the peak of the Japanese economic development, six inter-market keiretsus 309

Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

existed, each with several intra-market hierarchies. Nowadays, the keiretsu is more or less dysfunctional or dissolved. Parodying: An economy that is in a catch-up mode of development, technological innovation through piracy or parodying is the cheapest and fastest way of increasing GDP growth without excessive investments. Parodying through outright copying, licensing, or reverse engineering has been common in the case of Japanese, South Korean, and Taiwanese economic development. Product lifecycle theory predicted transfer of technologies from a declining country to a developmental country, although the prediction did not explain the process of parodying that is necessary in technology transfers. Rent-seeking: An economic behaviour taken by individuals, corporations, and even the state to increase their wealth without affecting any GDP growth. If business owners lobby bureaucrats and politicians to obtain business permits or eradicate competitors from the market, GDP actually decreases despite their wealth accumulation. Rent-seeking is a quick way of accumulating wealth without contributing to the nation’s capital size, labour productivity, or technological innovation. If policemen collect bribes from traffic violators, the nation’s GDP does not change, or might even diminish, although the wealth of corrupt policemen increases. Rent-sharing: If rent-seeking is organised with an on-going scheme that requires future payments to be constantly increasing exponentially, rent-seekers will have to plan strategic moves to contribute substantially to a nation’s capital size, labour productivity, and technological innovation. If corrupt politicians demand bribes from business owners who want business permits, the former can require the latter to pay annual briberies that would increase automatically every year in exponential rates. The latter may then have to formulate growth plans to meet the state’s demand in bribery payments, causing actual GDP growth. Rentsharing therefore explains why monopolies and oligopolies sometimes can induce high GDP growth for developing economies. Too big to fail: One way of neutralising state hostility against private property is to enlarge the sheer size of the property to threaten a “deadweight loss,” or economic inefficiencies caused by a large-scale capitalist divestment that would quickly decrease supply in the market, causing price hikes. In the case of South Korea, the chaebŏl used this option to co-opt the military state that tried to legitimise its regime by high GDP growth and full employment. The chaebŏl provided both to the economy, although simultaneously it threatened a pullout from the market if the state taxed it too much, either formally or informally. Most importantly, the chaebŏl also demanded state bailout plans when it faced financial difficulties deriving from rapid expansion and diversification through mergers and acquisitions. Tunnelling: An unethical business behaviour by corporate owners involving transfers of corporate wealth from one corporation to another. In an attempt to list a new corporation in the stock market, the owning family uses their listed company to buy goods and services from the new company in massive quantities to artificially increase the latter’s revenues. In another example, owners of a successful corporation transfer its corporate wealth to an undisclosed offshore corporation in order to avoid taxes. Artificially increasing owners’ salaries and dividends is also considered tunnelling, as well as their attempt to increase their stock values by purchasing unrelated but lucrative firms.

References Aoki, M. (1990) ‘Toward an economic model of the Japanese firm’, Journal of Economic Literature, 28(1): 1–27. 310

Economic miracle

Aoki, M. (1994) ‘The contingent governance of teams: analysis of institutional complementarity’, International Economic Review, 35(3): 657–76. Bae, K.H., and Form, W. (1986) ‘Payment strategy in South Korea’s advanced economic sector’, American Sociological Review, 51(1): 120–31. Baek, J.S., Kang, J.K, and Lee, I. (2006) ‘Business groups and tunneling: evidence from private securities offerings by Korean chaebols’, The Journal of Finance 61(5): 2415–49. Buchanan, J.M., Tollison, T.D., and Tullock, G. (1980) Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society, College Station: Texas A&M University Press. Campbell, T.L., and Keys, P.Y. (2002) ‘Corporate governance in South Korea: the chaebol experience’, Journal of Corporate Finance, 8: 373–91. Chang, S. (2003) ‘Ownership structure, expropriation, and performance of group-affiliated companies in Korea’, The Academy of Management Journal, 46(2): 238–53. Chang, S. (2011) Sony vs Samsung: the inside story of the electronics giants’ battle for global supremacy, Singapore: John Wiley & Sons. Chung, B.G., and Yang, Y.S. (1992) Hankuk chaebol bumun ui gyungje bunseok [An economic analysis of Korean chaebols], Seoul: KDI. Coase, R.H. (1937) ‘The nature of the firm’, economica, 4(16): 386–405. Cumings, B. (1984) ‘The origins and development of the northeast Asian political economy: industrial sectors, product cycles, and political consequences’, International Organization, 38(1): 1–40. Davis, L. (2008) ‘Licensing strategies of the new “intellectual property vendors”’, California Review Management, 50(2): 6–30. Eichengreen, B., Perkins, D.H., and Shin, K. (2012) From miracle to maturity: the growth of the Korean economy, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Centre. Gambetta, D. (2000) ‘Mafia: the price of distrust’, in D. Gambetta (ed.) Trust: making and breaking cooperative relations, available at . Accessed 25 June 2015. Ghoshal, S. (1988) ‘Environmental scanning in Korean firms: organizational isomorphism in action’, Journal of International Business Studies, 19(1): 69–86. Han, S. (1998) ‘The Korean path to modernization and risk society’, Korea Journal, 38(1): 5–27. Hankyung (2013) ‘Korea falls from number two to 11 in technology competitiveness . . . best in R&D success rates but last in commercialization’ Hankyung News, 06 June, viewed 14 September 2014, . Hart-Landsberg, M. (1993) The rush to development: economic change and political struggle in South Korea, New York: Monthly Review Press. Hattori, T. (1987) ‘Formation of the Korean business elite during the era of rapid economic growth’, The Developing Economies, 25(4): 346–62. Hattori, T. (1997) ‘Chaebol-style enterprise development in Korea’, The Developing Economics, 35(4): 458–77. Hsu, J.Y., and Saxenian, A. (2000) ‘The limits of guanxi capitalism: transnational collaboration between Taiwan and the USA’, Environment and Planning A, 32(11): 1991–2006. Ilyo Weekly (2014) ‘Chaebol management succession . . . wealth succession without social approval, a league of their own’, Ilyo Weekly, 27 May, viewed 14 September 2014, . Johnson, C. (1982) MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925–1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Kang, D.C. (2002) ‘Bad loans to good friends: money politics and the developmental state in South Korea’, International Organization, 56(1): 177–207. Khanna, T., and Yafeh, Y. (2007) ‘Business groups in emerging markets: paragons or parasites?’, Journal of Economic Literature, 45(2): 331–72. Kim, E.M. (1997) Big business, strong state: collusion and conflict in South Korean development, 1960–1990, Albany: State University of New York Press. Kim, H., Hoskisson, R.E., and Hong, J. (2004) ‘The evolution and restructuring of diversified business groups in emerging markets: the lessons from chaebols in Korea’, Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 21: 25–48. Kim, L. (1997) Imitation to innovation: the dynamics of Korea’s technological learning, Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business Review Press. Konrad, K.A., and Skaperdas, S. (1997) ‘Credible threats in extortion’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 33: 23–39. 311

Ingyu Oh and Hannah Jun

Koo, H. (2001) Korean workers: the culture and politics of class formation, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Krueger, A.O. (1974) ‘The political economy of the rent-seeking society’, The American Economic Review, 64(3): 291–303. Lew, S.C., Choi, W.Y., and Wang, H.S. (2011) ‘Confucian ethics and the spirit of capitalism in Korea: the significance of filial piety’, Journal of East Asian Studies, 11: 171–96. Lie, J. (2000) Han unbound: the political economy of South Korea, Stanford: Stanford University Press. Lie, J. (2004) Modern peoplehood, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Mankiw, N.G. (2014) Principles of economics, Stamford: Cengage Learning. Ministry of National Defense (2013) ‘Annual national defense budget trends’, Ministry of National Defense, viewed 14 September 2014, . Mo, J. and Weingast, B.R. (2013) Korean political and economic development: crisis, security, and institutional rebalancing, Cambridge: Harvard University Asia Centre. Moselle, B., and Polak, B. (2011) ‘A model of a predatory state’, The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 17(1): 1–33. Nooteboom, B. (2001) Learning and innovation in organizations and economies, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. North, D.C. (1993) ‘Institutions and credible commitment’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 149(1): 11–23. Oh, I. (1999) Mafioso, big business, and the financial crisis: the state-business relations in South Korea and Japan, Surrey, UK: Ashgate Publishing. Oh, I. (2013) ‘Joining innovation efforts using both feed-forward and feedback learning: the case of Japanese and Korean universities’, in A. Brem and E. Viardot (eds.) Evolution of innovation management: trends in an international context (pp. 208–235), New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Oh, I., and Park, H. (2001) ‘Shooting at a moving target: four theoretical problems in explaining the dynamics of the chaebol’, Asia Pacific Business Review, 7(4): 44–69. Oh, I., Park, H., Honeyama, S., and Kim, H. (2005) Mad technology: how east Asian companies are defending their technological advantages, New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Oh, I., and Varcin, R. (2002) ‘The mafioso state: state-led market bypassing in South Korea and Turkey’, Third World Quarterly, 23(4): 711–23. Oh, I., and Varcin, R. (2010) ‘Rent-sharing: organizational and technological innovations under military regimes in South Korea and Turkey’, International Journal of Technology Management and Sustainable Development, 9(2): 77–94. Pillay, P.N. (2010) Linking higher education and economic development: Implications for Africa from three successful systems, New Cape: Centre for Higher Education Transformation. Pirie, I. (2008) The Korean developmental state: from dirigisme to neo-liberalism, New York: Routledge. Porteux, J.N. (2013) ‘Policy, paramilitaries, nationals and gangsters: the processes of state building in Korea’, unpublished thesis, University of Michigan. Rozman, G. (1990) The East Asia region: Confucian heritage and its modern adaptation, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Saxenian, A. (1999) Silicon valley’s new immigrant entrepreneurs, San Francisco: Public Policy Institute of California. Siegel, J. (2007) ‘Contingent political capital and international alliances: evidence from South Korea’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 52: 621–66. Song, B. (2003) The rise of the Korean economy, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Trautvetter, C. (2010) Transitions to good governance: a case study of South Korea, Hertie School of Governance Working Paper No. 18, Berlin. Tsuru, S. (1996) Japan’s capitalism: creative defeat and beyond, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. US Patent and Trademark Office (2014) ‘All technologies report: January 1, 1989 – December 31, 2013’, US Patent and Trademark Office, viewed 14 September 2014, . Weber, M. (2013) Economy and society, Los Angeles: University of California Press. Williamson, O.E. (1983) ‘Credible commitments: using hostages to support exchange’, The American Economic Review, 73(4): 519–40. Wong, B.P. (2005) The Chinese in silicon valley: globalization, social networks, and ethnic identity, Washington, DC: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. 312

Economic miracle

Woo, J. (1991) Race to the swift: state and finance in Korean industrialization, New York: Columbia University Press. World Bank (1993) The east Asian miracle: economic growth and public policy, Washington DC: World Bank. Yee, J. (1998) ‘Risk society as a system failure: sociological analysis of accidents in Korea’, Korea Journal, 38(1): 83–101. Yadav, D. (2014) ‘Importance of compliance, regulations, and ethics in the wake of Korean ferry accident’, ASA Institute for Risk & Innovation, . Accessed 25 June 2014. Yonhap (2012) ‘From chief prosecutor to high court president . . . ex-senior judicial officers overflow in chaebol ranks’, Yonhap News, 30 January, viewed 14 September 2014, .

313

22 Democratization in South Korea Gregg Andrew Brazinsky

South Korea was one of the great anomalies of the twentieth century. During the period after World War II, dozens of new states in Asia and Africa gained their independence from colonialism. Many of them aspired to achieve rapid economic development and a workable form of democratic government. But by the end of the twentieth century, despite expansive American involvement in many cases, the vast majority of the post-colonial world continued to live in relative poverty, with less than a handful of states enjoying stable democracy. What made South Korea different? Why did it ultimately achieve a stable democratic government when so many other new states faced with similar circumstances failed? No one factor can answer these questions completely. In fact the process of democratization in South Korea during the years between 1945, when Korea was liberated from Japanese colonialism, and 1987, when South Korea’s military government agreed to step aside and allow free elections, was a complex one with a wide variety of different contributing factors. Nevertheless, there are certain features of South Korea’s history during this period that undoubtedly played a critical role in shaping the process. This essay examines the most important of these: the role of the United States, rapid economic development, and South Korean agency. It considers the importance of each of these three factors while offering a basic narrative of the key historical developments in South Korea’s democratization. Most of the existing literature on democratization in South Korea has taken a somewhat different approach. It has tended to put less emphasis on the role of outside actors and greater emphasis on the role of domestic forces. In particular, it has emphasized how different groups such as workers, women or ordinary people influenced or were influenced by South Korea’s democratic transformation (Armstrong 2006; Oh 1999; Shin 2014; S. Kim 2003). Much of this literature has primarily seen democratization as a sort of ground-up process driven primarily by the people. The United States is often viewed as a counterproductive force that hindered the emergence of South Korean democracy. But there are limitations to this approach. Korea did not have any democratic tradition before it was liberated from Japan in 1945, and Koreans had limited experience with democratic institutions. While it is argued here that Koreans struggled valiantly to turn their country into a democracy, the overall process cannot be understood without looking at a combination of internal and external factors and understanding the role Americans played in introducing democratic ideas and concepts. 314

Democratization in South Korea

First, however, it is important to explain what is meant by democracy in this essay. I have generally used the term as a shorthand, not for simple one-person, one-vote democracy, but for what might be called liberal democracy. Liberal democracy does not simply mean one-person, one-vote majority rule. Rather it is a form of democracy that is based on liberal principles including respect for the civil liberties of both the majority and the minority and equality before the law. Elections are free, fair and openly contested by candidates representing genuinely different positions on key issues (Zakaria 2003: 17). This was the kind of democracy that South Koreans came to aspire to and this is what they would ultimately manage to overcome the odds and achieve by the end of the twentieth century.

In the beginning Very few observers walking through the newly created Republic of Korea in 1948 would have given the country a very good chance of blossoming into a stable democracy in little more than a generation. At the time, South Korea was, to many, little more than a backwards “rump state.” The end of Japanese colonialism three years earlier had created tremendous economic dislocation throughout the Korean Peninsula; the division of the country into separate northern and southern states had served only to exacerbate the situation. To many Koreans at the time, subsistence and survival were the most important things (Brazinsky 2007: 32). Although Korean elites had aspirations to build a democracy similar to the ones that existed in Europe, the majority of Koreans had never lived under a democracy of any form and had virtually no experience with the procedural and civic aspects of democratic life. The years between 1945 and 1948 had been chaotic ones for Korea politically in which the peninsula was divided—occupied by the Soviet Union and the United States and, against the will of the vast majority of the Korean people, forced to accept division into two separate states. The inability of Washington and Moscow to reach a compromise that would reunify their zones of occupation through holding elections for the entire Korean Peninsula led to the intervention of the United Nations and to separate elections in the north and south. Unfortunately, neither of these elections offered the Koreans who participated in them a very positive introduction to the virtues of democratic life. The Americans and the Soviets skewed the political processes in their respective spheres of influence in such a way that only their own political allies could emerge triumphant (Lee 2013: 29–31). In the South, it was Syngman Rhee that seized the reins of political power with no small measure of American assistance. Americans had forged an alliance of convenience with Rhee for two key reasons: he was a devout anti-communist and, unlike many other conservatives in Korea whose reputations were tarnished by past collaboration with Japanese colonialism, Rhee had genuine credentials as a nationalist and leader of the early Korean independence movement. In an election that was largely boycotted by the political left, Rhee was elected the first president of the newly inaugurated Republic of Korea (ROK) in July 1948. Although the new government formed under Rhee’s leadership was formally democratic with a constitution and popularly elected National Assembly, the new president found ways to sharply limit political freedom and strengthen his own grip on power. He used the power of political patronage to award those who were most loyal to him. One American report on the new president’s cabinet appointments noted that there had been a “lack of any attempt to include in the present Government varying opinions or political groups” (Brazinsky 2007:18). Although Americans were deeply ambivalent about Rhee, they felt trapped into supporting him. During the first five years of its existence, South Korea confronted dire security threats, including domestic insurgency and a devastating war launched by the competing government 315

Gregg Andrew Brazinsky

in the north. Even after the Korean War ended, many feared that the armistice would not hold. In this context, American officials believed that there was little that they could do but tolerate Rhee’s authoritarianism despite the fact that he frequently made a mockery of US pretensions to be defending and assisting a “Free World” country. Doing otherwise, they feared, might bring about dangerous instability and lead to a communist takeover. The end result of American tolerance for Rhee’s authoritarian tendencies was the persistence of what at times seemed little more than a police state in South Korea until the president was overthrown in April 1960. Rhee took advantage of the emergency wartime situation to enlarge his own powers and make it possible for himself to seek multiple terms as president instead of the one term specified by the constitution. The president kept strict control over the national police and used it for paramilitary operations and intimidating his opponents. Rhee also encouraged the formation of notorious right-wing youth groups that sometimes attacked journalists or political figures who dissented against his regime. Although the Republic of Korea never developed into the kind of totalitarian state that existed north of the thirty-eighth parallel, the prospects for democracy appeared far from promising during its early years (Brazinsky, 2007: 104–106). But even if South Korea’s government remained authoritarian, democratic forces slowly began to emerge with American encouragement.

Promoting democracy America’s role in South Korean politics during the 1950s was in many ways a paradoxical one. There can be no question that American support for Syngman Rhee—reluctant as it may have been in some instances—proved critical to the formation and maintenance of an authoritarian state structure throughout the 1950s. At the same time, however, American officials hoped that South Korea would not remain permanently saddled with an authoritarian government like the one Rhee presided over. They looked forward to the time when Rhee would leave office. More importantly, they attempted to encourage democracy in South Korea from the bottom up through a variety of educational and cultural programs. Not all of these programs had the precise effect that was intended, and South Koreans never envisioned their democracy in the same way that Americans did. Nevertheless, these programs did help to establish some social structures and gave rise to new ideas that helped to encourage democracy in the long term. Many of these programs were launched as part of a broader US-led international effort to aid and reconstruct South Korea in the wake of the Korean War. The country was materially devastated after three years of brutal conflict with the north. Its industries lay in shambles, orphans numbered in the thousands, and destruction to homes and other property totaled hundreds of millions of dollars. During the decade after the Korean War, aiding South Korea became an important priority for both the United States and the United Nations. Washington established the United States Operations Mission in South Korea and gave it an annual budget of several hundred million dollars to carry out aid programs in different fields. At the same time, the United Nations Korea Reconstruction Agency (UNKRA) was established under the auspices of the UN, though Americans played a significant role in shaping the agenda for this organization as well. The stated goal of these organizations was generally to provide economic relief from the devastation caused by the war. But in doing so they inevitably sought to transfer new ways of thinking that could encourage democratization as well. An important case in point was in the ROK’s educational system. If Koreans were to become democratic citizens, Americans believed, then they needed to be educated and schools needed to guide them in the participatory aspects of democratic life. Koreans hungered for better education but opportunities were limited during and after the war. At the most basic level, 316

Democratization in South Korea

many of the school buildings had been destroyed during the war or converted to military barracks. In many instances, there simply were no physical structures that could be used for schooling. At the same time, the educational curriculum left much to be desired. Under Japanese colonialism, the schools had often served the purpose of assimilating Koreans into the Japanese empire (S. Kim and Caprio 2009: 33–43). Although the U.S. military occupation had initiated some educational reforms, the task was far from complete by the time the war started. In the aftermath of the war, both aiding in the reconstruction of schools and revising the education curricula became important priorities for many aid agencies. A vast expansion of educational opportunity occurred in South Korea as a result of these reconstruction efforts. American and UN agencies supplied materials for classroom construction, paper for printing textbooks and numerous other basic items needed to provide basic educational opportunities. The UNKRA assumed a large share of the responsibility for constructing new schools and classrooms. Through the organization’s efforts, more than 12,000 new classrooms were built in 1952–1953 in the ROK. As a result, primary school attendance grew from 2.4 million pupils in 1948 to 3.7 million in 1961. The number of students attending middle and high schools in South Korea also experienced a dramatic growth during these years (Brazinsky 2007: 43–47). American aid agencies did not stop at merely helping to build schools, they also sought to influence the curriculum. Democratic concepts were incorporated into textbooks, while new teaching methods designed to create a democratic citizenry were introduced to teachers (Brazinsky 2007: 46–50). Not all of these reforms had the intended effect. Many Americans sent to work with Korean teachers were dismayed that instructional methods did not actually change very much. Nevertheless, these changes made it possible for South Korean students to learn about democracy even if they could not experience it directly under Syngman Rhee’s rule. This was important given the rapidly growing number of students at all levels in South Korea. The numerous US official and private agencies active in South Korea during the post-war period also aimed to contribute to the country’s democratization through cultivating South Korean journalists. Americans believed that a free press was a prerequisite to a democratic society in the long run and sought to assure that one came into being in the ROK. The United States aided many pro-democracy journals that were openly critical of the Rhee government such as Sasanggye (World of Thought). The United States Information Agency (USIA) even initiated special tours of the United States for leading journalists and publishers. The idea behind such programs was to give media leaders the opportunity to see how the press functioned in a democratic society. Once they had the opportunity to witness the workings of the American media first hand, they would be more eager to help bring a free and democratic press to Korea. Here too, the United States seems to have had an impact as South Korean journalists became increasingly critical of their government over the course of the 1950s, despite Rhee’s efforts to keep them in check (Brazinsky 2007: 52–58). Finally, Americans recognized that if South Korea was to eventually transition to democracy, it would be necessary for the country to have civil servants dedicated to improving the function of the government. The United States therefore launched numerous programs to help train government officials and bureaucrats. The idea was to reach out to younger, uncorrupted civil servants and politicians that might eventually become the core of a more efficient, more democratic government. During the 1950s and 1960s, the Leaders Program operated by the USIA brought numerous South Korean assemblymen and local officials to the United States for tours, including future president Kim Dae Jung. The Ford Foundation arranged for many talented South Korean bureaucrats to attend special training programs at the Economic Development Institute in Washington (Brazinsky 2007: 59–67). 317

Gregg Andrew Brazinsky

American activities in South Korea could not produce democracy overnight, however. What they produced instead was greater tension between the government and elites. As the Rhee government grew even more despotic during the late 1950s, a rising generation of South Korean elites who had been exposed to ideas about democracy in schools, in the media and through contacts with the outside world became more dissatisfied. As a new decade dawned, South Korea was ripe for revolution.

From 19 April to 16 May The chain of events that would lead to the demise of Syngman Rhee’s government began during the spring of 1960. Although he was over eighty years old and bordering on senile, Rhee refused to let go of political power. During a presidential election held in March, Rhee’s henchmen launched a widespread campaign of ballot stuffing and destruction of opposition ballots. When the “results” of the election were announced and Rhee, despite his growing unpopularity, had somehow garnered over 80 percent of the votes, elite discontent began to spread rapidly. On 11 April, the body of a student who had been tortured by the police was suddenly found in the harbor in the southern city of Masan. When news reached the capital between 18–19 April, increasingly widespread student protests against the government began. Over the next few days, the protests continued to grow in scope and intensity, reaching the point where they threatened to throw the entire country into chaos. Facing increasing pressure both domestically and from the United States, Rhee finally stepped down on 25 April. Free elections, which ultimately turned the government over to the opposition Democratic Party were held in July (Henderson 1968: 174–181). For a brief period of time, the possibility of more genuine democracy appeared to take hold in South Korea. The newly elected prime minister, Chang Myŏn, presided over the ROK’s first local elections in Korean history in December 1960. South Koreans went to the polls to choose new provincial governors and a new mayor of Seoul. Freedom of expression and assembly blossomed. Moreover, the Chang government implemented some significant economic reforms that promised to break up the system of cronyism and corruption that had enabled Syngman Rhee to remain in power (Henderson 1968: 180–181). The new, democratic South Korean government led by Chang Myŏn survived less than one year, however. Despite its good intentions, its leadership was inexperienced and reluctant to use force. Demonstrations by radical student groups became increasingly common during the months after the revolution, and Chang’s government seemed unable to keep them under control. Nor did Chang have much success at alleviating the economic misery that had come to plague South Korea during the Syngman Rhee years. Both inflation and unemployment continued to grow under his leadership. Moreover, factionalism swiftly developed within the ruling Democratic Party due to disagreements between Chang and the president, Yun Po-sŏn. It did not take long for both American officials and South Korean citizens to begin to lose faith in the new South Korean government. According to a poll taken several months after Chang took office, the prime minister enjoyed the unreserved support of only 3.7 percent of South Korea’s population. (Henderson, 1968: 180–81). Americans and their conservative allies in South Korea feared that North Korea might take advantage of the chaos to reunify the country. Chang Myŏn’s government survived for less than a year. As Chang struggled to manage the economy and implement fundamental policies, South Korea’s formidable military grew increasingly impatient with civilian government. During the previous decade, the ROK Army had grown enormously both in size and influence thanks to massive American support during and after the Korean War. By the late 1950s, thousands of military officers had traveled to the 318

Democratization in South Korea

United States to receive special training. Moreover, the size and complexity of the ROK Army assured that those serving in it at the highest levels gained the kind of administrative experience that was lacking among most of South Korea’s civilian leaders. As Chang Myŏn’s government struggled to maintain order and launch South Korea on the path to economic development, the army looked on and became increasingly frustrated with the ineffectiveness of the civilian government (Brazinsky 2007: 84–100). On 16 May 1961, Major General Park Chung Hee (Pak Chŏng-hŭi) launched a bloodless coup d’état that swiftly ended democratic government in South Korea. Although Chang had heard rumors that such a coup was likely to occur, his government had few alternatives once Park managed to gain the support of the military. Once the coup had succeeded, Park temporarily assumed the post of Chairman of the Supreme Council for National Revolution (SCNR), and he would use the council to govern the ROK for the next two years. Although American officials on the ground in South Korea initially wanted to see civilian government restored, the Kennedy Administration soon came to support Park’s government, partially because it recognized that the chairman was deeply committed to restoring stability and promoting economic development. With the military now in control of South Korean politics, the country would go through a period of rapid social, economic and political change.

Park Chung Hee: development and democracy Park Chung Hee dominated South Korean politics for the next two decades. After ruling the country through the SCNR for two years, Park allowed free presidential elections in 1963, in part because he was pressured constantly by the Kennedy Administration to do so. Until 1972, elections continued to be held in South Korea, although the outcomes, while not completely predetermined, were heavily influenced by Park and his political allies. Under Park’s rule, a complex system of favoritism was established in which the government offered preferential treatment for certain business conglomerates (or chaebŏl) and the chaebŏl in turn rewarded Park’s political party with donations and other forms of largesse. The president also established the Korean Central Intelligence Agency (KCIA) as a powerful weapon that could be used to intimidate and control his opposition. Thus, on election days, Park’s opponents could receive votes and members of the opposition party were elected to the National Assembly (though they were always the minority), but the likelihood of Park or his party suffering a major loss under these conditions was very low. In 1972, Park suddenly abrogated the ROK constitution, however, and announced the creation of the new Yusin (meaning literally “revitalization”) System. Yusin was a harsh new system of authoritarian repression that placed strict limits on freedom of speech, introduced new methods of political repression, and essentially made Park the permanent president. Park Chung Hee clearly did not make establishing a viable democracy in South Korea one of his top priorities. Although he allowed free elections and some measure of dissent for some of the time that he was in power, for the most part he was mistrustful of democratic institutions and suspicious of American efforts to foist them upon South Korea. At the same time, however, during his nearly two decades in power Park did help to create socio-economic conditions that would eventually make democracy more tenable than it had been when he gained power. Park’s most notable achievement was, of course, that he managed to pull his nation out of the economic malaise that it was suffering from and launch it on a course of rapid economic development. When Park seized power, the Republic of Korea was still one of the poorest countries in the world and its per capita income was lower than that of many newly independent African countries. By the time Park was assassinated in 1979, South Korea’s per capita income had grown from 319

Gregg Andrew Brazinsky

around $80 to $3,000. The economy had averaged miraculous double-digit growth rates throughout the 1960s and 1970s. South Korea’s industrialization and economic growth are covered elsewhere in this volume, so they will not be covered in detail here. What needs to be mentioned, however, is the way that this economic development contributed to the country’s eventual democratization. The rapid economic development that occurred during the Park Chung Hee years contributed to South Korea’s democratization in several key ways. First, throughout human history there has been an established connection between the expansion of economic opportunity and the development of political liberty. One does not always lead to the other. Nevertheless, one might say that economic opportunity is constitutive of political liberty—meaning that it has the power to bring political liberty into being. When Park Chung Hee seized power in 1961, South Korea was still primarily an economic society. Most people had little choice other than to make their living from the land as previous generations had done. By the end of Park Chung Hee’s rule, this was no longer true. During the 1970s Park had also launched an economic program known as the “big push,” under which the South Korean economy transitioned from light manufacturing to heavy industries. The “big push” enabled the ROK to continue its rapid economic growth and diversify its economy (Woo 1991: 118–147). Industrialization helped to spur the growth of both labor and the middle class in South Korea, while creating new economic choices. Moreover, although students continued to be one of the most radical groups in South Korea, Park had realized that a strong education system was necessary if he wanted to turn his nation into an economic success story. Educational opportunities had continued to expand at all levels. What did all of this rapid economic growth mean for the typical South Korean? Of course, not everybody benefited equally. Nevertheless, in 1979, ambitious young South Koreans had a far greater chance to fulfill their aspirations for a better education and a middle class job than any previous generation. This change was a dramatic one that transformed the mentality of large segments of the population. It did not, in and of itself, lead to democracy. Nevertheless, it was natural for South Koreans who now had more economic choices to crave greater political freedoms. The emergence of these new classes also attenuated the state’s power. The government continued to do everything that it could to simultaneously foster and control the growth of large industries. But as industries grew larger, they eventually became loci of power in their own right. This combination of alternative centers of power and greater expectations among younger South Koreans unquestionably created some of the preconditions that would eventually lead to a political transformation. Park Chung Hee also helped to create the enabling conditions for democracy by enhancing both the security and stability of South Korea. Democracy is highly dependent on the ability of the state to protect citizens from both external and internal threats. During the 1950s and 1960s, perhaps the greatest threat to the establishment of a durable democracy in South Korea came from Pyongyang. If North Korea had ever been able to carry out its ambition to reunify the peninsula under Pyongyang’s leadership, it would have made the emergence of democracy anywhere on the Korean Peninsula impossible. Although Park did not eliminate the North Korean threat altogether, he certainly enhanced South Korea’s capacity to defend itself. Economic power and military power are closely interrelated. As the South Korean economy developed, so too did its capacity for autonomous defense. Park’s government also maintained internal order. It is certainly true that some of the measures taken by Park Chung Hee on this front—intimidating, arresting and torturing his opponents— were far too extreme. At the same time, liberal democracy has never developed in countries where personal property was not protected and basic political stability could not be guaranteed. 320

Democratization in South Korea

Despite the Yusin government’s atrocious record on human rights, Park did help to maintain civil order and the rule of law throughout his tenure in power. South Koreans generally could acquire and be secure in their own personal property and use it as they saw fit. In the long run, these rights gave South Koreans greater incentive to participate in the governance of their own society, even if they could not do so immediately. Ultimately, the impact of the Park Chung Hee era on South Korea’s later emergence as a democracy was very complicated and multi-faceted. There can be no question that Park went further than he needed to in order to maintain social order and maintain South Korea’s security. Although placing some limits on popular freedoms and participation may have been necessary in an economically impoverished country with no history of democracy like South Korea, the gross violations of human rights and basic civil liberties perpetrated by his regime were not. At the same time, political development in South Korea during the Park Chung Hee years followed a fundamentally ironic problem. Park succeeded magnificently at spurring rapid economic development in South Korea. But his very success helped to foster disillusionment with the dictatorship he had created. As South Koreans gained more economic choices as a result of the country’s rapid development, they became increasingly frustrated with their relative lack of political choices and this led to growing protests against his authority.

The rise of political dissent in South Korea The imposition of Yusin in 1972 led to growing protests against the government in South Korea. Initially, these protests were mainly carried out by elites such as students, intellectuals, and influential Christian ministers. Over the course of the 1970s, students and Christian churches worked together to mobilize South Korea’s growing class of industrial laborers against the Park regime’s growing authoritarianism. Workers endured harsh conditions in the ROK with labor unions suppressed fiercely by the government. Idealistic students often devoted their time to going into factories and training workers in the techniques of labor activism and social protest. The level of confrontation between the state and this alliance of dissident groups escalated swiftly during the early 1970s. American policy was mostly passive in the face of this potentially explosive situation. The Nixon Administration was focused on improving relations with the People’s Republic of China and limiting America’s overall involvement in Asia. It generally supported Park and hoped that his government would find a way of maintaining stability and feared that publicly criticizing the regime would only make things worse. Over time, however, events and circumstances made it increasingly difficult for Park to maintain his grip on political power. In 1976, Jimmy Carter was elected president in the United States. The Carter Administration made human rights one of its key foreign policy priorities, and the new president was far more willing to criticize America’s longstanding allies on their human rights records than his predecessors had been. Frictions between the Carter Administration and the Park government grew quickly, but Washington found that its influence over the government was diminishing rapidly. At the same time, Park found that his political position was weaker because he was now receiving growing measures of criticism from Washington, which had mostly looked the other way when it came to his regime’s authoritarianism in the past. By the late 1970s, dissident forces in South Korea were becoming increasingly determined. Park’s refusal to show any flexibility in the face of this rising tide of dissent would ultimately bring about his downfall. In August 1979, Park’s decision to suppress a strike at the YH Trading Company led to a series of escalating clashes between his government and democratic forces. Striking workers fled to the headquarters of the opposition New Democratic Party (NDP), which 321

Gregg Andrew Brazinsky

was still represented in the National Assembly, though its actual power was very limited. In response, Park expelled Kim Young Sam (Kim Yŏng-sam), the party’s leader, from the assembly, a move that in turn caused all remaining members of the NDP to resign their seats. Popular demonstrations, often led by students and workers, began in Pusan and soon spread throughout the country (Oh 1999: 71–72). All of a sudden, the stability of the South Korean government, long assumed to be unassailable, seemed to be in jeopardy. Key officials in Park’s government did not completely agree on how to handle the situation. Some argued for reform but others, including Park, argued that it was necessary to take a hard line with the protestors and assure the survival of the ROK government. When Park called a meeting of several of his top advisors on 26 October, an argument broke out among them. No detailed archival records about what was discussed and who made what arguments during the meeting exists. Apparently, however, the KCIA director Kim Chae-gyu became increasingly frustrated with Park over the course of the meeting. For reasons that are still not clear, Kim suddenly shot and killed both the South Korean president and his bodyguard Ch’a Ch’i-ch’ŏl (Brazinsky 2007: 232). The Yushin system died along with Park, but one key question still remained unanswered: What political direction would South Korea move in after Park’s death? Initially, it seemed like South Korea would evolve toward greater democracy. Prime Minister Ch’oe Kyu Ha (Ch’oe Kyu-ha) assumed the presidency after Park’s assassination and announced that the Yushin constitution would be revised and free elections would follow. Ch’oe also moved to restore the civil liberties of dissident politicians such as Kim Dae Jung (Kim Tae-jung), who had been kept under surveillance by the Park regime. But this promising new beginning soon turned into another harrowing ordeal for South Koreans who craved democracy. On 12 December 1979, Major General Chun Doo Hwan (Chŏn Tu-hwan), the leader of a clandestine association within the military placed Chŏng Sŭng-hwa, the army chief of staff, under arrest for allegedly playing a role in the assassination of Park Chung Hee. These trumped up charges were, in reality, little more than an excuse for Chun to take control over the South Korean military. Over the next few months, Chun’s position in South Korean politics slowly grew stronger while President Ch’oe’s became weaker. Under duress, Ch’oe appointed Chun director of the KCIA and promoted him to the rank of lieutenant general (Oh 1999: 72–78). Those desiring greater progress toward democracy in South Korea could read the writing on the wall; they knew that Chun intended to restore military rule. It was the tragic series of events that occurred in Kwangju during the spring of 1980 that would defer truly democratic governance in South Korea for the next seven years. When Ch’oe announced Chun’s promotion in April, student-led demonstrations exploded throughout South Korea and were accompanied by major industrial strikes. With anti-government protests continuing to grow in size and intensity, Chun declared martial law on 17 May. Military authorities closed major universities, suspended the National Assembly, and arrested major opposition leaders (Oh 1999: 80–81). Protests subsided in most parts of the country as a result of Chun’s show of force but continued unabated in the southwestern city of Kwangju. On 18 May, special warfare forces entered the city and were followed by paratroopers on 21 May. When some of the paratroopers fired on civilians, the protests took on a more violent turn with demonstrators seizing armaments and taking over government buildings. With chaos engulfing Kwangju, General John Wickham, the commander of American forces stationed in Korea, released the ROK Army’s Twentieth Division from its duties along the Demilitarized Zone. Chun used the Twentieth Division to suppress the uprising in Kwangju, killing between 200 and 2000 South Korean citizens in the process (Brazinsky 2007: 236–238). The United States, because of Wickham’s decision to release a combat division, has long been perceived by South Koreans as being complicit in these tragic events. 322

Democratization in South Korea

The picture for South Korean democracy looked bleak in 1980. The military had reasserted itself and brutally suppressed dissent. While Park Chung Hee had always enjoyed some measure of respect from many South Koreans despite his authoritarianism, Chun Doo Hwan was never very popular. But Chun did receive staunch support from the incoming Reagan Administration in the United States. He was invited to the White House in 1981, where he was warmly embraced by the new president, Ronald Reagan (Brazinsky 2007: 240–242). With US support and the powerful ROK military behind him, Chun’s position seemed unassailable. Despite Chun’s efforts to put a stranglehold on the process of democratization in South Korea, however, other factors militated against continuing military rule. There were two key factors that played a particularly important role in unraveling Chun’s grasp on political power: the growing power of minjung ideology and South Korea’s economic liberalization. During the 1980s, these two factors would slowly but surely erode Chun’s grip on power. Meaning literally “the people,” minjung ideology became a powerful unifying force for South Korean students, workers, intellectuals, theologians, and others who protested against the military rule. The concept of minjung was far more than an ideology of social or political protests. It informed the works of South Korean economists, historians, and artists who, in different ways, sought to represent the oppressed masses of Korean people as historical subjects (Lie 1998: 137–139). Minjung called for the restructuring of South Korean politics and society to favor the masses whose aspirations for democracy, it contended, had been suppressed by the combination of military rule and American hegemony. During the 1980s, pro-democracy activists in South Korea became more hostile to the United States than at any other time in South Korean history. Many demonstrations combined anti-Americanism with demands for reform by the ROK’s military dictatorship. Throughout the period between 1981 and 1987, such anti-government demonstrations became a common sight on the country’s major college campuses. The government frequently responded by sending in riot police armed with tear gas and torturing or imprisoning those responsible for the protests. The government managed to hold onto power through the use of violence, but the growing influence of minjung ideology was clearly making military rule untenable in the long term. Economic liberalization also contributed significantly to the momentum for democracy in South Korea. Although Chun Doo Hwan wanted South Korea’s rapid economic growth to continue, he did not have a clear economic agenda as Park Chung Hee had. He was strongly influenced by both pressures coming from the Reagan Administration advocating economic change and his advisors, many of who had been trained in the United States and subscribed to the free market ideologies espoused at many American universities. Park Chung Hee had used a system of state-guided capitalism to achieve rapid economic growth while, at the same time, making South Korean business conglomerates (or chaebŏl) heavily dependent on the state for loans and other kinds of support. During the 1980s, economic liberalization made new sources of capital, including foreign investment, available to South Korean business. The result was that the chaebŏl became less dependent on the state and more willing to see political reform occur (Woo 1991: 190–201). During the late 1980s, South Korea’s businesses and its growing middle class increasingly threw their weight behind democratization, making it even more difficult for the military to perpetuate its rule. By the late 1980s, South Korea looked increasingly unstable politically. On the one hand, it continued to be governed by a repressive military regime. On the other hand, anti-government protests were being joined by students, laborers, and the country’s increasingly influential middle class. The country seemed poised for a major political explosion and that is exactly what happened in 1987. 323

Gregg Andrew Brazinsky

The emergence of democracy Military dictatorship’s final hour in South Korea came during the spring of 1987. In April of that year, Chun went back on a promise that he had made earlier to allow a free presidential election and in June announced that Roh Tae Woo (No T’ae-u), another army general, would be his successor. The announcement set off a massive wave of anti-government demonstrations involving over one million people. There was no way for Chun to quiet these protests, short of deploying the military and running the risk of an all-out civil war. Although Reagan had been a supporter of Chun, the White House had learned a lesson from Carter’s inept handling of events in Kwangju. This time, Washington made it clear that it did not approve of the use of force by Chun’s government. In the face of strong pressure from both the South Korean public and the United States, Chun finally agreed to step down. On 29 June, Roh Tae Woo announced that free elections would be held in December and that significant constitutional reforms would be made (Brazinsky 2007: 249). Roh’s announcement was a pivotal moment in South Korea’s transition to a more democratic government, but the transition did not occur instantaneously. Free elections took place as promised in December 1987, but Roh managed to pull off a narrow victory. Roh had taken some of the credit for Chun’s resignation and anti-communism remained a powerful force in South Korean politics. Moreover, the two leading opposition candidates, future presidents Kim Dae Jung and Kim Young Sam, split the opposition vote, enabling Roh to win a small plurality. Nevertheless, the election had been the freest and fairest in Korean history, and members of the democratic opposition would soon have their own chances to serve as president—Kim Young Sam triumphed in the next presidential election held five years later and Kim Dae Jung was elected president in 1997. During the years since 1987, South Korea has continued to make political progress, refining and improving its democracy in ways that are suited for its own unique national circumstances. During the two and a half decades since then, the ROK has continued to enjoy free and fair elections, with power being transferred back and forth peacefully between competing factions on different ends of the ideological spectrum. The same cannot be said for the vast majority of nations that were once victims of colonial aggression. Since Chun’s ouster, civil society groups have become particularly influential in South Korea. Although military rule had ended, many of the trappings of Korea’s long history of authoritarian rule remained. Civil society groups played an important role in encouraging broad, democratizing reforms in nearly every aspect of South Korean life. Groups such as the Citizens’ Coalition for Economic Justice and the People’s Solidarity for Participatory Democracy aimed to promote democratization from both the top down and the bottom up. On the one hand, they reached out to newly elected officials to advocate for their causes, while at the same time, sponsoring research and engaging in campaigns to keep citizens aware of their responsibilities (Yeo 2013). Today, South Korean democracy continues to evolve. It is still imperfect. Some observers note that Korean political parties remain immature in that they are partially formed around loyalty to particular leaders rather than abstract principals and ideas. Corruption also continues to mar South Korean politics, although the ROK is often no different from the United States and other Western democracies when it comes to this issue. Nevertheless, South Korea’s halting but persistent transformation into a democracy during the last six decades demands the attention of all who wonder about the fate of freedom in the twenty-first century. In a world where nations continue to struggle to establish stable democratic institutions, South Korea is one of the few examples where such institutions could be created despite a history of domestic conflict and civil war. Though most countries cannot and will not follow the same path to democracy 324

Democratization in South Korea

that South Koreans did, understanding how democracy took hold there can unquestionably contribute to an appreciation of what might be involved in promoting it elsewhere. Ultimately, the fact that South Koreans are still perfecting their democracy by no means detracts from what they have accomplished. It should simply remind us that democracy is not a destination, but a process.

References Abelmann, Nancy. 1996. Echoes of the Past, Epics of Dissent: A South Korean Social Movement. Berkeley: University of California Press. Armstrong, Charles. 2006. Korean Society: Civil Society, Democracy and the State. London: Routledge. Brazinsky, Gregg. 2007. Nation Building in South Korea: Koreans, Americans and the Making of a Democracy. Chapel Hill, NC: UNC Press. Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, and George W. Downs. 2005 “Development and Democracy” Foreign Affairs 84 (September/October 2005):77–86 Clark, Donald N. 1986. Christianity in Modern Korea, Lanham, MD: University Press of America. Cole, David, and Princeton N. Lyman. 1971. Korean Development: The Interplay of Politics and Economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Cumings, Bruce. 2004. North Korea: Another Country. New York: New Press. Cumings, Bruce. 1997. Korea’s Place in the Sun: A Modern History. New York: Norton. Eckert, Carter, et al. 1990. Korea Old and New: A History. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Gleysteen, William H. 1999. Massive Entanglement, Marginal Influence: Carter and Korea in Crisis. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Halperin, Morton, et al. 2004. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York: Routledge. Hart-Landsberg, Martin. 1993. The Rush to Development: Economic Change and Political Struggle in South Korea. New York: Monthly Review Press. Henderson, Gregory. 1968. Korea: The Politics of the Vortex. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Kim, Samuel S. ed. 2003. Korea’s Democratization. New York: Cambridge University Press. Kim, Samuel and Caprio, Mark. 2009 Japanese Assimilation Policy in Colonial Korea 1910–1945. Seattle: University of Washington Press. Kim, Se-Jin. 1971. The Politics of Military Revolution in Korea. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. Lee, Steven Hugh. 2013 The Korean War. London: Routledge. Lie, John. 1998. Han Unbound: The Political Economy of South Korea. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Oberdorfer, Don. 1997. The Two Koreas: A Contemporary History. New York: Basic Books. Oh, John Kie Chiang. 1999. Korean Politics: The Quest for Democratization and Economic Development. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Seth, Michael. 2002. Education Fever: Society Politics and the Pursuit of Schooling in South Korea. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Sohn Hak-Kyu. 1989. Authoritarianism and Opposition in South Korea. New York: Routledge. Stueck, William. 2002. Rethinking the Korean War: A New Diplomatic and Strategic History. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Stueck, William. “Democratization in Korea: The United States Role, 1980 and 1987.” International Journal of Korean Studies 2 (Fall/Winter 1998): 171–80. Suh, Dae-Sook, ed. Korean Studies: New Pacific Currents. 1994. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Shin, Youngtae. 2014. Protest Politics and Democratization of South Korea: Strategies and Roles of Women. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books. Woo, Jung-En, 1991. Race to the Swift: State and Finance in Korean Industrialization. New York: Columbia University Press. Yeo, Andrew. 2013. “South Korean Civil Society: Implications for the U.S.-ROK Alliance” (Council Foreign Relations Working Paper). Zakaria, Fareed. 2003. The Future of Freedom: Illiberal Democracy at Home and Abroad. New York: Norton.

325

23 Women, gender, and social change in South Korea since 1945 Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

Introduction In the decades since the end of the Japanese colonial period, gender1 has been a central factor in social structure and social change in South Korea. Legacies of colonial gender formations lingered long into the post-liberation period, but gendered social role expectations, images, and daily practices for Korean men and women have also been transformed in dramatic ways. These changes themselves have generated reactions that have sought to reconstitute imagined traditions or which have advocated new gender formations. Any attempt to capture this complexity – and the scholarship of these processes – in a single essay will be no more than an overview, and a partial one at that. We have taken this dynamism as our point of reference; the changes to – and because of – gender are taken as guideposts to the more general issue of transformations in South Korean society and culture. Our themes include considerations of household structure and the divisions between public and private in terms of gendered expectations, roles, and practices around work and human relationships; feminist activism; and sexuality and gender2. We will attend to material as well as discursive and expressive domains in the local production and embodied experience of gender in South Korea. And while the scholarship of gender in South Korea in the twentieth and early twenty-first century exhibits some differences in interpretations, much of the literature points to a consensus regarding the circumstances of and pressures on women (and men), and of the enduring importance of gender in structuring social relations throughout this period.

Gender, labor, education, and home The Japanese colonial experience left a legacy upon which structures and concepts around gender were formed in the first years of Korean independence. With the sudden departure of the Japanese in 1945 and the simultaneous division of the peninsula, Koreans in the southern zone faced instability in governance, economy, and culture. Displaced Koreans returning from abroad strained the resources and social fabric of the countryside and swelled city neighborhoods.3 Politics under the American military government in Korea and, from 1948, under the Republic of Korea, 326

Women, gender, and social change

were contentious, and the outbreak of war in June 1950 threw the population into even deeper chaos. Established patterns of housing, work, family relationships, and care were disrupted. This social instability led to improvisations that often undermined existing gendered expectations and roles, and in reaction, gender itself became an explicit discursive domain for the reinforcement of what were thought of as appropriate and “traditional” Korean norms against “modern” aspirations of independence and individualism (H.J. Cho 1995; 2002). In particular, during the active hostilities between 1950 and 1953 and in the war’s aftermath, when most able-bodied adult men were engaged in the fighting, captured, or in hiding, many women and children had to work outside the home to support their families.4 Women’s labor force participation rate doubled during the war from less than 30 percent to more than 60 percent, and remained elevated throughout the 1950s (H.S. Kim 2009). Farming was the most common type of paid work women engaged in outside the home, followed by work in small factories, and peddling. Although the work activities of war widows were viewed as a positive adjustment to their unfortunate circumstances, the simultaneous increase in married women’s participation in the labor force was, in contrast, portrayed as a sign of their husbands’ inadequacies and as a perversion of social norms (H.S. Kim 2009). This inconsistency is just one of many discursive conundrums that structured South Korean women’s choices in the mid-twentieth century, generating social dilemmas for women regarding which behaviors were to be considered appropriate in terms of gender as well as other factors such as class, age, and social position. From the 1950s on, international development consultants and the ROK government agreed that low-cost, skilled labor was the key to South Korea’s economic future. Park ChungHee’s industrialization policies in the 1960s coordinated education, infrastructure, finance, and international relations to foster export-led economic development characterized by a partnership between an authoritarian state and powerful conglomerates known as chaebŏl. Central to this strategy was the recruitment of workers from the countryside to new industrial sites. Backed by government propaganda soliciting “industrial soldiers,” both men and women were increasingly drawn into the net of paid employment, a significant shift from family-based farm work and self-employment (S. Moon 2005; Cho and Koo 1983; Koo 1990). In most cases, the jobs men and women took reflected existing ideas of gender-appropriate role differentiation, although those notions and the specific labor positions associated with men or women changed over time. In the manufacturing sector, women predominated in “light” industry (for example, textiles, wigs, food, clothing, and electronics) while men monopolized jobs in construction and the heavy and chemical industry (particularly after Park’s emphasis on this sector beginning in the 1970s), and men held nearly all supervisorial positions in all factories (Cho and Koo 1983; Koo 1990; K.A. Park 1993). The experience of young women in factory work was shaped by male surveillance of the production floor, and, for rural female migrants, close monitoring of their comings and goings in factory dormitories or dilapidated housing complexes adjacent to the factory (Ogle 1990; Spencer 1988). The conditions in the factories themselves were infamous, including long hours and grueling shiftwork, extremely low wages (legally stratified by gender and, for married men, augmented to recognize men’s role in family support), unsafe work environments, sexual harassment, and abusive management tactics (Chun 2003; H.M. Kim 1997; Ogle 1990; Spencer 1988). The young women factory workers were also haunted by money concerns, family demands for support (often to fund investment in their own brothers’ cultural capital), and the pressure to get married and leave work. While the work of these young women was lauded as a contribution to national development, social anxiety around the perceived independence of these women was reflected in gossip and suspicions regarding their chastity. Nor was their foothold in employment firm: in the 1970s and early 1980s, global pressures on production costs, combined with a strategic shift to a greater emphasis on heavy 327

Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

industry (“men’s work”) increased the job insecurity and tarnished the status of young women factory workers (H.M. Kim 2005; Y.J. Park 1990). Moreover, not all urban job seekers were able to find work in manufacturing (and manufacturing work was strongly skewed to a younger labor force [Chang 1994]). Many women tried to scrape together a living selling things, serving food, and cleaning houses (along with sexual labor – see below). Economic fits and starts, combined with an ideological preference for men’s job security over women’s, shaped women’s frequently-interrupted work histories in the ROK’s first decades. Although industry held a privileged place in South Korean economic development, it depended upon the rural sector not only as a source of labor and affordable sustenance, but also as a site of imagination against which the dramatic difference of “modernity” could be contrasted. At its inception, the ROK was essentially an agricultural nation with a small urban population;5 the targeted recruitment of young workers from South Korean rural communities in the 1960s and 1970s inevitably altered the social fabric of the countryside. Between 1960 and 1985, the portion of South Koreans living outside urban areas fell from 61 to 35 percent, and the remaining rural population was increasingly composed of elderly residents (Korea Statistical Yearbook). Historically, women in the countryside had worked inside the home and alongside men in the fields, producing textiles for tax payments, making food and clothing for the family, and assisting in the raising of crops (Chang 1994). During the period of national industrialization, however, mechanization of some “male” farming tasks and the associated shifting of more manual farming tasks from men to women, along with the androcentric social impacts of Park Chung-Hee’s Saemaul Undong (New Village Movement) affected the gender balance in the countryside, as women were burdened with more responsibilities that were increasingly viewed as less modern than those men held (Shin Gills 1999; O. Cho 1998; Abelmann 1996). The distance (both geographic as well as imaginative) between new urbanites and the villages of their birth fostered nostalgia for an idealized Korean farm home tended by an iconic, hard-working, self-sacrificing mother. This became a standard trope in propaganda, literature, and film from the 1960s through the present, against which the behaviors of (non-fictional) contemporary urban women were often judged (McHugh and Abelmann 2005; Abelmann 2003). Although rural life was materially and socially transformed through this relationship with South Korea’s urbanization, becoming more intensively patriarchal and more impoverished, it was simultaneously presented and cherished as “authentic” Korean culture. Hidden in this ideal was the fact that farm work was the only sector where women customarily were understood to be engaged in productive labor throughout their lives (H.J. Cho 1988; H.J Cho 2000; Kendall 2002b). While by the mid-1960s, it had become not just accepted but expected that young women would seek work, married women’s participation in the paid workforce continued to generate ambivalence in media and in public opinion through the 1980s. Despite the presentation of young women workers as contributing to the national economy, engaging in paid work after marriage was widely perceived as a sign of a husband’s failure to provide for his family. Most women themselves hoped that their stint as paid workers would be a temporary phase in their lives (S. Moon 2005; S.K. Kim 1997). Indeed, except for those in the agricultural sector, most women exited the paid labor force as soon as they could after marriage. In contrast to men, who were expected to earn a living, women’s employment beyond young adulthood was considered an anomaly. This, however, masked an important truth: despite the ideal of stay-at-home housewives (an ideal already widely embraced in the 1960s), many married women re-entered the labor force (often after their children started school), yielding an employment rate of between 40 and 50 percent for married women throughout this period.6 The jobs married women took were often contingent or part-time positions (inferior to those available to them before marriage), but perhaps more important to the reinforcement 328

Women, gender, and social change

of the ideology of a strict gender dichotomy of work and home responsibilities was the fact that married women’s work was portrayed as anomalous at least through the 1980s (H. Cho 2005). The gendered categorical differences in employment expectations and opportunities in South Korea affected men as strongly as they affected women: working (regardless of the type: farm work, manufacturing, intellectual, or professional labor) was seen as constitutive of manhood. It was constructed as a social expectation as well as a patriotic duty of all men (S. Moon 2005; J.J.H. Lee 2002). The recruitment of rural men into the urban labor force in the 1960s paralleled the recruitment of rural women into factories, although men were steered to heavier production tasks and factory supervision, as well as construction, hauling, transport, and professional careers. The shape of masculine work was framed by several factors, including the push factor of widespread poverty and poor job prospects in the 1950s and 1960s. S. Moon (2005) also carefully documents the effect of the military as a dominant institution, particularly during the regime of Park Chung Hee. Conscription was (and remains) universal for young men (with limited exceptions). This male-only domain of activity had multiple effects on the gendering of South Korean society. Young men experienced a harsh environment characterized by hazing, hierarchy, and hard work that shaped ideas of Korean masculinity. At the same time, men reaped a lifetime of economic and social rewards for their service through direct benefits (veteran status accorded hiring preferences or was required of job candidates for many positions) as well as by the indirect benefits of the social connections forged in military units and the belief that their military service demonstrated discipline and patriotism. Military service thus was a key element in the establishment of gendered social and symbolic hierarchy throughout the second half of the twentieth century in South Korea. The chaebŏl-dominated export orientation of much of the South Korean economy from the 1960s through the mid-1990s also shaped the culture of employment. While all sectors were highly gender-segregated in hiring and work roles (Chang 1994), chaebŏl culture reflected military practice in its androcentrism, discipline and emphasis on hierarchy (Janelli with Yim 1993). South Koreans averaged among the world’s highest number of hours worked per week for much of this period (Koo 1990); married men were often away from their homes for much of the day, interacting with their families briefly on their one day of rest. The demand that workers arrive early and stay late was incompatible with two-parent working families, particularly as commercial childcare was poorly developed and urban households rarely included grandparents who might help out with childcare, but complaints that men did not share more domestic responsibilities were blunted by the media’s focus in the 1980s and 1990s on what was deemed an epidemic of stress-related illness among working men, emphasizing the patriotic self-sacrifice of men to the national call to work (J.J.H. Lee 2002). The exclusion of increasingly-educated married women from well-remunerated white-collar employment in the 1970s and 1980s facilitated the channeling of their human capital into childrearing. In these ways, the gendered configuration of employment expectations influenced the gendered dichotomy of domestic roles and vice versa, and together, these fed growing class differences. Women’s sexual work contributed in another significant way to the symbolic marking of the South Korean gender binary (S.H. Lee 2002): The market for commodified sexual services had expanded in the context of rapid urbanization in the 1960s and 1970s: as individuals left the oversight of their rural families and sought work in the cities, sex work evolved as a significant sector both for women’s employment (particularly in the context of high rates of unemployment and low pay for women) and for men’s consumption. Throughout the second half of the twentieth century, South Korean men’s demand escalated for high-end kisaeng entertainment, street prostitution, “room salons,” and sexualized services in coffee shops and barber shops (Lie 1995). 329

Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

E.H. Kim (1998) documented how the normalization of commodified sexual services reinforced male bonding (in particular, in the context of group visits to room salons) and demarcated class hierarchies; naturalized the superiority of men over women; and reproduced divisions among women according to their ability to fulfill rules of chastity (E.H. Kim 1998). Moreover, men and women accepted married men’s consumption of sexual services as “normal,” but judged female sex providers as lacking virtue and, in the context of the backlash against women’s central roles in consumer culture in the 1980s and 1990s, of excessive materialism. In addition to the domestic sexual services market, South Korean women also worked as prostitutes and sexualized entertainers in “camptowns” established through shady arrangements coordinating ROK government oversight, the US military, and sex industry professionals (K. Moon 1997), and after the 1965 Normalization Treaty with Japan, as prostitutes deployed to draw foreign currency by serving Japanese men visiting South Korea on sex tours facilitated by the ROK (Lie 1995). The fetishization of young women office workers (particularly in the chaebŏl), while not directly sexual, occurred in the context of – and reinforced – gender allocation of work positions and the normalization of married men’s employment-based sexual entertainment culture (Janelli with Yim 1993; E.H. Kim 1998). Gendered patterns of employment were closely connected to the course of educational development during the decades under consideration. Formal public education had penetrated Korean society slowly and unevenly during the colonial period7, and in 1945, just 22 percent of Koreans were literate, with illiteracy much higher among women than men (Seong 2009). Expanding education became a priority in the first years of independence for political and economic reasons. ROK educational policies accorded with international values embracing broad educational access throughout the society, yet the differential uptake of educational opportunities reveals gender and class differences persisting to the end of the twentieth century. Primary school attendance was mandated for boys and girls in 1950 and was made tuition-free in 1960. After this, rates of educational attainment rose quickly, although gender disparities persisted (particularly in population measures which included all age groups). In 1960, for example, the population of South Korean women (including all ages) averaged only 2.9 years of formal schooling, compared with 4.8 years for men; by 1980 the respective figures were 6.6 years and 8.7 years8 (Seong 2009). Given the financial and social costs of sending children to school (even without tuition fees and the costs of textbook and equipment, “gifts” to teachers, and charges for extra tutoring added up to serious financial burdens for poor households), family decisions regarding schooling were influenced by assumptions about not just the financial but the moral purpose and effects of literacy and education on boys and girls, as well as persistent gendered differences in the monetary return on educational investment (Seth 2002). Even after primary school attendance had become universal, into the 1970s girls were less likely to attend academic or technical vocational secondary school than were boys. There was also a clear trend for all but the highest-class families to invest more in boys’ education relative to girls’, with farming families investing the least in educating their daughters well into the 1980s (Seong 2009). Over time, as overall education levels rose, gender differentials in primary and secondary graduation rates diminished – although boys were steered to more academic or technical courses of study (Chang 1994).9 In contrast to primary and secondary levels of education, college remained a genderdifferentiated space into the new millennium. In the first decades of the new republic, South Korean colleges and universities produced a superfluity of (mostly male) college graduates. The high rates of unemployment among degree-holders generated unrest in a key demographic group, and the Park Chung Hee Administration attempted (with only partial success) to reduce college enrollments and shift educational fervor to vocational subjects in the 1960s. One legacy of the 330

Women, gender, and social change

low demand in the labor market for (male) college graduates was the relatively low proportion of women in the population of college students (as late as the 1990s, twice as many men as women were enrolled in higher education), as well as a presumption that women’s college attendance was for personal enrichment rather than professional training.10 Labor-market demand for university-educated women was weak, particularly in the context of masculinized workplace culture (S. Moon 2005; H.M. Kim 2005). And while many women trained in professional fields such as education, medicine, and business in the period between the 1960s and the 1990s, a significant fraction of women attending universities saw their own education as preparation for marriage and childrearing (M.H. Kim 1995; Cho 1998; Nelson 2000; Park and Abelmann 2004). Indeed, childrearing and the educational success of her children remained a key measure of a woman’s aptitude throughout the second half of the twentieth century, particularly (although not exclusively) for middle- and-upper-middle-class women. Shunted from the employment market, educated middle-class women were structurally and culturally encouraged to dedicate their efforts to fostering their children’s success (H.J. Cho 1995; H.J. Cho 1998). This goal required women to cultivate and mobilize a complex network of family members, friends and acquaintances for information, influence, and, often, financing of investments in the stock or real estate markets. The work of middle-class class reproduction was so multifaceted and time-consuming that women with college and advanced degrees who did pursue professional careers expressed concerns about their inability to fulfill their responsibilities as wives and mothers because of time and role conflicts (Nelson 2000; Y.E. Kim 1998; Lett 1998). Married women were also expected to perform the principle caretaking roles for their husbands’ parents, including frequent telephone contact and visits, preparation of foods, and arranging for health care (M.H. Kim 1996; H.J. Cho 2002). In fact, much of the scholarship on urban life in South Korea during this period indicates that while the specific content of gendered role expectations changed over time, the caring burden did not diminish for women. By the 1970s, women in their prime years of adulthood were encumbered with multiple expectations: to care for their in-laws as well as their own parents; to raise successful children; to support their husbands’ work outside the home by providing a peaceful and rejuvenating environment at home; to present the appropriate image to others through informed and careful consumer choices; and to manage the household budget, often including bringing in money through outside paid work, self-employment, or investment income. These activities – time-intensive and demanding multiple cultural competencies – also drove a wider gulf between wealthier and poorer families, demarcated by class-specific behaviors and yielding significant financial and social returns on investments among families that could afford them (Nelson 2006; H.J. Cho 1995; Park and Abelmann 2004). This intensive work of domestic and social reproduction was facilitated by a dramatic transformation in fertility and family structure. A post-liberation and post-war baby boom in the 1950s alarmed ROK planners and international aid advisors, and led to the 1962 launch of the far-reaching National Family Planning Program (DiMoia 2008; E.S. Kim 1997). The program quickly exceeded expectations: the average number of lifetime births per woman fell from around six in 1960, to just over four by 1975, to three by the later 1970s, and dropped below replacement levels by the mid-1980s (D.S. Kim 1994). Fewer children at home increased the maternal focus on each child, and the monetary and financial costs of childrearing and the competition for mother-facilitated school success reinforced the expectation for women to invest heavily in their children’s achievements (H.J. Cho 1995). The falling birthrate had other implications. In combination with the cultural preference for sons, the reduction in the ideal number of children led to markedly skewed birth rates in the 1980s and 1990s. Each birth became a high-stakes lottery, and evidence suggests widespread selective abortion of female fetuses. By 1990 the overall 331

Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

gender ratio at birth was the world’s highest, at 117 boys per 100 girls overall, with more skewed ratios for first-born and later-born children (Park and Cho 1995). In response, in 1991 the government instituted a crackdown against doctors’ illegal use of ultrasound to determine fetal sex. Media spread warnings about boys who would grow up unable to find wives. These factors, combined with strengthened bonds between adult women and their aging parents (themselves related to the political structure of eldercare built upon the expectation that adult women would act as primary caregivers to aging South Korea family members and the proximity of secondgeneration urban residents to their own parents), increased the value of daughters and helped to shift the birthrates back to near normal range by the later 2000s. Democratization and increasing prosperity ushered in a decade of optimism about social change in the late 1980s. The passage of the Equal Employment Opportunity Act in 1988 was a largely symbolic victory, criticized from the beginning as addressing only the most explicit causes of economic inequality. Yet a favorable global economy supported expanding employment opportunities, creating new openings for women to work and to take on higher-profile public positions. In the context of the elimination of restrictions on international travel and the cessation of state media censorship, South Korea grew more cosmopolitan in its outlook. Greater numbers of Seoul-based international corporations hired college-educated South Korean women, setting an example for local businesses. These advances made the misogynist backlash following the Asian Financial Crisis all the harder to bear (Song 2009). In the economic crash, employment contracted and employment security all but disappeared. Media focused on the tragedy of outof-work and homeless men, emphasizing again the incongruence of masculinity and unemployment; working women were urged to abandon their jobs to allow men to retake their rightful place in society (Song 2009). As in the past (Nelson 2006), South Korean women were held responsible in public discourse for the breakdown of social norms. The falling birthrate, increase in divorce, and rising numbers of unmarried women were once more attributed to women’s inappropriate or selfish choices.11 Taken as a whole, the literature on the incorporation of South Korean women into the workforce shows that beginning in the 1950s, most women participated at some point in their lives in paid employment, and that many of these women worked in some capacity for most of their adult lives. Yet the effect of women’s labor has not been seen to have increased women’s autonomy or rights as much as might be expected; through the twentieth century, South Korean women remained subject to gendered discrimination in the processes of preparation for employment, as well as in expectations for their work, employment opportunities, and in remuneration and security of employment. Moreover, family care work remained a nearly exclusively feminine domain, demanding time and multiple skills, with strong implications for the mutual production of both class and gender. The identification of mothers with their children’s educational, matrimonial, and career success in the context of competitive, compressed development undermined the energy for political critique of patriarchy (H.J. Cho 1998, 2000). Given these ongoing practices, women’s educational achievements and employment success has been seen as having ironically reinforced gendered stereotypes in South Korea (Won 2005; Han and Ling 1998).

Feminist activism and social change To a great extent, the political struggles undertaken by activists around gender inequality in the first decades after liberation were framed as part of the efforts of national modernization and development, or were subsumed by democratization movements (Hur 2011; Chun 2003; Jones 2006; Kim and Choi 1998; Lee and Chin 2007). In the months immediately following liberation 332

Women, gender, and social change

from Japanese colonial rule, the United States Army military government in Korea viewed Korean political activists in their governance zone with suspicion, and quickly squelched the brief revival of women’s socialist activism, along with other leftist political organizing (Hur 2011), although the American promotion of gender equality under the law is reflected in the 1948 ROK Constitution mandating universal suffrage and equal rights for men and women. Political and cultural suppression of open criticism of society or government continued through the administrations of Lee Sung Man (1948–1960), Park Chung Hee (1961–1979), and Chun Doo Hwan (1980–1988). During these four decades, fundamental criticism of patriarchy in the South Korean economy or political process was subject to state repression, but calls for moderate improvements in the circumstances of women were viewed as both indicators of and tools for the modernization of the nation. Liberal forms of women’s advocacy were generally construed by government leaders (and international donors and advisors) as advancing the national political and economic interests, and as such often were not only tolerated but, in some cases, were fostered or supported by the ROK government itself. Influenced by prevailing international development theories (and the international assistance and resources that came with them), principal reform objectives included opening greater educational and employment opportunities for women as well as – particularly in the 1960s and 1970s – providing effective technologies for and knowledge of family planning (DiMoia 2008). In the 1950s and 1960s, several institutions, including the Young Women’s Christian Association (YWCA), the Korean Association of University Women, and the Korean Center for Family Law (established in 1922, 1950, and 1954, respectively), provided the dominant framework for women’s reform-oriented activism. Other significant groups in this period included the Korean National Mother’s Association (established 1958) and the Korean Federation of Housewives’ Clubs (established 1963), which focused their efforts on issues of family planning, children’s education, consumer rights, and domestic labor. The Korean National Council of Women (KNCW), founded in 1959, served to coordinate efforts and allocate resources across these women’s interest groups (Palley 1990). KNCW supported, and was supported by, the Park and Chun Administrations and their authoritarian policies (Hur 2011; Suh 2012), contributing to an estrangement of critical social activists from a focus on women’s concerns. Alongside these government “women’s” programs and sanctioned institutional actors, the more radical political efforts of women were largely subsumed by the broader labor and leftist movements of the 1960s, ’70s, and ’80s. As discussed above, large numbers of young women were recruited into factory work in the 1960s and 1970s, in part because they were presumed to be temporary workers whose wages supplemented their family income, and so they were expected to make fewer demands for better pay or work circumstances than would men. In fact, however, from the 1960s, women were actively engaged in efforts to form labor unions, and although organized labor’s chief focus was on universal (non-gendered) workers’ rights, women workers often attempted to address gender-specific concerns (such as unequal pay and unequal opportunities, as well as sexual harassment) through union advocacy (Chun 2003; H.M. Kim 2005; S.K. Kim 1997; Ogle 1990). Women workers and women labor activists faced direct repression from male management, however, who aggressively resisted pressures to negotiate with women. The events following the election of a woman as the nation’s first female labor union president at the Tongil Textile Company in 1972 are indicative of the intersecting conflicts over economic and gendered control of workplace politics. Tongil management, uncomfortable with both the gender and politics of the new union leadership, continually harassed the female union leaders and attempted unsuccessfully to undermine the next three union election cycles.12 Management used shop-floor harassment, verbal slurs, and violence in the six-year-long struggle with the union, which ultimately resulted in the disbanding of the Tongil union. Just one year 333

Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

later, in 1979, the death of a woman worker participating in a strike at the YH Trading company further highlighted the vulnerability of women workers to labor exploitation as well as violent repression; news of this particular tragedy circulated widely and contributed to the agitation that led to the coup d’état against President Park (H.M. Kim 2005; S.K. Kim 1997). Women’s activism was constrained, however, by the shifting political and economic circumstances of the period. The anti-communist atmosphere of the 1950s and 1960s, along with President Park’s embrace of a developmentalist state-business partnership, provided the ideological foundations for the suppression of worker agitation.13 Moreover, widespread unemployment throughout the 1960s undermined public sympathy for the complaints of employed workers. The decade that followed was particularly difficult for women in industry; the 1971 emergency decree suspended basic rights of collective bargaining and collective action, while overinvestment in heavy and chemical industries in the 1970s squeezed light industries and smaller businesses where most women were employed, resulting in intensified exploitation of women workers (H.M. Kim 2005). The increasingly radical tactics of labor activists in the 1980s reflected both the closer cooperation of student activists and labor activists, as well as a strategic move toward intensified confrontational politics in the context of the Chun Doo Hwan regime.14 While students, intellectuals, organizers and workers held differing opinions about tactics, strategies, and goals, nevertheless, for most activists, the specific problems workers faced as women were considered secondary to the goal of ending the era of military dictatorship. Women workers and students were drawn into activities that reflected universalist notions of citizens and workers’ issues, without much sustained consideration of gender as a factor in labor oppression. Moreover, men in union leadership positions often marginalized women delegates, and disregarded women’s demands to end wage discrimination and sexual harassment at work (Chun 2003; Ogle 1990). During this period, women activists’ perspectives were strongly shaped by their class positions. While working-class women were wrestling with exploitation on the factory floor, South Korean women intellectuals were digesting contemporary feminist theories of the operations of an international patriarchy. The process for the development of the first “women’s studies” program in South Korea, established at Ewha Womans University in 1977 as the Korean Women’s Institute (Chang 1996; Yoon 1979), provided a high-status institutional context for intellectuals to think about the contemporary problems of women in South Korea. Initially, women’s studies scholars grappled with the texts of American and European feminists as the intellectual basis for their analysis of South Korean women’s conditions. Yet quite quickly, South Korean feminists began to question the applicability of Western feminist analysis, particularly individualistic psychological theories of women’s dependence on men, as well as the focus on gender and class to the exclusion of kinship and generation. They also identified problems with the embrace of women-in-development economic policies that characterized the state-affiliated women’s movement, and with the tendency to depend on technological and legal innovation to indirectly address poverty and inequality. Other universities soon created their own women’s studies courses, and the Korean Women’s Studies Association was established in 1984 (Chang 1996). These institutional contexts of research, argument, and inquiry enabled new feminist topics to come to the fore. Over time, feminist intellectuals in South Korea developed lines of critique and analysis that reflected the specific character of local and global gender dynamics, taking into account the history of Korean Confucian patriarchal social structures and law while also considering recent historical upheavals, South Korea’s global position and relations to the US and Japan, the influence of popular culture, and class variations in women’s circumstances. Acknowledging the urgency of pressing for an end to authoritarian rule, feminists also drew 334

Women, gender, and social change

attention to the fact that problems of gender and class oppression would not be solved simply through the establishment of democracy. Students and faculty associated with women’s studies programs began to advocate changes in law, employment, education, and culture – particularly the media – to address gender-specific problems. Many scholars have noted that, following the end of Chun Doo Hwan’s military regime in 1987, activists who had been centripetally drawn into the project of democratization were finally free to identify new goals and form new organizations for social action. This has been portrayed on the one hand as a positive development, facilitating the pursuit of diverse social and cultural objectives, but it has also been criticized as a period in which radical activism was transformed into more tempered, reformist civic engagement (Song 2010; Lee and Chin 2007). The proliferation of social movement groups provided space for feminists to take on a variety of issues (e.g. gender-based violence, eco-feminism, sexual exploitation) that had been deemed of secondary importance to the overarching goal of achieving an end to military authoritarian rule. The establishment in 1987 of Korean Women’s Associations United (KWAU), a more progressive alternative to the state-aligned KNCW, provided an organizational structure for many feminist organizations to meet, argue, and form collaborations around emerging and enduring problems and goals. Legal reform was a central focus in the post-1987 period. Women’s rights advocates had been engaged in efforts to achieve legal gender equality since the 1950s, with two areas in particular – family law and employment law – receiving sustained attention. Although the 1948 Constitution guaranteed citizens protection from unequal treatment based on gender, for decades this was little more than a paper promise. From the beginning, ROK laws relating to personal and family property, inheritance, authority over children, divorce, and child custody reflected deep material as well as conceptual gender inequalities. One particularly controversial element of the legalized patriarchy was the “family head” system (hoju), which was established by the Japanese colonial authorities and maintained in the ROK Civil Code after independence. Over nearly four decades, the family head system was defended on the one hand by cultural conservatives as the legal establishment of Korean Confucian family tradition, and challenged by feminist critics as inequitable, outdated, and patriarchal. Several scholars have emphasized the role of family law, and its defense as a reflection of Korean “tradition,” in the establishment and maintenance of “androcentric society” and patriarchal culture and practice (Shin 2006; Yang 2008). While efforts to achieve reform were ongoing throughout the years of authoritarian rule, the most significant victories (for example, the 1991 revisions that removed the presumption of exclusive paternal line rights to children of divorced parents and established the principle of spousal property division upon divorce, and the 2005 repeal of the family head system) came in the context of new democratic politics. Analysts differ in their analysis of the drawn-out struggle that resulted in the 2005 repeal of the family head system, but scholars of this legal reform agree that the altered material and political conditions after 1987, as well as the diversification and professionalization of feminist activisms, were essential to the process. Yang (2008) draws attention to differences between feminist activists targeting symbolic or material impacts of the law, while Suh (2012) emphasizes the combined effects of “outsider” groups, as well as institutionalized feminist organizations utilizing different tactics to bring about family law revision. This multifaceted approach to legal and political transformation yielded many other significant achievements during the 1990s and 2000s, including the passage of the Equality in Employment Act of 1999; the establishment of the Ministry of Gender Equality in 2001; the Anti-Sexual Traffic Act of 2004; and the rising number of elected women representatives to local and national office (Kim and Kim 2013). 335

Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

Sexual violence, intimate partner violence, and commercialized sexuality also rose to prominence as feminist concerns in the 1980s and 1990s. Until the 1980s, sexual assault was interpreted as damage to a woman’s chastity, and husbands had authority over wives’ bodies such that sexual demands and intimate partner violence – sexual or otherwise – was considered a private matter (Jung 2014). The newly established women’s studies courses provided intellectual space, beginning in the 1980s, to confront the existence and extent of sexual violence in South Korean society, and to expose the material and cultural effects of the construction of sexual violence as an act that brings shame upon the victim (Shim 1998). Incidents of sexual assaults of female student activists in that decade (in particular the well-publicized sexual harassment of students arrested in an anti-government demonstration in 1984, and the notorious sexual torture case of a former student factory worker who was arrested in 1987) gave further impetus to calls for bringing the issue of sexual violence to public awareness (Jung 2014). As a result, the first hotline for women to report intimate partner violence was established in 1983, and in 1991, activists opened the first center to support victims of sexual assault. The sexual commercialization of women’s bodies also became a focal issue for feminist analysis and activism in the 1980s. Initially, feminists addressed issues of patriarchy, neo-colonialism, and the state-sanctioned exploitation of South Korean women for commercial and political gain in their criticism of the ROK role in the development of the sex tourism industry (primarily aimed at Japanese visitors) and of sexual service “camptowns” for US military personnel (K. Moon 1997; Cheng 2002; Kim and Fu 2008; J.K. Lee 2010; Yea 2005). These issues received further attention in the 1990s, when the moral and practical claims of the aging “comfort women” survivors became a rallying point for feminist activists in South Korea (Soh 2008). Yet although several scholars have pointed out that the critique of sex tourism, sexual service camps around the US bases, and the colonial era experiences of “comfort women” should be not be viewed as phenomena disconnected from the context of everyday patriarchy in the (South) Korean context (Soh 2008; Lie 1995), the closely-related topic of domestic commercialization of South Korean women’s sexuality has received much less scrutiny (cf. Chang 2005). The rights of sexual minorities in South Korea gained increasing attention beginning in the late 1990s, with the expansion of political activism around specific communities and interests and the spread of a human-rights based political discourse. Many scholars have argued that the ROK’s mobilization of Confucian principles regarding the complementarity of two distinct genders, male and female, defined same-sex desire and practice as foreign and dangerous to the nation (e.g. Bong 2008). Homophobia in South Korea became more explicit and spread during the 1980s in response to the global fear of AIDS, further tying same-sex sexuality to foreign threats. Until the early 1990s, almost all individuals whose sexuality did not conform to the ideals of heteronormativity were closeted, ignored, harassed, or attacked. Global movements in support of sexual diversity made inroads into South Korean society in the late twentieth century; the first open associations of gay men and lesbians were established, often with the collaboration of Korean and expatriate students who had been educated abroad (Bong 2008; Park-Kim, Lee-Kim, and Kwon-Lee 2007). Celebrity revelations of their same-sex desires and of transsexual histories, along with films presenting sexual minorities in a positive light, helped to expand public awareness and acceptance of non-heteronormative identities in the 1990s (Choo and Ferree 2013). But even into the first decade of the 2000s, the problems and rights of sexual minorities were not adopted as central to feminist activism. According to Park-Kim, Lee-Kim, and Kwon-Lee (2007), the specific needs and issues of lesbians were, to a large extent, ignored or misused by women’s groups and women’s studies programs. Sexual behavior is not always the overt issue: conformity to the expectations of two-partner household formation and family 336

Women, gender, and social change

reproduction is built into the social system in South Korea. Song (2014) has documented the cultural and financial obstacles facing individuals who choose not to marry; J.S.P. Cho’s ethnographic work (2009) discusses the need for “contract marriages” between gay men and lesbian women to avoid harassment. However, since the late 1990s, at the urging of GLBT intellectuals and activists, feminists have been advocating for taking sexuality and gender diversity into account in the analysis of social and cultural issues (Park-Kim, Lee-Kim, and KwonLee 2007). In sum, “the women’s movement” in South Korea has evolved from its early bifurcation into, on the one hand, state-complicit programs that took middle-class women’s concerns as universal and which assumed modernization and economic development would lead to gender equality, and on the other, labor and pro-democracy activism in which gender-specific issues were seen as secondary to the goal of resolving political catastrophe. Feminist activists with widely diverse goals now engage in tactics ranging from formal politics and legal reform to disruptive agitation, and feminist scholars critique cultural and structural arrangements and assumptions with an eye to the intersectionality of class and gender; global flows of power, people, and ideas; and the mutual influence of discourses and economic and political circumstances.

Contemporary issues in gender studies In addition to employment, education, and activism, many other social and cultural elements partake in, and contribute to, the shaping of gender in contemporary South Korea. Scholarship of South Korean gender and society in the new millennium has focused heavily on the impacts of neo-liberal politics (Song 2014), consumer culture (Joo 2012; Epstein and Joo 2012; Jun 2010), and the growing visibility of a gay and lesbian community (J.S.P. Cho 2009; Bong 2008; Choo and Ferree 2013). The influx, beginning in the early 2000s, of large numbers of foreign women – some as refugees or sex workers, but mostly as brides for hard-to-marry South Korean men – has been the focus of numerous interesting studies that shed new light on South Korean gender formation (e.g. Freeman 2011; Cheng 2002; Choo 2013; J.H. Kwon 2015). The inability for farmers, as well as urban-dwelling men with low incomes, to find South Korean women willing to marry them – and their success in attracting foreign women to join them – is the result of a number of factors, including the gender-skewed birthrates of the 1980s and 1990s, South Korea’s high “cultural capital” (and relative prosperity) in the Asian continent, increasing acceptance of young South Korean women’s rights to decide whether and whom to marry, and lingering racialized patriarchal attitudes that at once romanticize and commodify foreign women. Government policies supporting the immigration of foreign brides will have long-lasting structural and cultural implications; the mixed-heritage children are triply burdened with poverty, the presumption of a significant “biological” qualitative difference from the dominant population, and the lack of a culturally-competent manager-mother. While public propaganda to support “multicultural” families focus on appreciation of the exotic domestic practices of the wives/mothers, little is yet being done to build opportunities for the growing children to escape a life of poverty. Other topics in the gendering of contemporary society that have attracted scholarly attention include the ways devotion to evangelical church life at once liberates women from oppressive domestic responsibilities and at the same time re-interpellates them into patriarchal structures and practices (Chong 2008) and the role of media and entertainment (in particular, the Korean wave as well as Korean sports) in generating particular gender-binary ideals of masculinity and femininity of body and behavior (Y. Kim 2012; I. Kwon 2014; Joo 2012; Epstein and Joo 2012; Lie 2014; Abelmann 2003; McHugh and Abelmann 2005). 337

Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

Conclusion While the experiences of South Koreans have clearly been shaped by a strong gender binary throughout the history of the ROK, scholars have documented shifts in the specific inflections of that binary over time. Initial expectations of inside/outside, private/public divisions of women and men have been transformed over time, adding public/outside responsibilities to the burdens of women in all social classes. Rules of chastity, marriage, and childrearing have loosened for women, although wider social opportunities for escaping the demands of heteronormativity have not been accompanied by financial structures supportive of alternative lifestyle decisions, nor has the expanding population of people living outside the normative expectations freed them from the injuries of prejudice and personal attack. Early scholarship debated whether a focus on defining and identifying Korean Confucianism and Japanese colonialism as roots of South Korean patriarchal structures and culture was more important than examining material economic and political causes of women’s oppression; middle-period scholarship often embraced a goal of describing the specific effects of patriarchy in women’s daily lives; and more recently, scholars focus on integrating analysis of neo-liberalism and globalization into the local experiences and structures of gender and gender diversity. Throughout this period, however, there is scholarly consensus about the enduring importance of placing gender in the center of social and cultural analysis in South Korea.

Notes 1 We take “gender” as a term referencing socially-produced categories that build on a presumed binary distinction between men and women achieved through repetitive performance of gender identities. In this essay we do not delve more deeply into the shaky grounding of this binary distinction. We do, however, wish to recognize the fluidity not only of the content and boundaries of the binary, but of the binary formation itself, despite its enduring authority in South Korean culture. 2 While we take a thematic approach to this topic, four time periods help to structure our analysis: the years immediately following the liberation from Japanese colonial rule through the Korean war and its aftermath (1945–1960); the push to industrialization under the authoritarian administrations of Park Chung-hee and Chun Doo Hwan (1961–1988), a period of radical activism as well as increasing middleclass prosperity during which the “housewife” ideal took hold; the early democratic period and blossoming of consumer culture as well as civic activism (1988–1997); and the period ushered in by the IMF crisis and its economic, political, and cultural repercussions (1998–2014). Clearly, these are rough distinctions, characterized by both foreshadowing and inertia across the temporal lines we have drawn. Nevertheless, they will help to locate our discussion of themes in a consistent framework and in a context of wider political and cultural transitions. 3 Between 1945 and 1955, the population of South Korea is estimated to have increased by 2.8 million due to return migration and migration from the north (D.S. Kim 1994). 4 The war is estimated to have generated approximately 300,000 widows and 100,000 orphans. 5 The urban population of southern Korea was estimated at about 15 percent in 1945. 6 Employment analysts comment on South Korea’s pronounced “M-curve” participation pattern for women in the labor force. The M-curve refers to the high initial rates of employment, deep dips during the early motherhood period, and a strong return to employment as children enter school. (Y.J. Park 1990; Palley 1990) 7 While almost 70 percent of Korean school-aged boys and more than 30 percent of school-aged girls were attending some elementary school by the late colonial period, taking Koreans of all ages into consideration, in 1944 only 14 percent of the total Korean population – and only 5 percent of Korean women – had ever attended any formal school (Oh and Kim 2000). 8 The 1980 gap was, ironically, larger than that in 1960, likely reflecting demographic factors, including gender differentials in mortality and longevity. 9 Alongside this process of educational equalization, however, schools themselves played a role in gendering the population, inculcating the normative gender-binary of South Korean culture through textbooks explicitly depicting active roles for men and caring roles for women (Chung 1994: 501). 338

Women, gender, and social change

10 This is reflected in the fact that many fields of study are highly gendered, including the sciences, law, engineering, and agriculture (all overwhelmingly masculine domains) and home economics, health, and the arts (considered feminine majors) (Chung 1994). 11 Women’s own understandings of their circumstances often differ from, but also are not isolated from, such mainstream misogynistic discourse. The pace of transformation of (South) Korean culture from 1945 on was dizzying. In the context of “compressed development” (H.J. Cho 2000), women tried to make sense of personal and national history, drawing on shamans (Kendall 1985), melodrama (Abelmann 2003), Confucianism, and evangelical Christianity (Chong 2008). 12 Two incidents in the six-year-long Tongil struggle are particularly notorious. In the first, management called in riot police to end the occupation of the factory by union members after management, hoping to replace the union leadership with pro-management workers, had arrested the union president; the women removed their own clothes in an attempt to shame the men for their aggression against women and workers, but the police were undeterred. More than a dozen women were sent to the hospital and more than seventy were arrested, but the women were undaunted. Two years later, a union election was disrupted when men painted the hall with human excrement and threw it at union members. Management blamed the union for destruction of company property, and on that excuse they were able to have the union charter rescinded. For details, see Ogle (1990); S.K. Kim (1997). 13 Although the right to union organization and action is enshrined in 1953 in the Labor Union Act, in practice worker activism was widely suppressed through kidnappings, beatings, arrests, and discursive messaging holding worker activists responsible for political instability and poor economic indicators. 14 In the context of Chun’s crackdown on student activists, many radical students dropped their studies and took jobs in factories in solidarity with workers. S.K. Kim (1997) documents the experience of female student workers in factories in the 1970s and 1980s, attending to differences between workers and activists around the identification of political issues specific to women workers (see also Song 2009).

References Abelmann, N. (1996) Echoes of the Past, Epics of Dissent: A South Korean Social Movement, Berkeley: University of California Press. Abelmann, N. (2003) The Melodrama of Mobility: Women, Talk, and Class in Contemporary South Korea, Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Bong, Y.D. (2008) ‘The Gay Rights Movement in Democratizing Korea’, Korean Studies 32: 86–103. Chang, P. (2005) ‘Talking about sexuality’ in P. Chang and E. Kim (eds.) Women’s Experiences and Feminist Practices in South Korea (pp. 117–154), Seoul: Ewha Womans University Press. Chang, P. (1996) ‘Women’s Studies in Korea’, Women’s Studies Quarterly 24(1/2): 317–326. Chang, P. (1994) ‘The gender division of labor at work’, in H. Cho and P. Chang (eds.), Gender Division of Labor in Korea (pp. 13–40). Seoul: Ewha Womans University Press. Cheng, S.L. (2002) ‘Changing Lives, Changing Selves: “Trafficked” Filipina Entertainers in Korea’, Anthropology in Action 9(1): 13–20. Cho, H.J. (1988 [1981]) ‘Korean Women and Their Experiences in the Traditional World’, in The Research Institute of Asian Women (ed.) Korean Women and Culture, Seoul: The Research Institute of Asian Women, pp. 25–51. (Reprint; Originally published in The Journal of Asian Women, 1981.) Cho, H.J. (1994) ‘The “Woman Question” in the Minjok-Minju Movement: A Discourse Analysis of A New Women’s Movement in the 1980’s Korea,’ in H. Cho and P. Chang (eds.), Gender Division of Labor in Korea (pp. 324–358), Seoul: Ewha Womans University Press. Cho, H.J. (1995) ‘Children in the Examination War in South Korea: A Cultural Analysis’, in S. Stephens (ed.) Children and the Politics of Culture (pp. 141–168), Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Cho, H.J. (1998) ‘Male Dominance and Mother Power: The Two Sides of Confucian Patriarchy in Korea’, in W.H. Slote and G.A. DeVos (eds.) Confucianism and the Family (pp. 187–208), New York: SUNY Press. Cho, H.J. (2000) ‘“You are entrapped in an imaginary well”: the formation of subjectivity within compressed development – a feminist critique of modernity and Korean culture.’ M. Shin (trans.), Inter-Asia Cultural Studies 1(1): 49–69. Cho, H.J. (2002) ‘Living with conflicting subjectivities: Mother, motherly wife, and sexy woman in the transition from colonial-modern to post-modern Korea’, in L. Kendall (ed.) Under Construction: The 339

Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

Gendering of Modernity, Class and Consumption in the Republic of Korea (pp. 165–196), Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Cho, H. (2005) ‘The Public-Private Division and the Quality of Women’s Lives’, in J.H. Oh (ed.) Globalization and Feminism in Korea (pp. 2–32). Seoul: Korean Women’s Institute at Ewha Womans University, Prunsasang Publishing. Cho, H. and P. Chang (eds.) (1994) Gender Division of Labor in Korea. Seoul: Ewha Womans University Press. Cho, J.S.P. (2009) ‘The Wedding Banquet Revisited: “Contract Marriages” between Korean gays and lesbians’, Anthropological Quarterly 82(2): 401–422. Cho, O. (1998) ‘The Problem of Identity Among Peasant Women in Korea’, Korea Journal 38(2): 66–81. Cho, U. and H. Koo (1983) ‘Economic Development and Women’s Work in a Newly Industrializing Country: The Case of Korea’, Development and Change 14(4): 515–531. Chong, K. (2008) Deliverance and Submission: evangelical women and the negotiation of patriarchy in South Korea, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Asia Center. Choo, H.Y. (2013) ‘The Cost of Rights: Migrant Women, Feminist Advocacy, and Gendered Morality in South Korea’, Gender & Society 27(4): 445–468. Choo, H.Y. and M.M. Ferree (2013) ‘Sexual Citizenship and Suffering Subjects: Media Discourse about Teenage Homosexuality in South Korea’ in C-M. Pascale (ed.) Inequality and the Politics of Representation: A Global Landscape (pp.128–143), New York: Sage. Chun, S. (2003) They Are Not Machines: Korean Women Factory Workers and Their Fight for Democratic Trade Unionism in the 1970s, Farnham, Surrey, UK: Ashgate Publishers. Chung, J.S. (1994) ‘Women’s Unequal Access to Education in South Korea’, Comparative Education Review 38(4): 487–505. DiMoia, J. (2008) ‘알맞게 낳아서 훌륭하게 기르자! (Let’s Have the Proper Number of Children and Raise Them Well!): Family Planning and Nation-Building in South Korea, 1961–1968’, East Asia Science, Technology and Society 2: 361–379. Epstein, S.J. and R.M. Joo (2012) ‘Multiple Exposures: Korean Bodies and the Transnational Imagination’, The Asia-Pacific Journal 10(33), August 13. Freeman, C. 2011. Making and Faking Kinship: Marriage and Labor Migration between China and South Korea, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Han, J. and L.H.M. Ling (1998) ‘Authoritarianism in the Hypermasculine State: Hybridity, Patriarchy and Capitalism in Korea’, International Studies Quarterly 42(1): 53–78. Henry, T. (Forthcoming) “Queer Lives as Cautionary Tales: Female Same-Sex Marriage in the HeteroPatriarchal Imagination of Authoritarian South Korea,” in T.A. Henry (ed.) Remembering Queer Korea: Modern/Colonial, Contemporary, and Current Formations. Hur, S.W. (2011) ‘Mapping South Korean Women’s Movements Before and After Democratization: Shifting Identities’, in J. Broadbent and V. Brockman (eds.) East Asian Social Movements, New York: Springer, pp. 181–203. Janelli, R. with D. Yim (1993) Making Capitalism: The Social and Cultural Construction of a South Korean Conglomerate, Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Jones, N.A. (2006) Gender and the Political Opportunities of Democratization in South Korea, New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Joo, R. (2012) Transnational Sport: Gender, Media, and Global Korea, Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Jun, S. (2010) Korean Masculinities and Transcultural Consumption: Yonsama, Rain, Old Boy, K-Pop Idols, Hong Kong: Hong Kong University Press. Jung, K. (2014) Practicing Feminism in South Korea: The Women’s Movement Against Sexual Violence, New York: Routledge. Kendall, L. (1985) Shamans, Housewives, and Other Restless Spirits, Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Kendall, L. (ed.) (2002a) Under Construction: The gendering of modernity, class and consumption in the Republic of Korea, Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Kendall, L. (2002b) ‘Introduction’, in L. Kendall (ed.), Under Construction: The gendering of modernity, class and consumption in the Republic of Korea (pp. 1–24), Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Kim, D.S. (1994) ‘The Demographic Transition in the Korean Peninsula, 1910–1990: South and North Korea Compared’, The Korean Journal of Population and Development 23(2): 131–155. Kim, E.H. (1998) ‘Men’s Talk: A Korean American View of South Korean Constructions of Women, Gender, and Masculinity’, in E.H. Kim and C. Choi (eds.) Dangerous Women: Gender and Korean Nationalism (pp. 67–118), London & New York: Routledge. 340

Women, gender, and social change

Kim, E.H. and C. Choi (eds.) (1998) Dangerous Women: Gender and Korean Nationalism, London & New York: Routledge. Kim, H.M. (1997) ‘Gender/Sexuality system as a labor control mechanism: Gender identity of Korean female workers in a U.S. multinational corporation’, Korea Journal 37(2): 56–70. Kim, E.S. (1997) ‘Women and the Culture Surrounding Childbirth’, Korea Journal : 174–194. Kim, H.M. (2005) ‘The Formation of Subjectivities among Korean Women Workers: A Historical Review’ in P. Chang and E.S. Kim (eds.) Women’s Experiences and Feminist Practices in South Korea (pp. 177–204), Seoul: Ewha Womans University Press. Kim, H.M. (2007) ‘The State and Migrant Women: Diverging Hopes in the Making of “Multicultural Families” in Contemporary Korea’, Korea Journal 47(4): 100–122. Kim, H.S. (2009) ‘Life and Work of Korean War Widows During the 1950s’, The Review of Korean Studies 12(4): 87–109. Kim, J.K. and M. Fu (2008) ‘International Women in South Korea’s Sex Industry: A New Commodity Frontier’, Asian Survey 48(3): 492–513. Kim, M.H. (1992) ‘Late Industrialization and Women’s Work in Urban South Korea: An Ethnographic Study of Upper-Middle-Class Families’, City & Society 6(2): 156–173. Kim, M.H. (1995) ‘Gender, Class, and Family in Late-Industrializing South Korea’, Asian Journal of Women’s Studies 1:58–86. Kim, M.H. (1996) ‘Changing Relationships Between Daughters-in-Law and Mothers-in-Law in Urban South Korea’, Anthropological Quarterly 69(4):179–192. Kim, S.K. (1997) Class Struggle or Family Struggle? The Lives of Women Factory Workers in South Korea, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Kim, S.K. and K. Kim (2013) The Korean Women’s Movement and the State, Abingdon, Oxon, UK: Routledge. Kim, Y.E. (1998) ‘Home is a place to rest: constructing the meaning of work, family and gender in the Korean middle class’, Korea Journal 38(2): 168–213. Kim, Y. (2012) Women, Television, and Everyday Life in Korea: Journeys of Hope, London: Taylor and Francis. Kim, Y.G. and S.J. Hahn (2006) ‘Homosexuality in Ancient and Modern Korea’, Culture, Health and Sexuality 8(1): 59–65. Koo, H. (1990) ‘From Farm to Factory: Proletarianization in Korea’, American Sociological Review 55(5): 669–681. Kwon, I. (2014) ‘It all leads to education: Korean motherhood, patriarchy, and class consciousness in the TV Drama Eligible Wife (Anaeui Jagyeok)’, Review of Korean Studies 17(1): 39–70. Kwon, J.H. (2015) ‘The Work of Waiting: Love and Money in Korean Chinese Transnational Migration’, Cultural Anthropology 30(2): 477–500. Lee, A.R. and H.C. Lee (2013) ‘The Women’s Movement in South Korea Revisited’, Asian Affairs: An American Review 40: 43–66. Lee, A.R. and M. Chin (2007) ‘The Women’s Movement in South Korea’, Social Science Quarterly 88(5): 1205–1226. Lee, J.K. (2010) Service Economies: Militarism, Sex work, and Migrant Labor in South Korea. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Lee, J.J.H. (2002) ‘Discourses of Illness, Meanings of Modernity: A Gendered Construction of Sônginbyông’, in L. Kendall (ed.) Under Construction: The gendering of modernity, class and consumption in the Republic of Korea (pp. 58–75), Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Lee, K.C. (1995) ‘Confucian Ethics, Judges, and Women: Divorce Under the Revised Family Law’, Pacific Rim Law & Policy Journal 4(2): 479–503. Lee, N. (2007) The Making of the Minjung: Democracy and the Politics of Representation in South Korea, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Lee, S.H. (2002) ‘The Concept of Female Sexuality in Korean Popular Culture’, in L. Kendall (ed.) Under Construction: The Gendering of Modernity, Class and Consumption in the Republic of Korea (pp. 141–164), Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Lett, D.P. (1998) In Pursuit of Status: The Making of South Korea’s ‘New’ Urban Middle Class, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Lie, J. (1995) ‘The Transformation of Sexual Work in 20th-Century Korea’, Gender and Society 9(3): 310–327. Lie, J. (1998) Han Unbound: The Political Economy of South Korea, Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Lie, J. (2014) K-Pop: Popular Music, Cultural Amnesia, and Economic Innovation in South Korea. Oakland, CA: U.C. Press. McHugh, K. and N. Abelmann (eds.) (2005) South Korean Golden Age Melodrama: Gender, Genre, and National Cinema, Detroit, MI: Wayne State University Press. 341

Laura C. Nelson and Cho Haejoang

Moon, K. (1997) Sex Among Allies: Military Prostitution in US-Korea Relations, New York: Columbia University Press. Moon, S. (2002) ‘Carving Out Space: Civil Society and the Women’s Movement in South Korea’, Journal of Asian Studies 61(2): 473–500. Moon, S. (2005) Militarized Modernity and Gendered Citizenship in South Korea, Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Nelson, L.C. (2000) Measured Excess: Status, Gender, and Consumer Nationalism in South Korea, New York: Columbia University Press. Nelson, L.C. (2006) ‘South Korean Consumer Nationalism: Women, Children, Credit, and Other Perils’ in S.M. Garon and P.L. Maclachlan (eds.) The Ambivalent Consumer: Questioning Consumption in East Asia and the West (pp. 188–208), Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Oh, S.C. and K.S. Kim (2000) ‘Japanese Colonial Education as Contested Terrain: What Did Koreans Do in the Expansion of Elementary Schooling?’ Asia Pacfic Education Review 1(1): 75–89. Ogle, G. (1990) South Korea: Dissent within the Economic Miracle, London and New Jersey: Zed Books, Ltd. Palley, M.L. (1990) ‘Women’s Status in South Korea: Tradition and Change’, Asian Survey 30(12): 1136–1153. Park, B.P. and N.H. Cho (1995) ‘Consequences of Son Preference in a Low-Fertility Society: Imbalance of the Sex Ratio at Birth in Korea’, Population and Development Review 21(1): 59–84. Park, K.A. (1993) ‘Women and Development: The Case of South Korea’, Comparative Politics 25(2): 127–145. Park, S.Y. (2012) ‘Stitching the Fabric of Family: Time, Work and Intimacy in Seoul’s Tongdaemun Market’, Journal of Korean Studies 17(2): 383–406. Park, S.J. and N. Abelmann (2004) ‘Class and Cosmopolitan Striving: Mother’s Management of English Education in Korea’, Anthropological Quarterly 77(4): 645–672. Park, Y.J. (1990) ‘Korean Patterns of Women’s Labor Force Participation During the Period, 1960–1980’, Korea Journal of Population and Development 19(1): 71–90. Park-Kim, S.J., S.Y.Lee-Kim, and E.J. Kwon-Lee (2007) ‘The Lesbian Rights Movement and Feminism in South Korea’, Journal of Lesbian Studies 10(3–4): 161–190. DOI 10.1300/J155v10n03_11. Seong, M.J. (2009) ‘Gender Inequality in Educational Attainment in South Korea, 1950s–1990s’, The Women’s Studies 77(2): 179–206. Seth, M. (2002) Education Fever: Society, Politics and the Pursuit of Schooling in South Korea, Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Shim, Y.H. (1998) ‘Sexual Violence and Sexual Harassment in a Risk Society’, Korea Journal 38(1): 102–130. Shin, K.Y. (2006) ‘The Politics of the Family Law Reform Movement in Contemporary Korea: A Contentious Space for Gender and the Nation’, The Journal of Korean Studies 11(1): 93–125. Shin Gills, D.S. (1999) Rural Women and Triple Exploitation in Korean Development, New York: St. John’s Press. Soh, C.S. (2008) The Comfort Women: Sexual Violence and Post-Colonial Memory in Korea and Japan, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Song, J. (2009) South Korea in the Debt Crisis: The Creation of a Neo-Liberal Welfare Society, Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Song, J. (2010) ‘“A Room of One’s Own”: The Meaning of Spatial Autonomy for Unmarried Women in Neoliberal South Korea’, Gender, Place and Culture: A Journal of Feminist Geography 17(2): 131–149. Song, J. (2014) Living on Your Own: Single Women, Rental Housing, and Post-Revolutionary Affect in Contemporary South Korea, Albany, NY: SUNY Press. Spencer, R. (1988) Yŏgong: Factory Girl, Seoul: Royal Asiatic Society, Korea Branch. Suh, D. (2012) ‘The Dual Strategy and Gender Politics of the Women’s Movement in Korea: Family Headship System Repeal Through Strategic Innovation’, Sociological Focus 44:2, 124–148, DOI 10.1080/00380237.2011.10571391. Won, S.Y. (2005) ‘Play the Men’s Game? Accommodating Work and Family in the Workplace’, Asian Journal of Women’s Studies 11(3): 7–35. Yang, H. (2008) ‘A Journey of Family Law Reform in Korea: Tradition, Equality, and Social Change’, Journal of Korean Law 8: 77–94. Yea, S. (2005) ‘Labor of Love: Filipina Entertainers’ Narratives of Romance and Relationships with the GIs in the US Military Camp Towns in Korea’, Women’s Studies International Forum 28(6): 456–472. Yoo, G. (2003) ‘Women in the Workplace: Gender and Wage Differentials’, Social Science Indicators Research 62/63: 365–385. Yoon, S.Y. (1979) ‘Women’s Studies in Korea’, Signs 4(4): 751–762. 342

24 The post-developmental state Economic and social changes since 1997 Jamie Doucette

Introduction This chapter discusses some of the broad economic and social changes that have shaped South Korea’s political economy since the 1997–98 Asian financial crisis. In short, that crisis led to expanded social inequality and diminished economic growth: consequences that have challenged policy makers, intellectuals, and social movements ever since. By extension, these changes have influenced the very understanding of Korea’s pattern of economic development. Once thought to be a pristine example of a ‘developmental state,’ the supposed virtues of the high-debt, stateled model were called into question following the economic crisis. State-business networks were reconfigured to promote greater transparency. New debt limits and other restrictions were placed on Korea’s large family-led conglomerates chaebol (chaebŏl) to improve their corporate governance. Free-market oriented policies were embraced as an alternative to developmentalism. However, in light of job insecurity and a less rapid pace of growth following neoliberal restructuring, the vices and virtues of the so-called ‘Korean model’ remain the subject of considerable public debate across the political spectrum, with some arguing for a return to the ‘golden days’ of the high-debt model and others for continued market-oriented reform as potential solutions for restoring economic growth and addressing social inequality. For many, the global economic downturn since 2008 has only made the need for solutions to these problems all the more pressing. Using the 1997–98 financial crisis as its point of departure, the aim of this chapter is to survey some of these broad changes that have occurred since 1997 with a focus on the challenges they have raised for the task of addressing inequality and expanding social welfare. The crisis was a watershed moment that crystallized a pattern of growing economic inequality, of which there are several causes: the growth of the irregular and migrant workforce; the expansion of speculative forms of investment in credit markets, stocks, and real estate; and diminished rates of economic growth stand out as the most salient. As discussed below, the source of these changes have much to do with the particular ways in which the institutions once known as Korea’s ‘developmental state’ – particularly, its financial and labour market policies, but also policies towards migration and urban and regional planning, among others – have been restructured at 343

Jamie Doucette

the behest of both domestic and international actors. Judged on the aforementioned policy areas alone, the period since 1997 is best considered to be an era of the post-developmental state, as many, though not all, of the institutions associated with the high-debt and high-growth model of the Park Chung-hee (Pak Chŏng-hŭi) period have been restructured. This transition does not mean, however, that the Korean state suddenly ceased to play an important role in shaping economic growth. Indeed, it still continues to regulate the economy – and, in some areas, its capacities to do so have been considerably enhanced – and even attempts to develop strategic sectors. My point is simply that the institutions associated with the highdebt model at its peak have been gradually, and in some cases abruptly, transformed. Furthermore, this has not in all cases been a negative process either, as this transformation has intersected with changes brought about through the ongoing process of democratization: including the expansion of labour and civil rights and the election of liberal administrations with an oppositional legacy tied to the democracy movements of the 1970s and 1980s.1 Nonetheless, economic restructuring has raised difficult, strategic challenges for the actors involved, particularly the liberal administrations of Kim Dae-jung (Kim Tae-jung) and Roh Moo-hyun (No Mu-hyŏn) that emerged from the broader constellation of forces that composed Korea’s democracy movements of the 1970s and 80s. These presidents promised to satisfy longstanding demands for greater social welfare and distribution but found themselves in the unenviable situation of having to steer the Korean economy through financial crises while also pursuing democratic reforms. Unfortunately, the embrace of free-market-oriented economic policies by these liberal governments exacerbated existing social inequalities. This led to popular complaints and voter dissatisfaction, and opened up democratic reformers associated with the liberal administrations to charges, from the left, of not living up to the legacy of the democracy movement and, from the right, of letting the economy falter under their watch, creating a ‘lost decade’ of economic growth. As a consequence of both the financial crisis and the expanding inequality that followed, the high-growth Park Chung-hee years have become, for many, an object of nostalgia. By depicting the Park era as a golden age of full employment, conservative political forces have sought to capitalize not only on their traditional support base among rural and regionalist voters but also to speak to an increasingly insecure generation of urban workers. Against his liberal predecessors, conservative president Lee Myung-bak (Yi Myŏng-bak) – who earned the nickname ‘the bulldozer’ for his tenure as CEO of Hyundai Construction – organized his 2007 election campaign on the promise of a return to the high-growth economic policies of the Park era. However, the global economic crisis and Lee’s pro-chaebol policies failed to revive the high-growth model. Instead, Lee’s administration became mired in controversy, much of it directed at his ecologically destructive and poorly constructed Four Major Rivers Restoration Project. While Lee’s successor, Park Geun-hye (Pak Kŭn-hye), daughter of former dictator Park Chung-hee, distanced herself from Lee’s discredited policies during the 2012 presidential elections. Her advisors depicted Park as a leader whose lineage positioned her as the appropriate figure to foster economic revival. Nonetheless, Park’s policies to date have done little to distinguish her from previous conservative administrations despite earlier promises to promote ‘economic democratization’ and foster a ‘creative economy’. Such rose-coloured views of the high-growth Park era, and prescriptions for a return to it, are not limited to the right, however. Prominent left-liberal reformers, such as the globally recognized development economist Ha-joon Chang have also praised the institutions of rapid development created by Park Chung-hee and advocated that progressives take a lesson from Park’s playbook in order to foster a Korean-style welfare state: one that would affirm the strategic economic planning of the Park Chung-hee period, but without endorsing the repression of 344

The post-developmental state

labour and civil rights. In advance of the 2012 election, Chang and his colleagues (H.J. Chang et al. 2012) advocated that a grand compromise be made between the state and the chaebol, whereby the state would guarantee the management rights of chaebol families – most of whom control their firms indirectly through dense, and often illegal, patterns of cross-shareholding among affiliates – in return for an agreement on increased taxation, investment, and job creation. However, these calls were drowned out by a growing consensus among moderate conservatives and liberal-progressives that ‘economic democracy’ based on principles of a ‘fair market economy’ that limits the power of the chaebol should be the guiding principle of future economic reform. As mentioned above, Park Geun-hye used this slogan during the election, but revised her promises to expand social welfare and quickly reverted to a pro-business platform after the election. The debate thus continues over how to reform the Korean economy and along what lines. This chapter is organized as follows. In the next two sections, I outline some of the major changes to Korea’s political economy since 1997: the first to the financial market and the second to the labour market. In the third section, I discuss some of the more recent proposals that have been made surrounding solutions to the problem of social inequality and the resilient power of the chaebol in the Korean economy.

The end of the high-debt model While scholars dispute the cause of the 1997–98 Asian financial crisis – some see it as the result of ‘crony capitalism’ while others see it as the effect of premature liberalization, and some both – there is a general consensus among them that the crisis spelled the end of Korea’s highdebt model of development (Hart-Landsberg 2001). For decades prior to the crisis, the Korean state supported this model by effectively bank-rolling Korea’s large family-led conglomerates through a variety of means, including export subsidies, policy-driven loans geared towards industrial upgrading and expanding the export market, and tight regulation of import and export licenses. These policies produced the highly diversified, but also highly indebted, industrial conglomerates known as the chaebol. Scholars associated with the theory of the developmental state praised these industrial policies for undergirding the chaebol growth and allowing Korea to rapidly catch up with industrialized countries. They argued that Korea’s embrace of pro-active, industrial policy showed that there was an alternative to the laissez-faire approach to development being promoted under the Washington Consensus and that countries that eschewed that model may even develop at a more rapid pace. Despite the high debt levels associated with this strategy, if combined with appropriate, long-range planning to promote export-led growth, this formula could lead to rapid growth and industrial upgrading (cf. S.I. Jeong 2004). While scholars debated the virtues of this model throughout the 1990s and into the present, the financial and industrial policies that had been identified by scholars of Korea’s ‘developmental state’ had already been gradually rolled back in advance of the 1997 financial crisis. The reform process had begun slowly at the end of the Park Chung-hee period (Y.T. Kim 1999) as state planners became worried about the power of Korea’s large conglomerates and sought to disperse their ownership so as to avoid an over-concentration of economic power. These early efforts at dispersing ownership and, by extension, encouraging markets for corporate control were largely unsuccessful. After all, as development state theorists have argued, Korea’s industrial policies were primarily oriented towards bolstering the monopoly power of the chaebol, provided they conform to a variety of performance-based targets aimed at expanding their productive capacity and exports to foreign markets. Whether or not there was a competitive market for the ownership of these firms (or corporate governance laws thoroughly enforced) was a second-order concern 345

Jamie Doucette

provided that the chaebol met their targets and did not seek to compete with the ruling bloc for political power. These early efforts at financial reform continued slowly throughout 1980s. However, the restructuring of Korea’s strategic industrial and financial policies did not pick up the pace until the government of Roh Tae-woo (who revived efforts to reduce cross-shareholding among the chaebol) before accelerating considerably with the announcement of Kim Young-sam’s (Kim Yŏng-sam) globalization (segyehwa) drive in the early 1990s. This drive aimed to foster more competitive market conditions by continuing to phase out policy loans and by liberalizing external borrowing on short-term credit markets. While these reforms were intended to strengthen competition by promoting a more competitive financial market, at the same time they exposed the Korean economy to new risks by weakening the ability of the Korean government to regulate the investments made by the conglomerates. The chaebol used this opportunity to finance new investments using credit obtained through poorly regulated financial intermediaries such as nonbank financial institutions (NBFIs) that borrowed extensively on foreign short-term credit markets. In summary, while much had changed before 1997, the highly indebted chaebol remained a constant. When the collapse of the Thai baht in 1997 caused international lenders to call in the short-term credit they had advanced to Korean firms and financial institutions, the NBFIs became rapidly insolvent, leading to a run on the Korean won and exacerbating the effects of the crisis. Due to exposure to international lenders’ rapidly changing short-term interest rates, many of the chaebol were exposed to the credit crunch induced by the 1997–98 financial crisis, and several of the top thirty business groups went bankrupt. The government was forced to intervene. As a consequence, the high-debt model would not survive the crisis. For many democratic reformers, liberal economists and international observers this was a good thing. They had long been critical of the behaviour of the chaebol in the Korean economy and the ways in which the government had allowed economic power to be concentrated in their hands. For instance, the IMF and other international lenders saw the high debt levels (the debt-equity ratio of the top thirty chaebol reached over 400 per cent by 1996, the year preceding the crisis) and low profitability of the chaebol as a moral hazard: a symptom of an underlying ‘crony capitalism’ (Kang 2002). This attitude was not unique to the IMF, however, but was shared by many domestic political forces as well. Prominent liberal economists regarded the crisis as the symptom of an underlying ‘virus’ whose source was the market-distorting power of the chaebol (Jang 2001: 73). They argued that the chaebol had used their murky corporate structure and control over affiliates to distort market competition, exploit subcontractors, and collude with corrupt politicians. This critical view of the chaebol was commensurate with Kim Dae-jung’s long promoted vision of a ‘mass participatory economy’. Under this vision, Kim promoted a liberal market economy model supported by an active civil society that, together with the government, would check the power of the chaebol and introduce greater transparency and accountability into economic planning (D.J. Kim 1985). Thus, for both Kim and many liberal activists in civil society organizations, the promotion of the market economy was seen as a way to dislodge the nexus between the state and domestic capital that had informed the old regime and re-embed the economy in more transparent relations. Chaebol reform was also strongly supported by the minority shareholder movement. This movement that had grown throughout the mid-to-late 1990s and sought to challenge the concentration of economic power in the hands of the chaebol through direct participation in the management of chaebol affiliates (Kalinowski 2008). The movement targeted the dense, and in most cases illegal, cross-shareholding (sanghoch’ulcha) practices through which chaebol families maintained managerial control over their affiliate firms, despite the fact they only held a fraction 346

The post-developmental state

of total company stock. This dense cross-shareholding structure allowed ruling families to exercise managerial discretion over all their affiliates; hence, critics complained that this structure usurped the opportunities of minority shareholders and constituted a moral hazard. They were particularly critical of the illegal transfers of controlling shares and other assets used to pass down ownership of the firm to the younger generation. Finally, chaebol reformers saw the high level of diversification within chaebol groups as a vice – an “octopus-like strategy of engaging in all businesses from A to Z” (Jang 2001: 75) – one that led to overreach and was reliant on excessive debt financing that eroded profitability. These reasons combined provided a strong rationale for eliminating cross-shareholding between affiliates and treating them as independent firms so that an allegedly more transparent and accountable management culture could be inculcated. In the words of one key economic reformer who led the shareholder rights movement, the existing system’s “entrenchment of authority, coupled with the lack of transparency, means it is impossible to make chaebol management accountable for failure or inefficiency” (Jang 2001: 82). For many economic reform activists and liberal politicians, the financial crisis thus represented a strategic opportunity to restructure the chaebol. As prominent Seoul National University economist Chung Un-chan put it at the time, “If such a great opportunity is squandered, we may not see another chance for a long time” (Chung 1999: 29). While not all were in favour of the IMF’s treatment regime of high interest rates, privatization, and austerity, many Korean government officials enthusiastically embraced the IMF treatment a necessary tool for change. Some of Kim Dae-jung’s core advisors, such as Bank of Korea governor Chon Chol-hwan (Chŏn Ch’ŏl-hwan) and Chief Economic Advisor Kim Young-kum, went above and beyond the IMF prescriptions and carried out supplementary reforms aimed at increasing transparency and expanding foreign ownership of Korean firms. In the wake of the crisis, strict debt limits were placed on the chaebol, and new regulations on cross-shareholding, succession, and diversification introduced (see K.W. Kim 2004 for an account of corporate governance reforms in particular). Distressed banks and financial institutions were privatized, and many purchased by foreign investors. After the initial recovery from the crisis, the state’s financial support of the chaebol was considerably rolled back. Instead of policy loans and performance targets for the chaebol, in the years after the crisis, the Kim and Roh governments sought to attract foreign capital to stimulate new investment. They did so in a variety of ways that included the negotiation of several bilateral free trade agreements (the most controversial of which was the Korea-US FTA); the rolling out of several new special economic zones that offered foreign firms generous exceptions on local taxes and regulations; and through the construction of an ‘international financial center’ in Youido that aimed to turn Korea into a regional ‘hub’ for financial services. However, none of these policies led to considerable foreign investment beyond the initial rush to purchase distressed assets in the wake of the crisis. And despite their impressive architecture and urban planning, neither the hub nor the zone policies have attracted the levels of foreign firms and investment they were originally intended to attract.

Labouring in lean times The punishment for the alleged ‘sins’ of the chaebol leading up to the crisis were not solely experienced by the ruling families themselves. The five biggest firms used the crisis to grow even larger. Instead, Korean workers were quickly and deeply affected as numerous firms faced bankruptcy when they could not service the rapidly expanding interest payments on their debt. For the most part, labour was asked to bear the majority of the burden of the transformation of Korean capitalism towards a more market-oriented model. A famous protest slogan from 347

Jamie Doucette

that period read: “I.M.F. = I’m fired.” The slogan captured the predicament of workers as firm after firm went bankrupt or was restructured, leading to layoffs, dismissals, and retrenchment. For many white- and blue-collar workers, these feelings of uncertainty and lack of security have continued to be felt since the crisis due to the proliferation of irregular or ‘non-regular’ forms of work – contract, temporary, day-shift, or other forms of insecure employment – that were institutionalized in the aftermath of the crisis. As S.J. Jeong (2007) has shown, the exploitation of labour through increased working hours and lower pay helped steer the recovery from the crisis and have, by and large, made Korean capitalism more profitable for capital since the crisis – leading to a recovery in the manufacturing rate of profit and even higher rates of profit for the financial sector. Despite this outcome, however, this increased exploitation did not lead to major increases in domestic investment, economic growth, or considerable expansion in welfare. It is perhaps one of the ironies of Korean democratization that the expansion of non-regular work that followed the crisis would probably not have been possible without the existence of a social dialogue between government, business, and labour. In other words, despite the fact that it was seen as undermining democratic demands for socio-economic equality, this expansion of non-regular work was itself facilitated by a gradual democratization of the relations between labour, business, and the state, including the recognition of umbrella union federations and an expansion of collective bargaining at multiple scales. This choice of social dialogue was largely due to the political context surrounding the election of Kim Dae-jung, whose support base included not only the southwestern Honam region but also, more importantly, the civil society and social movement organizations that emerged from the democracy movement. Moreover, the expansion of labour rights and representation of working class interests in politics had long been a demand of the democracy movement, a demand that Kim could not easily betray (Gray 2009). Kim could not fall back on the earlier, despotic modes of labour control favoured by his conservative predecessors, who had outlawed the democratic trade union movement and often moved quickly to repress strikes. Furthermore, for much of the 1990s, the democratic trade union movement had successfully contested managerial despotism at the firm level and had developed strong and independent workplace unions. Thus, instead of falling back on the coercive, and primarily enterprise-based labour relations of the developmental state era, Kim pursued national-level social dialogue to pursue a negotiated marketization of employment relations that expanded precarious work and eased redundancy, while providing for a minimal expansion of social welfare. In the midst of the crisis, the Economic and Social Development Commission (Korea’s main tripartite body) produced an agreement – though one subsequently rejected by the labour movement’s rank and file – that allowed for greater use of temporary and nonregular workers in specific sectors in exchange for expansion of social welfare and expanded coverage of the national pension and social security systems. However, for many, this nominal expansion of social security did not make up for the greater insecurity and increasing inequality caused by the crisis. Despite these results, some scholars considered Kim’s social compromise to represent the emergence of a unique Korean or East Asian style welfare regime: an alternative to the “excessive benefits” of universal models of welfare provision in Western countries (Kim government, cited in Gray 2009: 140). For instance, Kong (2004) interprets Kim’s social compromise as an effective response to the 1997 crisis as it restored international confidence in South Korea and allowed employment to rebound by promoting a “productivist conception of welfare” that can contain social-welfare costs and offer “high labour flexibility and the employment-led (rather than redistribution-led) alleviation of poverty” (30). Thus, Korea’s shortterm or ‘crisis corporatism’ was seen as an alternative to shock therapy: a more inclusive 348

The post-developmental state

neoliberalism pursued without the exclusion of labour. However, many observers overemphasized the ‘inclusive’ nature of this agreement by ignoring the greater labour insecurity and poor quality employment contract it endorsed. Criticizing the overly optimistic reception of Korean government’s welfare policies, Gray (2009) argues that Kim’s reforms established not a redistributive welfare state but a minimalist ‘workfare’ state. A number of Kim’s social assistance policies, such as his Minimum Living Standard Guarantee Programme were tied to training and community work as conditions (Kwon 2006: 732). Furthermore, the further commodification of labour that was bargained as a condition for this expansion effectively weakened labour’s bargaining power, which in turn has hampered further longer-term social partnership (cf. Gray 2009: 140–149). As casual workers are less likely to earn significant benefits under the system, which is compulsory but suffers from poor enforcement, welfare expansion has thus predominantly benefitted male and regular workers employed at large enterprises where they enjoy strong bargaining power rather than casualized, day, and self-employed workers who are known in Korea as non-regular workers. Since 1997–98, the flexibilization and marketization of employment relations have only expanded despite the fact that the Korean Confederation Trade Unions (KCTU) pulled out of further tripartite participation in protest of the original post-crisis reforms. Non-regular employment relations soon became further institutionalized as the government sought to expand the sectors in which irregular workers could be employed or took a casual approach to labour law enforcement. In the early 2000s it announced that it would expand the number of sectors where non-regular contracts could persist, eventually passing legislation in 2007 that removed limits on the sectors that could employ non-regular workers. At present, the number of non-regular workers in the Korean economy is somewhere between 34 per cent to greater than 50 per cent depending on how one measures it.2 Even by conservative estimates, this figure does not paint a hopeful image of social mobility. That this expansion occurred and was institutionalized under the watch of the liberal administrations of Kim Dae-jung and his predecessor Roh Moo-hyun – who expanded Kim’s labour market reforms through another ‘grand social compromise’ (one signed without participation of the KCTU) in 2007 – eventually led to the loss of support for these administrations and charges that they had not lived up to the aspirations of the democracy movement (Choi 2012). Finally, there are significant social dimensions to this expansion of non-regular work. For one, non-regular work is heavily gendered. The trans-nationalization of the Korean labour market through the expansion of foreign migrant labour and marriage migration also means that many migrants have found themselves in precarious employment relations. Jennifer J.Y. Chun (2010) argues that the situation represented by many of these workers is one of ‘legal liminality’. She notes how many of the intense labour struggles over the past 15 years have been waged around struggles over classification: whether a worker is regular or not, or even recognized as a ‘worker’ rather than a ‘contractor’; whether the organization that pays their wages is really their ‘employer’ or client; whether the workers themselves are to be accorded the same labour rights and human rights of naturalized citizens, and so on. The site of democratic labour struggle has thus dramatically shifted since the 1990s, moving from the struggle to establish independent unions to efforts to stem the expansion of non-regular work. While the large union confederations were slow to embrace the struggles of non-regular workers, they have gradually come to see such struggles as strategically important, given that the marketization of employment relations has enabled business to regain significant managerial control over workers and diminished the labour movement’s associational power, especially in smaller workplaces in which the labour movement has long had difficulty organizing. 349

Jamie Doucette

Despite the fact that Korean workers enjoy greater collective bargaining due to democratization, the struggles of non-regular workers have often been very intense as these labour rights have been more difficult to effectively exercise. For instance, when the legislation to expand non-regular work was announced in 2003, it was followed by the protest-suicides of several unionists at large firms such as Hyundai Heavy Industries. In many cases the strikes of these workers had been ruled illegal, and unionists’ assets were taken under damage claims and provision seizures that have become a common way of dealing with strikes since then, and that impose difficult personal costs for the workers involved (Doucette 2013). Since the late 2000s the struggles of irregular workers have continued to be intense, with workers resorting to a number of often desperate tactics such as factory occupations, high altitude protests (actions such as climbing construction cranes, transmission towers, or billboards), sambo ilpae marches (three steps, one bow) and ‘Hope bus’ campaigns to bring attention to their difficult struggles. These tactics have led to some success, especially at large firms where much subcontracting has been disguised (where the parent company owns its own subcontracting firms) and thus illegal. Overall, these difficult protest strategies highlight the sense of urgency among many workers and their families that something more substantive needs to be done about the expansion of precarious work in South Korea.

From political to economic democratization The expansion of non-regular work has significantly contributed to the expansion of inequality since the Asian financial crisis. But it is not the only source of such inequality. As discussed above, the restructuring of the labour market has been paralleled by significant financial changes. The government turned to the financial market rather than the banks as the desired source of capital for industrial investment. As part of this shift, bank’s financial resources that had been oriented toward the corporate sector in the past were reoriented to other investments, including households in the form of mortgage and consumer credit (Y.C. Park 2006). The shift has helped to fuel speculative bubbles in stock and credit markets and has contributed to significant asset price rises in urban property markets. While this shift has contributed to considerable urban development, it has also helped shape the expanding socio-economic inequality between those with property and other monetary assets and those without. Much of this urban development has been facilitated by a historic expansion of household debt. If the period of rapid industrialization was characterized by high savings in the sense of the low debt-to-income ratios among Korean wage earners (whose savings were used to finance industrial development), the boom in urban real estate development since the early 2000s has seen the reverse. It has been the product of heavy borrowing. The high amounts of leverage involved have thus raised concerns among Korean policymakers about how sustainable this development might be, particularly since it has led to periodic crises due to the oversupply in apartments and the collapse of some of the poorly regulated financial instruments (such as the market for project finance) used to finance much of the boom in residential construction (Son 2014). This phenomenon has raised concerns that Korea might be facing its own Japanese-style bubble. Furthermore, the expansion in the underlying prices of financial assets such as stocks and real estate have not corrected for the deficiencies of the old export-oriented developmentalist model. This financial expansion has not improved domestic demand (in the form of higher wages) or led to a fairer distribution of wealth. As a consequence, the Korean economy has become more rather than less dependent on its large exporters, which raises concerns about its vulnerability to competition from emerging economies as well as from downturns in global demand, as was witnessed during the 2008 financial crisis. 350

The post-developmental state

The new financial geography of Korean capitalism and its existent and emergent axes of inequality between regular and non-regular workers, native and migrant workers, asset-rich and asset-poor, among others, has led to renewed debate among politicians and reformers about how to create a fairer and socially sustainable economy. As discussed above, the solution of the Lee Myung-bak government was to try to revive the old high-growth model, mainly through infrastructure spending and deregulation that benefited the chaebol. While Lee did introduce some strategic industrial policies under his ‘Green Growth’ banner, much of the energy of his “New New Deal” went towards financing poorly designed infrastructure investment such as the Four Major Rivers Project and easing restrictions on laws governing the ability of industrial groups to own financial institutions. However, these pro-business policies were not successful in reviving economic growth and alienated a number of Lee’s party’s supporters. By the time of the 2012 presidential elections, it appeared that a new approach would be necessary. It was in this context that the major political parties embraced the slogan of ‘economic democratization’ in the lead up to the election. The moderate-conservatives who led the ruling Saenuri Party’s campaign, as well as intellectuals associated with the opposition Democratic United Party (DUP, renamed as the New Politics Alliance for Democracy after the election), proposed a range of policies aimed at addressing social polarization and the concentration of economic power in the hands of the chaebol. While both parties made promises to expand welfare spending, the predominant focus of their discourse remained focused on the chaebol and whether it was in the best interests of the Korean economy for the state to use its constitutional powers to place limits on their activities.3 Similar to the discussions surrounding the causes of the 1997 crisis, at the center of this debate was the question of what to do with the elaborate and often illegal cross-shareholding patterns of the chaebol. Policymakers in both parties advocated that further cross-shareholding be banned – while DUP reformers proposed unwinding the existing system altogether – so that a regime of ‘fair competition’ between the chaebol and non-chaebol firms could be established. The idea behind this policy being that, by extension, such reforms would help independent businesses flourish, foster job creation and prevent such practices as the exploitation of subcontractors by chaebol affiliates, illegal transfers of resources between firms, and dynastic control by the ruling family. The emphasis put on chaebol reform as ‘economic democratization’ attracted the attention of several liberal-left critics, such as the development economist Ha-joon Chang and his associates, who complained that the market-oriented chaebol reform policies proposed under the banner of economic democracy would do little to establish a proper welfare state (their preferred form of ‘economic democracy’). Instead of restructuring the conglomerates’ cross-shareholding patterns, Chang and his associates proposed that the government pursue a different strategy of economic reform. They argued that an agreement should be made that guarantees the existing management rights of the chaebol over their affiliate firms in return for increased domestic investment, corporate taxation, and job creation. The logic behind this proposal was that if management rights were secure – making it easier for chaebol families to transfer ownership rights to the next generation and ward off speculative takeovers – the chaebol would agree to the greater taxation and investment needed to foster a Korean welfare state. Chang and his colleagues were particularly critical of fellow liberal reformers’ efforts to reform the chaebol towards AngloAmerican market norms based on shareholder value. They argued that these policies promoted speculative capital at the expense of industrial capital and, by extension, denigrate the institutions of high-speed growth that were an integral feature of Korea’s developmental state model, which they tend to see in a positive light (S.E. Lee 2012). Instead of further market reform, they argued for a return of developmentalist industrial policy, control over speculative capital, and the emulation of Scandinavian-style welfare policies. 351

Jamie Doucette

Conclusion While Chang’s proposal’s praise of Park Chung-hee’s industrial policies and depiction of the chaebol as victims of financial capital (rather than as an active component of it) created controversy among liberal-left reformers, it was not seriously entertained during the election. Nonetheless, it is worthy of attention here, as it cast light on a persistent dilemma encountered by reformers and politicians about the legacy of Park Chung-hee’s developmental state, not to mention the difficulties involved in addressing long-standing problems associated with it such as the power of the chaebol and the lack of a more substantive social welfare system. While Park’s ‘developmental state’ was regarded as an ideal type by many scholars, it has been rarely regarded as a desirable model by democratic reformers until recently. For them, the purported meritocratic economic planning at the heart of that model was difficult to discern when viewed from the standpoint of labour and civil society that were the target of much regimentation, repression, and exploitation during the dictatorship era. Nonetheless, when prescribed as an alternative to an equally idealized free-market vision of development, it is also easy to understand how a defense of the state’s capacity to govern the market and promote economic growth appears desirable. This is the dilemma of the ‘post-developmental state’ represented by the end of the high debt model: a problem of deciding what role the government, chaebol, and formerly excluded actors such as labour and civil society should play in the development of an alternative approach to politics, economy and society. At the heart of this challenge are legitimate concerns about the concentration of power in the hands of the chaebol and the difficult question of what constitutes a socially and economically just restructuring of the conglomerates and wider economic institutions. Merely enforcing free market norms in a technical manner risks confining the problem of unequal economic power to intra-class relations between capital holders such as majority and minority shareholders and small and large business. It does little to address the situation of labour, whose interests have remained the most marginal during the course of democratization (Choi 2012). Likewise, a reprise of industrial policy without the development of a strong countervailing force that can counter-balance state and capital also seems likely to prolong existing inequalities of power and influence. Pro-business proposals that merely protect the management rights of the chaebol face the familiar criticism that they merely put growth over distribution, the market over social justice, and capital against workers. An alternative approach that sought to develop a democratic welfare state would have to find a way to put taxation, redistribution and labour standards as the first order of concern, and by extension orient industrial policy towards providing solutions to social and environmental problems that have accompanied Korean industrialization. So far, both the conservative and main opposition parties have only stumbled toward such solutions. While it has a broad following among workers and supporters of the democracy movement, the NPAD has had great difficulty proposing substantive alternatives to neoliberalism. Meanwhile, while Park Geun-hye’s election proposals acknowledged the need for a universal pension and welfare systems, she quickly watered down such policies. For instance, her pledge to significantly expand universal old-age pensions was reduced to a more minimal, means-tested benefit that did not sufficiently address the high levels of poverty among Korean seniors (see Klassen and Yang 2013 for analyses of Korea’s policies towards its ageing population). Meanwhile, Park’s policies for addressing Korea’s rapidly declining fertility rate – while providing some decent funding for early childhood education – have also lacked effectiveness as they have not been followed up with sufficient employment protections for female workers. Part of the problem is that Park, like her liberal predecessors, is hesitant to raise income or corporate taxes to pay for such welfare expansion. At the end of the day, it seems that a greater emphasis on 352

The post-developmental state

distribution over growth, and a more substantive approach towards the democratic participation of labour and other diverse political voices in the process of economic restructuring is needed. Until then, the establishment of a Korean welfare state will remain a minimalist project, and the predicament of the post-developmental state – insecure work, expanding inequality, and unequal social power – set to continue.

Glossary Cross-shareholding (Sanghoch’ulcha): The Korean term for cross-shareholding is sanghoch’ulcha, but a more direct translation this term might be ‘reciprocal’ or ‘mutual equity investment’. Chaebol families use these cross-investments or cross-shareholding to maintain control over their conglomerate group as a whole, even though they hold a minimal amount of stock in most of the group’s affiliates: in most cases the family may own less than 5 per cent of total stock in core affiliates. The usual pattern is that the ruling family owns a large quantity of shares belonging to a non-listed, de facto holding company (e.g. Samsung Everland) that owns a high percentage of shares belonging another affiliate (e.g. Samsung Electronics) which owns shares belonging to another (e.g. Samsung Techwin), and so on. This creates a dense, interconnected web through which they maintain managerial control over the whole group. The Four Major Rivers Restoration Project: The Four Major Rivers Restoration Project was an ambitious construction and engineering project launched in early 2009 by the administration of conservative President Lee Myung-bak. Viewed as an attempt to mediate the effects of the 2008 global downturn on the Korean economy through fiscal policy, the project involved the dredging of Korea’s four largest rivers and the construction of weirs, bikeways, and recreational facilities along each waterway. While the project purported to revitalize river ecosystems, facilitate flood management, and secure water resources, it was viewed by many as a costly project designed to reward construction firms rather than revitalize ecosystems. The hefty price tag of the project (which cost close to 20 billion US dollars), its hasty design, and lack of thorough environmental assessment were criticized by many local governments, environmental NGOs and social movements. Korea’s Bureau of Audit and Inspection also criticized the project for its poor construction and planning. River silting, leaky weirs, and algal blooms created by the project continue to raise controversy. Korean Confederation of Trade Unions (KCTU): The Korean Confederation of Trade Unions (KCTU) is a national trade union confederation with roughly 700,000 members. Unlike its rival, the formerly pro-government and relatively pro-business Federation of Korean Trade Unions (FKTU), the KCTU was formed out of the battle for independent trade unions during the democracy movements of the 1970s and 1980s. The Great Worker Struggle that quickly followed the June Democratic Uprising of 1987 led to an increase in independent workplace organization among Korean trade unionists. In order to break away from enterprise-level corporatism that often dominates Korean labour relations and to advocate for progressive policies that benefit workers at the industrial and national scale, these unionists chose to form the KCTU in 1995. The confederation was not officially recognized as a legal worker’s organization until 1999, under the government of Kim Dae-jung. Developmentalism: Developmentalism can be described as a political and economic ideology that prioritizes the goal of national economic development over and above redistributive policies, democratic participation, as well as liberal ideas of a free and self-regulating market. 353

Jamie Doucette

Developmentalism prescribes that the state play a guiding role in promoting development through industrial and fiscal policies that lead to industrial upgrading and expanded market share. Critics of developmentalism point out, however, that developmentalist policies often prioritize economic growth (especially GDP growth) and the development of the forces of production over social and human development, not to mention environmental concerns associated with industrialization in general. Furthermore, the emphasis of developmentalist economic policies on elite-led planning and strategic government-business networks, and their frequent justification in terms of national security (e.g. as under the Park Chung-hee regime), raise additional concerns about the lack of democratic oversight over economic policies within developmentalist regimes.

Notes 1

2

3

While a deeper engagement with the various theories of the developmental state is beyond the scope of this chapter, further criteria for a such a transition might be made in terms of changes to the social composition of the Korean state and to changes in the ideational projects embraced by the economic bureaucracy (see Y.T. Kim 2008, 1999) for such an argument). Since the late 1990s, the assumptions of developmental theory increasingly became an object of criticism for its simplified understanding of state capacity as being autonomous from or external to social and political conflicts and for its undertheorization of class relations. Nonetheless, the idea of developmental state remains a useful heuristic description for the high growth policies of the Park Chung-hee era. For excellent conceptual critiques of developmental state theory, see D.O. Chang (2009) and H.Y. Song (2013a). While the term ‘non-regular worker’ is not widely used outside of Korea and Japan, its usage resonates with cognate terms such as irregular work and precarious work, and encompasses forms such as casual and contingent labour, part-time work, temp or dispatch work, subcontract work, and home-based and day labourers. We might also add disguised subcontracting, precarious self-employment, ‘special’ employment, and perhaps even migrant labour to the mix (see Grubb et al. 2007, p. 76 for a good discussion of some, but not all, of the various metrics use to measure the incidence of non-regular work in South Korea). Item 2 of Article 119 of the Korean constitution grants the state the ability to “regulate and coordinate economic affairs in order to maintain the balanced growth and stability of the national economy, to ensure proper distribution of income, to prevent the domination of the market and the abuse of economic power, and to democratize the economy through harmony among the economic agents.” See the Constitution of the Republic of Korea. Available online: http://korea.assembly.go.kr/res/low_01_ read.jsp?boardid=1000000035 (accessed 10 January 2013).

References Chang, D.O. (2009) Capitalist development in Korea: Labour, capital and the myth of the developmental state, London: Routledge. Chang, D.O. (2011) ‘Neo-liberalism, union responses and the transformation of the South Korean labour movement,’ in G. Gall, A. Wilkinson, and R. Hurd (eds.) The international handbook of labour unions: Responses to neo-liberalism, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 207–227. Chang, H.J., Jeong, S.I., and Lee, J.T. (2012) Making the right economic choice [in Korean], Seoul: Boo-Kie. Chang, K.S. (2010) South Korea under compressed modernity: Familial political economy in transition, New York: Routledge. Chun, J.J.Y. (2010) Organizing at the margins: The symbolic politics of labor in South Korea and the United States, London: Cornell University Press. Cho, H.Y. (2012) ‘Democratization as De-Monopolization and its Different Trajectories: No Democratic Consolidation without De-Monopolization.’ Asian Democracy Review (1): 4–36. Choi, J.J. (2012) Democracy after democratization: the Korean experience, Palo Alto, CA: Walter H. Shorenstein Asia Pacific Research Center Books. Chung, U.C. (1999) East Asian economic crisis – What is and what ought to be done: The case of Korea. Institut fur Europaische Wirtschaft discussion paper 26. Bochum, Germany: Ruhr University. 354

The post-developmental state

Doucette, J. (2010) ‘The terminal crisis of the Participatory Government and the election of Lee Myung Bak’, Journal of Contemporary Asia 40(1): 22–43 Doucette, J. (2013) ‘Minjung tactics in a post-Minjung era? The survival of self-immolation and traumatic forms of labour protest in South Korea,” in G. Gall (ed.) New Forms and Expressions of Conflict in the Workplace, London: Palgrave-Macmillian, pp. 212–232. Gray, K. 2013. ‘The Political Cultures of South Korea.’ New Left Review (79): 85–101. Gray, K. (2009) Korean workers and neoliberal globalization. London: Routledge. Grubb, D., Kap, J. and Tergeist, P. (2007). “Addressing labour market duality in Korea.” OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers 61. Paris: OECD. Hart-Landsberg, M. (2001) ‘Economic crisis and restructuring in South Korea: Beyond the free marketstatist debate.’ Critical Asian Studies 33(3): 403–430. Kang, D.C. (2002) Crony capitalism: Corruption and Development in South Korea and the Philippines. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Kang, D., Leheny, D. and Cha, V. (2013) Dialogue about elections in Japan and Korea. Journal of Asian Studies 72(2): 233–250. Kalinowski, T. (2008) ‘State-society synergy and co-optation: The case of the minority shareholder movement in South Korea’, Korea Observer 39(3): 339–367. Kim, D.J. (1985) Mass Participatory Economy: A Democratic Alternative for Korea, Washington: University Press of America. Kim, J.B. (2013) Chaebol Policy for Supression of Economic Power Concentration. Knowledge Sharing Program and Ministry of Strategy and Finance, Republic of Korea. Kim, J.I. (2012) Why Economic Democracy Now? For the future of the Korean Economy [In Korean] Seoul: Donghwach’ulpansa. Kim, K.W. (2004) ‘Chaebol restructuring and family business in Korea.’ Department of Economics, Seoul: Korea National Open University. Kim, S.J. (2002) ‘Financial sector reform in Korea: A dilemma between ‘bank-based’ and ‘market-based’ systems.’ Korea Journal 42(1) 42–73. Kim, Y.T. (2008) Bureaucrats and entrepreneurs: The state and the chaebol in Korea. Seoul: Jimoondang. Kim, Y.T. (1999) ‘Neoliberalism and the decline of the developmental state’, Journal of Contemporary Asia 29(4): 441–461. Kwon, H.J. (2006) ‘South Korea’, in T. Fitzpatrick., H.J. Kwon, N. Manning, J. Midgely, and G. Pascal, (eds.) International Encyclopedia of Social Policy, New York: Routledge, 730–734. Jang, H.S. (2001) ‘Corporate governance and economic development: The Korean Experience.’ In F. Iqbal and J.I. You (eds.) Democracy, market economics, and development: An Asian perspective, Washington, DC: World Bank Publications, 73–94. Jeong, S.I. (2004) Crisis and restructuring in East Asia: the case of the Korean chaebol and the automotive industry. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Jeong, S.J. (2010) ‘Korean left debates on alternatives to neoliberalism’, in A. Saad-Filho and G. Yalman (eds.) Economic Transitions to neoliberalism in middle-income countries: policy dilemmas, economic crises, forms of resistance. London: Routledge, 154–165. Jeong, S.J. (2007) ‘Trend of Marxian ratios in Korea: 1970–2003’, in M. Hart-Landsberg, S.J. Jeong, and R. Westra (eds.) Marxist Perspectives on South Korea in the Global Economy, Burlington, VT: Ashgate. Jwa, S.H. and Lee, I.K. (eds.) (2004) Competition and corporate governance in Korea: Reforming and restructuring the chaebol. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. Klassen, T.R. and Yang, Y.J. (eds.) (2013) Korea’s retirement predicament: The ageing tiger. Abingdon, Oxon, UK: Routledge. Kong, T.Y. (2004) ‘Neo-liberalization and Incorporation in Advanced Newly Industrialized Countries: A view from Korea.’ Political Studies 52: 19–42. Lee B.C. (ed.) (2006) Developmental dictatorship and the Park Chung-hee era: The shaping of modernity in the Republic of Korea. Paramus, New Jersey: Homa and Sekey Books. Lee, B.C. (2006) ‘Political Economy of Korean Development after Liberation: A Critical Reflection.’ Korea Journal (Autumn) 49–79. Lee, J.K. (2010) Service Economies: Militarism, Sex Work, and Migrant Labor in South Korea. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Lee, N.H. (2007) The Making of the Minjung: Democracy and the Politics of Representation in South Korea. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. 355

Jamie Doucette

Lee, S.E. (2012) ‘Chang Ha-joon: Dismantling chaebol is economic democratization? It’s naive to think so.’ Korea Focus. Available online at http://www.koreafocus.or.kr/design3/Interview/view.asp? volume_id=131&content_id=104436&category=J. Accessed July 2014. Lee S.O. and Wainwright, J. (2010) ‘Revisiting Regulation Theory for the Analysis of South Korean capitalism.’ Journal of the Economic Geographical Society of Korea 13(4): 562–583. Lim, T. (2010) ‘Rethinking belongingness in Korea: Transnational Migration, “migrant marriages: and the Politics of multiculturalism.’ Pacific Affairs 83(1): 51–71. Moon, S.S. (2005) Militarized Modernity and Gendered Citizenship in South Korea. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Park, B.G. (2012) ‘Social movements and the geographies of economic activities in South Korea. In J. Peck, E. Sheppard and T. Barnes (eds.) Wiley-Blackwell Companion to Economic Geography, London: WileyBlackwell, 486–500. Park, B.G. (2011) Territorial politics and the rise of a construction-oriented state in South Korea. Korean Social Sciences Review 1(1): 185–220. Park, G.S. and Kim, K.P (2008) ‘Financial crisis and the minority shareholders’ movement in Korea: The unfolding and social consequences of the movement.’ Korean Journal of Sociology 42(8): 59–76. Park, Y.C. (2006) Economic Liberalization and Integration in East Asia: A Post- Crisis Paradigm. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Seo, B. (2013) ‘Socio-spatial dialectics of crisis formation and the 1997 crisis in Korea’, Geoforum, 45: 156–167. Shin, G.W. and Chang, P.W. (eds.) (2011) South Korean Social Movements: From Democracy to Civil Society, London: Routledge. Shin, K.Y. (2012) ‘Dilemmas of Korea’s New Democracy in an Age of Neoliberal Globalisation.’ Third World Quarterly 33(2): 293–309. Shin, K.Y. 2010. ‘Globalisation and the Working Class in South Korea: Contestation, Fragmentation and Renewal.’ Journal of Contemporary Asia 40(2): 211–229. Shin, J.S. and Chang, H.J. (2003). Restructuring Korea INC. London: Routledge Curzon. Son, J.Y. (2014) ‘Korea’s development finance at the crossroads’, in S. Watcher, M. Cho, M.J. Tcha, (eds.) The Global financial crisis and housing: A new policy perspective, Cheltenham, UK: Edgar Elgar, 208–230. Song, H.Y. (2013a) ‘Marxist critiques of the developmental state and the fetishism of national development’, Antipode, 45(5): 1254–1276. Song, H.Y. (2013b) ‘Democracy against Labour: The Dialectic of Democratisation and De-democratisation in Korea’, Journal of Contemporary Asia, 43(2): 338–362. Song, J.S. (2009) South Koreans in the Debt Crisis: The creation of a neoliberal welfare society. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Woo, Meredith Jung-en. (2007) ‘The New East Asia’, New Left Review (47): 57–69.

356

25 Global Korea John Lie

Until the 1980s the very conjunction of the term “global” with “Korea” would have been an incongruity or an oxymoron. After all, the master signifier of Korea was the “Hermit Kingdom”; Korea was antipodal to any commonsense notion of “global.” Google’s Ngram View reveals that the nouns “Korea,” “Corea,” and their cognates rarely appeared in print in the postGutenberg West. Korea’s rather shadowy presence on the world’s historical stage should not be surprising given its tributary status under a series of Chinese empires, which was then superseded by Japanese colonial rule in the twentieth century. Indeed, imperial Japan threatened Korea’s expunction from world history and geography in the first half of the twentieth century. In the shadow of the two neighboring civilizations, Korea’s cultural achievements remained occluded to the outside world, save for several signature exports, such as celadon and ginseng. Consequently, the very mention of Korea routinely puzzled otherwise educated people in much of the world until the 1950s. For too long, Korea remained the answer to the trivial question of the polity between China and Japan. Until the 1988 Seoul Olympics, the only notable modern event associated with Korea was the Korean War. Even then, its most common moniker remains the “forgotten war” (Blair 1987). In short, the idea of “global Korea” would have been strange because the world remained largely oblivious to and about Korea. In the twenty-first century, we cannot but talk about globalization when we talk about South Korea. The plausibility of an entry on “global Korea” is readily apparent in a world where Samsung cell phones and Hyundai automobiles are ubiquitous and the music video “Gangnam Style” remains the single most watched YouTube video. One cannot do so as easily for North Korea, one of the few states to actively resist incorporation into the capitalist world-economy. Yet when we consider Korea, past and present, North or South, we cannot bypass the inextricably intertwined relationship of the Korean Peninsula with the rest of the world. This essay will focus on globalization and South Korea, but the Korean polity has always been and remains a transnational and globalized entity.

The Korean War, the Cold War, and non-global Korea The Korean War was an international war (Stueck 1995; Wada 2014). Inasmuch as it was a civil war, countries far beyond the Korean Peninsula deployed soldiers and weapons in the 357

John Lie

war-ravaged peninsula. In spite of its considerable destruction, its rather marginal status in world history owes to its temporal proximity to a truly massive international war (World War II) and to a series of postcolonial wars that convulsed the former colonial powers (Algeria in France, Vietnam in the United States, etc.). Be that as it may, the Korean War long remained the most significant event associated with Korea, outside of the Korean Peninsula. What the Korean War confirmed was that neither North Korea nor South Korea could be understood beyond its place in the Cold War and hence in its international context. Whether we consider economic aid or political support, the place of the Soviet Union, China, and the Second World for North Korea or that of the United States, Japan, and the First World for South Korea remained essential to make sense of the two Koreas. Liberation did not come from within, after all, and the elevation of Kim Il-Sung in the North and Rhee Syngman in the South cannot be understood apart from their connections to their patrons in the Soviet Union and China or the United States, respectively (Armstrong 2013; Lie 1998). The critical significance of the global or international context in understanding Korea is the first sense in which we can stress the salience of global Korea. In this regard, the long political and ideological dependence on successive Chinese empires marks the traditional history of Korea (Kang 2010). Much the same can be said about colonial Korea (Japan) and postcolonial Koreas. Any serious account of Korean polities cannot exclude the preponderant impact of the contiguous – and faraway – empires (e.g. Schmid 2002). Any balanced perspective on the Korean Peninsula from its origins – the ancestors of modern ethnic Koreans came originally from Africa and did not generate spontaneously in the Korean Peninsula – to the Korean War – an international war that overlapped a domestic political struggle – can hardly exaggerate the role of the external and the exogenous: the study of Korea is perforce the study of global Korea. Nevertheless, what is striking about the domestic self-understanding in (and much of scholarly writings on) both post-independence Koreas is the accent on the national and the endogenous. Precisely when the international context impinged so profoundly – one is tempted to say definitively – on Korea, the historiographies in both Koreas became resolutely nationalistic and inward-looking (cf. Em 2013). In spite of diametrically opposed ideologies, the two Koreas became something of a mirror image of each other: formally alike in their zealous devotion to blood-based nationalism that stressed native and indigenous genealogies over external and exogenous events and influences (Shin 2006; Lie 2014). Nationalist historiography and social sciences were influenced by and in turn shaped the political primacy of semi-nationalism: “semi” because both the North and the South largely excluded the other from their egocentric outlook. An exemplary instantiation of this mindset can be found at the Academy of Korean Studies in South Korea. In a large map of the Korean Peninsula at its main lecture hall, the territory of North Korea is left blank: no Pyongyang and not even the nationally sacred peak Paektusan. Korean Studies in this line of thinking is South Korean Studies. For several decades after the Korean War, then, the two Koreas remained deeply embedded in the global Cold War but ideologically involuted in their nationalist narratives and selfconceptions. Thus the conjunction of “global” and “Korea” appears problematic from the regnant Korean worldview(s). Park Chung-hee’s nationalism, no less than Kim Il-Sung’s juche (selfreliance) philosophy, stressed nationalism that dovetailed well with the narrative of the Hermit Kingdom. To speak of Korea, North or South, past or present, was perforce a particularistic discourse, encased in the territorial terrain of the Korean Peninsula. To discuss Korea was to analyze it largely as an autonomous entity, as non-global Korea. Sure enough, contemporary politics focused preponderantly on domestic matters at a time when few North or South Koreans ventured abroad. 358

Global Korea

It would be remiss, however, to neglect the appeal of foreign, especially putatively more advanced, cultures. Even in the realm of ruling political ideologies, the North appealed to international communism or Marxism, whereas the South claimed adherence to Western (and especially American) liberalism. Popular consumption of movies and music – from colonial-era Japanese-influenced works to the post-liberation bifurcation of Soviet and Chinese culture in North and of the United States in South – brought the modern – advanced and sophisticated, and therefore something desirable – to many Koreans. Even Korean national cuisine came to be shaped by foreign imports and external influences (Cwiertka 2012). Internal internationalization – in a sense a continuation of the pre-modern valorization of Chinese culture – proceeded rapidly even at the height of cultural nationalism. The awareness of the world outside in turn accentuated the self-conception of Koreanness. Rather than village, regional, or provincial identities – and even more salient status distinctions – the self-identification as Korean became paramount. In the immediate post-Korean War decades, it is North Korea rather than South Korea that boasted a more international or cosmopolitan outlook and policy. This is in part because of the internationalist thrust of communism, and North Korea sought actively to interact with other countries in the socialist bloc in the 1950s and 1960s (Scalapino and Lee 1972). The increasingly authoritarian rule by the late 1960s elevated the place of juche ideology and demoted the role of the international (Cumings 2004). It is safe to say that North Korea remains one of the most closed countries in the world, whether we think of the penetration of global economic institutions (such as ATM machines or fast-food chains) or of the world wide web in the twentyfirst century (Lankov 2012). North Korea, ideologically and practically, approaches the ideal of the hermit polity. It is the 20/20 hindsight, however, that presumes the superiority of the South over the North. Just as North Korea has not always been closed off, South Korea has not always embraced the external and the global. Somewhat surprisingly, given that Park Chung-hee’s rule has become so closely associated with the policy of export-oriented industrialization, South Korea under his rule was also relatively closed off from the rest of the world because of economic and cultural protectionism (Lie 1998). Economic protectionism – the desire to protect foreign currency reserves in order to fuel South Korea’s export-oriented industrialization and to nurture its nascent industries – was mandated. Cultural protectionism was part and parcel of authoritarian nationalism, seeking to keep foreign and therefore dangerous elements. In the 1970s, even anodyne articles in Time Magazine would be censored (literally cut out of the magazine by diligent censors). Symptomatic was the extensive effort to curb foreign influences – often resorting to outright censorship – even in the realm of popular music (Lie 2015). Economic and cultural protectionism did not mean that the two Koreas did not participate in political struggles for legitimacy on the world stage. To be sure, it was part and parcel of the grand struggle of the Cold War, but the fratricidal rivalry – along with those of the two Germanys and the two Vietnams – enhanced passionate enmity. Given the paucity of business people or students abroad – and very little to offer in terms of economic or cultural exports – both North and South Korea engaged in espionage and propaganda. At times these efforts were innocuous, such as translating the collected writings or speeches of Kim Il-sung and Park Chung-hee into non-Korean languages. Culture was usually the terrain in which these inter-Korean struggles surfaced most visibly, whether in the South Korean attempt to export the “traditional” Korean dance troupe Little Angels or the North Korean effort to propagate engaged literature. Sports, whether soccer or taekwondo, often served as a civil war by other means (Cha 2008). At other times they amounted to international crimes, such as the North Korean capture of ordinary Japanese citizens or the South Korean heist of the losing presidential candidate Kim Dae-jung. 359

John Lie

The undercover struggles, emblematic of Cold War political culture, brought notoriety to both Koreas (such as the quickly forgotten Koreagate in 1976 when the South Korean Tongsun Park sought to peddle influence among US politicians). Yet the dominant reality was that the two Koreas struggled to gain global recognition of even their very existence in the Cold War decades (except, to repeat, as a place of the “forgotten war”). As consequential as the Korean War and the continuing war between the two Koreas remained, they were often an afterthought in the global Cold War (Khong 1992; Masuda 2015).

The Seoul Olympics, political democracy, and internationalization in South Korea The Seoul Olympics – similar to other quasi-propagandistic Olympiads, such as Berlin in 1936, Tokyo in 1964, and Beijing in 2008 – presented South Korea to a world that had little if any knowledge of the country. On the one hand, it sought to showcase South Korean development to the world. Rather than the devastation from the Korean War or the ensuing poverty of the country, South Korea was presented as a modern, increasingly wealthy country. On the other hand, it was a terminus of the long legitimation struggles by the military regime to win popular support inside and outside South Korea. The 1980 Kwangju Uprising was only the most vociferous expression of widespread disenchantment with the military rule. Chun Doohwan, who succeeded Park after his 1979 assassination, promulgated what came to be known as “3S” policy – sex, screen, and sport – to generate popular approbation. Most importantly for the military and political elites in South Korea, the 1988 Olympics marked South Korea’s triumph over North Korea on the global stage. However successful North Korea had been in some spheres before then, its place would spiral downwards in terms of global reputation and respect, eventually settling as a rogue state, human rights disaster area, or an economic basket case (poverty, famines, and worse) (e.g. Demick 2009; cf. Ryang 2012). The 1988 Olympics proved to be a major turning point for South Korea. The crescendo of social movements against authoritarian rule reinstated formal political democracy (here one should not neglect that the zealous effort to cleanse South Korea of negative images abroad, such as authoritarian rule, that facilitated the democratic transition). It also vouchsafed South Korea’s outward-looking economic policy and an attempt to brand it as a technologically reliable and even advanced country. What is crucial is that the twin impulses were united in propelling South Korea’s stress on internationalization or globalization and even its very identification as an international or global player. Especially from the early 1980s, with the loosening of foreign travel and the growing enrichment of South Koreans, study abroad became a veritable mania among ambitious, upwardly mobile South Koreans. It would be tempting to see South Korea’s education mania as an unbroken tradition from pre-modern times, but its renewed emphasis owes to South Korea’s dynamic, export-oriented industrialization, which required a large army of engineers and office workers knowledgeable about producing and selling in export markets. It was the fundamental consequence of land reform that propelled South Koreans to seek fortune in capitalist industrialization rather than traditional, land-based agrarian economy (Lie 1998). The definition of the elite shifted from the social background of the landowning class to the attainment of educational credentials, especially from leading foreign, and especially American, universities. Foreign study and export-oriented industrialization accentuated the salience of the international among South Korean political, economic, and cultural leaders, who had already been looking to the United States as a political leader and as a model of modernity. The nationalist sentiment – expressing itself at times as an inferiority complex or the proverbial chips on the 360

Global Korea

collective shoulders of South Koreans – became inextricably, and perhaps paradoxically, intertwined with an outward orientation. It is difficult for a foreigner even today even to escape a barrage of questions from South Koreans about how she finds the country. A more sustained articulation of this impulse is the obsessive effort to rank South Korea among world powers in everything from GDP to university rankings. The Ministry of Foreign Affairs’ “Global Korea” website is symptomatic, collecting foreign coverage of South Korean in everything from economic matters to cultural achievements. To think about South Korea was to think about South Korea’s place in the world. The trend would accelerate in the 1990s and thereafter.

Counter-global South Korea? In the 2010s North Korea, though not as hermetically closed off as some suggest, remains outside the Washington Consensus. The country is neither capitalist nor neoliberal, neither democratic nor liberal. The dominant ideology of juche legitimates a form of involuted nationalism that keeps North Korea as a country that is relatively immune to global influences and trends. In contrast, South Korea in the early twenty-first century is a global country. It embraces globalization, whether economic or cultural, and seeks to be a global player in everything from electronics to fashion to sports to music. As I suggested, however, the idea of global South Korea is a relatively recent phenomenon. The military regime pursued a culturally nationalist policy, including widespread censorship, but it also relied increasingly on export-oriented industrialization to legitimate its rule. More relevant, in a predominantly rural and agrarian country with limited communication and transportation infrastructure and relatively low educational attainment, South Korea in the 1960s could be characterized as parochial and perhaps even xenophobic. Surely few foreign visitors in South Korea until the 1970s saw the country as in any way cosmopolitan or global. The educated stratum tended to be more cosmopolitan than their less educated counterparts. Certainly the generalization holds true for the colonial period and the high tide of US influence on South Korea in the 1950s (when it became fashionable among elite South Koreans to use American first names). Yet by 1960, South Korean university students were voicing stridently nationalist concerns. In part they were criticizing Rhee Syngman’s corrupt rule that was subservient to the US, but they were also acting as inheritors to the politics of nationalism that defined the anti-colonial movement (C.-S. Lee 1963). The 1960 April Student Revolution, which toppled Rhee from power, was nationalist to the core. The opposition to the 1965 Normalization Treaty with Japan mobilized the students and enhanced their nationalist passion. As Park’s rule turned increasingly autocratic, the student movement fused with the antigovernment movement that in turn broadened its social base to constitute the people’s (minjung) movement (N. Lee 2009). By the 1980s the South Korean people’s movement incorporated not only students and intellectuals but also farmers, factory workers, and even office workers. What united them was in fact the opposition to military rule but also the invocation of “the people” that harbored a deeply nationalist ideology. By the 1980s, then, both the military regime and the anti-government movement converged in their nationalism, even hyper-nationalism. Even the previously sacrosanct US became the target of virulent hatred as an unwelcome external influence (Moon 2013). What had begun as a government nationalist policy of lessening dependence on Chinese characters became a leftwing fad to write even numbers in Korean script in the mid-1980s. Nationalism became something of a benchmark of everything from historiography and political discourse to popular culture and commodity consumption (Nelson 2000; Shin 2006). South Korean ethnoracial homogeneity became taken for granted, mirroring in turn the North Korean racial ideology of 361

John Lie

racial purity (Myers 2010; Lie 2014). The ubiquitous invocation of “we” and “us” presented South Koreans as united and homogeneous, inward-looking and xenophobic, and antiinternational and counter-global. That is, there was a strong tendency within South Korea to excoriate foreign influences and to counter globalization. The hyper-nationalist trend in South Korea would ebb after the 1990s. It would be remiss, however, to forget the nationalist surge that remained a strong, if not the strongest, current for both the military rulers and the anti-government protesters in the 1970s and 1980s. South Korea’s embrace of the global was far from ordained, and almost all foreign observers in the 1980s would have found the idea of global South Korea problematic.

From Segyehwa (internationalization) to the 1997 IMF crisis Kim Young-sam (1993–98), the first civilian president after the reinstatement of political democracy, stressed segyehwa (internationalization or globalization) as the centerpiece of his administration. By the mid-1990s, segyehwa had become a buzzword in South Korea, inescapable in business talk as in popular discourse. The dark side of globalization – the 1997 Asian financial crisis that came to be known in South Korea as the 1997 IMF crisis – cast a long shadow on his goal and seemed to squelch it. Yet, ironically, it is the 1997 economic shock that firmly implanted globalization as the commonsense of South Korean life. As many critics readily pointed out at the time, it remained unclear what exactly Kim meant by segyehwa. Presumably it was part and parcel of the post-Cold War discourse of globalization – mooted everywhere from Paris and London to Cambridge, Massachusetts, and Cambridge, England – and the euphoric, even utopian, pronouncements about world peace and the peace dividend, the potential for Korean unification, the entrenchment of political democracy, continuing economic enrichment, and the emergence of South Korea as a global player. Be that as it may, Kim was not engaged in conceptual clarification as an analytical philosopher but in sloganeering as a political leader and a democratically elected one at that. It is also the case that there was nothing much new substantively in what Kim proposed in contrast to his predecessors. Whether we turn to South Korean business interest in exports or the desire of South Koreans to study abroad, the changes were quantitative rather than qualitative. The most consequential outcome of Kim’s sloganeering was that the idea of “internationalized” or “globalized” South Korea became widely discussed and debated. Whoever pronounced on the present and the future of South Korea in the mid-1990s could not escape talking about segyehwa. The 1997 IMF crisis was devastating not only in terms of economic contraction and massive unemployment but also in terms of psychic shock. The myth of uninterrupted growth and the hubris that some South Koreans were beginning to express and display were shattered almost overnight. In this regard, it paralleled the long period of economic gloom that followed the bursting of the property market bubble in Japan in the early 1990s. In spite of considerable similarities – most obviously, two export-oriented economies that had enjoyed decades of uninterrupted growth until the 1990s – the general orientation of the two countries after their 1990s crisis is striking. In Japan the general trend was to look within and to cultivate its internal market so much so that observers began to talk about Japan’s Galapagos Syndrome (a secluded archipelago that spawns unique flora and fauna). In contrast in South Korea, there was a renewed stress on looking outward and to seek foreign opportunities. Rather than cultivating domestic demand, as their Japanese counterparts were engaged in, South Korean business conglomerates stressed their outward orientation. Whether we look to Eastern Europe, Central Asia, Latin America, or Africa, South Korean corporations, such as Samsung, Hyundai, and LG, became 362

Global Korea

ubiquitous in the early twenty-first century, whereas the once–fabled corporations such as Sony, Toyota, and Hitachi have low visibility in these areas. It may very well be that South Korea’s outward orientation is part of a larger stress on innovation and creative destruction (in contrast to Japan’s more conservative and measured policy). In this regard, technological transformations sweeping the world in the late twentieth century – most importantly, information technology – may have given advantage to the latecomer South Korea. I recall interviewing Sony executives in 1985 about Samsung Electronics, which had just been launched. The normally taciturn Japanese executives either smirked or laughed, but merely two decades later Samsung had superseded Sony (Chang 2008). Part of the success of South Korean businesses is their thoroughgoing external orientation and stress, including the strategic reliance on the international market, and hiring engineers and managers educated abroad. Yet it is also possible to see contemporary South Korea’s stress on relentless newness and innovation – and the concomitant destruction of tradition – that made it more competitive in global capitalism. Facing a massive economic and social crisis, the long-term dissident Kim Dae-jung ascended to the presidency at seemingly the worst possible moment in 1998. The recognition of the crisis’s severity, however, facilitated the implementation of two major reforms. First, the Kim Dae-jung regime promoted information technology in general and established a nationwide infrastructure for digital communication (Oh and Larson 2011). By 2005, South Korea emerged as the first country to shift from dial-up to broadband and boasted not only the largest penetration of broadband but also the fastest Internet connection in the world. In part South Korea benefited from the advantage of backwardness. Unlike in the neighboring Japan, for example, South Korea had not invested heavily in the R&D of earlier analog information technology and its outward orientation facilitated the absorption of the latest developments in the United States, Japan, and elsewhere to create a state-of-the-art information technology infrastructure. The development of hardware and infrastructure in turn encouraged the rapid expansion of software and applications in South Korean life. South Koreans were not only quick to adopt smartphones and other new devices but also became pioneers in the nascent world of online gaming (Jin 2010). Second, the Kim Dae-jung regime sought seriously to limit economic concentration and the monopolistic tendencies of the country’s largest conglomerates. Although most conglomerates survived the IMF crisis and Kim’s anti-monopoly policies relatively unscathed, the pervasive influence of big business declined at least momentarily. The new economic opportunities were seized especially in creative and “fashionable” industries, such as fashion and design or music and film, that depended on South Korean studying abroad. Whether we look at innovative videogame makers, film producers and directors, or popular music agencies and impresarios, many were launched in the aftermath of the 1997 IMF crisis (Lie 2015). South Korea emerged as a global powerhouse in the culture industry in the late 1990s. In other words, the surface crisis occluded considerable economic dynamism and the transition from an economy that depended on heavy and chemical industries to one that relied increasingly on more advanced technologies, be they science-based (electronics) or social-based (fashion). Curiously, then, it is not so much the impact of Kim’s internationalization policy but rather the shock of the 1997 IMF Crisis and the Kim Dae-jung regime’s policy that entrenched the outward-looking, global orientation for South Korea. It is possible to delineate a straight line from traditional Korean dependence on China or Rhee’s obeisance to the United States or Park’s export-oriented industrialization policy to the contemporary global orientation of South Korea. Yet it would be more accurate to locate in the 1990s the thoroughgoing global 363

John Lie

orientation of South Korea. In this regard, Kim Dae-jung personified the transformation of South Korea from a provincial country and people to an increasingly cosmopolitan one. In foreign policy (Nordpolitik, or a rapprochement with North Korea, that emulated the Ostpolitik of West Germany) or personal quest (to win the Nobel Peace Prize), Kim worked ferociously to be part of the larger world and to gain recognition therein. To be South Korean meant to be at once intensely nationalist but also insistently global (cf. Chang, Seok, and Baker 2009). Never mind that few could define precisely what “global” implied and in this regard no different from the early desire to emulate the United States – or Japan or China – and be “modern.” The idea of being “global” encapsulated and synthesized these earlier desires and impulses. Global Korea was the master identity of contemporary South Korea in the age of globalization.

Globalization and South Korea By the early years of the twenty-first century, South Korea became inextricably intertwined with the global. Contemporary South Korea cannot be understood from its place in the world and its global ambitions. The most obvious way in which to speak of South Korea is to speak of global South Korea is in the realm of business and economy. South Korea’s export-oriented economy scatters not only products “Made in South Korea” around the world but also dispatches South Korean business people and their concerns across the globe. One would have to look far and wide to find a place without the palpable presence of South Korean corporations. More than their global presence, the inevitable impulse of South Korean business is to export and its global orientation defines South Korean capitalism. Hence, not only are foreign credentials and training valued but South Korean corporations also seek to attract global talent, either by outsourcing or hiring foreigners. The profit motive is ubiquitous and South Korean corporations are no exceptions to the general rule. Yet there is something more to the outward orientation of South Koreans, whether we turn to young South Koreans studying abroad or eager South Korean missionaries around the world. Needless to say, numerous factors are at work but one enduring theme is the South Korean quest for modernity: to take its place in the global stage, among “advanced” countries, as a recognized and respected member. At times the quest verges on the vainglorious, such as the concerted drive to gain a Nobel Prize for South Koreans or to win gold medals at the Olympics. Some become dismal failures, such as the disgraced scientist Hwang Woo-suk, whereas others become national celebrities, such as the feted ice skater Kim You-na, but they constitute the two faces of the same coin: the South Korean quest for global recognition. As suggested earlier, global success, especially in “advanced” areas such as fashion, design, and popular music, is especially valorized (Hong 2014). It would be easy to provide a social-psychological narrative to the desire for modernity and recognition. An education in nationalist history – in which Korea played a distant second fiddle to China before the twentieth century, was colonized by Japan in the first half of the twentieth century, and suffered from national division in the second half – should make many South Koreans eager for their country to have their place in the sun and to gain recognition and respect. Nevertheless, the quest for the modern and the global is inherent in the dynamics that convulsed South Korea since its founding. Japanese colonial rule destroyed not only the traditional Confucian polity but also the regnant ideologies of traditional Korea. Land reform destroyed the material basis of the Confucian literati-landlords. The Korean War destroyed the country and the countryside (and made the political division semi-permanent). Intense industrialization resulted in probably the most rapid rural exodus in world history. Put simply, 364

Global Korea

South Korea has become untethered from its past and something like constant change became its principal constant. In this context, it is not surprising that both at the individual and the collective level, the quest for betterment or upward mobility became something of a master desire. The quest for the modern and the global is in this sense a repudiation of the past and the embrace of a better future – in this sense not much different from the proverbial American Dream. It is merely clothed in the language and culture that is the detritus of the recent Korean past. The quest for the modern and for betterment underlies the extensive Korean diaspora. Sizable ethnic Korean populations can be found not only in East Asia but also in the Americas and Europe (in addition to students and business people in OECD countries, and missionaries and business people in less affluent countries). Although Korean diaspora is as old as the history of Korea, South Korea has been a major sender country, especially to the United States (Abelmann and Lie 1995). The extensive diasporic populations in turn contribute to South Korea’s role in the world. Whether we look to the early successes of export-oriented industrialization in the 1960s – when textile export benefited from ethnic Koreans in Japan who provided technology and marketing – or the recent surge of popular music – South Korean students in the United States, as well as Korean Americans, often provide musical knowhow and even talent – the Korean diaspora plays an indisputable and indispensable role in South Korea’s external success (Lie 1998, 2015). The extensive diaspora constitute the imagined unity of Korea as a global phenomenon. The valorization of the global has other consequences. As noted earlier, South Korea, like North Korea, was largely xenophobic and embraced ethnoracial homogeneity until the 1980s. Yet the idea of global South Korea – and the examples not only of the multicultural and multiethnic United States but also other OECD countries – made multiculturalism as a major government policy initiative in the early years of the new millennium. That is, multiculturalism and even multiethnicity became desirable not only to attract global talent but also to make South Korea seem more modern and global (Lie 2014). To take another example, Christianity rapidly emerged as the most visible religion in South Korean life by the 1980s. In spite of the variety of historical and cultural reasons for the rapid dissemination of Christianity in South Korea, one important factor is the association of Christianity with modernity and “cultural advancement” (the dominant religion, after all, of the United States). What has come to characterize South Korean Christianity beyond the stress on this-worldly success is its outward orientation. South Korean Christian missionaries are now the second largest group of missionaries after Americans (Han 2009). South Korean Christianity is thus symptomatic of global South Korea. In summary, disparate forces have forged South Korea as a globalized country. Yet, as I have argued, the association was far from ordained, and marks a concatenation of relatively independent factors. Nevertheless, its export-oriented economy and the extensive diaspora, among other factors and forces, make South Korea’s engagement with global affairs all but inevitable. The trend has deepened since the 1990s and the global orientation – paradoxically with the persistence of nationalism – characterizes contemporary South Korea.

Global Korea as a mode of scholarship In the age of globalization, the practice of historical and social-scientific writings has come to stress transnational and global dimensions of human and social activities (e.g. Hunt 2014). The proliferation of scholarship written under the signs of world history, world-systems analysis, global history, transnational history, and so on point to the pervasive dissatisfaction with 365

John Lie

received nation-focused and sometimes nationalist historiography. Given that the modern state functioned as the dominant institution of the past two centuries, it should not be surprising that the bulk of historical and social-scientific scholarship takes place within the crucible of the modern nation-state, which in turn is often projected backwards to distort our understanding of the past (Lie 2004). It is unfortunate that historical and social-scientific writings on East Asia, and especially on Korea, still continues under the aegis of a nationalist straitjacket. Precisely when Western scholarship on the West has decisively moved to more explicitly transnational, regional, and global modes of historical writing, Korean history (whether practiced within or without the Korean peninsula) still remains resolutely nationalist. As much as transnational and supranational dimensions of historiography have received short shrift, we should be mindful that regional and diasporic dimensions of Korean history, past and present, remain woefully under-researched. Nationalist historiography accentuates the past as a relatively stationary entity and presumes a great deal more homogeneity than was probably the case. Our contemporary globalization has alerted us to the massive transnational movements of capital, commodities, information, and people, but the same insight can be applied usefully to evoke the past in its manifold complexity and diversity. Modern human beings first entered the Korean peninsula some 30,000 years ago, and we can only presume that population movements continued since then but we simply don’t have much information or insight. The seemingly new fact of globalization should alert us to the older reality of transnational processes. Finally, the idea of global Korea should alert scholars and non-scholars to the comparative dimensions of the history of the Korean Peninsula. A particular foible of nationalist scholarship is to assume one’s national history as distinct and probably unique but, as Marc Bloch (1949) pointed out, all history is, at bottom, comparative history (or one can say the same about socialscientific knowledge, which should be at once comparative and historical). It is of course not the case that all national histories are alike but comparisons – facilitated in turn by the globalization of historical knowledge – should alert scholars to the similarities and differences from other places and other times. The comparative dimension should make the study of Korea in turn relevant for non-Koreanists and even non-Asianists. The age of globalization should usher in the possibility of truly global knowledge.

References Abelmann, N., and J. Lie (1995) Blue Dreams. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Armstrong, C. (2013) Tyranny of the Weak: North Korea and the World, 1950 to 1992. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Blair, C. (1987) The Forgotten War. New York: Times Books. Bloch, M. (1949) Apologie pour l’histoire. Paris: Armand Colin. Cha, V.D. (2008) Beyond the Final Score: The Politics of Sport in Asia. New York: Columbia University Press. Chang, S.-J. (2008) Sony vs Samsung. Singapore: John Wiley. Chang, Y., H. Seok, and D.L. Baker (eds.) (2009) Korea Confronts Globalization. London: Routledge. Cumings, B. (2004) North Korea: Another Country. New York: New Press. Cwiertka, K.J. (2012) Cuisine, Colonialism and Cold War: Food in Twentieth-Century Korea. London: Reaktion Books. Demick, B. (2009) Nothing to Envy: Ordinary Lives in North Korea. New York: Spiegel & Grau. Em, H. (2013) The Great Enterprise: Sovereignty and Historiography in Modern Korea. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Han, J.H.J. (2009) Constructing Korean/American Evangelical Missions. Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Berkeley. Hong, E. (2014) The Birth of Korean Cool: How One Nation Conquered the World Through Pop Culture. New York: Picador. 366

Global Korea

Hunt, L. (2014) Writing History in the Global Era. New York: Norton. Jin, D.Y. (2010) Korea’s Online Gaming Empire. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Kang, D.C. (2010) East Asia Before the West: Five Centuries of Trade and Tribute. New York: Columbia University Press. Khong, Y.F. (1992) Analogies at War: Korea, Munich, Dien Bien Phu and the Vietnam Decisions of 1965. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Lankov, A. (2012) The Real North Korea. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Lee, C.-S. (1963) The Politics of Korean Nationalism. Berkeley: University of California Press. Lee, N. (2009). The Making of Minjung: Democracy and the Politics of Representation in South Korea. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Lie, J. (1998) Han Unbound: The Political Economy of South Korea. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Lie, J. (2004) Modern Peoplehood. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Lie, J. (ed.) (2014) Multiethnic Korea. Berkeley, CA: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, Berkeley. Lie, J. (2015) K-pop. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Masuda, H. (2015) Cold War Crucible. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Michell, T. (2010) Samsung Electronics and the Struggle for Leadership of the Electronics Industry. New York: Wiley. Moon, K.H.S. (2013) Protesting America: Democracy and the U.S.-South Korea Alliance. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Myers, B.R. (2010) The Cleanest Race: How North Koreans See Themselves and Why it Matters. Brooklyn: Melville House. Nelson, L.C. (2000) Measured Excess. New York: Columbia University Press. Oh, M., and J.F. Larson (2011) Digital Development in Korea. London: Routledge. Ryang, S. (2012) Reading North Korea. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Asia Center. Scalapino, R., and C.S. Lee (1972) Communism in Korea, Part 2. Berkeley: University of California Press. Schmid, A. (2002) Korea Between the Empires. New York: Columbia University Press. Stueck, W.W. (1995) The Korean War. Princeton: Princeton, NJ University Press. Shin, G.W. (2006) Ethnic Nationalism in Korea. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Wada, H. (2014) The Korean War: An International History. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.

367

26 Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013 Avram Agov

Relations between the two Koreas since 1945 can be characterized as a permanent state of war in different forms. Reunification has been an existential national issue on the Korean Peninsula, while efforts to achieve a unified state have defined the approach of the two Koreas to one another. The division and inter-Korean relations are inseparable from the architecture of the Cold War. Even though the global Cold War has ended, its peninsular version persists and perpetuates the Korean partition. International relations involve interaction between different states, but the two Koreas have sought to represent the whole peninsula as a single state. Hence this is the first major feature of the North-South relations – competition to represent a single Korean entity either by unifying the Korean Peninsula or by gaining more international recognition than its rival. The premise of each Korean state is that the other Korean state is illegitimate and is not supposed to exist, which is the second characteristic of inter-Korean relations. The Republic of Korea (ROK) and the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea (DPRK) still do not recognize each other and are technically at war. The mutually exclusive paradigm has determined very toxic and unpredictable relations. The northern and southern halves of the Korean Peninsula were temporarily divided along the 38th parallel, but the postWorld War Two arrangement among the Allies became a long-term separate state solution, similar to the division of Germany. The paradox of the inter-Korean relations is that the foreign policy of each Korean state has been largely determined by the existence of the other, even though the peninsular interactions are founded on the principle of mutual exclusion. Solutions to the Korean Question have been dominated by denial, rejection and conflict. The main forms of direct interaction between the two halves of the Korean Peninsula were diplomatic isolation, hostility, subversion or war. Since the Demilitarized Zone (DMZ) sealed off the two Korean states from each other, the regional alliance systems became the main outlet for inter-Korean relations. There were attempts at dialogue and reconciliation, however, and we will also examine the episodes which marked a shift from confrontation to cooperation on the Korean Peninsula. Another feature of the inter-Korean rivalry is its longevity compared to its closest parallel during the Cold War era – inter-German relations. One of the main reasons for the persistence of the inter-Korean conflict is that the Koreans fought a fratricidal war which further deepened and cemented the division of Korea for generations to come.

368

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

Studies of the liberation, occupation, division of the Korean War reveal important aspects of the formative period of the interactions between the two halves of the Korean Peninsula. Nevertheless, the historiography of inter-Korean relations from a longer-term perspective is mostly confined within studies of the history of either South Korea or North Korea and their respective alliance systems, as the division of the peninsula led to division of its scholarship as well. This dichotomy seems inevitable, given the gravity of the nation-state as main point of departure in the investigation of international relations. But there are a few studies, such as the ones by Barry Gills, Don Oberdorfer, Taik-yong Humm and Eui-gak Hwang, which focus on the two Koreas and their interaction. This essay will briefly outline major events and stages in the history of inter-Korean relations from 1945 until 2013. The narrative will take into account internal and external factors that have shaped the relations between the two halves of the Korean Peninsula.

Division and war, 1945–1953 The Korean civil conflict was rooted in the colonial period (1910–1945) and deepened during decolonization. After Liberation on 15 August 1945, the internal strife took the form of deeply opposing political entities. Social cleavages provided the platform for the division of Korea, while the international framework structured the actual separation. On 10–11 August, 1945, the US State-War-Navy Committee decided to divide Korea into two occupation zones. The Soviet Union, which had joined the war against Japan (as agreed at Yalta and Potsdam in 1945), accepted the American proposal for the partition of Korea along the 38th parallel. The division of the Korean peninsula was a temporary solution during a trusteeship period (trusteeship was agreed by the Allies at Cairo and Teheran in 1943), leading eventually toward the full independence of a unified Korean state.1 The three years between the Liberation and the creation of separate Korean states marked not only a process of molding two political entities but also growing alienation and isolation between them. While the negotiations between Allies for a unified Korean government were turning destructive, the administrations in the two zones were growing into proto-governments with distinct ideologies and political agendas. The peninsular division added to the economic chaos which ensued after the collapse of the Japanese economic zone. Still, for some time there were still exchanges between the two halves of the peninsula – the North supplied the South with electricity, for example. Movement of people between the two zones was still possible until 1947 despite the restrictions.2 The division and occupation of the Korean Peninsula was a transition from intra-Korean to inter-Korean conflict between emerging separate polities. The divergence between northern Korea and southern Korea started from the beginning of the occupation by the Soviet and American armies of the two halves of the peninsula. The Soviet Union and the United States were still allies, but their irreconcilable political systems and ideologies and differing interests set the conditions for the diverging paths of their respective occupied zones. By 1947, the northern and southern halves of the Korean Peninsula were entangled in the global antagonism between liberal capitalism and communism. The United States referred the Korean Question to the United Nations after the US-Soviet Joint Commission failed to agree on a unified Korean government. The United Nations Temporary Commission on Korea (UNTCOK) was established to oversee democratic elections in Korea. The Soviet Union and northern Korean authorities boycotted the commission. The commission violated earlier agreements between the powers on Korea, according to the Soviet delegate to the UN, Andrei Vyshinsky, while Kim Il Sung called the commission’s delegates “running dogs” of the United States. The 369

Avram Agov

UNTCOK-supervised elections in southern Korea in May 1948 presaged creation of a separate southern government (Cumings 1997: 211). Separate elections were held in northern Korea in August. Institution building in the two occupation zones culminated with the establishment of the Republic of Korea (ROK) on 15 August 1948 with Rhee Syngman (Yi Sŭng-man) as president, and the Democratic People’s Republic of Korea (DPRK) a few weeks later on 9 September with Kim Il Sung (Kim Il-sŏng) as prime minister. The two leaders symbolized the different political paths and foreign affiliations that the two halves of divided Korea would follow. Kim, a 33-year-old former anti-Japanese fighter in Manchuria and military officer in the USSR, returned to northern Korea aboard a Soviet ship from Vladivostok to Wŏnsan with dozens of his comrades on 18 September 1945. The 70-year-old Rhee, an exile in the United States and graduate of Princeton University, was flown to Seoul on General MacArthur’s plane in midOctober 1945. Foreign powers were instrumental in the territorialization of the civil conflict in Korea, which evolved to a stand-off between two state structures, thus amplifying the confrontation. The Korean War, 1950–1953, deepened and expanded the intra-Korean civil schism into an interstate war with enhanced military capabilities of the two rival sides which were further reinforced by international alliances. The Armistice Agreement, signed on 27 July 1953, ended the military operations on the Korean Peninsula, but not the war. The fault line between the two world blocs sharpened and deepened on the battleground of Korea. Even though the Korean War was a global conflict, the major powers tried to diminish the significance of their involvement or disguise it. For the Koreans, however, it was total war which resulted in horrific human losses and destruction. Three million Koreans (two million of them in the North), mostly civilians, were dead, injured or missing. The legacy of the Korean War is a major obstacle to reconciliation between the two Koreas. Coping with the war legacy has determined the history of the Korean Peninsula ever since.

Postwar reconstruction, militarization, and “Second Korean War,” 1954–1970 The failure of the Geneva Conference in 1954, designed by the armistice agreement to reach a peaceful settlement of the Korean Question, reconfirmed the division of the Korean Peninsula. The two Koreas were too far apart in their positions on establishing a unified government, while the great powers implicitly agreed to maintain a divided Korea within their respective spheres (S. Lee 2001: 119). The DPRK and ROK each built fortifications along the DMZ and braced themselves for a protracted war of political and economic attrition. American troops remained in South Korea, and the United Nations Command, encompassing US forces and the ROK Army, continued to function as the supreme military body in South Korea. The Chinese People’s Volunteer Army withdrew from North Korea by 1958 and the Korean People’s Army (KPA) has been solely responsible for the defense of the DPRK. South Korea looked more dependent on the American security shield, but North Korea too was dependent on its alliances with the Soviet Union and China for both security and economic aid. In the postwar period, the quest for supremacy and legitimacy by the two Koreas shifted from the battlefield to the areas of economy, diplomacy and propaganda. North Korea recovered from the rubble of the war and embarked on an impressive period of economic growth in the 1950s, while South Korea lagged behind. Socialist countries provided vital aid to the DPRK, but so did the United States to the South. A major part of the fraternal assistance to North Korea was in the form of industrial projects including financing, construction and technology 370

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

transfer, while the American aid was mostly supplies of food and consumer goods. Despite political repression accompanying the consolidation of Kim Il Sung’s power after 1956, the DPRK government was able to mobilize scarce labor and other resources through the centralized planning of the state-owned economy. The collectivization of farms expanded the allocation of resources to industries, although it also caused disruptions in food supply. Stronger economic results gave confidence to North Korea for a more active approach toward South Korea, seeking to set forth a peaceful unification process. The North’s initiatives also stemmed from the Marxist paradigm of the “inevitable” victory of socialism and communism, which meant that reunification would be achieved under Northern terms. Between 1954 and 1958, the DPRK made a flurry of proposals to the ROK, such as a non-aggression pact and mutual troop reduction, a peace agreement, cultural and economic cooperation, national elections under a neutral states’ supervision, inter-Korean conferences or joint sessions of the two legislatures, and for an international conference for reunification. The Rhee government viewed North Korea’s overtures as propaganda and rejected the proposals (Gills 1996: 59–60). The ROK was more vulnerable and the memories of the war, including the KPA invasion, were still too vivid for bridging the gulf between the two halves of the peninsula. An example of North Korea’s favorable positon over its southern rival is the repatriation of Korean residents in Japan, who were mobilized as colonial laborers during World War Two. North Korea-sponsored repatriation programs started in 1959 with the support of the General Association of Korean Residents in Japan (Ch’ongryŏnhaphoe) and the Japanese Red Cross. The repatriation of Koreans was a big propaganda victory for the DPRK, particularly given that the majority of the repatriates to North Korea were originally from the South. From December 1959 to December 1961, 75,000 repatriates arrived in North Korea (Armstrong 2013: 116). After the postwar reconstruction, North Korea appeared to offer more opportunities for the Koreans living in Japan, many of whom also harbored political sympathies to the DPRK. Major General Park Chung Hee (Pak Chŏng-hŭi) led a relatively bloodless coup d’état in Seoul on 16 May 1961. This military takeover can be viewed in the context of political and social instability following the April 1960 revolution, when student and public protests toppled Rhee Syngman’s administration, and as a reaction to the corruption in the army and the administration. The inability of the South Korean government to respond adequately to the economic competition from the North was detrimental to the South’s security. As director of army operations before the coup, Park was well aware of North Korea’s economic superiority at that time. The junta in South Korea was inseparable from the inter-Korean Cold War matrix. North Korean officials harbored a short-lived hope that the abrupt change in government in the South could advance inter-Korean dialogue. It took only two days for the North Korean leadership to shift its opinion on the forces behind the coup from “progressive” to “reactionary,” which reflected Park’s actions against the opposition in the South immediately after he took power.3 Still, there were secret inter-Korean talks initiated by Park in September which did not make much progress, but for a while the atmosphere between the two Koreas was not as hostile and acrimonious as before. The North and South withdrew to their Cold War shells after the prospects for improving their relations disappeared by the end of 1961. Both Koreas embarked on militarization in the 1960s with the help of their allies. The militarization was rooted in the inter-Korean rivalry and had significant domestic and external implications. Park Chung Hee’s regime cracked down on dissent and launched an ambitious economic program. The South Korean government expanded the ROK’s military capability and was involved in the Vietnam War by committing 320,000 troops to Indochina, which further strengthened the US-ROK military alliance. Park’s strong anti-communist bent and the ROK’s participation in the Vietnam War fueled more tensions on the Korean Peninsula. The Sino371

Avram Agov

Soviet split evolved into an intra-socialist cold war which posed a dilemma for the DPRK. At first, North Korea sided with China, but after 1965 it reinvigorated its relations with the Soviet bloc at the expense of the PRC. The Cultural Revolution in China created tensions in SinoDPRK relations, while the North Korean leadership felt the economic costs of strained relations with the Soviet bloc countries and was determined to mend fences with them. The cracks and uncertainty in the socialist world compelled the North Korean government to rely more on its own resources for defense and economic development. North Korea evolved into an “impregnable fortress” as the regime called for simultaneous development of the economy and defense – holding a “sickle in one hand and a gun in the other.” DPRK’s militarization escalated after 1966 and involved allocation of considerable resources to the military (between 30 and 50 percent of the budget), the creation of a huge militia force, the mobilization of labor, and the tightening of political and social controls. The creation of a garrison state in North Korea was parallel to more militant posture against the South. The North Korean military infiltrations in the South occurred after 1953, but they increased in the 1960s, shifting the strategy from intelligence gathering and building a revolutionary base to attempts at destabilizing South Korea and instigating insurgency. A new wave of infiltrations in 1966 involved commando raids and incidents along DMZ, which sometimes escalated into firefights, including artillery. Thirty South Korean soldiers and ten civilians were killed in clashes with infiltrators by October 1966, which made the ROK army stage a retaliatory attack. Firefights along the DMZ intensified between 1966 and 1969, which is referred as the “Second Korean War.” In 1967, there were around 100 reported infiltrations by the Northern forces in the South, while in 1968, they doubled. The culmination of North’s subversive campaign was the assassination attempt against Park Chung Hee on 21 January 1968. Unit 124 of the KPA with 31 commandos reached several hundred meters from the Blue House, the presidential palace, before they were repelled and eliminated by ROK security forces. Infuriated, Park planned a retaliatory operation against Kim Il Sung by establishing a Unit 684 – a commando group composed of former convicts who were trained more than three years on Silmido Island in ROK waters near Inch’ŏn. The operation was aborted in 1971 in lieu of improved chances for interKorean dialogue. Kim Il Sung’s plan to fuel a revolutionary movement in the South suffered a setback after Park’s regime cracked down on the Revolutionary Party for Reunification in the summer of 1968 and executed its founder, Kim Chong-t’ae, a South Korean communist. North Korea’s guerrilla activities in the South, coupled with the seizure of the American intelligence ship Pueblo in January 1968 and the shooting of an EC-121 spy plane in 1969, escalated tensions on the Korean Peninsula to a boiling point. Kim Il Sung purged militant generals in the KPA whose guerilla tactics against the South had backfired. After 1968, the North Korean infiltrations decreased, as their goal shifted to intelligence gathering and covert networks.

Vacillations between reconciliation and conflict, 1971–1991 Despite the intractable ideological and political divide, the DPRK and ROK shared similarities of developmental dictatorship in their quest for military and economic supremacy which would solve the reunification problem on their own terms. The militarization of the two Koreas in the 1960s was interconnected, the same was true of the political process in the two parts of the Korean peninsula. The Yushin (revitalization) constitution, adopted in November 1972, turned Park Chung Hee’s presidency into a legal dictatorship by granting him enormous powers, such as ruling by decree and an unlimited term in office. The Yushin regime coincided with the 1972 North Korean constitution. The new DPRK constitution elevated Kim Il Sung to the new post of President; affirmed suryŏngje (leader’s system); and enshrined chuch’e (self-reliance) 372

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

– the creative application of Marxist-Leninism “to the realities of our country” – as a “guiding principle” of the party-state (Article 4 of 1972 DPRK Constitution, quoted in C.-S. Lee 1976: 194). Meanwhile, South Korea was gaining momentum at the expense of its Northern rival on the back of an industrialization drive and export promotion. Park Chung Hee initiated the Heavy and Chemical Industries Promotion Plan in late 1971, focusing on six industries: iron, steel, nonferrous metals, shipbuilding, chemicals, and machines. The industrialization program, tailored along the Japanese model, was very ambitious, particularly given the lack of natural resources in the South and the skepticism of the American advisors. The plan was born out of the inter-Korean rivalry and aimed at enhancing the defense capabilities of the ROK. A similar preoccupation with national defense prompted the North Korean government to promote its own machine industries in the 1960s. Park Chung Hee followed keenly the DPRK’s economic performance and reportedly had comparative charts of economic data of the North in his office. By the mid-1970s, South Korea had surpassed North Korea in living standards, even though the DPRK was still ahead of the ROK in terms of GNP per capita based on official exchange rate (Hwang 1993: 123). Between 1965 and 1976, North Korea’s GNP doubled, still a respectable performance despite the slowdown caused by declining exports and rising foreign debt. But the South Korean GNP tripled during the same period, which laid the foundation for the long-term economic disparity between the two Koreas. International recognition and support were key factors for enhancing the legitimacy of the two Korean states. The Third World became an arena for North-South competition, as the two Koreas were already integral parts of the opposing Cold War blocs. The two Korean states were involved in their own “scramble” for ties in Africa and Asia. The North had an upper hand in engaging developing nations. Independence, anti-imperialist struggle, solidarity movements and commercial interests were the foundation for building the DPRK’s relations with Third World countries, such as Indonesia, India, Egypt, Iraq, Algeria, and Congo, among others. Even though the DPRK continued to be denied participation in the UN debate on the Korean Question, while ROK had the sole right to represent Korea, the Pyongyang government was gaining ground in the inter-Korean diplomatic competition. The increased presence of postcolonial countries in the United Nations started to shift the balance in favor of North Korea after 1958. North Korea’s active policy toward liberation movements and emerging nations in the 1960s and the 1970s increased its international support. As a result, by 1975, North Korea reached diplomatic parity with South Korea (Gills 1996: 261). New regional dynamics and internal developments in the two Koreas led to a détente on the peninsula in the early 1970s. The thaw between the United States and the Soviet Union, the normalization of Sino-American relations in 1971 and the American policy in Asia – known as the Nixon Doctrine – shaped the international background for the beginning of inter-Korean dialogue. Both sides had their own rationale for approaching each other: Kim Il Sung believed that the time of revolutionary change in the South was close and thus peaceful unification could be possible. The American decision to withdraw 20,000 troops from South Korea encouraged Kim’s optimism. A proclamation of the Supreme People’s Assembly to South Korean people on 13 April 1971, stated that the DPRK was ready to solve the unification peacefully in the event that after the removal of Park Chung Hee’s “faction” in South Korea, a people’s rule was established, or a democratic figure came to power. But on 6 August, Kim Il Sung expressed readiness to negotiate with various parties in the South, including Park Chung Hee’s Democratic Republican Party. During a meeting with the visiting Nicolae Ceausescu in Pyongyang in June 1971, Kim reasoned that in the absence of American forces, the South Korean 373

Avram Agov

people could install a “democratic progressive government” which would draw the Koreans close to each other so that the unification could be achieved peacefully.4 For his part, Park Chung Hee was increasingly concerned with perceived weakened American commitment to South Korea’s security in line with the Nixon Doctrine. The American position at the Paris Peace Talks for a settlement in Vietnam must have further undermined the Park regime’s trust in its American ally. The South Korean government was concerned about the possibility of US-DPRK relations in the wake of the US-PRC breakthrough. In addition, President Park grew more confident in South Korea’s economic performance vis-à-vis its Northern rival and he felt that the Seoul government could engage in inter-Korean dialogue from an enhanced position. At a speech on 15 August 1970, which marked Liberation Day, Park proposed the beginning of humanitarian talks between the two Koreas and “peaceful competition” with North Korea. In September 1971, the two Korean states held Red Cross negotiations regarding divided families, following the South Korean initiative. In turn, Kim Il Sung proposed a peaceful treaty between the DPRK and ROK in January 1972.5 The dramatic visit of the newly-appointed KCIA director Yi Hu-rak to Pyongyang on 2–5 May 1972 and his meeting with Kim Il Sung led to further conciliatory measures. The détente on the Korean Peninsula produced the historic 4 July 1972 Joint Communiqué, which was the first attempt at achieving peaceful unification. The Communiqué proclaimed three principles of unification: 1) the problems must be solved without foreign interference and with the Korean people’s own forces; 2) unification must be implemented in a peaceful manner; and 3) a unified nation should be created despite the ideological differences of the political systems.6 The two sides established a North-South Coordinating Committee, co-chaired by Kim Yŏng-ju, Kim Il Sung’s brother and a Politburo member, and Yi Hu-rak. Park Chung Hee and Kim Il Sung announced separate plans for unification in June 1973. The announcements revealed growing discord between the two sides as well. The North Korean leader proposed a confederation-type of unification in which the two Korean states would preserve their political systems and govern their domestic policy, while foreign policy could be entrusted to a unified body. In October 1973, Kim Il Sung explained to his visiting Bulgarian counterpart, Todor Zhivkov, that such a confederation system would require reduction in military spending and would lead to the elimination of the “reactionary regime” in South Korea, because without an army the people would rise. The North Korean leader admitted that the proposed confederation would be very difficult to materialize under the current circumstances and that it was a “political slogan” intended to “draw the workers and the peasants” and demonstrate to “democratic forces” in the South that North Korea was for peaceful unification, while South Korea was against it. Kim blatantly stated that if “more democratic government” was established in the South, the DPRK would not bring up the slogan for confederation, but simply “call a revolution.”7 The North Korean leadership grew increasingly suspicious and uneasy about the Yushin constitution, which strengthened anti-communism in the South and played a significant role in the DPRK’s decision to withdraw from the inter-Korean dialogue. On 28 August 1973, North Korea suspended meetings within the North-South Coordinating Committee reportedly in response to Kim Dae Jung’s kidnapping by KCIA agents. The abduction incident served as pretext for North Korea to withdraw from the dialogue. The failed détente on the Korean Peninsula pushed the two Korean states into a new cycle of confrontation. Kim Il Sung seemed to have abandoned his peaceful approach toward unification and returned to the more militant posture which characterized North Korea’s policy in the 1960s. With the North Vietnamese army poised to capture Saigon and unify the country, Kim Il Sung declared optimistically in Beijing on 18 April 1975 that Asia was on a “high tide 374

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

of revolution.” Kim unsuccessfully prodded the Chinese leadership to support armed unification of Korea during his visit. China wanted to prevent the Korean question from derailing its relations with the US and Japan or from getting involved in a military conflict on the Korean Peninsula. By 1974, an ailing Mao had modified his revolutionary view, stating that “we may not mention that the current world tide is a revolution.”8 As a result of the cold Chinese response, Kim Il Sung gave up military means to achieve unification. A new assassination attempt against Park Chung Hee on 15 August 1974 marked renewed hostility between the two Koreas. President Park was delivering a speech for the twenty-ninth anniversary of the Liberation in the National Theater in Seoul, when Mun Se-kwang, a Japaneseborn Korean, fired shots that missed Park but killed his wife Yuk Yŏng-su instead. It is widely believed that Mun acted under instructions from Pyongyang, but the DPRK link has not been categorically proven.9 Military tensions on the Korean Peninsula increased dramatically following the “axe murder incident” on 18 August 1976, when KPA soldiers killed two American officers in the Joint Security Area (JSA) of the DMZ. The American officers were attacked when their team, composed of American and South Korean soldiers, attempted to trim a tree hindering the view between posts. The UN Command responded with deployment of disproportionate force to cut the tree in an attempt to intimidate the North Korean side. The show of force was considerable, involving US helicopters and bombers circling around the zone. The DPRK expressed “regret” over the incident in the JSA, which was an admission of responsibility. The crisis can be seen in the broader context of the tense atmosphere on the Korean Peninsula following the first Team Spirit military exercises held by the US-ROK forces several months earlier. North Korea was involved in the kidnapping of Japanese and South Korean citizens. The most high-profile South Korean victims were film director Shin Sang-ok and his former wife and actress Ch’oe Un-hŭi, who were abducted in 1978 to develop the film industry of North Korea. They managed to escape from their North Korean minders during a visit to Vienna in 1986. After the botched inter-Korean dialogue, the DPRK tried to engage the United States in direct negotiations concerning a peace treaty, starting with Kim Il Sung’s letter to the US Congress in 1973. In 1976, the North Korean leader even sent a letter to president-elect Jimmy Carter seeking direct contacts. Kim also conveyed similar messages to the American president through Ceausescu in 1978 and Tito in 1979. The United States would not start negotiations with North Korea without South Korean participation. President Carter even briefly entertained the idea of meeting both Kim Il Sung and Park Chung Hee in order to reach a North-South settlement, following the model of the Camp David peace agreement between Israel and Egypt. The American president in fact proposed a three-way meeting of diplomats during his visit to Seoul in June 1979, but North Korea rejected his initiative (Oberdorfer 1997: 104–105). The anti-government protests and the assassination of Park Chung Hee by the KCIA director Kim Chae-gyu on 26 October 1979 threw South Korea into turmoil. Major General Chun Doo Hwan (Chŏn Tu-hwan), Commander of the Defense Security Command and investigator of his mentor’s assassination, initiated a bloody coup with fellow generals from hanahoe (literally “group of one”) – a secret officer circle in the army. On 12 December, Chun diverted army units from the area close to the DMZ, including part of the Ninth Division under the command of General Roh Tae Woo (No T’ae-u) – Chun’s classmate from 1955 class of the Korean Military Academy – and launched a daring attack on the Army headquarters in Seoul as a first step in installing a new military regime. The Kwangju Uprising in May 1980, which the South Korean propaganda falsely attributed to North Korean communist agents, further increased the uncertainty and tension on the Korean Peninsula. Still, the two Koreas engaged in ten “preliminary” meetings between February and August 1980 – the first encounter since dialogue 375

Avram Agov

ended in 1975. And for the first time, they referred to each other by their official names – DPRK and ROK (C.-S. Lee, 1985: 122). In 1981, the two sides held high-level meetings through their Red Cross organizations. The DPRK resorted to subversive tactics to undermine Chun Doo Hwan’s military regime, which continued Park Chung Hee’s anti-communist policies. North Korea’s foreign clandestine operations were put under the control of Kim Jong Il (Kim Chŏng-il) – an official successor of his father Kim Il Sung from the Sixth Congress of KWP in 1980. North Korean agents attempted to assassinate Chun Doo Hwan during his visit of Rangoon (Yangon) on 9 October 1983. A bomb explosion in a mausoleum of the national cemetery missed the South Korean president, but killed 17 officials, including three South Korean cabinet ministers and three Burmese officials. Two of the three conspirators were captured and one of them, Kang Minchul, admitted that he was a KPA officer. The bombing happened before Inter-Parliamentary Union meeting opened in Seoul. The incident led to the suspension of DPRK-Burmese relations, but it also strained Sino-North Korean relations, as the Chinese had proposed trilateral talks between DPRK, ROK and US on behalf of its ally, shortly before the bombing in Rangoon. The 1983 crisis was followed by attempts to resume the inter-Korean dialogue. North Korea reiterated its proposal for a three-way meeting in January 1984, in order to conclude the peace treaty. DPRK’s initiatives aimed to prevent an increase of American forces in South Korea and to “expose the United States’ excuses” for its military presence. In September of the same year, the North Korean Red Cross sent food and other supplies for flood victims in South Korea. The two Koreas held parliamentary meetings in 1985 and organized the first family reunions, as 35 South Koreans visited Pyongyang on 20 September. After 1985, the two sides used a secret diplomatic channel, through which they discussed even a possible summit between Kim Il Sung and Chun Doo Hwan, among other issues (Oberdorfer 1997: 147–149). The interKorean dialogue made little progress, however, and the relations deteriorated again in 1986. By this time, the Team Spirit US-ROK military exercises had reached 200,000 combined personnel. The DPRK viewed the two-month maneuvers south of the DMZ as threatening and suspended all inter-Korean exchanges in January 1986, after the ROK declined to call off Team Spirit. On 29 November 1987, a bomb explosion on Korean Air Flight 858 (from Abu Dhabi to Bangkok) was another dark episode in inter-Korean relations. Two North Korean agents planted a time bomb, which exploded midair and destroyed the plane, killing all 115 people on board, mostly South Koreans. The purpose of the terrorist attack was reportedly to destabilize the South Korean government and intimidate countries from participating in the 1988 Seoul Olympics. One of the bombers, a female agent, Kim Hyŏn-hŭi, survived a suicide attempt (her partner died in the hospital after taking cyanide) and was arrested in Bahrain. Kim confessed to the attack and was sentenced to death in South Korea, but President Roh Tae Woo pardoned her. As a result of the bombing, the US State Department listed DPRK as a state sponsor of terrorism. Mikhail Gorbachev’s “new thinking” in Soviet foreign policy and the improvement of SovietAmerican relations laid the foundation for the final phase of the Cold War. Gorbachev’s Krasnoyarsk speech in September 1988 also signaled a readiness to forge economic ties between the Soviet Union and South Korea. In this new international environment, President Roh Tae Woo tried to reach out to the DPRK by pursuing Nordpolitik, which resembled Chancellor Willy Brandt’s Ostpolitik toward Eastern Germany. The South Korean president proposed the promotion of trade between the two Koreas, exchanges of visits, and further humanitarian contacts between the two Koreas. On August 15 1988, Roh proposed an inter-Korean summit. Kim Il Sung replied that if the South accepted his proposal for confederation, the two leaders could hold a summit in Pyongyang. Kim also declared a non-aggression policy line toward South 376

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

Korea. Inter-Korean contacts also involved the South Korean opposition. North Korean foreign minister Ho Dam met opposition leader Kim Young Sam in Moscow in June 1989, and unsuccessfully tried to persuade him to visit North Korea. As Soviet perestroika, the fall of the Berlin Wall and the democratization of Eastern Europe started to break down the Cold War order, Roh’s “northern politics” was accompanied by efforts to establish ties with North Korea’s socialist allies. Hungary announced the exchange of permanent missions with ROK on 13 September 1988. Other Eastern European countries also established diplomatic relations with the ROK. The Soviet Union followed suit, as economic considerations played a part in promoting relations with South Korea. On 4 June 1990, Gorbachev and Roh Tae Woo met in San Francisco, and in September, Moscow decided to establish diplomatic relations with Seoul. Kim Il Sung was so upset with the Soviet “betrayal” that he declined to meet the Soviet foreign minister Eduard Shevardnadze, who was visiting Pyongyang in September 1990 to explain the shift in Soviet policy toward the ROK. DPRK foreign minister Kim Yŏng-nam told Shevardnadze that normalization of relations with South Korea would increase pressure on the North to open up in order to “overthrow the socialist regime in our country” and annex DPRK like the German scenario. Kim threatened his guest, saying that Soviet recognition of the South would nullify the 1961 Soviet-North Korean Alliance Treaty and that North Korea would be free to develop nuclear deterrents against American nuclear weapons on the Korean Peninsula, since the Soviet defensive “umbrella” stipulated in the treaty would no longer offer protection.10 There was more to come in a series of setbacks for the DPRK’s diplomacy by the end of Cold War. The Sino-North Korean “blood alliance” also suffered when China expanded economic ties with South Korea. In May 1987, Kim Il Sung visited China in an attempt to persuade Deng Xiaoping to terminate contacts with South Korea. Deng recommended that Kim not rely on military force and to try to improve relations with Japan and the US in order to seek a “realistic solution” for the problems on the Korean Peninsula. The PRC and the ROK established diplomatic relations on 24 August 1992. The collapse of the Soviet Union further shifted the strategic situation on the Korean peninsula. The cross-recognition between North Korea’s (former) allies and South Korea was not reciprocated by establishing diplomatic relations between North Korea and the West and Japan. The increased uncertainty prompted Pyongyang to pursue more active inter-Korean dialogue. The diplomatic exchanges culminated with two prime ministerial talks, held in Seoul on 4–7 September and in Pyongyang on 16–19 October in 1990. The director of National Security Planning, Sŏ Sŏng-wŏn, secretly visited Pyongyang in early October and met Kim Il Sung and Kim Jong Il, while KWP secretary Yun Ki-bŏk and Roh Tae Woo met in Seoul in November. The meetings failed to reach an agreement on a joint declaration dealing with unification and the idea of a Korean summit did not materialize. But the two prime ministers met again in Pyongyang in October 1991 and also in Seoul in December of the same year, achieving a breakthrough in relations, similar to the 1972 development. On 12 December, the two sides signed the Agreement on Reconciliation, Non-Aggression and Exchanges and Cooperation, which has been most promising in their bilateral relations. The accord included mutual recognition of each other’s systems, but fell short of recognizing the existence of the two states on the peninsula. The agreement called for transforming the armistice into a “state of peace” and non-use of force against each other. The document also envisioned economic, cultural and scientific exchanges. On the back of the North-South reconciliation agreement and Roh Tae Woo’s announcement that South Korea was free from nuclear weapons in December 1991, the two Koreas reached another historic nuclear pact on 19 February 1992. In their Joint Declaration 377

Avram Agov

on the Denuclearization of Korean Peninsula, the two sides pledged not to “test, manufacture, produce, receive, possess, store, deploy or use nuclear weapons.” They also agreed “not to possess nuclear reprocessing and uranium enrichment facilities” and to set up a Joint Nuclear Control Commission for reciprocal inspection of other’s facilities.

Nuclear Korean Peninsula, 1992–1997 The nuclearization of North Korea was part of its regime’s security efforts in a perceived hostile environment, which became increasingly unstable after 1991. But the nuclear problem was rooted in the unfinished Korean War. The arms race between the two Koreas was an essential element in their battle for supremacy. The US threat of using nuclear weapons during the Korean War and the deployment of nuclear warheads in South Korea in 1957 had an impact on North Korea’s perception of its vulnerability. DPRK started to acquire knowledge and technologies on nuclear energy as early as 1956, when North Korean scientists worked at the Nuclear Research Institute in Dubna, USSR. The Soviet government agreed to assist DPRK in building a nuclear research center in 1959. In 1965, the Soviet Union delivered a research nuclear reactor (two to four MW) to North Korea, which started operations in 1967. The North Koreans built an experimental gas-graphite moderated reactor (five MW) in Yŏngbyŏn, which used natural uranium fuel. The reactor, designed after an old British prototype, became operational in 1986, and a processing facility started to separate plutonium (needed for atomic bombs), approximately in 1989. In 1985, the Soviet Union also agreed to help DPRK build a nuclear plant (the Soviets had declined earlier North Korean requests, dating from the 1960s), while the Pyongyang government signed the Nuclear Non-Proliferation Treaty (NPT). The project made little progress, however, in the face of a declining Soviet economy and deterioration of Soviet-North Korean relations. DPRK’s intention to acquire atomic bomb dates perhaps from the 1970s and its clandestine nuclear program underscores the limitations of the Soviet Union and China to contain their ally’s nuclear ambitions. North Korea’s resolve to become a nuclear power strengthened after the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991. When the inter-Korean denuclearization talks were held in December 1992, a nuclear reprocessing plant in Yŏngbyŏn was near completion. Possession of nuclear weapons became a strategic priority of the North Korean regime as a guarantee for its existence in the uncertain post-Cold War environment. South Korea became more concerned over its security after the partial withdrawal of American troops from ROK in 1971. The fall of South Vietnam in 1975 hastened Park Chung Hee’s aspirations to acquire nuclear weapons. The South Korean government officially abandoned its plans under American pressure and the ratification of the NPT in 1975. Still, a secret nuclear program continued until Chun Doo Hwan shut it down in 1980. The United States withdrew its tactical nuclear weapons from South Korea in 1991, while the ROK remained under the protection of the American nuclear umbrella. The beginning of 1992 looked promising for the Korean Peninsula in light of the interKorean denuclearization agreement and DPRK’s efforts to normalize relations with the United States. Following a meeting between US Under-Secretary of State Arnold Kanter and KWP Secretary Kim Yŏng-sun in New York on 22 January 1992, the DPRK signed a safeguards agreement with the International Atomic Energy Agency (IAEA) in Vienna eight days later. But the IAEA inspections of Yŏngbyŏn complex raised the suspicions that the DPRK was running a clandestine nuclear weapons program. At the same time, inter-Korean relations entered a new crisis by the end of 1992, as the Joint Nuclear Control Commission reached a deadlock on the short-notice inspections. Also, presidential elections in South Korea cooled the enthusiasm for 378

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

the inter-Korean dialogue, while the US-ROK decision to resume Team Spirit exercises, which had been suspended in 1992, further deteriorated the atmosphere between the two Koreas. The DPRK refused IAEA’s demand for “special inspections” in Yŏngbyŏn.11 The North Korean government announced its withdrawal from the NPT in March 1993, which was to be implemented three months later. However, in June, a last-minute joint USDPRK statement, negotiated and agreed upon by Under Secretary of State Robert Gallucci and Deputy Foreign Minister Kang Sŏk-ju “suspended” North Korea’s withdrawal from NPT in exchange of American security assurances to Pyongyang. It was somewhat of a breakthrough for North Korean diplomacy in dealing directly with the United States, something that South Korea consented to as long as it involved only the nuclear problem. But the US-DPRK negotiations in Geneva in July 1993 expanded the scope of issues and included ideas for a “package deal,” such as the shifting of North Korea’s nuclear program to less proliferation-prone lightwater reactors. The shift from limited US-DPRK talks, focused on preventing North Korea from withdrawing from NPT, to wider range negotiations made the South Korean government increasingly nervous of being sidelined by its ally in shaping the policy toward North Korea (Oberdorfer 1997: 283, 291). President Kim Young Sam’s policy toward North Korea vacillated between a compromise and a hardline stance, reflecting the mood in the public and the media. The breakdown of international inspections in North Korea prompted the IAEA’s board to turn the matter over to the UN Security Council in March 1994. The collapse of South-North working-level talks in Panmunjom – where the North Korean negotiator threatened his South Korean counterparts that if war broke out, then Seoul would turn into a “sea of fire” – as well as the Kim Young Sam administration’s decision to deploy Patriot missiles, dramatically escalated the tension on the Korean Peninsula in the spring of 1994. The UN Security Council’s deliberations to impose sanctions on the DPRK, following the IAEA’s alarm, triggered angry responses in Pyongyang, which likened the punitive action to a “declaration of war.” The defueling of the nuclear reactor in Yŏngbyŏn – the unloaded fuel rods were considered a tangible threat of building nuclear bombs – and IAEA’s declaration that it was unable to verify the reactor’s past further ignited the confrontation on the Korean Peninsula. The crisis forced the US military to prepare a war contingency plan. The North-South stand-off became so unpredictable that the South Korean government organized large civil defense drills. The US officials were planning an evacuation of American civilians from Seoul, while citizens in the capital were stockpiling food in case war broke out. Former US president Jimmy Carter’s visit to North Korea in mid-June and his meetings with Kim Il Sung made a breakthrough in both US-DPRK nuclear negotiations and in NorthSouth relations. Kim agreed to a nuclear freeze (not to place new fuel rods in the reactor and not to reprocess the removed fuel rods) and in return North Korea would receive help for building light-water reactors. (Light-water reactors are less suitable for producing plutonium for nuclear weapons compared to gas-graphite moderated reactors.) The North Korean leader also accepted Kim Young Sam’s proposal for an inter-Korean summit, which was delivered through Carter. As a result, the US dropped their sanctions drive and plans for military deployments to Korea. The Korean peninsula moved away from the abyss of brinkmanship to a relaxation of tension and the possibility for rapprochement. There were plans for a historical summit between the Korean leaders in Pyongyang on 25 July, but Kim Il Sung unexpectedly died of a heart attack on 7 July. The Great Leader’s sudden death not only cancelled summit preparations, but it also led to the rapid deterioration of interKorean relations. Kim Yong Sam’s initial reaction to the unexpected turn of events in the North was to put the ROK army on maximum alert. The authorities in the South banned any expression of condolences to the North and, on the day of Kim Il Sung’s funeral in Pyongyang, made 379

Avram Agov

public Russian documents revealing his role in starting the Korean War. The North Korean response returned to bitter anti-South propaganda, while South Korean officials envisioned the imminent collapse of the DPRK. Nevertheless, the U.S.-DPRK nuclear negotiations continued in Geneva. The US-North Korean Agreed Framework, signed on 21 October, stipulated the provision of light-water reactors (total 2000 MW) to North Korea in exchange for freezing all activity on its existing reactors and permitting continued monitoring by IAEA, including “special inspections.” The two sides also agreed to open diplomatic liaison offices in the two capitals as a first step to full normalization of relations. North Korea was to implement the 1991 North-South joint declaration on denuclearization and re-engage in the inter-Korean dialogue. The ROK government officially endorsed the deal, even though South Korean objections persisted. In March 1995, the US, Japan and South Korea set up the Korean Peninsula Energy Development Organization (KEDO) in order to supply two reactors to North Korea, as South Korea was primary financial contributor to the project (Oberdorfer 1997: 357, 366). The implementation of the KEDO project was fraught with difficulties and obstacles, stemming from domestic politics of the participants and the volatile situation on the Korean Peninsula. In September 1996, a North Korean submarine incursion incident led to South Korea’s suspension of all KEDO-related activities, as well as inter-Korean economic cooperation. North Korea in turn threatened to abandon the agreed framework and restart its nuclear program in Yŏngbyŏn. Meanwhile, the ROK army designated twelve targets in North Korea for retaliation if new provocations arose. The crisis subsided after North Korea issued a statement of “deep regret” for the submarine incursion in December 1996. The DPRK also agreed to participate in a joint ROK-US briefing in New York on four-power peace negotiations – the two Koreas, US and China – a format that had been proposed by Presidents Clinton and Kim Young Sam. Economic sanctions against DPRK remained and no steps were taken toward establishing diplomatic relations with the US, as there was a growing suspicion of an underground uraniumenrichment facility (a second possible route to nuclear weapons) in North Korea. In 1998, the North Korean government warned that it would resume its nuclear research. The KEDO began the construction of the first light-water reactor in August 2002 (the two reactors were to be ready by 2003), but indefinitely halted work several months later. In October, during a meeting with Assistant Secretary of State Kelly in Pyongyang, North Korean officials stated that DPRK was an independent country and that they had the right to possess nuclear weapons for defense purposes. When the CIA reported that North Korea was building a centrifuge facility for uranium enrichment, the US administration discontinued their shipments of oil (part of the agreed framework) to North Korea in December 2002. The two Koreas re-engaged in the humanitarian field in the 1990s. In 1995, the North Korean economy was on the brink of collapse after several years of continued decline. The state distribution system disintegrated and the food supply situation became desperate, forcing the government to appeal for outside help. South Korea sent 150,000 tons of rice to the North, but refrained from providing further food relief amidst the submarine incursion crisis. However, as evidence of starvation in the North mounted, the South Korean Red Cross started to ship rice in 1997 (as much as 40,000 tons). The ROK was also one of the major financial contributors to the UN World Food Program which provided 200,000 tons of food to North Korea.

Sunshine era, 1998–2007 The inauguration of President Kim Dae Jung in January 1998 marked the beginning of a more positive policy of South Korea toward North Korea. The crux of the “Sunshine Policy” was 380

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

the acceptance of peaceful coexistence of the two Koreas, although it fell short of legally recognizing the DPRK. The new approach moved away from containment and isolation of the North towards a more active engagement and of cooperation in various areas and on different levels. The rationale of the new policy was that reconciliation and exchanges could stimulate change in North Korea and eventually the two Koreas could unify. North Korea’s initial response to this change of attitude was criticism of the new Seoul policy as a “political assault” on its system, but as the time passed, the North became more receptive to the separation of economic cooperation from political issues, and it recognized benefits from the new environment in interKorean relations. The first significant result of Seoul’s positive approach of engagement was the summit between Kim Dae Jung and Kim Jong Il in Pyongyang on 13–15 June 2000. The June 15 Joint Declaration called for: 1) resolving the reunification issue independently; 2) exchange of visits by separated family members; and 3) promotion of economic cooperation and exchanges in cultural, sports, health, and other fields. The two sides decided to use multiple channels for negotiations – such as the Red Cross, ministerial meetings and military working-level talks – to facilitate the cooperation. The summit dramatically improved the atmosphere in the bilateral relations, and President Kim Dae Jung was greeted by thousands of enthusiastic Seoul citizens upon his return from Pyongyang. The most tangible outcome in the inter-Korean economic cooperation was the creation of the Kaesong Industrial Complex (KIC), which opened in December 2005. The complex developed with the ups and downs that reflected the pulse in the inter-Korean dialogue. Even though the KIC did not expand as originally planned, its scale and implications as a joint undertaking were unprecedented. Using North Korean labor and South Korean capital, as well as know-how for manufacturing consumer goods for export, the project became a mini-version of what a future Korean economic community might look like. (As of 2013, the KIC employed 53,000 North Korean workers and involved 123 South Korean companies.) Mount Kŭmgang Tourist Region was another product of the 2000 Korean summit. This resort was established in 2002 to facilitate visits from the South. By 2008, approximately two million South Koreans had visited the scenic mountain getaway. Bus tours from South Korea to Kaesong were also arranged to expand civic exchanges. Following the agreements, the two Koreas restored railway links between Kaesong and the DMZ in 2003, and freight service started in 2007. The collapse of the North Korean economy in the 1990s led to the Great Famine, which the regime called the Arduous March (konanŭi haenggun). The humanitarian disaster caused between 600,000 and over one million deaths (Haggard and Noland 2007: 11). Meanwhile, Kim Jong Il formulated a military-first policy (sŏn’gun chŏngch’i) after the mid-1990s, although the North Korean historiography traces it back to the 1960s. The “revolutionary idea of attaching great importance to the army” was a policy tool to consolidate Kim’s power, mobilize scarce resources and labor, and tighten controls in society. The North Korean government tried to address the economic difficulties by introducing limited liberalization measures in July 2002, which was conducive to the economic cooperation between the two Koreas. But the policy was reversed in 2005 and old patterns of central planning and controlled markets were reinstated. The inter-Korean cooperation helped North Korea to stabilize economically and expand its foreign relations. The ROK not only did not block efforts of other countries to forge ties with Pyongyang – a pattern from the global Cold War era – but actually encouraged them to do so. Between 2000 and 2001, the DPRK established diplomatic relations with the UK, Italy, Germany, The Netherlands, Spain, Belgium, Luxemburg, Brazil, Canada, and New Zealand, among others. The South Korean non-governmental sector also nourished linkages between the two halves of the peninsula in the second half of the 1990s and the early 2000s. South Korea’s NGOs 381

Avram Agov

responded to North Korea’s call for international help in 1995, amidst severe food shortages. Their activities received official sanction by the Kim Dae Jung administration and expanded after 1998. From 1995 to 2001, South Korean NGOs donated nearly USD 162 million in form of food, clothes, and medicine to North Korea (Flake and Snyder 2003: 87). South Korean business also became active in promoting ties with the North. One notable example is Chŏng Chu-yŏng, the founder of Hyundai group who was born in Asan, North Korea. Chŏng became known for his “cattle diplomacy,” when he crossed the DMZ with a cattle herd loaded on trucks as a donation to North Korea just before the first inter-Korean summit in Pyongyang. The good spell in inter-Korean relations revealed how important political thaw was for reinvigorating the linkages between the two halves of the peninsula. Inter-Korean relations also suffered setbacks during the “sunshine” era. After President George W. Bush identified North Korea as part of “Axis of Evil” in January 2002, the DPRK government temporarily terminated the talks with the South. In June 2002, a naval skirmish occurred between the two Koreas in a disputed maritime area in the Yellow Sea. Two North Korean vessels crossed the Northern Limit Line – which was considered the boundary by South Korea versus the Military Demarcation Line – and attacked South Korean patrol boats. In retaliation, South Korean reinforcements pushed back the North Korean vessels. The clash caused the death of thirteen North Korean and six South Korean sailors. Revelations surfaced that the South Korean government paid USD 500 million to Pyongyang in order to facilitate the June 2000 summit and this revelation created a political storm in Seoul, including the conviction of six businessmen in 2003. The chairman of Hyundai Asan, Chŏng Mong-hŏn, who was reportedly involved in the back-channel dealings with the DPRK, committed suicide during the scandal. President Roh Moo Hyun (No Mu-hyŏn) followed in the footsteps of his predecessor Kim Dae Jung by formulating a “peace and prosperity policy” toward the DPRK in 2003. Roh crossed the DMZ on 2 October 2007 on his way to Pyongyang, where he met Kim Jong Il for the second inter-Korean summit. Although the second meeting between the Korean leaders was not as dramatic as the first summit, it generated positive momentum and cappedoff ten years of the Sunshine Policy. They adopted a peace declaration that called for the implementation of the 15 June Joint Declaration from 2000; embracing efforts to overcome differences in ideologies and systems; the replacement of the armistice with peace treaty; talks for easing military tension and economic cooperation; the creation of special zone around Haeju in North Korea; humanitarian exchanges and family reunions; and cooperation in the fields of education, culture and sports. Between 2002 and 2009, there were sixteen rounds of family reunions at the Mt. Kŭmgang resort, involving 10,673 South Koreans and 5,539 North Koreans. South Korea increased its humanitarian aid to North Korea, which included the annual delivery of 450,000 tons of food and 300,000 tons of chemical fertilizers from 2003 to 2007. From 1998 to 2007, the total South Korean aid provided to North Korea was worth USD 7.18 billion.12 The inter-Korean trade expanded to USD 1.79 billion in 2007, which constituted almost one-third of the DPRK’s foreign trade, which matched the volume of Soviet-North Korean trade which peaked in 1988. The number of North Korean refugees to the South also increased: from 71 in 1998 to 2,551 in 2007. By 2010, the total number of refugees from the North reached 20,407. The most high-profile North Korean defector was Hwang Jang Yop (Hwang Chang-yŏp), a former chairman of Standing Committee of the Supreme People’s Assembly (position which he held until 1983) and a leading chuch’e ideologue. Hwang fell out of favor with the new North Korean leader Kim Jong Il and defected to South Korea via the South Korean embassy in Beijing and the Philippines in 1997. 382

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

The improvement of inter-Korean relations did not solve the nuclear issue on the Korean Peninsula. Nuclear proliferation problem entered a new dangerous phase, as the agreed framework was unraveling. The DPRK announced its withdrawal from NPT on 10 January 2003. The Bush Administration opted for a multilateral approach to tackle the nuclear problem in contrast to the previous bilateral one adopted by the Clinton Administration. The Six-Party Talks – including the two Koreas, US, China, Japan and Russia – commenced in August in Beijing. It was not until the fourth round of the talks in September 2005, however, that the parties agreed on a joint statement, which outlined steps needed for the denuclearization of the Korean Peninsula. The DPRK agreed to abandon its nuclear weapons and programs and return to the NPT. The other parties acknowledged North Korea’s right to develop nuclear energy and were ready to discuss the delivery of light-water reactors. In addition, the US and ROK committed not to deploy nuclear weapons in Korea. Yet, a new cycle of confrontation quickly followed. The US sanctions against DPRK’s trading entities provoked a strong reaction from Pyongyang. Further, North Korea conducted its first nuclear test on 9 October 2006 and dynamics quickly deteriorated. The UN Security Council issued Resolution 1718, which called on DPRK to refrain from further nuclear and missile testing and to rejoin the talks. The Six-Party negotiations resumed in February 2007, which resulted in an agreement on the first steps of implementing the Joint Statement in the next sixty days. North Korea sealed its reactor and declared its nuclear activities in June, and the US removed DPRK from the Trade with the Enemy Act and from the list of states that sponsored terrorism, steps that were agreed to in February. But disagreements on the verification mechanisms for North Korea’s nuclear program stalled the progress of the Six-Party Talks in December 2007.

Shadows over Korea, 2008–2013 South Korean President Lee Myung Bak (Yi Myŏng-bak) reversed the “Sunshine Policy” after questioning its character of “appeasement.” Past policies of Lee’s predecessors toward the North also created friction with ROK’s allies: the United States and Japan. The conservative South Korean administration aimed at providing conditional economic assistance to the DPRK over the next ten years, with the goal of bridging the gap between the two Koreas. Inter-Korean cooperation was intended to help the North Korean economy reach a USD 3,000 per capita income during that period, hence the “Vision 3000” policy. The main condition for South Korean aid was the implementation of the 2005 Joint Statement, which had been issued at the Six-Party Talks for the denuclearization of North Korea. President Lee also prioritized human rights issues in his policy toward North Korea, which had an adverse effect on inter-Korean dialogue. The DPRK labeled the South Korean government a “reactionary clique.” Exchanges between the two Koreas were either canceled or limited. In 2008, after a South Korean tourist was shot and killed by a North Korean soldier in the Mt. Kŭmgang resort area, the Seoul government terminated tours to the North. Inter-Korean relations continued to deteriorate after North Korea test-fired an Unha-2 threestage rocket on 5 April 2009, in which the third stage failed to separate properly. The UN Security Council issued a presidential statement, declaring that the test was a violation of the October 2006 Resolution 1718, and new sanctions were adopted against the DPRK afterwards. North Korea declared that it would not participate in the Six-Party Talks and that it would also abrogate previous agreements. On 25 May 2009, The DPRK conducted a second nuclear test. As a result, on 12 June, the UN Security Council adopted new sanctions and arms embargoes against North Korea. The following day, the DPRK admitted for the first time that a uranium 383

Avram Agov

enrichment program existed for the production of fuel for a light-water reactor. This was another blow to inter-Korean relations. Military tensions on the Korean peninsula escalated to a dangerous level in 2010 in the wake of two significant incidents. On 26 March, a North Korean submarine allegedly fired a torpedo at a South Korean corvette Cheonan, which sank near Paengnyŏng Island. The island lies in a sensitive, disputed area of the Yellow Sea, 16 kilometers off the North Korean coast and 121 kilometers from an area where joint US-ROK naval exercises were being conducted at that time as part of Key Resolve war maneuvers. As a result of the Cheonan sinking, 46 South Korean seamen lost their lives. The incident can be viewed in the context of ongoing disputes between the DPRK and ROK over sea borders, which has led to frequent naval clashes. Only four months earlier, a naval battle between the two sides in the area left several North Korean sailors dead. In May, South Korea announced it would stop almost all trade with North Korea, and that it would conduct joint US-ROK naval exercise in response to the sinking. North Korea presented its own list of punitive measures, which included cutting off all ties with the South – except the operation of the Kaesong Industrial Complex – and it threatened to attack any South Korean vessel crossing the Military Demarcation Line, which was declared as a sea border by Pyongyang in 1999. Another grave incident occurred in November in the disputed Yellow Sea zone. Following live-fire exercise by South Korean forces, North Korean artillery opened fire on military and civilian targets on Yŏngp’yŏng Island (located 12 km off the North Korean coast), killing four South Koreans. The ROK army retaliated by firing on North Korean military positions. In response to the DPRK’s provocation, ROK and US conducted previously scheduled but expanded joint naval exercises in the Yellow Sea while the South Korean army reinforced the defense of Yŏngp’yŏng Island. Inter-Korean relations hit a new low point after North Korea successfully launched an Unha-3 rocket into space on 12 December 2012. It was a breakthrough in the DPRK’s ballistic missile program, as it demonstrated the capability of sending vehicles roughly 10,000 km, although it had not reached the capability to build miniature warheads for mounting on a missile. Consequently, the UN Security Council Resolution 2087 condemned the launch on 22 January 2013. The DPRK escalated the rhetoric and declared that it would continue the missile tests and the development of its nuclear program; it even threatened the US with launching long-range missiles. On 12 February, North Korea conducted a third nuclear test and declared that it would end the Armistice Agreement on 13 March. At that time, the United States and South Korea conducted the joint military exercise Foal Eagle, which involved B-52 bombers from an American air base in Guam and B-2A stealth bombers (which flew directly from Missouri to the Korean Peninsula) as an affirmation of the “nuclear umbrella” over South Korea. The war of words reached unprecedented levels, as North Korea declared a “state of war” against the South on 30 March. North Korea’s saber-rattling, albeit not unusual, can be partially explained by the recent power succession to Kim Jong Un (Kim Chŏng-ŭn) – the youngest son of Kim Jong Il. There was little time to prepare for the transition after Kim Jong Il died on 17 December 2011, and the young Kim had to quickly assert his leadership. According to such interpretation of North Korea’s militant attitude, Kim Jong Un needed to demonstrate that he could stand up to the DPRK’s enemies in order to enhance his credentials as the new Supreme Leader, particularly among the military – a key for power succession. North Korea announced that it would restart its nuclear reactor in Yŏngbyŏn and closed entry to the Kaesong Industrial Complex – the last functional project of the inter-Korean cooperation. In August, the two sides agreed to reopen the complex, which signaled the end of the crisis. The crisis was a test for the new South Korean President Park Gun Hye (Pak Kŭn-hye). The daughter of late President Park Chung Hee, the new president formulated her own approach 384

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

to North Korea – “trustpolitik,” which aimed to resume dialogue with North Korea. South Korea made a commitment to restore aid and cultural exchanges with the North in return for a better rapport with Pyongyang – a compromise between the “sunshine” approach and a hardline policy. The fact that Park visited Pyongyang and met Kim Jong Il in May 2002 as chairwoman of the Korea-Europe Foundation helped to facilitate her communication with the North Korean leadership. For his part, Kim Jong Un – a third -generation leader from the Kim family – sent a positive signal to the South during his 2014 New Year address in which he called for establishing a “favorable climate” for improving relations between the North and the South and for unity the of all Koreans, who “should open a new phase for independent reunification, peace and prosperity this year.”13 It seemed that the DPRK was ready to start a more positive phase in inter-Korean relations. Only time will tell how far the two Korean leaders might go in promoting linkages and cooperation across the DMZ. After almost seven decades of separation and extremely divergent historical trajectories, the two Koreas continue to polarize and distance themselves from each other, making the possibility of reunification increasingly daunting. Notwithstanding, there are some key factors that make for achieving reconciliation possible. The first condition is to end the Korean War, which means the replacement of the armistice agreement with a peace treaty. The peninsular Cold War architecture is the root cause for a continued division, so until it is dismantled, the inter-Korean antagonism will continue to persist. The peace process entails steps toward denuclearization of North Korea and military de-escalation, as well as the recognition of the DPRK by the United States and Japan. Some argue that a “grand bargain” – including denuclearization, recognition and economic aid to North Korea – was perhaps the most effective formula for achieving permanent peace, but at the current moment the prospects of such an equation are still dim. DPRK’s determination not to give up its nuclear arsenal – which is perceived by the regime as its last stand against the hostile world surrounding the country – is an obstacle for reaching such an agreement and, more importantly, for implementing it. In recent years, North Korea has more vigorously expanded its nuclear program and has conducted a space launch, which has enhanced its bargaining position and has also increased the security risks on the peninsula. One possible way to deal with the nuclear problem has been offered by Siegfried Hecker, a Stanford University professor and the former director of the Los Alamos National Laboratory. Hecker put forth a formula of “three No’s”: no more bombs (meaning no plutonium and highly enriched uranium); no better bombs (including testing and missile launches); and no exports.14 Even if North Korea agreed to this, it would still be a difficult proposition for domestic political reasons, as Washington and Seoul would hardly accept a solution which would fall short of complete denuclearization. Clearly, no solution can be found without some flexibility and compromise from all sides. Major players in the East Asian region are interested in peace, but they are even more concerned with preserving stability, which is associated with the status quo or a divided Korean Peninsula. Reunification of Korea is not exactly against the interests of China, Japan, and the United States, but it is not their priority either. Without a Helsinki-type process of collective regional security and cooperation, permanent peace on the Korean Peninsula will continue to remain out of reach. The participants in the Six-Party Talks, for example, could constitute such a regional security mechanism. On several occasions, the two Koreas have reached different degrees of rapprochement and a common understanding that they should pursue reunification independently, but the historical context of division is also inseparable from external factors. Similarly, peace and reconciliation are closely connected to foreign powers, starting from the conclusion of peace treaty. 385

Avram Agov

The two Koreas have premised reunification on the concept that it should be achieved on each state’s terms. This means that one of the two should prevail and the other would have to disappear, hence the irreconcilable inter-Korean antagonism. The race for superiority has defined inter-Korean relations since the inception of the two Korean polities. Despite the huge economic gap (North Korea is three percent of the South Korean economy), South Korea has not been able to “win” the peninsular Cold War. For all practical purposes, the two Koreas have developed mutual deterrents as insurance policies and the zero-sum game cannot achieve significant progress toward reunification in the foreseeable future. Thus, mutual recognition of the two Koreas is another important condition for reconciliation and the reunification process. DPRK’s Marxist vision of revolution in the South further deepened the conflict between the two Koreas in the global Cold War era. Expectations of North Korea’s collapse by ROK and its allies have also led to missed chances for reaching a comprehensive peace regime and a durable reconciliation between the North and the South. Isolation and impoverishment have pushed North Korea further toward militarization and bellicose rhetoric and provocative behavior. Recognizing the fact of the division is important step toward overcoming it. Another key factor for the reunification process is its prioritization by the two Korean states. Their pledged commitment to unity has been backed by statements, unmatched by consistent and comprehensive policies. On the contrary, there are interests and forces in both the DPRK and the ROK, which are either afraid or directly opposed to unification. One example is the North Korean political and military elite, who are doomed if unification is achieved through absorption by the South. Further, concerns of prohibitively high unification costs (some estimates reach one trillion USD) and insecurity on the Korean peninsula discourage South Korean policy makers and the public to support reunification, at least in the short-run. The two Koreas have followed diverging paths, so the historical trend is to make the division permanent. Shifting the centrifugal dynamics on the Korean peninsula will require profound changes, both internally and externally. Bridging economic and social gaps between the two sides is an extremely difficult task, although the economy seems the most promising sphere for promoting inter-Korean exchanges and cooperation. An even bigger challenge to reunification is the emergence of separate Korean nations with distinct identities and values. Korea has been moving from “two states – one minjok (nation)” towards a “two states – two nations” reality. The history of Korean division and prospects of unification would be further illuminated by studying the issue of nation formation in the long-term partition of Korea. Inter-Korean relations could be examined from anthropological, cultural, social and psychological perspectives, outlining the connecting and disconnecting points between the two Koreas. Study of North Korean migration to the South, for example, can provide revealing intersecting points between the two Koreas on the humanitarian level. The scholarship of inter-Korean relations needs more research in various fields, such as economics, politics, security, diplomacy and culture, which includes also the link between domestic policies and the approach of the two Korean states toward each other.

Notes 1 Interestingly, this was not the first time Korea had been divided by foreign powers in modern history. A secret clause of the Yamagata-Lobanov agreement in 1896 stipulated the division of Russian and Japanese spheres of influence in Korea along the 39th parallel, even though the agreement was related only to the movement of limited number of troops from both sides and did not lead to the actual partition of the country. 2 Interview with former North Korean resident Sofia, May 2013. 386

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

3 Archive of Chinese Ministry of Foreign Affairs (CFMA) 106–00581–03, Report from the Chinese embassy in the DPRK, Minutes of Conversation between Kim Il Sung and Qiao Xiaoguang, Re: the Military Rebellion in South Korea, 16 May 1961: 19–20; 106–00581–06, Memorandum from the Chinese embassy in the DPRK, Meeting of Central Standing Committee of Korean Worker’s Party on 18 May 1961, 21 May, 1961:32–33. 4 Romanian Central Historical Archive (ANIC), File no. 43/1971, Report from the Romanian embassy in the DPRK, Minutes of Conversation on the Occasion of Party and Government Delegation on behalf of the Romanian Socialist Republic to the DPRK, Pyongyang, 10 June 1971. North Korea International Documentation Project (NKIDP), Woodrow Wilson International Centre for Scholars. 5 Kim Il Sung articulated his five-point peace treaty proposal at the 2nd session of the Fifth SPA in April 1972: 1) suspension of the increase of armed forces and arms race; 2) withdrawal of all foreign troops, including those of the US; 3) reduction of the armed forces of the North and the South to under 100,000 troops and under, and sharp arms reduction; 4) termination of import of all kinds of weapon, tactical equipment and materials; 5) signing a peace treaty which will solve the aforementioned issues and guarantee that the North and the South will not use force against each other. Archive of the Bulgarian Ministry of Foreign Affairs (AMVRB), opis 31, delo 116, 1882, Report from the Bulgarian embassy in the DPRK, Second Session of the Fifth Supreme People’s Assembly of the DPRK and the issues addressed by Kim Il Sung, ambassador Yanko Georgiev, Pyongyang, 10 July 1973, 50. 6 Political Archive of the German Ministry of Foreign Affairs (PA AA MfAA), C 951/76, Report from the embassy of the GDR in the DPRK, Information provided by DPRK Deputy Foreign Minister Kim Yŏng-taek to ambassadors of East European countries on 3 July 1972, Pyongyang, 4 July 1972, NKIDP. 7 AMVRB, opis 29, Delo 69, 1609, Minutes of Conversation between Kim Il Sung and Todor Zhivkov, held on 25 October 1973: 133–135. 8 Yafeng Xia and Zhihua Shen, “China’s Last Ally: Beijing’s Policy Toward North Korea during the U.S.-China Rapprochement, 1970–1975,” Diplomatic History (2013): 26. 9 Recent reports dispute the North Korean involvement in the assassination plot, as the Japanese investigations failed to confirm Mun’s alleged links to the DPRK or the Ch’ongryŏnhaphoe in Japan. 10 Sergei Radchenko, “North Korea and the End of the Cold War,” paper at international conference “China-DPRK Relations during the Cold War,” Shanghai, October 14–15, 2011. 11 The IAEA introduced special inspections to assess suspicious undeclared facilities, after it was established in 1991 that Iraq had a clandestine nuclear program in secret sites close to those inspected by the international agency of undeclared nuclear waste sites. 12 Leonid Petrov, “The Politics of Inter-Korean Economic Cooperation, 1998–2009,” The Asia-Pacific Journal: Japan Focus, http://www.japanfocus.org/site/make_pdf/3190, accessed August 5, 2014. 13 Nodong sinmun, New Years’ Address, January 1, 2014. 14 Siegfried Hecker, “North Korea Reactor Restart Sets Back the Denuclearization,” Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists, October 17, 2013, http://thebulletin.org/north-korea-reactor-restart-sets-back-denuclearization, accessed August 3, 2014.

References Agov, Avram. (2013) “North Korea’s Alliances and the Unfinished Korean War,” Journal of Korean Studies 18, no. 2 (Fall 2013): 225–262. Armstrong, Charles K. (2002) The North Korean Revolution, 1945–1950. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Armstrong, Charles K. (2013) Tyranny of the Weak: North Korea and the World, 1950–1992. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Armstrong, Charles K. (2009) “Juche and North Korea’s Global Aspirations,” Working paper #1, North Korea International Documentation Project, Woodrow Wilson International Center of Scholars, Spring. Brzezinski, Zbigniew. (1971) The Soviet Bloc: Unity and Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Buzo, Adrian. (1999) The Guerrilla Dynasty: Politics and Leadership in North Korea. London and New York: I.B. Tauris and Co. Ltd. Childs, David. (1988) The GDR: Moscow’s German Ally. London: Unwin Hyman. 387

Avram Agov

Chung, Chin O. (1978) P’yŏngyang between Peking and Moscow: North Korea’s Involvement in the Sino-Soviet Dispute, 1958–1975. Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press. Chung, Young Chul. (2007) “The Suryŏng System as the Institution of Collectivist Development,” The Journal of Korean Studies 12, no. 1 (Fall 2007): 43–74. Collins, Robert. (2014) “A Brief History of the ROK-US Combined Military Exercises,” 38 North, February 26, 2014. Cumings, Bruce. (1983) “Corporatism in North Korea,” Journal of Korean Studies, no. 4: 1–32. Cumings, Bruce. (1990) The Origins of the Korean War, Volume II: The Roaring of the Cataract, 1947–1950, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Cumings, Bruce. (1997) Korea’s Place in the Sun: A Modern History. New York: Norton. Cumings, Bruce. (1997) “Time to End the Korean War,” The Atlantic Monthly (February). 71–79. Cumings, Bruce. (2004) North Korea: Another Country. New York: The New Press. Flake, L. Gordon and Scott Snyder (eds.) (2003), ed. Paved with Good Intentions: The NGO Experience in North Korea, Westport, CT and London: Praeger. Foot, Rosemary. (1985) The Wrong War: American Policy and the Dimensions of the Korean Conflict, 1950–1953. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Frank, Rüdiger. (1996) Die DDR und Nordkorea. Der Wiederaufbau der Stadt Hamhúng von 1954–1962 (The GDR and North Korea: The Reconstruction of the City of Hamhŭng, 1954–1962), Aachen, Germany: Shaker. Frank, Rüdiger. (2008) “Lessons from the Past: The First Wave of Developmental Assistance to North Korea and the German Reconstruction of Hamhŭng,” in Pacific Focus, vol. XXIII, no. 1 (April 2008): 46–74. Gills, Barry K. (1996) Korea versus Korea: A Case of Contested Legitimacy. New York, London: Routledge. Goncharov, N. Sergei, John W. Lewis, and Xue Litai. (1993) Uncertain Partners: Stalin, Mao, and the Korean War. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Han, Hongkoo. (2013) “Colonial Origins of Juche: The Minsaengdan Incident of the 1930s and the Birth of the North Korea-China Relationships,” in Jae-Jung Suh (ed.) Origins of North Korea’s Juche: Colonialism, War, and Development (pp. 33–62), Lanham, MD: Lexington Books. Humm, Taik-young. (1999) Arming the Two Koreas: State, Capital, and Military Power. London and New York: Routledge. Haggard, Stephan and Marcus Noland (2007) Famine in North Korea: Markets, Aid, and Reform. New York: Columbia University Press. Hwang, Eui-gak. (1993) The Korean Economies: A Comparison of North and South Korea. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press. Jian, Chen. (1994) China’s Road to the Korean War: The Making of the Sino-American Confrontation. New York: Columbia University Press. Kwon, Heonik and Byun-Ho Chung. (2012) North Korea: Beyond Charismatic Politics. Plymouth, UK: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc. Lankov, Andrei. (2002) From Stalin to Kim Il Sung: The Formation of North Korea, 1945–1960. London: Hurst & Company. Lankov, Andrei. (2005) Crisis in North Korea: The Failure of De-Stalinization, 1956. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press. Lee, Chae-jin. (1996) China and Korea: Dynamic Relations. Stanford: Hoover Press. Lee, Chong-sik. (1976) “The 1972 Constitution and Top Communist Leaders,” in Dae-sook Suh and Chae-jin Lee (eds.), Political Leadership In Korea. Seattle: University of Washington Press. Lee, Chong-sik. (1985) “The Evolution of North-South Korean Relations,” in Robert Scalapino and Hongkoo Lee (eds.) North Korea in Regional and Global Context. Berkeley: University of California. Lee, Steven. (2001) The Korean War. New York: Longman. Myers, Brian. (2010) The Cleanest Race: How North Koreans See Themselves and Why it Matters. Hoboken, NJ: Melville House Publishing. Merrill, John. (1989) Korea: The Peninsular Origins of the War. Newark, DE: University of Delaware Press. Naimark, Norman, and Leonid Gibianskii. (1997) The Establishment of Communist Regimes in Eastern Europe, 1944–1949. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Noland, Marcus. (2004) Korea after Kim Jong Il. Institute for International Economics. Washington DC, #71. Oberdorfer, Don. (1997) The Two Koreas: A Contemporary History. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Special:BookSources/9781933633916. 388

Inter-Korean relations, 1945–2013

Ostermann, Christian and James Person (eds.) (2011) The Rise and Fall of Détente on the Korean Peninsula, 1970–1974. Washington DC: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars. Park, Han-sik and Kyung-ae Park. (1990) China and North Korea Politics of Integration and Modernization. Hong Kong: Asian Research Service. Rieber, Alfred. (2009) “Popular Democracy: An Illusion,” in Vladimir Tismaneanu (ed.), Stalinism Revisited, The Establishment of Communist Regimes in East-Central Europe. Budapest-New York: Central European University Press, pp.103–130. Shen, Zhihua. (2012) Mao, Stalin, and the Korean War: Trilateral Communist Relations in the 1950s. London and New York: Routledge. Shen, Zhihua. (2000) “Sino-Soviet Relations and the Origins of the Korean War: Stalin’s Strategic Goals in the Far East,” in Journal of Cold War Studies, vol. 2, no. 2, (Spring 2000): 44–68. Shen, Zhihua. (2002) “Sino-North Korean Conflict and its Resolution during the Korean War,” CWIHP Bulletin Issue 14/15, 2002: 9–24. Shen, Zhihua and Danhui Li. (2011) After Leaning on One Side. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Suh, Dae-sook. (1988) Kim Il Sung: The North Korean Leader. New York: Columbia University Press. Szalontai, Balazs. (2006) Kim Il Sung in the Khrushchev Era. The Soviet-DPRK Relations and the Roots of North Korean Despotism, 1953–1964. Washington DC: Stanford University Press and the Woodrow Wilson Center Press. Szalontai, Balazs and Sergey Radchenko. (2006) “North Korea’s Efforts to Acquire Nuclear Technology and Nuclear Weapons: Evidence from Russian and Hungarian Archives,” CWIHP Working Paper No. 53, Washington DC: Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars, August 2006. Tismaneanu, Vladimir. (2009) “Diabolical Pedagogy and the (Il)logic of Stalinism in Eastern Europe,” in Vladimir Tismaneanu (ed.), Stalinism Revisited, The Establishment of Communist Regimes in East-Central Europe. Budapest-New York: Central European University Press, pp. 25–50. Van Ree, Eric. (1989) Socialism in One Zone: Stalin’s Policy in Korea, 1945–1947. Oxford, UK: Berg. Wada, Haruki. (1998) “The Korean War, Stalin, and Japan,” in Social Science Japan Journal, vol. I, no. I, 1998: 5–29. Weathersby, Katlyn. (1993) “Soviet Aims in Korea and the Origins of the Korean War, 1945–1950: New Evidence from Russian Archives.” CWIHP, Working Paper 8, 1993. Xia, Yafeng and Zhihua Shen, (2013) “China’s Last Ally: Beijing Policy toward North Korea during the US-China Rapprochement, 1970–1975,” Diplomatic History, vol. 38, no. 5: 1083–1113. Zubok, Vladoslav. (2007) A Failed Empire: The Soviet Union in the Cold War from Stalin to Gorbachev, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. Zubok, Vladislav and Constantine Pleshakov. (1996) Inside the Kremlin’s Cold War: from Stalin to Khruschev, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

389

This page intentionally left blank

Index

Note: Page numbers in bold type refer to figures. Page numbers in italic type refer to tables. 1884 (Kapsin) Coup 36, 130 7.1 Measures 254 Acheson, Dean 186, 189, 190 Agricultural-Industrial Bank 91 Agriculture: in Chosŏn 20, 21, 22, 84, 88; colonial period 131–133; North Korea 222–223, 235, 252, 253 see also famine; South Korea 328 An Ch’ang-ho 72 An Chung-gŭn 36, 158 An Kil 205 Andong Kim 17, 44 April Revolution 305, 318, 361 Appenzeller, Henry 70 Arduous March 206, 251, 381 Asian Financial Crisis 291, 292, 293, 343, 345–347, 350, 363 Asian NICs 277, 296, 309 Assimilation, Japanese policies of 112–121 August Plenum 215 Auto Transport Union 284, 288 Bonesteel, Charles 173, 184 Britain 30, 32, 34, 172, 284 Buddhism 64, 65, 66, 74, 96, 98, 148, 159 Capitalism: Colonial period 126, 128, 162; Confucian capitalism 296; in early modern Korea 53, 54; emergence in modern Korea 71, 81, 87 Cairo Declaration 172, 177 Catholicism, see Christianity Ch’a Ch’i-ch’ŏl 322 chaebŏls 291, 296, 298–307 passim, 323, 329, 343–352 passim Chang In-hwan 158 Chemical Unions 285–287 Cheju Rebellion 185 Chiang Kai-shek 184 Chang Myŏn 318–319

Ch’anggŭk 133 children in North Korea China: aid to North Korea 222, 229; colonial period 163; relations with Chosŏn 1, 4, 18–19, 27–37, 46, 82, 83, 92, 100, 154–156 ; relations with North Korea 208, 214–216, 224, 235, 241, 251, 377; role in Korean War 177, 183, 186–191 Chinese Communist Party 184, 207, 215 Chinese People’s Volunteers 188 Chinju Rebellion 20, 45 Chipkangso 100–101 Cho Man-sik 165, 174, 202 Ch’oe Ch’ang-ik 200 Ch’oe Che-u 48, 68, 74, 76, 95–98, 104, 105 Ch’oe Kwang 208 Ch’oe Kyu-ha 322 Ch’oe Rin 118, 119 Ch’oe Si-hyŏng 68, 74, 76, 96–98, 100–102 Ch’oe Ik-hyŏn 29 Ch’oe Nam-sŏn 2, 118, 119, 162, 164 Ch’oe Yong-gŏn 204, 205 Ch’ŏlchong, 17, 44 Ch’ŏlla 95, 97, 99 Ch’ŏllima movement 215, 226 Chŏn Myŏng-un 158 Chŏn Pong-jun 68, 98–121 Ch’ŏndogyo 58, 74, 76, 105, 159, 162 Chŏng Yag-yong 17, 18 Chŏngjo 16, 17, 18, 19 Chŏnju 97 Ch’ongryŏn 230, 231 Chosin Reservoir 189 Chosŏn: Economy 21–22, 81–93; Reform movements 43, 46–58; state and politics 15–21, 27–37, 44–46; historiography of 3–4, 52–59 Christianity: Chosŏn period 63, 66, 70, 71–73, 131; colonial period 131, 148, 159, 160, 162; 391

Index

persecution of 17–18, 28, 66; in South Korea 365, 366 Chu Yong-ha 200, 203 Chun Doo Hwan (Chŏn Tu-hwan) 55, 322, 323, 324, 375, 376 Ch’ungch’ŏng 95, 97, 102 chungin 3 Chŭngsang-gyo 76 Cinema: colonial period 133; in North Korea 375 Cold War 183, 262, 358–360 colonial modernity 124–138, 158 comfort women 116, 165, 178, 270, 336 COMECON 154, 225 communism 161, 163, 184, 268, 305 concubinage 143, 268 Confucian ethics 18, 19, 21 Confucianism 20, 22, 48, 51, 64–68, 96, 98, 154 Crony capitalism 346 Cuban Missile Crisis 215 Culture policy (bunka seiji) 113–115, 141, 161 Cultural Revolution 191, 216, 218, 268 culture nationalism 161, 162, 359 Daegu (Taegu) 288, 306 Daewoo 299 Dai-ichi Bank 91 Daoism (Taaosim) 64, 66, 96, 98 Darwinism 51, 56, 124, 155 Deliberative Council 48 Demilitarized Zone (DMZ) 192, 368, 370, 372, 375 Democratic People’s Republic of Korea (DPRK) 186 see also North Korea de-Stalinzation 214 developmental state 309, 343, 353 division of Korea 171–178, 185, 262, 369–370 divorce in North Korea 264 domestic sphere 136, 142 East Asian Tigers see Asian NICs “eastern ways, western means” 88 “economic miracle” 295–309 education: colonial period 113, 114, 115, 143–144; women’s education 143–144, 330–331; in South Korea 360, 361 Education Act of 1911 113 Enlightenment (Kaehwa) Movement 53–54, 124, 130, 142, 155 Enlightenment party see Enlightenment Movement equal emphasis policy 216 Equal Opportunity Act 332 factory girl 147 familism 266, 267 392

family: in North Korea 266–268; in South Korea 331–332 “family head” (hoju) system 335 Family law: colonial period 148, 149; in South Korea 333, 335 Family planning 331–332 famine in North Korea 234–243, 251–252; famine deaths controversy 239–240; origins 235–236 farmers 131–133, 199, 203, 223, 227, 305, 337, 361 Five-Year Plans in North Korea 215 France 29, 30, 34 Fourteen Article Oath 73 Fukuzawa Yukichi 47, 130, 155 Gangnam-style 357 gender see women Gender Equality Law (North Korea) 263, 264 General Sherman 29, 30, 45 Germany 33, 34, 364, 368 “global Korea” 357–366 Great Han (Taehan) Empire 35, 51, 57, 130 “guerilla state” 7 Hangyŏng 202 Han’gŭl 50, 125, 154, 157 Hara Takashi 120 Hideyoshi see Imjin War Hong Chae-hak 29 homogeneity 4, 127, 361, 365, 366 Hong Kyŏngnae (see also Kyŏngnae Rebellion) 20, 44 Hong Yŏng-sik 130 Hong Zhunxian 30, 46 Hŏnjong 17 Hulbert, Homer 73 human rights 246, 321, 336 Hwang Jang Yop (Hwang Chang-yŏp) 218, 239, 382 Hwang Woo-suk (Hwang U-sŏk) 364 Hwanghae 102 hyangyak 133 Hyegyŏng, Lady 16 Hyŏn Yŏng-sŏp 118, 119 Hyundai 362 Ilchinhoe 58, 157, 165 Im Kwan-t’aek 185 Imjin War (Waeran) 154 Imo Soliders’ Mutiny 83 imperialism 15, 27–37 passim Inch’ŏn 30, 32, 35, 85, 87 independence, loss of 36–37 Independence Club 35, 49–50, 56, 57, 104, 157

Index

International Monetary Fund (IMF) see Asian Financial Crisis Itō, Hirobumi 36, 158 Japan: Annexation of Korea 83, 84, 91; Assimilation policy 111–121, 158; Japanese colonialism; colonial rule 111–121, 125–138, 158–165; Korean relations with Chosŏn 27–28, 30, 33–37, 45, 50–51, 86–93, 100, 173; Relations with South Korea 361 Jeon Taeil (Chŏn T’ae-il) 300 Juche (chuch’e) 211–219, 225, 235, 359, 372 Kabo Reforms 34, 48–49, 55, 56, 73, 81, 86–89, 92, 130 Kaechu 87 Kaesŏng Industrial Complex 381 Kaesŏng merchants 22 Kang Man-gil 3, 55, 56 Kang Yang-uk 203 Kanghwa, Treaty of 15, 29, 45, 63, 67, 83, 154 Kangwŏn 102 Kapsin Coup (Coup of 1884) 28, 55, 86, 156 Kennan, George 183, 189 Khrushchev 212, 225 Kim Chae 203 Kim Chae-gyu 322 Kim Ch’aek 205 Kim Chong’t’ae 372 Kim Dae Jung (Kim Tae-jung) 317, 324, 344, 346–349, 359, 363, 364 Kim Hong-jip 46, 55 Kim Hwal-lan 118 Kim Jong Il: 246–259 passim, 268 , 370, 382; early career 247–248; leader of North Korea 222–226, 228–229; personality 248–249; successor to Kim Il Sung 209, 218, 228 Kim Jong Suk (Kim Chŏng-suk) 268 Kim Jong Un 209, 246, 285 Kim Il Sung: early career 163, 174, 177, 198; foreign policy 370–379 passim; political thought 211–219, 268; role in establishing North Korean state, 177, 98, 197–201; role in Korean War 183, 185, 188, 189 Kim Kae-nam 101 Kim Ku 163, 165, 171–172, 174, 177, 211 Kim Kyu-sik 174 Kim Ok-kyun 47, 130 Kim Song-hwan 187 Kim Sŏng-su 174, 185 Kim Tu-bong 200, 201, 203 Kim Ung 205 Kim Wŏn-ju 141 Kim Yŏng-ju 34 Kim Yŏn-su 185 Kim Yong-bŏm 199

Kim Young Sam (Kim Yŏng-sam) 322, 324, 379 Kim You-na (Kim Yu-na) 364 Kim Yun-sik 47, 55 Kimilsungism see juche kisaeng 133, 134, 135, 145, 329 Kojong 17, 27, 29, 30, 34, 36, 37, 45, 57, 67, 73, 99, 142, 154, 156, 159 Kŏmun-do 32, 33 Korea, historians of 2–9 Korean Democratic Women’s Union 262 Korean Federation of Trade Unions (KFTU) 285 Korean (North) People’s Army: establishment of 205–206; role in Korean War 186, 187, 188 Korean Provisional Government (Provisional Government of the Republic of Korea) 160, 171, 172, 184 Korean War: conflict 186–191; destruction in North Korea 222, 267; historiography of 6–7, 180–183; impact of 265, 357–359, 370; origins 183–186; outcome 175, 191–192 “Korean Wave” 1, 337 Korean Workers’ Party: founding 14, 198–202, 212 Koryŏ 16, 64, 153 Kwangmu Emperor 37, 57, 156 Kwangmu Reforms 81 Kwangju (Gwangju) Massacre 54, 305, 322 Kwŏn Kŭn 18 Kŭnuhoe 148 Kyŏngnae Rebellion 66 Kyŏngsang 99 Labour: Colonial period 116, 146–148; North Korea 226, 227, 267; South Korea 277–293, 300, 305, 307, 348–349; Women in labour force 146–148, 267, 329–330, 333, 352 Lady Hyegyŏng 16 land reform 203, 262 Law to Eradicate Remnants of Feudal Practice 264 Leaders Program 317 Lee Myung-bak (Yi Myŏng-bak) 344, 351 LG 302, 362 Li Hongzhang 30 liberation (from Japan) Literature: colonial period 125, 128–129, 133, 134, 136, 161; Low-Rodgers Expedition 29 Maitreya 66 March First Movement 103, 105, 113, 14, 115, 141, 159–160, 172, 184 Manchuria 91, 119, 158, 163, 186 Manchurian Incident 164 Mao Zedong 186, 188, 218, 229 393

Index

Marriage: Chosŏn period 263; colonial period 115, 144; in North Korea 263–266; in South Korea 328, 331, 337 markets, in North Korea 228, 271 Marxism see communism McArthur, Douglas 188, 189 Meiji Reforms 46, 47, 49, 89 Meiji Restoration 30, 93, 101, 113 Merchants: Chosŏn 22, 32, 82, 91; Merchant guilds 85 Methodist Church see Christianity “military first” policy 218, 381 “military rule” (budan seiji) under Japanese 113 minjok (folk, nation) 137 minjung 52, 104, 105, 128, 131, 323, 361 missionaries 33, 70–73, 75, 98, 129, 131, 159, 160, 365 Miura Gorō 34, 49 Mizuno Rentarō 114 Modern boy 136, 137, 149 Modern girl 136, 144, 149 modernization 3, 155, 157, 158, 161, 333, 337 see also colonial modernity Moffet, Samuel 75 Mokp’o 35, 93, 131 Mongol Invasions 154 monolithic ideological system 217 Moscow Conference 175 Mu Chŏng 205 Muccio, John 186 music 133, 135 Musillan Rebellion 20 Na Hye-sŏk 149 Name Order of 1940 116–117 Namin 49, 74 Nampo 225 Nationalism: Chosŏn 154–158; Colonial period 158–166; premodern Korea 153–154; in North Korea 361–362; in South Korea 358–359, 361 nationalist history 364 Neo-Confucianism see Confucianism neoliberalism 9, 349, 352 Network for North Korean Democracy and Human Rights 242 New Woman (sinyōja) 125, 128, 141, 144–145, 149 newspapers 50, 51, 88, 117, 156 NGOs 239, 242, 381–382 Nine-27 camps 242 nobi 22 Nordpolitik 364, 376 North Korea: constitution 218; economy 215, 216, 217, 221–223, 234–243 passim; 253–255; economic stagnation 223–231, 253, 246; ideology 246, 247, 257–258; image of 1; 394

foreign policy 212–216, 249–250, 257, 258; historiography of 7–8; human rights 234, 242, 257, 258; military 224, 242, 252, 256, 259; origins of 197–209; relations with South Korea 216, 368–386 passim; role in Korean War 186–191; society 262–272 North Korea Branch Bureau 199, 201 North Korean People’s Committee 202–204, 2009 Northeast Anti-Japanese Army 184 Northern Assembly 100, 102 Northern Learning 47, 54 nuclear weapons 246, 249–251, 378–379 Nuclear No-Proliferation Treaty 378, 379 O Ki-sŏp 199 Ŏ Yun-jung 47 OECD (Organization of Cooperation and Development) 307, 366 Open Port Period 82, 84, 87, 93 Oppert, Ernst 29, 45 Oriental Development Company 91 Orientalism 5 Pacific War 145 Paek Nam-un 2, 211 Pak Ch’ang-ok 224 Pak Che-ga (Chega) 17, 54 Pak Chi-wŏn (Chiwŏn) 17 Pak Hŏn-yŏng 201, 207 Pak Kŭm-ch’ŏl 217 Pak Kyu-su 29, 30, 46 Pak Ŭn-sik 2, 51, 159 Pan-Asianism 119, 155 P’anmunjŏm 189, 190 p’ansori 133, 134, 135 Park Chung Hee (Pak Chŏng-hŭi) 229, 300, 319–321, 329, 344, 352, 359, 361, 371–375 passim Park Geun-hye (Pak Kŭn-hye) 344, 352 ParK, Tongsun (Pak Tong-sŏn) 360 Patriotic Enlightenment Movement 49–51, 53, 56 patriarchy 266, 268, 300, 332–336 partrilineality 148 peasants 3, 44, 45, 86, 87, 95, 132–133, peddlars’ guild POW issue 187, 189–191 Presbyterian Church see Christianity Privy Council 50 Program to Increase Rice Production 132 Protectorate 36, 51, 71, 157 Public distribution system (PDS) 227–228, 242, 253 Pueblo Incident 372 Pusan 35, 83, 87, 89, 91, 132, 188, 288, 322 Pusan Perimeter 188

Index

P’ungyang Cho 17, 44 P’yŏngan 202, 205 Pyongyang (P’yŏngyang) 35, 86, 88, 225 P’yŏngyang Revival 71, 74, 76 Queen Min 34, 156 Qing see China railroads 90, 91, 131 Rangoon Incident 376 rationing see public distribution system reform movements in late Chosŏn 46–58 refugees from North Korea 235, 382 religion: Chosŏn 62–76, 97, 98; colonial period 116; see also Buddhism, Christianity, Confucianism, Tonghak Republic of South Korea see South Korea Residency-General 36, 51 Rhee, Syngman (Yi Sŭng-man) 160, 163, 174, 183, 184, 187, 189, 303, 315–316, 361, 370 rice exports 86, 87, 92, 131 Roh Moo-hyun (No Mu-hyŏn) 344, 375, 382 Roh Tae Woo (N T’ae-u) 376, 377 Romenenko, Andrey 207 Roosevelt, Franklin 177, 184 Rural Revitalization Program 133 Rusk, Dean 173, 177, 185 Russia: relations with Chosŏn Korea 30, 33–36, 50–51, 173 Russo-Japanese War 36, 51, 84, 90, 157 sadae (serve the great) 214 Saemaŭl Undong (New Village Movement) 328 Saitō, Makoto 113 Samguk Yusa 154 Samsung 299, 302, 306, 362, 363 Sangje 68 Scranton, Mary Mary sedo chŏngch’I (dominance of consort clan) Seikanron 30 Sejong, King 16 “self-reliance” 212 see also juche Self-strengthening 46, 48, 88, 90, 92, 105, 130 Seoul 1, 6, 32, 87, 136, 145, 187, 318 Seoul Olympics 360 Seven-Year Plan 217 sexuality in North Korea 268–271 Shamanism 64, 65, 66 Shanghai Incident 163 Shinto 116, 118, 164 Shirak (Silhak, Sirhak) (Practical Learning) 29, 54 Shufeldt, Robert 30, 33 Silla 153 Sin Chae-ho 2, 51, 159, 211 Sin Kyu-sik 159 Sin’ganhoe 161 Sino-Japanese War 35, 84, 95, 100, 142, 156

Sino-Soviet split 216, 225 slavery 49 sexual slavery 147, 178 see also comfort women Sŏ Chae-p’il 49, 72, 130 Sŏ Chang-ok 101 social Darwinism 56, 112, 149, 155 Socialism 162 see also communism Son Ki-jŏng 118 Son Pyŏng-hŭi 74, 102 Song Chin-u 174, 185 sŏngbun 242, 243, 255 sŏwŏn (academy) 19 South Korea: Democratization 314–325; economy 277–298 passim, 295–308, 343–353, 373; foreign policy 361–363 370–383 passim see also United States; historiography of 8–9; image of politics 324–325, 357–266 passim, 370–385 passim; relations with North Korea 250, 370–384 passim South Korean Workers’ Party 201 Southern Assembly 100, 101, 102 Soviet Union: colonial period 161, 163; aid to North Korea 212, 215, 216, 229, 235, 246; occupation of Korea 176, 197–199, 207–208; relations with North Korea 212–216, 249–251; role in division of Korea 172–177; role in Korean War 186–191 “speed battles” 226 Stalin 176, 183, 188, 192, 207, 212 Stevens, Durham 158 suffrage movement in Colonial Korea 115 Sunjo 17 Sunjong 36, 158 Sunshine Policy 380–382 Supreme People’s Assembly 175, 217, 239, 247, 357 Suryŏng (leader) 217 Taegu see Daegu Taewŏn’gun 17, 29, 30, 45, 47, 82, 99 Takaki, Kudō 146 Takashi, Hara 113, 120 Tan’gun 162 Temple Ordinance 74, 76 theater 133–134 Three Revolutions Team Movement 247 Tianjin, Connvention 30 Third World 177, 373 Thirty-eight parallel 173, 175, 177, 183, 189 Tongbaekchŏn 82 Tonghak 48, 58, 68–70, 76, 95–98, 130, 156 Tonghak Rebellion 36, 48, 55, 56, 69, 76, 86, 95–106, 130, 156 Tongnae 22 T’ongni Kimu Amun 46 trade unions see labour Treaty of Amity 31 395

Index

tributary system 4 Truman, President 181, 187, 188 ŭibyōng (righteous armies) 158 Ǔiju 91

Underwood, Horace 70, 78 United Nations 165, 174, 181–182, 186, 187, 234, 236, 315, 370 UN Commission of Inquiry on North Korean Human Rights 234 UN Temporary Commission on Korea (UNTOCK) 174, 369 UN Trusteeship 174, 176 United States: aid to South Korea 316–318; Influence on South Korea 314–323 passim; occupation of Korea 185, 234; relations with Chosŏn Korea 29–32, 36, 45, 83; relations with North Korea 375–378–380, 382; role in division of Korea 171–178; role in Korean War 186–191 U.S.-USSR Joint Commission 174, 202, 203, 204, 206, 207 Ǔnsan 35 Western imperialism 28 “Western Learning” 29 Wilson, President 159, 184 “wise mother, good wife” 129, 142, 143, 145, 149 Women: colonial period 116, 128, 136, 141–149; in North Korea 262–272; in South Korea 326–338; in South Korean labour force 327–329; women and modernity 128 Wŏnsan 87 World Food Program 234, 241 World War II 111, 120, 171, 176

396

Yalu River 189 yangban 19, 27, 44, 67, 99, 129, 130, 183 Yŏngjo 16 Yi dynasty see Chosŏn Yi Chae-myŏng 158 Yi Chong-song 205 Yi Hang-no 29 Yi Hu-rak 374 Yi Hyŏn-san 65 Yi Ki-baek 3, 52 Yi Kwang-su 125, 136, 161, 164 Yi Man-sŏn 29 Yi Pong-chong 163 Yi Pyŏng-do 2 Yi Seung-hun 76 Yi Sŭng-hun 66, 72, 76 Yi Sŭng-man see Rhee, Syngman Yi Wan-yong 158 Yi Yong-gu 74 Yi Yōng-su 118 Yi Yŏng-sun 118, 119 YMCA 71, 72 Yŏ Un-hyŏng 174, 211 Yŏhŭng Min 44 Yŏngbyŏn 249, 250, 378 Yŏngjo 16, 17 Yŏsu Rebellion 185 Yu Kil-chun 55, 130 Yu Kwan-sun 160 Yu Tŭk-kong 17 Yuan Shikai, 32, 48 Yun Ch’i-ho 49, 72, 118 Yun Pong-gil 163 Yusin (Yushin) 319, 322, 372 Zainichi 120, 121