Reasons of State: Oil Politics and the Capacities of American Government 9781501726330

In this lucid and theoretically sophisticated book, G. John Ikenberry focuses on the oil price shocks of 1973–74 and 197

155 54 15MB

English Pages 234 [230] Year 2018

Report DMCA / Copyright

DOWNLOAD FILE

Polecaj historie

Reasons of State: Oil Politics and the Capacities of American Government
 9781501726330

Citation preview

Reasons of State

A volume in the series

Cornell Studies in Political Economy EDITED

BY

PETER j. KATZENSTEIN

A full list of titles in the series appears at the end of the book

Reasons of State OIL POLITICS AND THE CAPACITIES OF AMERICAN GOVERNMENT

G. JOHN IKENBERRY

CORNELL UNIVERSITY PRESS Ithaca and London

Open access edition funded by the National Endowment for the Humanities/ Andrew W. Mellon Foundation Humanities Open Book Program. Copyright © 1988 by Cornell University All rights reserved. Except for brief quotations in a review, this book, or parts thereof, must not be reproduced in any form without permission in writing from the publisher. For information, address Cornell University Press, Sage House, 512 East State Street, Ithaca, New York 14850, or visit our website at cornellpress.cornell.edu. First published 1988 by Cornell University Press Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Ikenberry, G. John.   Reasons of state : oil politics and the capacities of American government / G. John Ikenberry. p. cm. — (Cornell studies in political economy) Includes index. ISBN-13: 978-0-8014-2155-6 (cloth) — ISBN-13: 978-0-8014-9488-8 (pbk.) 1. Petroleum industry and trade—Government policy—United States. 2. Energy policy—United States. I. Title. II. Series. HD9566.I525 1988  333.79'0973'—dc19  88-3660 The text of this book is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/

For my parents

Contents

Preface 1. The Oil Shocks and State Responses

IX

1

2. Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

21

3. The American State and Energy Policies

48

4. The Limits of International Cooperation

80

5. The Limits of State Building

104

6. The Limits of Technology and Spending

138

7.

The Market as State Strategy

8. Reasons of State Index

165 191

Preface

What capacities does the modern American state possess to cope with rapid international political and economic change? This is the core question informing this book, and it emerges from recent histor­ ical events and theoretical debates. Events of the last fifteen years underscore the importance of national adaptation. International eco­ nomic and political hierarchies are again changing as profoundly as they did in the 1 870s and 1 940s. Amid these sh ifting historical sands, the international power of the United States is eroding. In the dec­ ades before World War I, the United States could isolate itself from international political and economic change. After World War II the unprecedented power of the United States allowed it to set the terms of adj ustment and change. But the last quarter of the twentieth cen­ tury presents new realities ; the United States is both more involved in the global political economy and less able to shape its course . Theorists of international relations and political economy have taken note of these historical developments, of course, and a variety of theoretical debates have raged over the relationships among the power of the state, political sovereignty, and economic interdepen­ dence. Since the early 1 970s, old questions of order and change in international relations have been examined anew. Traditional con­ ceptions of the state and the state system have been challenged by scholars embracing a new interest in the multinational corporation, transnational organizations, bureaucratic politics , and transgovern­ mental relations. To some the changes were ephemeral; to others, profound. To address these large-scale theoretical problems, I focus on the issue of "state capacity," and do so by investigating a key set of historIX

PREFACE

ical events that propelled these controversies-the oil shocks of the 1 970s. In examining the capacity or "weightiness" of the state, partic­ ularly the American state, I look to understand the constraints on and opportunities for states-as organizational entities-to realize the goals they embrace. At moments of crisis, what can states accomplish ? What international and national resources and instruments of power can state officials marshal in the face of international change? How do domestic structures provide opportunities or set limits on the ability of states to achieve official obj ectives? In the United States, I argue in this book, policy responses to the oil shocks were shaped and channeled by the institutional structures of the state. Various policy responses were attempted, but those which succeeded were the responses that built upon existing channels of state action. The circuitous path of American energy adjustment since 1 97 3 is explicable in terms of institutional configurations of the state which predated the first oil shock. The historical legacy of earlier policy struggles and the broad sweep of state building are essential guides if we are to understand the capacity of the American state in the 1 970s and beyond. As a consequence, it is important to probe the historically unique and institutionally circumscribed character of state intervention in the economy and the society. The deep significance of these institutional forces is underlined by two additional themes that emerge in this book. First, the oppor­ tunities and constraints that institutional structures mold for state action influence the venues in which state officials seek to solve adjust­ ment problems. In particular, domestic institutional constraints on American energy policy initially encouraged policy makers to resort to international strategies of adjustment. At the same time, however, the absence of similar constraints in other industrial oil-consuming nations, together with the inability of American officials to live up to their foreign commitments, thwarted international agreements to contain the effects of rising oil prices. The interlocking nature of domestic and international energy politics is thus revealed . Second , the eventual American resort to market pricing in order to achieve energy adjustment reflects the importance of the market as an instrument of state capacity. The extension or maintenance of markets can be a powerful tool of the state, a tool used in the service of national and geopolitical objectives. In a nation such as the United States, where it is difficult to build visible new institutional capacities for the state, manipulation of the market has great importance as an instrument of national policy. The theoretical task at hand is to understand the role and dynamics x

Preface of institutional change and the manner in which institutional struc­ tures shape, bend, alter, and blunt ongoing policy struggles. The theoretical enterprise does not end with this book. The goal, an ade­ quate theory of institutions, remains as important as it is elusive. At this stage we need malleable theoretical templates that are, as Susanne Hoeber Rudolph suggests in an evocative metaphor, "made of soft clay rather than hard steel, that adapt to the variety of evidence and break when they do not fit." We have learned a lot, but there is still a lot to know. The overall argument of this book has not been published else­ where, although parts of it have been presented in various articles. The typologies of adjustment strategies presented in Chapter 1 con­ tain materials previously published in "The State and International Strategies of Adjustment," World Politics, October 1 986. This material is adapted by permission of Princeton University Press. "The Irony of State Strength : Comparative Responses to the Oil Shocks," published in International Organization, Winter 1 986, contains some of the core ideas on state capacity which appear in Chapter 8. Sections of this article are used, in modified form, by permission of the MIT Press. Chapter 7 contains materials that also appear in "Market Solutions for State Problems : The International and Domestic Politics of Amer­ ican Oil Decontrol," International Organization, Winter 1 988. Chapters 2 and 3 contain materials that also appear in "Conclusion: An Institu­ tional Approach to American Foreign Economic Policy," International Organization, Winter 1 988. This book has benefited from the generous assistance of teachers, friends, and colleagues. I owe special thanks to Charles Lipson and Theda Skocpol, my teachers at the University of Chicago. Each pro­ vided intellectual guidance and encouragement over many years and in ways that will be difficult to repay. Theda Skocpol was particularly helpful as I wrote this book. As teachers, both have given me stan­ dards of scholarly excellence that will continue to inspire me through­ out my professional career. Lloyd Rudolph was also an important adviser in the early stages of this project. I also owe a special debt of gratitude to David A. Lake and Michael Mastanduno, who have touched this book in what to them may have seemed endless sessions of discussion and criticism. Equally important was their camaraderie, which began five years ago when we were Research Fellows at the Brookings Institution. These personal and professional relationships have enriched this project in untold ways. xi

PREFACE

A score of other friends and colleagues have improved this book with their advice and criticism. Beverly Crawford, I . M. Destler, Jeff Frieden, Barbara Geddes, Judith Goldstein, Peter Gourevitch, Joanne Gowa, Stephan Haggard, Peter Hall, Jeffrey Hart, Miles Kahler, Robert Keohane, Stephen Krasner, John Odell, Ken Oye, Robert Putnam, Richard Samuels, Duncan Snidal, and Peter VanDoren pro­ vided criticisms and suggestions on chapters of the book or on articles that preceded it. Peter Cowhey, Harvey Feigenbaum, Peter Katzen­ stein, and Edward Morse read an earlier draft of the entire manu­ script and provided detailed suggestions. Tom Ryan and David Pavelchek provided valuable research assistance. Valerie Kanka pro­ vided careful secretarial and research assistance. The editorial efforts of Roger Haydon at Cornell University Press measurably improved the manuscript. As is appropriate for a book that stresses the importance of institu­ tions, I have received considerable support from several organiza­ tions. Early support for the project was provided by the Brookings Institution, where I was a Research Fellow in the Foreign Policy Stud­ ies Program during 1 982-83. Writing was also carried on at the Uni­ versity of Chicago with financial assistance from the Institute for the Study of World Politics and the Program on Interdependent Political Economy. At Princeton University, the Woodrow Wilson School for Public and International Affairs generously provided summer fund­ ing and other forms of support. Travel and research assistance was also funded by the university's Committee on Research in the Hu­ manities and Social Sciences. The final preparation of the manuscript was made possible by financial assistance from the Center for Interna­ tional Studies and its director, Henry Bienen. The Institute for Ad­ vanced Study provided a refuge for the final preparation of the book. This book is dedicated to my parents, Nelda B . Ikenberry and Gilford J. Ikenberry, Jr. , who across the years have provided love and moral support without fail-the rarest and most important ingre­ dient of all. G. J OHN Princeton, New Jersey

xzz

I KENBERRY

Reasons of State

CHAPTER ONE

The Oil Shocks and State Responses The embargo on oil by the oil-producing states in the winter of 1973-74 together with the drastic rise in the price of oil have clar­ ified like a stroke of lightning certain basic aspects of world politics which we might have understood theoretically simply by reflection but which were brought home by the drastic change in power rela­ tions which these two events imply. Hans J. Morgenthau, 1975

The political and economic foundations of the Wes tern world were shaken in the 1 970s by an upheaval in international petroleum mar­ kets. A group of small, oil-producing nations in the Middle East en­ gineered two momentous price shocks, in 1 973-74 and 1 979. To many observers at the time the rise of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries, and the economic turmoil that surrounded it, marked a turning point in postwar history. The remarkable postwar expansion of the advanced industrial economies was at an end ; no longer could governments promise unlimited economic growth. Nor could they retain exclusive control over the management of the world economy; developing countries, particularly those rich in resources, had to be brought into the system. Most important, American postwar leadership, already perceived to be on the wane, looked to have been dealt another, perhaps decisive, blow. An era was ending. The shape of the new one remained to be negotiated. 1 10ne contemporary historian, writing in 1 975, argued that the economic and politi­ cal turmoil generated by higher oil prices was "the opening stage of a struggle for a new world order, a search for positions o f strength in a global realignment, in which the weapons (backed, naturally, by the ultimate sanction of force) are food and fuel." Geoffrey Barraclough, "Wealth and Power : The Politics of Food and Fuel," New York Review of B ooks, August 7, 1975, p. 2 3. I

REASONS OF STATE

From the perspective of a later decade it seems there was less change than met the eye. The industrial nations weathered the oil price shocks, even if particular political leaders did not. The political and economic power of OPEC has come and gone. The prospect of far-reaching negotiations to advance the economic plight of develop­ ing nations has never appeared more fanciful. Nonetheless, the oil price upheavals of the 1 970s generated chal­ lenges that were real enough. They signaled not just higher energy prices but also a broader socioeconomic crisis, on a scale not seen for a generation, as they confronted the countries of the industrial world with a variety of dilemmas. The oil shocks cast up insidious prob­ lems-issues of energy security, economic adjustment, and leadership and cooperation within the industrial world . The international dilem­ mas were variously defined, and a host of policy responses were brought to bear on them. Cooperative international responses aimed at mitigating the severity and effects of price increases ; they largely failed . Across the industrial world, government leaders pursued sepa­ rate national policies, some more successfully than others. The United States, though less dependent on imported OPEC oil than other industrial nations, was no less pressed to decide how to adjust its economy and society to new international energy markets. Higher energy costs engaged officials responsible for both foreign policy and domestic policy, and proposals for action found their way onto many different policy agendas. Across political and economic life, very little was beyond the reach of the oil price revolution. International crises of this sort pose intriguing questions for stu­ dents of politics. Crises are, as one analyst notes, "critical moments when national character and institutions [are] thought to be decisively tested ."2 I share the conviction that political responses to crises can reveal essential characteristics of a nation's institutions-their ca­ pabilities and their limitations. In this book I am interested in two particular issues. One is the capabilities of nations and limitations on their cooperation to address the common dilemmas of the oil shocks. The possibilities for coopera­ tion among the advanced industrial nations were obvious. Why did cooperation among oil-importing industrial nations prove so elusive? The other issue is the capabilities of politicians and executive officials, particularly in the United States, to direct the course of energy adjust­ ment. What resources and mechanisms did American political leaders have at their disposal? In the case of American energyadjustment, 2 Randolf Starn , "Historians and Crisis," Past and Present 52 (August 1 97 1 ) 9. ,

2

The

Oil

Shocks and State Responses

why were so many different courses of action pursued, and why did some fail and others succeed? As I trace the circuitous path of Ameri­ can adjustment, both international and domestic, I answer these ques­ tions, and my answers emphasize the shaping, constraining features of national political institutions and the organizational structure of policy making.

THE OIL PRICE REVOLUTION

October 17, 1973, the day of the Arab OPEC embargo, was "energy Pearl Harbor day."3 In response to the outbreak of war between Israel, Egypt, and Syria, the Arab members of OPEC announced an embargo on oil shipments to countries supporting Israel. The United States, which was in the midst of approving emergency military as­ sistance to Israel, was their primary target.4 OPEC members agreed to cut back oil production, and in the next two months world supplies dropped by about 9.8 percent. The price of oil traded on the spot market in Rotterdam rose from $6. 7 1 a barrel in October to over $ 19 a barrel in December, and across 1974 the official price of OPEC oil rose from its pre-embargo level of about $3 a barrel to over $ 1 i a barrel. A relatively stable petroleum regime, managed by the large oil firms and protected by American diplomatic and military strength, had collapsed. In 1979, after several years of relative stability, prices again rose sharply. The second oil crisis began in late 1978 with a disruption in Iranian production sparked by domestic political upheaval. A short­ term cutback in production by Saudi Arabia in January 1979 helped reduce world supply on a scale similar to 1973, and as before, prices moved rapidly higher. In the early months of 1979 spot market prices rose from $ 19 a barrel to $3 1 a barrel. By mid- 1980 the weighted average of OPEC oil had moved to about $32 per barrel. In seven years crude oil prices, adjusted for inflation, had increased more than 500 percent. 5 OPEC had dramatically reversed the terms of trade, and a massive transfer of wealth resulted. For oil-importing nations, price increases 3S. David Freeman , Energy: The New Era (New Yor k : Vintage, 1974), p. 1. 4See Federal Energy Administration, Office of I nternatio nal Affairs. U.S. Oil Com­ panies and the Arab Oil Embargo: The International Allocation of Constricted Supplies, Report prepared for Subcommittee on Multinational Corporations of the Se nate Committee on Foreign Relations, 94th Cong., 1st sess., January 25, 1975, app. 1. 5For changes in oil prices see Philip K. Verleger, Jr ., Oil Markel1 in Turmoil: Au Economic Analysis (Cambridge, Mass . : Ballinger, 198 2) , pp. 29-53.

3

REASONS OF STATE

Table I. Current account balances of OPEC , OECD , and non-oil developing cou ntries , 1 97 3 - 1 980 ($ billions)

O P EC OECD No n-oil developing countries

1 973

1 974

1 975

1 976

1 977

1 978

1 979

1 980

9 19

62 - 1 6. 5

30 12

39 -5.5

3 1 .5 - 10

5 28

70 - 13

1 20 - 47

- 1 1 .5

- 3 1 .5

-3 7

- 24. 5

-i 9.5

3o . 5

- 47

- 62

-

Current accou nt balances a r e surpluses o r deficits o n good s, services, a n d private transfers. SouRCE. OEC D , Economic Outlook, various issues.

raised import costs and lowered real income. The oil revenues of the OPEC countries rose approximately $10 billion in 1 974 alone, and the transfer of real income to OPEC countries amounted to about 2 per­ cent of the gross national product of the member-states of the Orga­ nization for Economic Cooperation and Development. During the second oil price shock OPEC oil revenues rose about $ 1 80 billion. The transfer of income was again about 2 percent of OECD gross national product.6 Data on current-account balances between OECD and OPEC countries reflect in part the magnitude of the income transfers involved (see Table 1). These oil crises were high drama at the time, but signs of an im­ pending change in relations between oil producers and consumers appeared long before 1 97 3 . Behind the immediate actions taken by OPEC producers was a convergence of incremental changes in the international production and consumption of energy. Three trends were particularly important. First, a remarkable surge in economic growth in the mid- and late 1 960s was shadowed by steady growth in energy demand across the industrial world. Second , the production costs of oil were very cheap, and oil gradually replaced coal as the preeminent source of energy. Finally, while other regions of oil pro­ duction were nearing capacity, the Middle East and North Africa had almost limitless petroleum reserves. 7 As oil became increasingly important to the Western economies and its production became geographically more concentrated , changes were occurring in relations between oil-producing governments and multinational oil companies. In the late 1 960s and early 1 970s a large number of independent oil companies began operations in regions 6See Stanley W. Black, "Learning from Adversity: Policy Respo nses to Two Oil Shocks," Essays in International Finance no . 1 60 (Princeto n, N .J . , December 1 985), p. 5. 7Joel Dar mstadter and Hans H. Lansberg, "The Eco nomic Background," i n Ray­ mond Verno n , ed . , The Oil Crisis: In Perspective, Daedalus 1 04 ( Fall 1 975), 1 6.

4

The Oil Shocks and State Responses

exclusively controlled and managed by the major firms. More com­ panies began to compete for oil contracts, giving the producing na­ tions new advantages in bargaining.8 By 1 970, moreover, the posted price of Middle Eastern oil had declined every year in real terms since 1 947 (except for several years in the mid- 1 95os) .9 Host governments had reason to renegotiate prices with the oil companies. In 1 970 Libya demanded a new concessionary agreement with the major oil companies and, by threatening nationalization and cutbacks in production, extracted new price and tax arrangements. Standing behind Libya was OPEC . In 1 968 OPEC had foreshadowed this new bargaining campaign, resolving that oil prices should keep pace with the prices of industrial products and that its members should deter­ mine prices and profit shares. Libya's success and the other renegotia­ tions that followed stemmed from the changing patterns of supply and demand noted above, together with fear of energy shortages in Europe, OPEC's newfound resolve, and the willingness of indepen­ dent petroleum companies to agree to terms previously unacceptable to the major firms. 1 0 Price increases would be the chief legacy of the October embargo. The attempt by Arab OPEC members selectively to embargo oil sup­ plies failed, in large part because of the role the international oil companies continued to play in supply and distribution. Nonetheless, the OPEC challenge was perceived not just as an effort to redress longstanding economic grievances but as an attempt to alter the for­ eign policy of consumer nations. The threat was manifestly political as well as economic. ENERGY ADJUSTMENT PROBLEMS

These shocks confronted Western importing countries with imme­ diate demands to adjust their economies and address matters of ener­ gy security. Regarding issues of security of access, Western Europe and Japan were more threatened than the United States, even though the 1 973 embargo was directed primarily at America. Almost all of Japan's petroleum came from foreign (mostly Middle Eastern) sources, and almost 70 percent of the energy Japan required came in the form of petroleum. France also was highly dependent on OPEC 8See Raymond Vernon, "An Interpretation," in ibid . , pp . 1- 1 4 . 9Louis Turner, Oil Companies in the International System (London: Allen & Unwin, 1 980), p . 1 25. 10 Edith Penrose, "The Development of Crisis," in Vernon, The Oil Crisis, pp. 40-42.

5

REASONS OF STATE

oil; West Germany, with a substantial national coal industry, was less so. Though their resources differed, the industrial importing nations faced a common set of international challenges. Most important, the industrial oil-consuming nations had a common interest in reducing demand in the international oil market. The disruptions of i 973-74 and i 979 involved only modest shortfalls in oil supplies, but both times the dramatic jump in oil prices, on the spot market and in the official prices posted by OPEC , resulted in part from the competitive scramble by users to protect themselves against loss of supply. Short­ term incentives to hedge against the uncertainty of future supplies led governments and oil companies to bid up prices. That it was a politically inspired embargo which triggered the first oil shock heightened the common Western perception that the imme­ diate threat was to energy security. Yet economic adjustment to high­ er oil prices caused problems that were both broader and more pro­ found, interacting with other long-term and cyclical problems and blurring boundaries between energy concerns and larger economic predicaments. As one study noted in i 976, "Increasing trade in pe­ troleum and higher prices have given rise to complex economic trans­ actions, providing every state with new opportunities for influencing other states, while making each more sensitive to the actions of oth­ ers." 11 The price increases disrupted and disequilibrated a range of international markets and national economic systems. The challenges for governments involved adjusting national economies to higher en­ ergy prices and changing competititve positions. The problems at this level were enormous. They included paradox­ ical macroeconomic problems-the price increases had both inflation­ ary and deflationary effects on domestic economies. In the terms of traditional monetary and fiscal policy, as a result, the proper response was neither obvious nor straightforward. Traditional policy choices could address either inflation or unemployment, but they could not address both at once.12 The high price of OPEC oil was also reflected in balance-of-pay­ ments deficits. Immediately after the embargo, government officials llNazli Choucri, International Politics of Energy Interdependence: The Case of Petroleum ( Lexington , Mass.: Lexington Books, 1 976) , p. 53 . 1 2See Robert S. Pindyck and Julio J. Rotemberg, "Energy Shocks and the Mac­ roeconomy," in A lv in L. Alm and Robert] . Weiner, eds. , Oil Shock: Policy Response anri Implementation (Ca mbridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1 984) , pp . 97- 1 1 2 . See the general discus­ sion of the macroeconomic effects of the energy crises in Peter F. Cowhey, The Problems of Plenty: Energy Policy and International Politics (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1 985), pp . 2 4 7-50.

6

The

Oil

Shocks and State Responses

from all the major importing nations worried about the ability of particular nations to pay for higher-priced oil. Discussions began con­ cerning emergency lending to nations in chronic deficit. American officials proposed a $25 billion Financial Solidarity Fund to supple­ ment existing international monetary reserves for this particular form of adjustment. The problem of coping with such deficits also opened up a variety of subsidiary policy options.13 Payments deficits could be attacked, for example, by selling more products abroad or by restrict­ ing oil imports. In any case, problems of industrial competitiveness quickly became a part of the dilemma.14

GOVERNMENT RESPONSES TO THE

OIL SHOCKS

Across Europe and in Japan and the United States, national pat­ terns can be detected in the attempts of government leaders to cope with the surge in oil prices. The divergent policies reflected dif­ ferences in government priorities-whether states wanted mac­ roeconomic adjustment and industrial competitiveness or security of energy supply, or had larger foreign policy objectives. Different em­ phases in turn reflected differences in objective economic circum­ stances, as well as differences in the policy instruments available. In the midst of a common shock, distinctive national policies emerged. The French government emphasized national control over energy production and supply. This decision led to two initiatives. First, the French government addressed security of supply with a series of com­ mercial agreements with OPEC producers, particularly the Saudi gov­ ernment. This initiative involved government-to-government, long­ term commercial and barter contracts. Second, after 1973 the French government accelerated its already large commitment to civilian nu­ clear energy, embarking on the most ambitious nuclear power pro13See Jan Tumlir, "Oil Payments and Oil Debt in the World Economy," Lloyds B ank Review, July 19 7 4 , pp. 1-14, and Thomas 0. Ende rs, "The Role of Financial Mecha­ nisms in the Overall Oil Strategy," Department of State Bulletin, March 10, 1975, pp. 312-

1 7 . Efforts by the Interim Committee of the IMF are discussed in Robert Solomon, The

International Monetary System, r945-19 76 (New York: Harper & Row, 1977), Chap. 17. On subsidiary options see Choucri, International Politics, pp. 55-58.

14The literature on the economic impact of the oil shocks is vast. See, e.g., T. M. Rybczynski, ed., The Economics of the Oil Crisis (New York: Holmes & Meier, 1976); Edward F ried and Charles Sch ultze, eds., Higher Oil Prices and the World Economv: The Adjustment Problem (Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 1975); and Daniel Yergin, .;Crisis and Adjustment: An Overview," in Yergin and Martin Hillenbrand, eds., Global Insecu­ rity: A Strategy for Energy and Economic Renewal (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 198 2) pp. 128. ,

7

REASONS OF STATE

gram in Europe. 15 By the end of the decade France was far more reliant than the United States, West Germany, and Japan on nuclear energy. In both respects the state was at the center of the French response. Japan and West Germany emphasized the problems of industrial competitiveness and macroeconomic adjustment. Their policies were not confined to petroleum production but addressed industrial effi­ ciency across sectors. Both countries launched a commercial offen­ sive, attempting to balance payments by selling more exports, particu­ larly to the oil-exporting countries of the Middle East. They also engaged in some industrial restructuring. Japan scaled down or phased out parts of such energy-intensive industries as aluminum and petrochemicals. Both countries also launched programs that would prove to be as important as actual restructuring, to encourage indus­ trial energy efficiency. The Japanese strategy was the product of specific steps to address the problems of inflation, balance-of-payments deficits, growth, and unemployment. From 1 973 to 1 975 the government pursued a tight monetary policy to address inflationary pressures. Through 1 977 ex­ ports began to restore equilibrium to trade payments-helped by a depreciated currency and overall growth in world markets. In 1 978 and 1 979 normal levels of growth were restored. Adjustment entailed numerous programs for energy conservation and efficiency : research on new conservation technologies, tax incentives and low-interest loans, and conservation regulations all became part of the Japanese response. 1 6 The West German response was neither as elegantly formulated nor as coherently implemented. In many respects it involved an inten­ sification of established economic policy, which worked to encourage 1 50n security of supply see Louis Turner, "Politics of the E nergy Crisis," International Affairs (London) 50 (July 1 974), 404- 1 5, and Horst Mendershausen , Coping with the Oil Crisis (Baltimore : Johns Hopkins University Press, 1 976). On the general rise of oil trading by states see Aliro A. Parra, "The International Role and Commercial Politics of National Oil Companies," OPEC Review 6 (Spring 1 98 2 ) , 1 - 1 3. See also Nicholas Wade, "France's All-Out Nuclear Program Takes Shape," Science 209 (August 2 2 , 1 980), 884-89. I6See Teruyan Murakami, "The Remarkable Adaptation of Japan's Economy," in Yergin and Hillenbrand , Global Insecurity; Richard Samuels, "The Politics of Alternative Energy Research and Development in Japan," in Ronald A. Morse, ed. , The Politics of japan's Energy Strategy (Berkeley : Institute of East Asian Studies, University of Califor­ nia, 1 98 1 ) , pp. 1 34-63; Robert Albota, "Japan's Varied Responses to Energy Vul­ nerability," International Perspectives, July-August 1 98 1 , pp. 1 6- 1 9; Hirofumi Shibuta, "The Energy Crises and Japanese Response," Resources and Energy 5 ( 1 983), 1 29-54 ; and Masao Sakisaka, "Energy Alternatives: Present State and Future Problems," jour­ nal ofJapanese Trade and Industry, November-December 1 983, pp. 25-29.

8

The Oil Shocks and State Responses

stable and competitive export industries, and it was reflected in a willingness to let the economy absorb the price shocks. As John Zysman notes, "the required transfer of real resources out of con­ sumers' pockets and into exports was accomplished quickly and with limited inflationary consequences. Overall trade surpluses were main­ tained and bilateral balances brought back into the black at the same time that inflation was kept below other national rates."17 The Ger­ man response relied heavily on the adjustment mechanisms of the market, with government intervening to speed the process along. Within the energy sector itself, government strategy sought to strengthen but not to control energy companies.18 In Japan and Germany energy adjustment was a form of industrial policy. The governments sought to work on the consumption side of the energy problem by encouraging industrial adaptation. They an­ ticipated that a sustained and economywide adaptation would help export-oriented industries mitigate the effects of oil-price increases and that efficiency programs would reduce demand for imported oil.

EVOLUTION OF THE AMERICAN RESPONSE

The American response to the oil shocks was distinctive in several respects. First, the United States was the only country that initially sought a concerted, multilateral response to OPEC. Whereas other countries moved to adjust their internal economies to higher oil prices and to strengthen commercial ties to OPEC states, the United States worked to create a common bargaining position among consuming nations. Second, the United States was the only country that con­ trolled domestic petroleum prices at the time of the first oil shock. 19 These price controls, the legacy of the Nixon administration's anti­ inflation program, sheltered consumers from higher prices and made it difficult to use the market to push forward the process of adjust­ ment. Under such constraints, government officials began the search for a workable response to higher oil prices. 1 7John Zysman, Governments, Markets, and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of Industrial Change ( Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1983), p. 251; see also Edward N . K rapels, Pricing Petroleum Products: Strategies of Eleven Industrial Nations (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1982), pp. 131-35. 1 8See Dieter Schmitt, "West German Energy Policy," in Wilf rid L. Kohl, ed., After the Second Oil Crisis: Energy Policies in Europe, America, and japan (Lexington, Mass.: Lex­ ington Books, 1 982) , p. 1 40, and U.S Department of E nergy , Office of International A ffairs, Energy Industries Abroad (Washington, D.C. , September 1 98 1 ). 1 9See Krapels, Pricing Petroleum Products.

9

REASONS OF STATE

International initiatives to coordinate the policies of industrial countries toward OPEC were launched by State Department officials in i 97 3 , with the earliest efforts beginning prior to the October em­ bargo. After the embargo, Secretary of State Henry Kissinger led the attempt to confront OPEC directly in order to roll back prices. Unable to achieve results through ministerial contacts with selected OPEC countries, American officials called for unity among importers. Kiss­ inger hoped to coordinate the energy policies of the advanced indus­ trial nations and, by so doing, jointly reduce oil consumption, thereby causing OPEC to moderate prices. Although other Western government officials were skeptical, they met in conference at Washington in February i974. The following November agreement was reached among seventeen advanced indus­ trial countries (the French abstained) on the creation of the Interna­ tional Energy Agency. Kissinger had ambitious plans for the new international organization, but the IEA became a modest mechanism for contingency oil-sharing agreements and the exchange of informa­ tion.20 It became a focal point for the many international schemes proposed to mitigate financial and import vulnerabilities. As a device by which to recapture the erstwhile petroleum order, however, the IEA fell far short of American hopes. American international strategy shifted. Rather than confront OPEC directly in an effort to push back prices, the U.S. government adopted a more defensive posture, trying to facilitate a dialogue be­ tween consuming and producing nations in order to establish stable international oil prices. Kissinger, hoping to protect Western invest­ ments in energy development, proposed a "common floor price" for oil. He also suggested an international consortium to pool capital for energy investment as well as to conduct joint research and develop­ ment. Such agreements among the consuming nations would, he thought, permit more constructive negotiations with OPEC on prices, stable markets, and petrodollar recycling. Again his proposal met with resistance from other consuming nations. His initiative for an oil price agreement was pursued into i 975, and led to proposals to nego­ tiate agreements on other raw materials, but proposals to negotiate 20Q ther analysts give more weight to cooperative action by industrial oil-importing nations, particularly as instituted in International Energy Agency p lans and p rograms. See Robert 0. Keohane, After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1 984) , pp . 2 1 7-40, and Ann-Margaret Walton , "Atlantic Relations; Policy Coordination and Conflict: Atlantic Bargaining over Energy," International Affairs 52 (April 1976), 1 80-96. IO

The Oil Shocks and State Responses

stable floor prices did not provide any headway on the ultimate American goal, which was to get OPEC to moderate or reduce oil prices. Even before these international schemes had been played out, an­ other set of initiatives began at the national level to make the U. S. government a direct participant in domestic energy production. In effect, the government would fashion for itself a new and enlarged role in the energy sector. The initial effort, unveiled as Project Inde­ pendence, was an elaborate planning program to create the statistical and informational basis for policy making on energy conservation and production. The most ambitious proposal, the Energy Resource Finance Corporation, came in 1975 from the Ford administration and involved a massive federal finance authority to direct investment into alternative energy technologies. These programs, had they been suc­ cessful, would have greatly enlarged domestic energy production. Such initiatives envisioned a major reworking of the relationship between the federal government and the energy industry, but "in­ stitutional breakthroughs" did not occur. The ability of the govern­ ment to plan, coordinate, and intervene in energy markets was not significantly expanded, despite considerable efforts by government officials and politicians. By the end of the decade the U. S. govern­ ment was no more weighty a presence in the energy area than it had been at the beginning. Although long-range planning and outright control remained elu­ sive, a third type of energy adjustment policy did take root-federal spending programs aimed primarily at pushing forward new energy technologies. By the end of the decade the government was giving massive support to energy research and development. The disburse­ ment of funds did not challenge the private organization of energy production, but it allowed modest administrative direction over the prospective development of alternative or advanced energy technolo­ gies. Congress was comfortable with the notion of spending money, and throughout the 1970s, government expenditures on energy R & D expanded quickly. None of these strategies addressed an important underlying prob­ lem. Price controls and regulations in place prior to the 1973 shock kept domestic oil prices lower than international prices. These price controls shielded consumers from the full brunt of higher OPEC oil costs and provided cost advantages to domestic refiners. Indirectly they subsidized consumption and discouraged domestic production. Moreover, short-term responses to market dislocations extended the II

REASONS OF STATE

price and allocation rules. As government officials confronted energy adjustment, a full-blown regulatory apparatus (and the interests it served) stood squarely in the way of policy. A return to market pricing in petroleum was not an alternative to the other policy responses. Indeed, the State Department premised its plans for international cooperation on full adjustment of the Ameri­ can economy to higher international oil prices. As other strategies fell short of expectations, however, the issue of oil pricing grew in impor­ tance. Decontrol was first made a central component of adjustment strategy in 1 975, but Congress vigorously opposed the Ford admin­ istration's announcement of a "presidential initiative to decontrol the price of domestic crude oil."21 The Carter administration came to office opposing decontrol, but, to encourage conservation, quickly turned to the price mechanism . It proposed the Crude Oil Equaliza­ tion Tax as a way to prevent domestic producers from reaping wind­ fall profits while making U.S. consumers pay world prices. This imag­ inative attempt to create market conditions, at least on the demand side, failed before a skeptical Congress. New international pressures in 1 978 and 1 979 led the Carter ad­ ministration to embrace market pricing as the single most decisive form of government action available. The second round of OPEC price shocks and vigorous demands by oil-importing allies strength­ ened the move by executive officials toward decontrol. Oil pricing became increasingly embedded in larger and complex matters of for­ eign policy and international economics. In July 1 978 foreign eco­ nomic policy officials within the Carter administration maneuvered to link an American pledge on energy pricing to German and Japanese agreements to reflate their economies. Executive officials used for­ eign policy to redefine what was at stake in the decontrol proposal, effectively shifting the balance of power in the struggle among do­ mestic groups over oil-pricing policy. These developments brought what was for energy policy the most important outcome of the dec­ ade: in April 1 979 the decision to decontrol domestic prices was announced. What had begun as an ambitious international agenda for coopera­ tion ended with a decision to dismantle government regulation. American executive officials grudgingly scaled down their policy ob­ jectives. Unable to achieve cooperation among industrial nations, a group of executive officials had backed efforts to transform the state's role in the energy sector and to distribute massive amounts of funds 21State of the Union Message, January 1 3 , 1 975.

12

The Oil Shocks and State Responses

through existing channels. In the end, however, a government that appeared to have few alternatives embraced a return to market forces. This final course of action had been unavailable at the time of the first oil shock, and it eventually succeeded largely because other strat­ egies failed. Had price controls not been in place before 1 973, the U.S. economy would have felt the full brunt of rising prices, which would have enforced the adjustments other nations took for granted. At the moment of crisis, however, the regulatory apparatus was too firmly established to be disassembled, and so the decontrol option was not available. The failure of other proposals in a sense cleared the ground for the market proposal; a logic of trial and error, largely implicit, was at work. The market strategy seemed to some unam­ bitious, even a capitulation to private industry, but in fact served broad "state" goals . Moreover, the reimposition of market pricing was a formidable task for executive officials, who confronted entrenched consumer and industry interests. The price shocks generated interlocking national and international problems. Executive officials made the national response to the ener­ gy crisis a matter of foreign policy significance, seeking to enlist allies in a coordinated Western strategy, but such initiatives hinged on the ability of public policy to influence the domestic consumption and production of energy. At various moments across the 1 970s domestic and foreign policy proposals were intimately dependent on one an­ other, even while the government departments concerned were largely separate. What can we learn from the sequence of policy strategies? First, the shifts were not discrete, sequential movements. As noted above, inter­ national cooperative schemes envisaged substantial reductions in the American consumption of imported petroleum : an orchestrated lowering of oil imports by the industrial nations was to undercut OPEC pricing decisions. Thus the United States sought to minimize the costs of adjustment, but cooperative action would still have re­ quired government steps to dampen domestic consumption and spur production. Also, spending programs were proposed repeatedly throughout the decade, as were efforts to redefine the government's role in the energy sector, which began long before international efforts collapsed. Finally many executive officials emphasized market adjustment from the very beginning of the crisis. Decontrol as an adjustment policy had to wait, however, until domestic and interna­ tional circumstances evolved to emphasize it. Second, the shift of strategy was really a shift in emphasis and in IJ

REASONS OF STATE

commitment. Emphases changed as government officials ran into constraints; policy was pursued until it failed. A logic of policy is exhibited here. It is not that of straightforward rationality but more of the trial-and-error variety. Administration officials were not simply trying to develop appropriate energy adjustment policies but trying to find tools and instruments that government could effectively employ. They were asking not just what the federal government should do but also what government could do. The American response to the oil shocks is conventionally present­ ed as a case of policy failure, and certainly executive officials in sever­ al administrations found that their ability to implement their policy goals was severely limited. Individual proposals were blocked or sig­ nificantly redesigned by congressional representatives and commit­ tees. Nonetheless, by the end of the decade the policy of oil price deregulation did signal a successful end to the search for a workable response. The question, then, is not why executive officials failed to produce an effective response but why responses unfolded as they did before terminating in a market response. Explanation requires that we explain why executive officials generated different policy pro­ posals in a particular sequence-not just to account for a policy "out­ come" but to explain both the motivation for and disposition of policy proposals. Historical cases of energy adjustment, that is to say, are part of the more general phenomenon of national adjustment to in­ ternational economic change.

INTERNATIONAL CHANGE AND NATIONAL ADJUSTMENT

Many international and domestic forces set states in motion, but none is more important than the constant pressure for national ad­ justment to international political and economic change.22 Constant, differential changes between national and international systems pro­ duce pressure for action. As Robert Gilpin notes, "In every interna­ tional system there are continual occurrences of political, economic, and technological changes that promise gains and losses for one or another actor. . . In every system, therefore, a process of diseq22T he concept of adjustment is well-established in the economics literature as part of the standard trichotomy in exchange-rate theory : adjustment, liquidity , and confi­ dence. Benjamin Cohen traces this trichotomy back to a "celebrated international study group of 32 economists in 1 964." Cohen, Organizing the World's Money (New York: Basic. Books, 1 97 7 ) , p. 2 7 7 n . 1 8 . Political scientists have also begun to use the concept of adjustment or adjustment policy . Pioneering works are Zysman , Governments, Markets, and Growth, esp. pp. 9 1 -93, and Peter J. Katzenstein , Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe ( Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1985), chaps. 1-2.

The Oil Shocks and State Re�ponses

uilibrium and adjustment is constantly taking place."23 This differen­ tial change may involve systemwide economic upheaval, as in the depression of the 1 930s or the oil price revolution of the 1 970s. It can also be more gradual, as in the changing competitive position of par­ ticular industrial sectors in advanced industrial countries. Change promises gains and threatens losses for nations and groups within nations, and for this reason states get involved in the adj ustment process.24 Adjustment can take place in the absence of or in spite of govern­ ment policy and strategy. International financial markets, for example, responded to petrodollar recycling much more effectively than West­ ern officials anticipated, and a portion of oil price increases was ab­ sorbed in inflation. Such international market processes can reequili­ brate or adjust national economies to prevailing international conditions. But even if governments direct adjustment policy primarily at the margin of larger international processes, policy is still significant. The stability and security of nations can depend on actions taken at the margin. What is of marginal importance in the long term may be of powerful significance for political and economic actors in the short term . Marginal actions stretched over extended periods, moreover, can result in profound political and economic change. 25 We can conceive of the actions of states as controlled by strategies that states develop to cope with adjustment problems .26 Adjustment 23Robert Gilpin , War and Change in World Politics ( New York: Cambridge Un iversity Press, 1981), p. 1 3. 24See Gilpin , War and Change; R. J . Barry Jones, Change and the Study of International Relations: The Evaded Dimension (London: Pinter, 1981); Ole R. Holsti et al. , eds. , Change in the International System (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1 980) ; and John A. Vasquez and Richard W. Mansbac h , "The I ssue C ycle: Conceptualizing Long-Term Global Political Change," International Organization 37 (Spring 1 983 ) . 25For a rather abstract discussion of system c hange and differen tial response see Herbert Simon , "The A rchitectu re of Complexity ," in The Science of the A rtificial, 2 d ed . (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1981), pp. 1 93 - 2 2 9 . The issue is also discussed in terms of international equ ilibrium and disequilibriu m. See Richard Rosecrance, International Relations: Peace or War? (New York: McGraw Hill, 1 973), pp. 1 1 3- 1 4 . 26The terms "adjustment strategy" and "adjustment policy" are used in terchange­ ably here to designate a set of policies embraced by the central executive offic ials of government as the chief means or organizing basis by which the govern ment is to respond to or cope with the energy c risis. The polic ies themselves are proposed cou rses of action or inaction (e.g., laissez- faire) directed toward goals articulated by the officials. Adjustment strategy is not necessarily identical with the polic y outcomes of the whole of the national government. Nor is adjustment strategy necessarily consistent with other policies of the same government. Rather, it is the articulated goals and proposed course of action of the executive officials of govern ment. Where there are differences of opinion within the executive b ranch over adjustment strategy , the goals and proposals of the most sen ior officials and, ultimately, the president himself, are identified as govern ment policy. See John S. Odell.U.S. International Monetary Policy: MarkPls, Power, . and Ideas as Sources of Change ( Princeton: Princeton University Pres s." 1 98 2 ) , p p. 15 ff.

15

REASONS OF STATE

Figure

I.

A typology of national adjustment strategies I n ternational

Dom estic

Offen sive

C reate new i nternational reg i m e

Change domestic structure

Defens ive

Remedial steps to d efend cu rrent reg i m e

P rotect domestic structure

strategy may be directed outward at international change, or inward at domestic structural transformation, or somewhere between to maintain existing relationships. 27 Adjustment Strategies Solutions to adjustment problems can address the location of ad­ justment (international or domestic) and the objective of the solution (defensive or offensive), whether to transform the (national or inter­ national) system or to preserve the existing arrangements. This ty­ pology, summarized in Figure l , indicates the four possibilities for states seeking to address adjustment problems. Offensive international adjustment is the most ambitious type of response. It involves the creation of new rules of the game for inter­ national interactions ; the number of states necessary to create an international regime and the required level of adherence to rules and procedures is considerably greater than for other strategies. The trade regime of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, the Bretton Woods monetary system, and the proposed rules embodied in the New International Economic Order are the most ambitious examples. 28 27J n an analogical way Kenneth Waltz talks about internal and external means of balancing geopolitical power. I nternal balancing refers to the domestic mobilization of power common to the two central states in a bipolar system. External balancing refers to the making and breaking of allies and is common to multipolar systems. The sources and implications of internal and external mobilization strategies remain an important research question. Waltz, Theory of International Politics (Reading, Mass. : Addison­ Wesley, i 979) , p. i 68 . 2 8It is international offensive adjustment that Stephen Krasner describes in his analy­ sis of Third World demands for authoritative international rules and norms to cover North-South economic relations. Developing countries, he argues, are "exposed to vacillations of an international system from which they cannot extricate themselves but over which they have only limited control." Because of obdurate internal weaknesses, developing countries have consistently sought to create international regimes that will mitigate this structural vulnerability. Krasner, Structural Conflict: The Third World against Global Liberalism (Berkeley : University of California Press, 1 985), p . 4 .

16

The Oil Shocks and State Responses

The initial American response to the 1 973-74 oil shock was an international offensive policy. State Department officials made at­ tempts to forge a collective reponse by industrial oil-consuming coun­ tries, thereby inducing OPEC member governments to moderate or roll back oil prices. Such was the rationale of American executive officials : collaborative efforts to restrain oil imports and to foster alternative sources of energy, they argued, would give the industrial countries a stronger position from which to bargain with OPEC over prices. The strategy was directed at reestablishing the old petroleum order. In effect, the initial U.S. response to unanticipated interna­ tional change was to go to the source of that change and reverse its course. I f offensive international adjustment seeks to alter the sources of change, defensive international adjustment involves the use of inter­ national agreements to moderate international economic change, in effect forging international agreements to protect existing domestic industries and institutions. The Multi-Fiber Agreement, for example, has evolved over several decades into an elaborate system whereby textile-producing nations distribute market shares. Change in the sec­ tor stems from shifting comparative production costs and tech­ nological advantages among and between advanced and developing nations. The agreement, initially sought by the United States in an effort to protect domestic textile producers, mandates market shares in a wide range of textile goods. In recent years a multitude of com­ mercial agreements has been negotiated in various trade sectors to accomplish the same ends. These agreements frequently take the form of negotiated trade quotas and orderly marketing agree­ ments. 29 With the failure to develop a collaborative strategy to confront OPEC directly, State Department officials moved to an international defensive strategy. The United States now aimed to facilitate a di290n the M FA see Vinod K. Aggarwal, Liberal Protectionism: The International Politics of Organized Textile Trade (Berkeley : University of California Press, 1 985 ) ; more gener­ ally, David Yoffie, Power and Protectionism: Strategies of the Newly Industrializing Countries (New York: Columbia University Press, 1 983), and also Susan Strange and Roger Tooze, eds . , The International Politics ofSurplus Capacity (London: Butterworth , 1 980 ) . In some respects the difference between international offensive and international defen­ sive strategies is captured in Robert Keohane's distinction between "control-oriented" regimes and "insurance" regimes. Keohane, "The Demand for International Regimes," International Organization 36 (Spring 1 982), 3 25-55. Control-oriented regimes seek to prescribe and regularize behavior among participants within the regime. Members gain a high measure of control over the behavior of other actors. Insurance regimes are less ambitious and seek to pool risks of specific international economic change among regime participants. Whereas control-oriented regimes attempt to go to the source of deleterious international change, insurance arrangements aim to soften the impact of that change.

REASONS OF STATE

alogue between consuming and producing nations in order to sta­ bilize international prices. To protect massive Western investments in energy development, Secretary of State Kissinger proposed a com­ mon price floor for oil, which would strengthen the reliability of petroleum prices and supplies over an extended period of time. The proposal was defensive in that the United States was now willing to countenance higher oil prices. The agreement sought to moderate price increases and gain more time for industrial importing nations to make domestic adjustments. Domestic offensive strategy changes the structure of national in­ dustries and institutions in an effort to cope with international eco­ nomic change. It may involve phasing out or encouraging the growth of particular industries or creating new arrangements that facilitate domestic economic adjustment. Governments focus their efforts in­ ward, adapting institutions and redeploying resources. One form of this strategy may involv� vigorous and c;tntib patory government ac­ tion to gain an . edge o � er competitors. Investment in R&D, ra­ tionalization of corporate decision making on investment, and other government tactics encourage or coerce private firms to alter their behavior. In another form of the strategy, the government may stand asi d e and let market forces transform the economy. Here the state acts by not acting; the state, a "gatekeeper," chooses to keep the gate open.3 0 In responding to higher oil prices, the European and Japanese governments primarily pursued domestic offensive policies. These efforts took many forms, ranging from passive measures that allowed international oil prices to move through the domestic economy to aggressive programs of industrial restructuring. The Japanese gov­ ernment, for example, phased out such energy-intensive industries as aluminum and petrochemical production. The West German govern­ ment was less interventionist, acting primarily to ensure that indus­ trial producers and energy consumers weighed the full costs of in­ creased energy prices. Similarly , the American decontrol of oil prices was a domestic offensive policy, though it emerged much later than did policies in Europe and Japan. Domestic defensive adjustment is a protective strategy that seeks to avoid change altogether, and it typically culminates in the erection of 30See the discussion of Japanese "anticipatory adjustment policy" in M ichele Schmiegelow, "Cutting across Doctrines: Positive Adjustment in Japan," International Organization 39 (Spring 1 985), 26 1 -96. The OECD uses several categories of adjust­ ment to characterize national patterns in the 1 970s and beyond . See OECD, Positive Adjustment Policy-Managing Structural Adjustment (Paris, 1 98 3 ) .

18

The Oil Shocks and State Responses

barriers to new forms of change. The tariff is the most obvious state action, but subsidies and other non tariff barriers conform to the same defensive strategy . 3 1 Throughout much of the i 97os the American maintenance of price controls was a domestic defensive response to international charge.

CONCLUSION

Two crucial questions emerge from this sketch of energy adjust­ ment in the 1 970s. First, why did industrial countries pursue diver­ gent energy adjustment policies, and what were the implications of these divergent policies for international cooperation and conflict? We need to know why the United States pursued a collaborative pol­ icy in the initial stages of the crisis and why other industrial countries pursued independent national policies. Second, why did American energy adjustment evolve through a sequence of policy initiatives, from international to national, and from interventionist to market-based ? We need to explain why American executive officials initially sought international cooperation. Once en­ ergy adjustment policy had moved to the domestic level, moreover, we need to explain the sequence of policies observed . This search for explanations for the style and evolution of adjust­ ment policies, in their international and domestic guises, centers on the "weightiness" or "capacity" of the state. The key is the Machiavel­ lian question concerning the constraints and opportunities for states to realize the goals they embrace. The notion of state capacity, accord­ ing to Theda Skocpol, refers to the ability of states "to implement official goals, especially over the actual or potential opposition of powerful social groups or in the face of recalcitrant socioeconomic circumstances. "32 At moments of crisis, what can states accomplish? What international and national resources-power-can state offi­ cials marshal in the face of international dilemmas ? How do domestic structures shape the ability of states to achieve official objectives? 3 1 Tariffs need not always be associated with defensive domestic adjustment. When used to nurture infant industries, tariffs may help transform the industrial structure of a nation. Similarly, investment in research and development can be defensive rather than offensive in its design. 32Theda Skocpol, "Bringing the State Back In," in Peter Evans, Dietrich Ru �sch � meyer, and Skocpol, eds . , Bringing the State Back In (New York : Cambridge Umvers1ty Press, 1 985), p. 9. See also the concluding essay in that volume and Eric Nordlinger, On the Autonomy of the Democratic State (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1 98 1 ), pp. 8-28.

REASONS OF STATE

These questions about state capacity require attention to the interac­ tion between state officials and their environment. The American response to the oil crises provides a window on to the more general attempts of the United States to cope with transfor­ mations in the postwar international system. The problems American government officials encountered in asserting international lead­ ership in the midst of the oil crises forced officials to make difficult internal adaptations. As the international political and economic posi­ tion of the United States continues to decline, these difficult internal adjustments are becoming the grist of domestic politics and a decisive constraint on foreign economic policy. The oil shocks forced the U.S. government to explore the scope and limits of its international and domestic capabilities.

20

CHAPTER Two

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy The difference between international politics as it actually is and a rational theory derived from it is like the difference between a pho­ tograph and a painted portrait. The photograph shows everything that can be seen by the naked eye ; the painted portrait does not show everything that can be seen by the eye, but it shows, or at least seeks to show, one thing that the naked eye cannot see : the human essence of the person portrayed . Hans J . Morgenthau, 1 960

Disruptions in international oil markets and rapidly escalating prices during the 1 970s generated a wide range of socioeconomic challenges to which government leaders in the industrial world were forced to respond . The unfolding events of that decade prompt two questions. First, why did the United States campaign for a concerted international response while officials in the other major nations were emphasizing narrower, national programs? Differences in policy re­ flected both distinctive conceptions of what was at stake and divergent capacities for solving energy and related problems. They also had fateful implications for the inclination of states to join in cooperative actions that would foster mutual gains. Second, why did American officials move from international to domestic and from interven­ tionist to market policies? A process of trial and error was at work. What motivated executive officials to move through a sequence of proposals, and why did some ideas fail and others succeed ? These questions, and the larger issue of the capacity of states to cope with international political and economic change, require a the­ oretical appreciation of the bases of state action. Various literatures 21

REASONS OF STATE

address the explanation of policy outcomes. Building upon several promising lines of analysis, I present an institutional approach to understanding adjustment policy.

APPROACHES TO FOREIGN ECONOMIC POLICY

In seeking to explain the actions of states, analysts make a basic distinction between sources of state behavior that emanate from the international system and those that come from the domestic system. 1 "Systemic" explanations trace state actions to the structure of incen­ tives and constraints created by the international system as a whole. Societal explanations trace state actions to pressures and constraints generated within the domestic political system, where theorists have attempted to explain foreign economic policy by focusing on the play of private group or class interests ( "society-centered" explanations) or by focusing on the shaping and constraining influence of government institutions and the officials within them ( "state-centered" explan­ ations) . Systemic Explanations The international system, according to systemic theorists, generates enduring and powerful pressures on nation-states and , consequently, on foreign economic policy. The basic features of the international system of concern to these theorists are found within three arguments about the international system central to the Realist tradition of analy­ sis. First, the international system is dominated by sovereign states, each beholden to no higher authority than itself nor to any purpose higher than the protection of the nation's territorial integrity and material well-being. Second, the primacy of states and their substan­ tive interests stem from the anarchy of the international system. Co­ operative agreements and mutual restraint may flourish at various historical moments, but behind international cooperation is the en­ during absence of authority to enforce agreement. Finally, in a system so constituted, states tend to behave purposively and pursue what their representatives perceive to be national or state interests.2 ! See Kenneth Waltz, Theory of International Politics (Reading, Mass . : Addison-Wesley, 1 979) . 2See Robert 0. Keohane, "Theory of World Politics: Structural Realism and Be­ yond," in Ada W. Finifter, ed. , Political Science: The State of the Discipline (Washington, D.C . : American Political Science Association, 1 9 83); John A . Vasquez, The Power of

22

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

The structure of the international system has a basic and relentless impact on state action. It should be understood, according to Kenneth Waltz, in terms of an ordering principle (e.g. , anarchy) and a particu­ lar distribution of power. The international system is similar in struc­ ture to the market in that both are systems created by self-regarding actors. The system , Waltz argues, is the unintended yet inevitable and spontaneously generated outgrowth of activities by nation-states con­ cerned fundamentally with their own survival. Different types of sys­ tems generate different international outcomes ; multipolar systems, for example, tend to be less stable than bipolar ones. Recurring pat­ terns of international behavior are explained in terms of the enduring organizational structure of the international system. Other systemic theorists address more proximate internationa i out­ comes, such as policy coordination and the creation and maintenance of regimes. The theory of hegemonic stability, for example, attempts to account for such outcomes as international economic openness and regime strength in terms of the distribution of economic capabilities among the major powers of the system. Because of the power and interests of dominant states , it is hypothesized , hegemony will lead to openness and stable regimes .3 Some systemic theorists have gone be­ yond general incentives and attempt to specify more precise sets of state goals. In developing a theory of "international economic struc­ ture," for example, David A. Lake constructs a deductive framework that specifies variations in expected national trade strategies based on the relative international economic position of nations. The relative size and productivity of national economies provide the crucial situa­ tional variables that weigh on the likely trade strategy chosen by par­ ticular nations. 4 Changes in the behavior of nation-states, and in system outcomes, are explained by systemic theorists in terms of changes not in the internal characteristics of nation-states but in the system itself or in Power Politics (New B runswick: Rutgers U niversity Press, 1 983); and Robert G. Gilpin, "The Richness of the Tradition of Political Realism," International Organization 38 (Spring 1 984), 287-304. 3See Robert 0. Keohane, "The Theory of Hegemonic Stability and Changes in International Economic Regimes, 1 967- 1 97 7 ," in Ole Holsti et al. , Change in the Interna­ tional System (Boulder, Colo. : Westview, 1 980), pp. 1 3 1 -62 ; Stephen Krasner, "State Power and the Structure of International Trade," World Politics 28 (April 1 976), 3 1 74 3 ; and Krasner, ed. , International Regimes (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1 983) . 4David Lake, "Beneath the Commerce of Nations : A Theory of International Eco­ nomic Structures," International Studies Quarterly 28 ( 1 984), 1 43-70; "I nternational Eco­ nomic Structures and American Foreign Economic Policy, 1 887- 1 934, " World Politics 35 (July 1 985), 5 1 7-43 ; and Power, Protection, and Free Trade: International Sources of U.S. Commercial Strategy, 1 887- 1939 ( Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1 988).

23

REASONS OF STA TE

the relative position of particular nation-states. Waltz argues that "it is not possible to understand world politics simply by looking inside of states , " but systemic theory is constructed at such a level that it does not require the analyst to look inside the nation-state at all. This level of analysis provides the situational context for state action, by setting the outer boundaries within which policy must be constructed and sustained. 5 Systemic theory does not intend to explain foreign policy. The international system generates incentives and constraints ; it rewards and punishes the actions of states.6 But it does not provide a theory of state action as such. More differentiated systemic theories, such as Lake's, do provide specific sets of national preferences that self-in­ terested states are likely to follow. Once again, however, the ability of states to perceive and act upon those interests hinges on domestic circumstances. The virtue of the international-centered approach is that it provides the situational context for foreign economic policy. Explanation of actual policy outcomes requires additional conceptual variables that reside within nation-states.

Society-Centered Explanations Societal explanations trace outcomes back to the domestic forces or political groups that lay claim to foreign economic policy. Societal interests and groups, and their impact on policy outcomes, are con­ ceptualized in various ways. Two prominent society-centered ap­ proaches stress different elements within society that influence or shape policy outcomes. Drawing on pluralist theory , the interest-group approach focuses on the play of organized groups within the policy process. Policy is the outcome of the competitive struggle among groups for influence over specific policy decisions. Government institutions provide an arena for the competition among groups and do not decisively bias the decisions that emerge. In its simplest formulation, this approach an­ ticipates a spontaneity and fluidity in the involvement of interest

5Waltz, Theory, p. 65. See the critique of systemic theory in Robert 0. Keohane, After Hegemony (Princeton: Princeton University Press, i 985), pp. 25-29. 6The impact of international structure on state action is described in this literature in terms of constraints. Waltz argues that "actors may perceive the structure that con­ strains them and understand how it serves to reward some kinds of behavior and to penalize others. But then again they either may not see it or, seeing it, may for any of many reasons fail to conform their actions to the patterns that are most often rewarded and least often punished . . . . The game one has to win is defined by the structure that determines the kind of player that is likely to prosper." Waltz, Theory, p. 9 2 .

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

groups in policy making. Various types of groups-industry associa­ tions, unions, consumer groups-are activated and form coalitions on the basis of the particular issues at stake. As issues change, so do the groups involved and their coalitions. This pluralist formulation does not directly relate interests and the involvement of groups in policy making to broader social structures. Explanations for policy outcomes emerge from the societal interests at stake and the groups that effec­ tively organize to get involved in decision making. 7 This approach. has been used widely in the analysis of foreign eco­ nomic policy. Various scholars have explained American trade policy, for example, in terms of the domination of private groups.8 Govern­ ment is understood to be primarily passive, either providing a neutral arena or acting as a disinterested referee. Societal groups make de­ mands , government supplies policy; policy is the outcome of shifting group coalitions. If the character of societal interests is understood, the explanation of policy follows easily. A second approach, developed to explain policy outcomes in com­ parative perspective, employs a larger-scale and more structured con­ ception of societal interests and groupings. Most prominently, Peter Gourevitch has traced distinctive national economic policies during the Depression of the 1 930s to systemic differences in the position of (broadly drawn) social and industrial groups. The major social groups he identifies-agriculture, industry, and labor-are further divided in terms of international competitive position, and resulting model of societal or sectoral interests provides the basis to explore cross-nation­ al variations in coalitional limits and possibilities. Shifts in policy are traced back to shifts in sectoral preferences (understood as a function of the sector's changing "situation" within the international economy) and the emergence of cross-sectoral coalitions. When societal interests and groupings are understood, an explanation of policy follows.9 7The seminal statements of the pluralist perspective are Arthur F. Bentley, The Process of Government (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1 980) ; David B . Truman , The Governmental Process: Political Interests and Public Opinion (New York : Knopf, 1 95 1 ) ; and Robert A . Dahl, Who Governs ? (New Haven: Yale University Press , 1 963). Subse­ quent revisions of the pluralist model of policy making dispute many of its elements but retain the basic society-centered focus. See Theodore J. Lowi, The End of Liberalism (New York: Norton, 1 969), and Charles E. Lindblom, Politics and Markets (New York : Basic Books, 1 977). 8See, for example, E. E . Schattschneider, Politics, Pressures, and the Tariff (New York: Prentice-Hall, 1 935); Raymond A. Bauer, Ithiel de Sola Pool, and Lewis Anthony De�ter, American Business and Public Policy: The Politics of Foreign Trade, 2d ed . (Chicago: Aldme-Atherton, 1 97 2 ) ; and Peter F. Cowhey and Gary C. Jacobson, "The Political Organization of Domestic Markets and U.S. Foreign Economic Policy," U niversity of California, San Diego, unpublished paper, 1 984.

25

REASONS OF STATE

Society-centered explanations locate the domestic groups and coali­ tions that gain advantage from particular policy outcomes and that may support or sustain those policies. Yet they do not help us when the interests and capacities of groups are themselves influenced or shaped by larger domestic institutional structures . The organizational structure of the state, and the preference of administrators and politi­ cians who occupy positions within that structure, may weigh heavily in policy outcomes. State structures, by shaping the institutional terrain where policy struggles are played out, can have an important if indi­ rect influence on access to decision making and the resources that bear on decision making. State officials also may blunt, shape, or ignore the activities of social groups. An approach that focuses ex­ clusively on social groups, in sum, captures only the demand for policy, not its supply. To understand how policy responds to societal demands, we need a more explicit understanding of the "black box" of the state. In trade policy, for example, the responsibility for decision making was gradu­ ally transferred from the Congress to the executive branch in the decades following the disastrous Smoot-Hawley tariff of 1 930. In­ terest-group demands for protection did not abate, but executive in­ stitutions were less responsive to those demands . 1 0 State-Centered Explanations A substantial literature incorporates the state into societal under­ standings of foreign economic policy, developing state-centered ex­ planations in two ways. First, unlike the interest-group approach, it finds the state able to develop and implement autonomous prefer­ ences, even in the face of pressure from private interests. Foreign economic policy is not simply the hostage of societal groups ; the state 9Peter Gourevitch, Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Eco­ nomic Crises ( Ithaca: Cornell University Press , i 986). For a similar approach see Tom Ferguson, " From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition , and American Public Policy in the Great Depression," International Organization 38 ( Winter i 984), pp. 4 1 -94. This societal approach is compatible w ith an instrumental neo­ Marxist o rientation . See Jeff Frieden , "From Economic N ationalism to Hegemony : Social Forces and the Emergence of Modern U . S. Foreign Econo mic Policy, i 9 1 41 940," International Organization 42 (Winter i g88). I OSee Robert Pasto r , Congress and the Politics of U.S . Foreign Economic Policy, 1 9291 9 7 6 (Berkeley : University o f California Press, 1 980) ; Judith Goldstein , "Ideas, Institu­ tions , and T rade Policy," and Stephan Haggard , "T he Institutional Foundations of 'Hegemony ' : Explaining the Reciprocal Trade A g reements Act of i 934 ," both in Inter­ national Organization 42 (Winter i g88); and I. M . Destler, American Trade Politics: System under Stress (Washington, D . C . : Institute for International Economics, i 986).

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

may be able to resist or blunt interest-group or class demands in favor of its own independent set of policies. Attention focuses on state officials who, pursuing their own agenda, develop and seek to imple­ ment an autonomous set of preferences. Second , the organizational structure of the state may have broader and often unintended effects on the interests and capacities of individuals and groups-private groups and public officials alike-and , consequently, on policy out­ comes. The state, in this view, is a set of well-entrenched institutions that undergird the policy process and influence the outcomes . The first line of inquiry focuses on the autonomy of goals embraced by state officials and their impact on policy. In American policy on raw materials, for example, Stephen Krasner identified a set of pecu­ liarly "state" goals that systematically triumphed over the competing interests of private corporations. I I The autonomous actions of the state came from decision makers in the executive who, by virtue of their insulated position, were able to conduct foreign policy in accor­ dance with a stable set of goals. Government institutions are not sim­ ply an arena of policy conflict from this perspective ; they also provide platforms from which executive officials can pursue distinctive goals that are not easily traceable to the interests or activities of private groups and may in fact provoke powerful societal opposition . The autonomy of state officials may also stem from the role that policy experts and bureaucrats play in the policy process. In the emergence of welfare policy in Britain and Sweden, for example, H ugh Heclo argues, civil servants were instrumental in developing and implementing breakthroughs in social policy. Many forces influ­ enced policy-stages of economic development, struggles of interest groups and political parties, leadership of government admin­ istrators-but Heclo concludes that the bureaucracies in both coun­ tries were the leading agents of policy innovation. 1 2 If state officials have some degree of autonomy, what are the ori­ gins of state interests? I 3 One response stresses the importance of bureaucratic or narrow organizational interests. The maintenance or 1 1 Stephen D. Krasner, Defending the National Interest (Princeton : Princeton U niversity Press, 1 978). 1 2 Hugh Heclo, Social Policy in B ritain and Sweden (New Haven : Yale U niversity Press, 1 97 4 ) , p. 30 1 . 1 3 Peter Gourevitch, for example, argues that "the basic problem with this line of reasoning is that it provides no explanation for the orientation of state policy in the supposedly state-dominated countries. " See "The Second I mage Reversed : The Inter­ national Sources of Domestic Politics," International Organization 3 2 (Autumn 1 978), 903 ; see also Philippe Schmitter, "Neo-corporatism and the State," in Wyn Grant, ed . , The Political Economy of Corporatism (New York: St. Martin's, 1 985).

27

REASONS OF STATE

expansion of bureaucratic missions and control over budgetary re­ sources, according to this perspective, lead to systematic and autono­ mous government actions. 1 4 Another response suggests the impor­ tance of bureaucratic problem solving and social learning. Govern­ ment officials, Heclo argues, are as much engaged with "puzzling" as they are with "powering. " Policy innovations may emerge as straight­ forward efforts by officials to anticipate or react to a variety of so­ cioeconomic crises and dilemmas. 1 5 A third response focuses on the unique foreign policy mandate of executive officials. 1 6 Organiza­ tional position within government is decisive ; it is why these officials tend to hold policy views that differ from those of other officials within government and from those of societal groups. None of these three approaches gives clear-cut, a priori predictions as to when and in what ways government officials will pursue autonomous goals. In each case the question remains empirical, a matter of reconstructing the actual behavior of government officials. The broader organizational structures of the state, within which bureaucratic and executive officials operate, form the focus of a sec­ ond state-centered literature. It is concerned with the origins and dynamics of state structures and with the impact of these organiza­ tional structures on policy outcomes. This state-centered literature is rooted in Max Weber's political sociology of the state. Weber under­ stood the modern state to be a compulsory association claiming sov­ ereign and coercive control over a specific territory and population. 1 7 I t is distinguished from other social organizations by its monopoly claim on the legitimate use of violence. Force is not the only means available to the state, and in most countries it is rarely exercised , but it is the only means specific to the state. All other instrumentalities are built around it. Within a defined territory, the state's monopoly on force is the precondition for the sanctioning of law and property rights and , ultimately, for resolving political conflict. Everything else follows from this circumstance. 1 8 Weber grants the state a significance unto itself as a set of relatively 1 4See, e.g. , Graham Allison, Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis (Boston : Little, Brown, 1 97 1 ), and Morton H. Halperin, Bureaucratic Politics and Foreign Policy (Washington, D.C. : Brookings, 1 974). 1 5 Heclo, Modern Social Policy, p. 305 . t 6 See especially Krasner, Defending the National Interest. t 7See Max Weber, Economy and Society, ed. Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich (Berke­ ley : University of California Press, 1 978), p. 56. 1 8 Max Weber, "Politics as a Vocation," in From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology (New York : Oxford University Press, 1 946), p. 78 . For an elaboration of this view see Peter P. Nicholson, "Politics and Force," in Adrian Leftwich, ed . , What Is Politics? The Activity and Its Study (Oxford : Blackwell, 1 984) , pp. 33-45. The point is captured by Samuel E. Finer: "Tell a man today to go build a state; and he will try to establish a definite and

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

differentiated organizations that are not reducible to or merely reflect socioeconomic setting. Built around legal and bureaucratic institu­ tions, the state both is distinct from and interacts with other economic and social structures. 19 The independence of the modern state from society and economic classes is bound up with the search for legiti­ mate forms of political domination and the resulting emergence of legal-rational authority. Comprehensive legal rules, manifest in for­ mal government organizations, provide legitimacy to the stable set of expectations rulers and ruled alike attach to the exercise of political power.20 The Weberian perspective leads to the identification of the general characteristics of states, but recent theorists explore variations in the institutional characteristics of states and their interrelationships with larger political, economic, and social structures. They are concerned with specifying the nature of and variations in state capacities. The goals state officials develop and their ability to carry them out depend on existing institutional tools and resources. 2 1 In addition, the in­ terests and capacities of social groups and classes are shaped and influenced by prevailing organizational structures of the state. 22 Fundamental to the state-centered perspective is the belief that government activities and public policy are not simply expressions of defensible territorial boundary and compel those who live inside it to obey him. Having done this he will have founded his State. " Finer, "State-building, State Boundaries and Border Control," Social Science Information 1 3 ( 1 974), 79. 1 9The Weberian distinction between state and society is noted by Randall Collins: "Individuals or groups are coordinated on two analytically distinct principles, which correspond to the spheres of 'society' and 'state.' In the sphere of 'society,' groups are formed as 'constellations of interests,' in which the parties act together voluntarily for what they feel is their mutual benefit. Such groups are formed on two bases : coinci­ dence of interests in the economic market, and feelings of identity with others who hold a common culture or ideal. In the sphere of the 'state,' coordination is based on domination, in which one individual or group is placed in a position to enforce his will on the others. Such coordination is based on an organizational apparatus of domination and on some kind of principles of legitimacy. In both spheres of action, there is a struggle for advantage . . . . I ndividuals struggle for advantage within organizations, and organizations struggle with each other." Collins, "A Comparative Approach to Political Sociology," in Reinhard Bendix, ed. , State and Society: A Reader in Comparative Political Sociology (Berkeley : University of California Press, 1 968), pp. 48-49. 20Weber, Economy and Society, 1 : 2 1 2-26. 2 1 See Peter J. Katzenstein, ed . , Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States ( Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1 978), and John Zysman, Governments, Markets, and Growth (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1 983). 22 E.g., Theda Skocpol and Kenneth Finegold, "State Capacity and Economic Inter­ vention in the Early New Deal," Political Science Quarterly 97 ( 1 982), 255-78; Margaret Weir and Skocpol, "State Structures and the Possibilities for 'Keynesian' Responses to the Great Depression in Sweden, B ritain, and the United States," in Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Skocpol, eds., Bringing the State Back In ( New York: Cambridge University Press, 1 985), pp. 1 07-63 .

REASONS OF STATE

societal demands or straightforward responses to international politi­ cal and economic conditions. The organizational structures of the state and the administrators and politicians within them exert power­ ful influences on the circumstances and activities of policy making. Organizational structures influence the types of policies likely to be generated and successfully implemented by influencing the access groups and individuals have to policy making and the resources they are able to wield . State structures thus affect the capacity of various individuals and groups to pursue their goals. Moreover, politicians and executive officials are positioned to pursue policy goals that do not merely reflect social interests . These state officials, enabled and constrained by organizational structures, may blunt, reshape, or ig­ nore social demands on policy. At the same time, they are well placed to interpret and act upon the pressures and opportunities that arise from the nation's changing international position. The strength of this structural, state-centered approach is its focus on enduring institutions within which government officials and pri­ vate groups and individuals are situated . For those interested in ex­ plaining policy outcomes, however, the approach has weaknesses as well. An exclusive focus on state structures may obscure important interactions between public and private actors. The organizational characteristics of societal groups and classes may be as important as the formal characteristics of the state to the ability of state officials to implement policy . Moreover, the structural orientation of the ap­ proach may obscure the importance of individual behavior and of political process in shaping specific outcomes. 23 The organizational structures of the state may constrain individuals and groups, but they do not exclude individual action. At particular historical junctures those organizational structures may in fact be altered or transformed . I find the state-centered line of inquiry promising because of the questions it asks. A focus on foreign economic policy (or, more specif­ ically, energy adjustment) leads to questions about state capacity , about the ability of government officials to develop and implement effective policy in order to deal with large-scale international political and economic problems. State capacity must, however, be formulated in such a way as to allow societal and international variables to be integrated into explanations of policy outcomes. 23This argument is made by Peter Hall, Governing the Economy: The Politics of State (New York: Oxford U niversity Press, i g 86). For a critique of "state-centered structurnlism" see Margaret Levi, Of R ule and Revenue (Berkeley: University of California Press, i g8 8 ) .

Intervention in Britain and France

30

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

AN

INSTITUTIONAL APPROACH TO POLICY EXPLANATION

The perspective I am developing is an institutional approach. As I argued earlier, the most promising analysis does not simply replace societal and systemic explanations with state-centered explanations. Rather, the task is to appreciate the interaction of these variables and the manner in which the organizational features of the state and the activities of executive officials and politicians mediate larger societal and international forces. This approach is "institutional" because it conceives of mediation and interaction as grounded in institutional relationships that persist over time and that are relatively resilient against the idiosyncratic actions of groups and individuals. 24 I follow three lines of this institutional approach as they relate to the politics of energy adjustment. First, I focus on the manner in which political and economic crises reveal the forces that sustain and reshape the organizational structures of the state. Second, I examine the types of state actions that are likely to follow from variations in the larger domestic and international setting of the state. Finally, I exam­ ine variations in the capacities of state officials and in their organiza­ tional underpinnings. State Formation and U. S. Intervention in the Energy Sector All states have core organizations that carry out fiscal, coercive, judicial, and administrative activities within their domain . Variations abound , however, in the activities and organizational structures of states, both between states and within states over time. The role of representative or parliamentary bodies, the centralization and co­ herence of bureaucratic organizations, and the political resources and access to decision making of executive officials are all aspects of the prevailing organizational structures of the state. At this general level, therefore, we are looking at the "architecture" of the state and its interlocking parts. State structures are important because they tend to persist over long periods of time and because they serve to shape and constrain the actions of groups and individuals struggling over public policy. 2 4See the discussion of this approach in James March and Johan P. Olsen, "The New I nstitutionalism: Organizational Factors in Political Life," A merican Political Science Re­ view 78 (September 1 984), 735; Stephen D. Krasner, "Approaches to the State : Alter­ native Conceptions and H istorical Dynamics," Comparative Politics 16 Oanuary 1 984) , 2 2 3-45. Peter Hall also describes his enterprise as an institutional approach, in Govern­ ing the Economy.

31

REASONS OF STATE

Politicians and bureaucrats at any given moment are not in a position to create state capacities to meet specific challenges. The institutions within which these individuals operate and the legacies of previous policy constrain the possibilities for current policy action. Because institutions are neither fluid nor able to respond to the immediate needs of state officials, they exert a powerful influence on what offi­ cials can actually accomplish.25 A variety of historical forces has shaped the origins and trajectories of modern states and given them distinctive organizational charac­ teristics. Variations in the sequence and timing of political and eco­ nomic development and the state-building responses to economic de­ pressions and wars have had powerful effects on representative and bureaucratic organizations. In advance of the spread of democratic institutions, for example, many European nations constructed power­ ful administrative organizations that strengthened the role executive officials could play in subsequent periods of economic and political development.26 War and geopolitical conflicts in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries also helped centralize European state bureau­ cracies, creating incentives for the development of extensive capaci­ ties for economic intervention and extraction. In the United States the constitutional mandate of the nation's founding preserved a loose federal system that dispersed sovereignty across national, state, and local levels and among judicial, congres­ sional, and executive branches. In the nineteenth century, when Eu­ ropean state bureaucracies were expanding, the United States re­ mained a government of courts and parties. Highly competitive political parties and patronage-oriented democratic politics strength­ ened the role of congressional-centered government. The spread of a mass-based, democratic political system in the United States preceded the establishment of centralized administrative institutions, unlike in Europe, and this sequence of political development served to con­ strain bureaucratic centralization throughout the nineteenth centu­ ry. 27 2 5The inertial characteristics of institutions are discussed in the Conclusion. See also G . John Ikenberry, "Conclusion: An Institutional Approach to American Foreign Eco­ nomic Policy," International Organization 42 (Winter 1 988). 2 6See Charles Tilly, ed . , The Formation of National States in Western Europe (Princeton: Princeton U niversity Press, 1 975); Gianfranco Poggi, The Development of the Modern State (Stanford : Stanford University Press, 1 978); Reinhard Bendix, Kings and People: Power and the Mandate to Rule (Berkeley : University of California Press, 1 978); and Michael Mann, "The Autonomous Pow e r of the State : Its Origins, Mechanisms and Results," Archives europeennes de sociologie 24 ( 1 984), 1 85-2 1 3 . 2 7See Stephen Skowronek, Building a New American State: The Expansion of National Administrative Capacities, 1 877-1920 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1 982),

]2

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

The relatively isolated economic and geopolitical position of the United States in the decades prior to World War I also reinforced a congressionally dominated political system. Large internal markets and the absence of a large, capable government bureaucracy permit­ ted hierarchical and integrated business enterprises to grow in the late nineteenth century. Whereas European nations developed exten­ sive institutional relationships between business and the state in this formative industrial period, American public officialdom played a subsidiary role in economic development. 28 The basic organizational fea tu res of the American state were built upon but largely unchanged during the world wars and Depression of the twentieth century. Involvement in the world wars did not have the same effect on state building in the United States as it did in ·Conti­ nental Europe. America mobilized for war with a variety of tempo­ rary administrative programs that brought private business directly into the offices of the state. These state-sponsored, but privately run, emergency programs were easily disassembled in the postwar years, largely preserving the decentralized organizational features of the state.29 This preservation of the state's decentralized and fragmented orga­ nizational structure is striking in comparative perspective, but some islands of bureaucratic capacity did emerge. In the 1 930s the Depres­ sion and a changing international economic environment provided an impetus for executive centralization in trade policy. Passage of the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1 934 (RTAA) signaled a long­ term transfer of responsibility for trade policy from Congress to the executive. The result was a decline in the direct influence that societal groups could wield over trade policy. Later, World War II put the United States in a position to act upon the new set of international demands and opportunities, and the crisis of war and the subsequent emergence of Soviet-American hostilities had catalytic effects on for­ eign and economic policy institutions and the power of the executive. Franz Schurmann argues that there were systematic interactions be­ tween war, ideology, and executive power. The crisis of war acted to and J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The United States," in Raymond Grew , ed. , Crises of Political Development in Europe and the United States (Princeton : Princeton University Press, 1 978). 28See David Vogel, "Why Businessmen Distrust Their State : The Political Con­ sciousness of American Corporate Executives," British journal of Political Science 8 ( 1 978), 45-78. See also Andrew Shonfield, Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power (New York : Oxford University Press, 1 965), pp. 2 98-3 29. 29For a discussion of wartime mobilization, see Robert A. Dahl and Charles E . Lindblom, Politics, Economics, and Welfare (New York: Harper, 1 953), p p . 402- 1 2 .

33

REASONS OF STATE

"increase the power of the executive levels of organization." At the same time the unrivaled international position of the United States in the later stages of the war and its aftermath gave Presidents Franklin Roosevelt and Harry Truman extraordinary opportunities to articu­ late a broad "ideological vision" that also strengthened the role of the executive.30 Conceptions of organizational structure are useful in situating the role and capacities of groups and state officials as they struggle over policy at particular historical periods. Left at this architectural level, however, they assume that groups and individuals are automatically channeled into courses of action that conform to the overarching organizational structure of state and society. We need also to focus on moments when groups and individuals seek to change or overcome institutional constraints , and in particular on efforts by executive offi­ cials and other individuals to build new state capacities. An under­ standing of the dominance of a private system of petroleum produc­ tion and distribution in the United States and the "weak" position of executive officials must take into account the timing and phases of industrial and bureaucratic development in the decades spanning the turn of the century. Several critical periods of American political and economic history shaped for decades the structure of relations be­ tween the private petroleum industry and public officials. State involvement in the petroleum industry was fixed in organiza­ tional structures that were not easily altered . Government-industry relations in the industry conformed to a more general pattern in which the state's regulatory involvement in industrial activities was highly circumscribed . This pattern, striking in comparative perspec­ tive, is part of the broad historical development of business and state organization in the decades spanning the turn of this century. Dis­ tinctive are the rise of big business organization, conflict between large and small firms, and the limited techniques available to the state in its efforts to get involved in industrial affairs. Government-business relations were also fixed in ways specific to the petroleum industry, because of the international and domestic evolution of the industry, the state's involvement in mediating industrial conflicts, and the peri­ odic concern of state officials with issues of energy supply and energy security. Attempts to extend state capacities in the energy sector were spo­ radic and fragmentary, an exercise that left executive officials with 30franz Schurmann, The Logic of World Order (New York : Pantheon, 1 974) , pp. 8 , 2 1 22.

34

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

few planning capacities and mechanisms for involvement. At mo­ ments of crisis for national security, executive officials made efforts either to become more directly involved in energy production or to develop added planning capacity. Such initiatives were generally blocked or dismantled after the crisis had passed. Institution building did not survive the crises that provoked it. The Janus-Faced State and Strategi,es of Adjustment States participate in both domestic and international political sys­ tems. Made up of different organizational capacities and modes of operation, states occupy a unique position to mediate internal and external change-J . P. Nettl's image of a gatekeeper is apt. 3 1 The international and domestic activities and capacities of states are inex­ tricably linked. Untangling the logic of the state's Janus-faced rela­ tionship with its international and domestic settings provides an initial understanding of the bases of state action. Although states vary widely, all are composed of organizations that make exclusive claims to the sovereign and coercive control of a ter­ ritory and its population . These monopoly claims legitimate a variety of core activities : the raising and disbursement of revenue, the pro­ mulgation and enforcement of rules and property rights, and the maintenance of political order. States also claim to define and repre­ sent broad national interests and seek to protect and advance those interests in the face of international competition .32 States are thus separate from but enmeshed in a complex set of relationships with society. It is a conception of the state captured most effectively in historical analyses of states at their moments of birth . Charles Tilly has sketched a series of relationships between war mak­ ing, capital accumulation , extraction , and European state making. He notes that leaders of nascent states, engaged in war with adjacent powerholders , needed to extract resources from local producers and traders : "The quest inevitably involved them in establishing regular access to capitalists who could supply and arrange credit, and to im­ posing one form of regular taxation or another on the people and activities in their sphere of control. " But capitalists were capable of 3 IJ . P. Netti, "The State as a Conceptual Variabl e , "

World Politics 2 0 (J u l y 1 968), 559-

92. 32This definition of the state i s d rawn from Weber,

Economy and Socifty, 1 : 5 6 , and State and 1 968), pp. 1 5 4-69. See also Theda Cambridge University Press , 1 979),

Otto Hintze, "The State in H istorical Perspective , " i n Rei n h a rd Bendix , ed . ,

Society

(Berkel e y : U n iversity o f California Press,

Skocpol, States and e s p . p p . 30-3 2 .

Social Revolutions

( New Yor k :

35

REASONS OF STATE

movement (they had what Albert Hirschman calls "movable proper­ ty"), and therefore state officials had to form alliances with various social classes and to foster capital accumulation. At the earliest mo­ ments in the building of European states, state leaders were con­ fronted with a double-edged imperative : to harness domestic wealth so as to strengthen the state's foreign position, and to do so in a way that would not scare off capitalists or diminish economic growth. 33 State intervention can stifle economic growth and diminish reve­ nues even when mobility of productive resources is low. International competition, and the resulting need of the state to extract societal resources for military and foreign policy purposes, may constrain states even in relatively closed national economies. Indeed , the logic of a state's bargaining relationship with a society extends beyond con­ siderations of economic growth. As Tilly notes, "the processes of bar­ gaining with ordinary people for their acquiescence and their sur­ render of resources-money, goods, labor power-engaged the civilian managers of the state in establishing limits to state control, perimeters to state violence, and mechanisms for eliciting the consent of the subject population. "34 This underlying dilemma-the continu­ ing need for the state to extract resources and impose costs on the society and economy while maintaining the confidence of economic actors and the consent of the population-is no less acute for the contemporary state . All states share these core features and face these basic domestic dilemmas, but they differ widely in the manner in which they are organized and the extent to which they can draw resources from and impose costs on the society and economy. The domestic activities of the state cannot be separated from its 33Charles Tilly, "Warmaking and Statemaking as Organized Crime," in Evans, Rueschemeyer, and Skocpol, Bringing the State Back In, p. 1 7 2 , and Albert Hirschman, "Exit, Voice, and the State," World Politics 3 1 (October 1 978), 90- 1 07 . Douglas C. North spells out this fundamentally double-edged relationship between state and cap­ ital, presenting a more elaborate utility-maximizing model, in Structure and Change in Economic History (New York : Norton , 1 98 1 ) . See also Margaret Levi, "The Predatory Theory of Rule," Politics and Society 10 ( 1 98 1 ) , 43 1 -65, and John A. C. Conybeare, "The Rent-Seeking State and Revenue Diversification," World Politics 35 (October 1 98 2 ) , 25-4 2 . The state exchanges the provision of particular services (e. g . , the mainte­ nance of property rights) for privately generated revenue. It attempts to structure these services so as to maximize revenue. The state is constrained , however, since there is always the possibility that rivals can provide the same services. North argues: "Where there are no close substitutes, the existing ruler characteristically is a despot, a dictator, or an absolute monarch. The closer the substitutes, the fewer degrees of freedom the ruler possesses, and the greater the percentage of incremental income that will be retained by the constituents" (Structure and Change, p . 2 7 ) . 34Charles Tilly, Big Structures, Large Processes, Huge Comparisons (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1 985).

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

participation in the larger system of states. International geopolitical and economic pressures and opportunities, for example, can prompt states officials to attempt internal socioeconomic reforms or to direct the course of national economic development-activities that may or may not conflict with domestic social and economic interests. The ability of the state to protect or enhance the nation's international position hinges in important respects on the internal political and material resources of th. e nation and the state's access to them. 35 Likewise, the state's international activities are intimately tied to its domestic position. The international system can provide an arena for state officials attempting to solve domestic problems, typically as states try to extract resources and political support from other states. Lead­ ers of developing countries, for example, often find foreign aid and diplomatic recognition vital to the maintenance or enhancement of their domestic political standing. 36 Equally important, state officials may seek international agreements to redistribute or mitigate the eco­ nomic and political costs of international economic change, thereby reducing the political and economic burdens those state officials would otherwise shoulder.37 A state's international position depends on its relative military and economic capabilities. These international capabilities refer to its ac­ cess to and influence over the international system-access to and influence over the behavior of other actors. Similarly, the state's do­ mestic position depends on its ability to perform a range of activities such as the reallocation of productive resources and the imposition of costs on the economy and society. Variations in these domestic and international capacities have implications for the manner in which states pursue adjustment policy. The international position of a state influences its policy of adjust­ ment. The more powerful the state is, the more it will emphasize international strategies. States that are strong internationally will at­ tempt to solve adjustment problems within the international arena, thereby distributing the costs of adjustment among nations and re35This observation is emphasized by classical Realists. See Hans J. Morgenthau, Power among Nations, 6 th ed. (New York : Knopf, i 985), and E. H . Carr, The Twenty Years Crisis, r 9 r 9 - 1 93 9 : An Introduction to the Study of International Relations, 2d ed. (London: Macmillan, i 962), chap. 8. 36See W. Howard Wriggins, The Ruler's Imperative: Strategies for Political Survival in Asia and Africa (New York: Columbia University Press, i 969) . 37For a general discussion of international-domestic linkages see G. John Ikenberry, "The State and I nternational Strategies of Adjustment," World Politics 39 (October 1 986). See also Ikenberry, David A. Lake, and Michael Mastanduno, "Toward a Realist Theory of State Action," unpublished paper, 1 986.

37

REASONS OF STATE

Table 2. Distribution of gross economic resources among the five major market­ economy countries, 1 960- 1 980

Year

United State s

Germany

Britain

France

Japan

U . S . as % of Five Top Countries

1 960 1 970 1 975 1 980

505 989 1 539 2587

72 1 05 420 819

71 1 22 141 204

60 14 1 33 9 652

43 204 499 1 036

67 60 51 46

SOURCE. United Nations Statistical Yearbook (New York, 1 98 1 ) , p. 1 5 1 .

ducing individual burdens. International strategies of adjustment usually require cooperation among nations. All states might benefit from an international strategy, but only powerful states can wield the political and economic resources necessary to gain agreement on their own terms and to induce others to accede to their wishes . In principle, combinations of weak states can agree to an international offensive strategy but, at the very least, they will find it difficult to do so. As a result, less powerful states are likely to emphasize domestic strategies. The international position of a state can be gauged by a variety of measures . Indicators particularly relevant to the position of industrial countries relative to international petroleum markets are provided in Tables 2 and 3. The distribution of gross economic resources indi­ cates that, despite a decline in relative position, the U . S . economy remained a clear international leader throughout the 1 970s. More revealing are measures of relative capability in the energy area. Although U . S . import dependence grew in the years following the 1 973-74 crisis , imports remained a far smaller percentage of total energy consumption than in Europe and Japan. Aggregate imports were approximately half the size of European imports and roughly similar to those of Japan. The relative share of oil imports in domestic energy consumption was low, but the absolute share of imports in total imports by industrial countries was high , giving the United States greater opportunities than other consuming countries to exer­ cise influence over international oil markets. Its large absolute share of imports gave the United States the ability to alter international supply and prices ; the small place of those imports in domestic energy consumption meant that the costs of curtailing imports would be smaller for the United States , everything else being equal, than for other industrial importing countries. These indicators suggest that in 1 9 7 3 , the United States was in a favorable international position to influence the course of the oil 38

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy Table 3 .

Petroleu m i m ports of major Western countries,

1 97 1 - 1 979 a) Oil i m port dependence ( o i l i m ports as a percen tage of total energy requirement)

U nited States France Germany Japan

1 97 1

1 973

1 9 75

1 977

1 9 79

6% 67 42 68

10 % 75 42 74

1 5% 64 37 70

20 % 65 44 70

1 9% 64 39

66

SOURCE. Calculated from data i n I n ternational E nergy Agen­ cy ,

Energy Balances of OECD Countries, 1 9 7 1 1 I 9 8 1 ,

Par i s : O E C D ,

1 98 3 . b) O i l i m ports (thousand barrels daily)

U n ited States Western E u rope Japan

SouRCE. 16.

1 97 3

1 9 75

1 97 7

6 , 2 55 1 5 ,4o5 5 ,480

6,025 1 2 ,6 1 0 4 ,945

8,7 1 0

84 1 0

1 3 , 2 95 5,5 1 0

1 3 ,080 5 , 605

BP Statistical Review of World Energy,

1 9 79

J u ne 1 98 4 , p.

c ) U . S . oil balance E xcess Prod uction

1 96 7 1 97 3 1 979

Oil I m ports as

Capacity as %

Net U . S .

% o f Consumption

of Consum ption

Position

35 48 43

25

+6 - 25 - 40

*

*

* exact fi g u re not available b u t close to zero .

SOURC E . Robert Keohane, After Hegemony ( Princeto n : Prince­ ton U n iversity Press, 1 98 5 ) , p. 1 99 .

crisis. However, the United States did not have surplus domestic pro­ duction, a resource that had proved important in responding to ear­ lier disruptions in international markets. To exercise its potential market power, therefore, the United States had to cut domestic con­ sumption of imports. Unlike in previous supply disruptions, it could not simply release excess domestic production onto world markets . The substantial international capabilities of the American state thus hinged on its domestic capabilities ; in this case, its ability to cut im­ ports and adjust to higher oil prices. The domestic position of the state influences the strategy of adjust39

REASONS OF STATE

ment. The more constrained a state is by its relations with its economy and society, the more it will emphasize international strategies of adjustment. States that find it difficult to impose costs on their domes­ tic societies will be more inclined to seek international solutions. Con­ versely, states that have the capabilities to redeploy domestic re­ sources and impose the costs of change on society will emphasize domestic offensive strategies. These relationships between the domestic and international capaci­ ties of states and adjustment strategies combine to provide a fuller set of propositions about state action. States that are internationally powerful but domestically constrained will have a dominant interest in an international strategy of adjustment; such was the position of the United States as it entered the oil crisis of 1 973-74. U . S . executive officials pursued an international offensive strategy after 1 97 3 , al­ though the nation's international power was insufficient for the strat­ egy to succeed. States that are less powerful internationally, but that can redeploy domestic resources and impose costs on society, will emphasize domestic strategies of adjustment. The Europeans (the French most prominently) and the Japanese were in this position in 1 97 3 . None of these states was powerful internationally in the energy area, but each had various means to influence the course of domestic energy adjustment. Disparities in international and domestic positions led the advanced industrial states to adopt initially divergent strategies of adjustment. I am not proposing a theory about the determinants of international collaboration . Rather, the advanced industrial states were confronted with divergent international and domestic constraints and oppor­ tunities, which influenced national preferences for specific forms of international agreements. In the American case, domestic constraints on adjustment (particularly oil price controls) made international op­ tions more attractive. At a later point those constraints made it diffi­ cult for the United States to play the international leadership role it envisaged. In contrast, the European and Japanese states had a wider array of options to pursue energy adjustment on a national or region­ al basis, and so to then the American proposals seemed less necessary. The divergent positions of various states did not preclude interna­ tional cooperation-indeed , some forms of cooperation emerged during the second oil shock. But the availability or absence of other options clearly influenced the value that states attached to coopera­ tion. The failure of cooperative schemes forced U.S. officials to con­ front domestic capacities for adj ustment, and in particular the organi­ zational foundations of state capacities.

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

State Capacities and Alternative Adjustment Strategies The role and capacities of executive officials are influenced by the iorganizational structures of the state in which they are situated . I n the United States these structures are characterized by a fragmentation of political sovereignty across levels and branches of government and have left executive officials with a relatively modest bureaucratic plan­ ning capacity and few mechanisms for direct intervention in specific sectors. Organizational structures, however, are not immutable . At moments of national crisis, politicians and administrative officials have sought with varying degrees of success to expand their capacities to respond to economic crisis and change. Moreover, the capacities of executive officials should not be measured simply in terms of the mechanisms at their disposal. The ability to abstain from intervention or withdraw from specific sectors of the economy can also be crucial to the successful pursuit of policy objectives . From conceptions of the capacity of executive officials that focus on the policy process and situate its characteristics within broader struc­ tures of state and society have emerged general propositions about the ability of leaders to accomplish state goals and about the weakness and strength of advanced industrial states.3 8 A variety of organiza­ tional structures differentiate states according to their capacities. John Zysman, who is interested in the abilities of advanced capitalist states to become involved as coherent and weighty actors in industrial adjustment, focuses on mechanisms of recruitment in the national civil service, degree of centralization within government civil service, and independence of the civil service from legislative oversight. These characteristics of government structure, he argues, can be com­ bined into a single measure of a state's capacity for intervention .39 The character of specific "policy networks" and "policy instru­ ments," Peter Katzenstein argues, are shaped by the larger structures of state and society. The manner and effectiveness with which states can intervene in their economies are directly related to the character of their policy networks and the range of policy tools available to 38See Peter J. Katzenstein , "International Relations and Domestic Structures: For­ eign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States," International Organization 30 (Winter 1 976), 1 -4 5 ; Katzenstein, Between Power and Plenty; Krasner, Defending the National Interest, esp. chap. 3 ; and Zysman, Governments, Markets and Growth. 39Zysman, Governments, Markets and Growth, p . 300. For discussions of the higher civil service see Ezra Suleiman, Politics, Power and Bureaucracy: The Administrative Elite (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1 974) ; John A. Armstrong, The European Admin­ istrative Elite (Princeton : Princeton U niversity Press, 1 97 3 ) ; Hugh Hecla, A Government of Strangers (Washington, D.C. : Brookings, 1 97 7 ) ; and Suleiman , ed . , Bureaucrats and Policy Making ( New York: Holmes & Meier, 1 984).

41

REASONS OF STATE

government officials : "The number and range of policy instruments emerge from the differentiation of state and society and the cen­ tralization of each." Each advanced industrial country represents a different balance between state and society.40 Zysman is more con­ cerned with the capacity of specific bureaucractic institutions, but both writers have notions of broad differences in the capabilities of states-differences derived from the historical play of political and economic development. State strength, they suggest, is fundamentally reflected in the organization and resources of bureaucratic govern­ ment and its insulation from competing actors . The most prominent strong state in these formulations is France, where permanent organizations of government officials have access to numerous policy tools and resources they can legitimately deploy in the regulation of a wide range of social and economic activities. There is every reason to place the state at the center of political analysis. Direct and indirect policy instruments can be used selectively to influ­ ence private economic decisions and practices . Moreover, networks of officials from private firms, state enterprises , and administrative bu­ reaus reinforce the state's influence over the economy. French policy networks for trade, finance, and energy policy, Katzenstein finds, are state-centered , and American policy networks are society-centered.4 1 The United States is the exemplary weak state. The American state is fragmented and decentralized , possessing few of the instruments and resources necessary for strategic intervention in the economy and society. In no single issue-area is there a comprehensive, effective policy planning agency, much less for government as a whole, despite repeated presidential attempts to construct one. Frequent turnover among high-level executive officials and narrow divisions of bureau­ cratic authority create a "government of strangers" and severely hinder the emergence of effective bases of power.42 The U nited States is not simply a late bloomer, but its political institutions are fundamentally malformed for the emergence of a strong state. Useful in identifying variations in policy instruments and resources available to state officials, this approach helps us understand why U . S . 40Peter J. Katzenstein, "Conclusion: Domestic Structures and Strategies o f Foreign Economic Policy," in Katzenstein , Between Power and Plenty, and Katzenstein , " I nterna­ tional Relations and Domestic Structures," International Organization 30 (Winter 1 976), 1 5. 4 I See Andrew Shonfield , Modem Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power ( London: Oxford University Press, 1 965) , pp. 1 2 1 -50; Suleiman , Politics, Power and B ureaucracy; and Katzenstein, " International Relations and Domestic Structures,"

p . 43 ·

42Heclo , A Government of Strangers.

42

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

officials had trouble with direct production of energy in the 1 970s and soon turned to subsidies. However, strong and weak characteriza­ tions do not capture the nuances and variations in the capacities of states . The strong state of France has been challenged by descriptions of the role of intrest groups and clientilistic relationships more exten­ sive than earlier depictions of a centralized , autonomous state recog­ nized . 43 Recent studies of Japanese state-society relations also reveal a state bureaucracy severely constrained by interest groups and political parties.44 Clearly state strength is more complex than a strong-weak distinction can capture.45 Likewise, the simple image of a weak American state, able to do little more than register interest group demands, is misleading. We need a more differentiated conception of state capacity, one that probes more deeply the fit between particular policy instruments and particular crises. It is precisely the search for such a fit that involved American executive officials in a sequence of adj ustment proposals during the oil shocks of the seventies. In this sense, the capacity of the state must be discovered by the officials who seek to exercise it. Moreover, state capacity is more than the expansion of state con­ trols or activities. The withdrawal of direct regulatory controls or the abstension from intervention may also provide evidence of state ca­ pacity. Such considerations frustrate simple distinctions between strong and weak states and lead to an exploration of variations in state capacities within a single nation across time and issue-areas . 43In a new study of the French state and the notarial profession, Ezra Suleiman takes issue with the conventional, strong state image. Suleiman argues that the capacities of the French state are best understood in historically cyclical terms, where the interven­ tionist efforts of a strong state to reshape societal groups result in transformations of relations with society and, utimately, in a diminution of state capabilities. See Private Power and Centralization in France: The Notaires and the State (Princeton: Princeton Uni­ versity Press, 1 988). See also Jack Hayward , The State and the Market: Industrial Patriotism and Economic Intervention in France (B righton: Wheatsheaf, 1 986) ; Harvey B. Feigen­ baum, The Politics of Public Enterprise: Oil and the French State (Princeto n : Princeton University Press, 1 985 ) ; and Helen Milner, "Resisting the Protectionist Temptation: I ndustry and the Making of Trade Policy in France and the U nited States during the 1 970s," International Organization 4 1 (Autumn 1 987), 639-65. 44See the new interpretations of Japanese state capacities in Richard J. Samuels, The Business of the Japanese State: Energy Markets in Comparative and Historical Perspective (Ithaca: Cornell U niversity Press , 1 987), and David Friedman, The Misunderstood Mira­ cle: Industrial DevelO'fJment and Political Change in Japan ( Ithaca : Cornell U niversity Press, 1 988). The distinctive symbiotic relations between J apanese state and economy-what he calls "organized capitalism" -are also discussed by Ronald Dore in Flexible Rigidities: Industrial Policy and Structural Adjustment in the Japanese Economy, 1 9 70-80 (Stanford : Stanford U niversity Press, 1 986). 45See also G. John Ikenberry, "The I rony of State Strength : Com parative Responses to the Oil Shocks in the 1 970s," International Organization 40 (Winter 1 986), 1 05-3 7 .

43

REASONS OF STATE

In the course of American energy adj ustment, politicians and exec­ utive officials attempted to build additional state capacities for coping with the problems of energy adjustment. These efforts came on the heels ' o f the failure of international cooperation. The early efforts at state building sought to increase the information about energy avail­ able to policy makers-this was the rationale of Project Indepen­ dence. Later, a small group of officials proposed to create capacities for the direct financing of energy exploration and production, as in earlier crises seeking to enlarge the direct management ability of the state. These proposals failed, opposed by a wide array of interest groups and public officials within Congress and the executive branch. Some opponents feared the encroachment of the state on the private operation of energy finance and production. Others were skeptical about the purposes to which new state capacities would be put or about the possibility of their being subverted by private interests. At the same time the institutional legacy of the past weighed heavily on proposals for change. In particular, the scarcity and fragmentation of bureaucratic expertise and operational capability provided few bases from which to build new government powers and responsibilities . What state builders in the 1 970s needed were organizational toe­ holds. Without them, state-building proposals were easily defeated . Executive officials fell back on capacities or mechanisms that the American state has always favored. An enormous upsurge in spend­ ing made use of a traditional instrument of public policy, and a mod­ est administrative organization was created to channel energy R & D funds into private hands. The spending option was attractive both to Congress and to the executive, particularly when financed from the proceeds of a tax on windfall oil profits. Senators and representatives could use the funds to nourish a wide assortment of constituencies ; executive officials could use the programs to influence larger patterns of energy research and development. Nonetheless, research funding could not address immediate energy problems. I ndeed, as these spending programs grew in size, they made the problems posed by price and allocation controls all the more apparent. In the end executive officials discovered that the reconstruction of market pricing for petroleum was the most effective approach to energy adjustment. They faced formidable domestic obstacles. Pe­ troleum price controls, enacted prior to the 1 973-74 shock, partially shielded consumers and also advanced the commercial position of segments of the petroleum industry. These interests, represented in Congress, pushed successfully to preserve and extend price and al­ location controls. Consequently, the move toward market pricing it­ self required vigorous state action. 44

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

The notion that the capacities of the state may be exercised in the withdraw! and not merely the extension of government controls is not appreciated by those who associate strength with direct state involve­ ment in the economy and society . The analytical confusion lies in the dichotomy of state and market. The state (or authority) and the mar­ ket (or exchange) are separate and distinctive modes of organization or social control, and, as Charles Lindblom argues, nations differ in the degree to which "market replaces government or government replaces market."46 But differences in the balance of market and government activity are not in themselves indications of the strength or weakness of the state or of private enterprise. The political and economic ends that markets serve and the forces that organize and sustain those markets are empirical matters. The state may organize or extend markets in the service of national and geopolitical obj ectives, of course, and the seminal statement of this view is Karl Polanyi's study of the nineteenth-century rise of English capitalism . Polanyi argues that the emergence of national markets was the result not of the "natural" and gradual expansion of nascent local and transnational trading relationships but rather of deliberate state policy. The construction of markets in England was the product of actions by a mercantilist state that saw national eco­ nomic development as vital to strengthening the nation's interna­ tional position.47 States also make more limited and sometimes very sophisticated efforts to enforce or extend market relations for a variety of political obj ectives. Japanese industrial policy, for example, occasionally uses as its central instrument the selective opening of domestic markets to international competitive pressures. State officials have used such market openings to encourage the rationalization of a domestic indus­ trial sector; at other times they may wield the threat of market open­ ing to encourage businesses to comply with other industrial policy goals. At the very least, the use of market mechanisms is likely to serve a mixture of private interests and state policy goals. 48 In the U nited States the decision taken in 1 979 to decontrol oil prices was not simply or primarily a ratification of private commercial interests . The policy itself was politically costly to the Carter admin46Lindblom, Politics and Markets . 47 Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation (New York: Farrar & Rinehart, i 944). 48Daniel Okimoto, Between MIT/ and the Market (Stanford : Stanford University Press, forthcoming), and John Zysman and Stephen S. Cohen, "The Mercantilist Challenge to the Liberal International Trade Order," paper prepared for the Joint Economic Com­ mittee of the U.S. Congress, 1 98 2 , p. i 2 . For a recent analysis of these relationships and processes of "mutual adjustment," see M ichael Barzelay, The Politicized Market Economy: A lcohol in B razil's Energy Strategy (Berkeley : University of California Press, i g86).

45

REASONS OF STATE

istration and engaged executive officials in an elaborate set of moves to ensure its success . In preceding years , officials had pursued a vari­ ety of adj ustment policies, involving e fforts to transform the state's role in the energy sector as well as programs to distribute massive amounts of funds through existing government mechanisms. In the end, however, executive officials found that their most powerful tool was a return to the market.

CONCLUSION

My purpose is to explain why the industrial nations traveled diver­ gent paths in their pursuit of energy adj ustment and to explore the implications of these divergent strategies for international coopera­ tion among nations. I also seek to account for the evolution of energy adj ustment in the United States, which began with an international strategy and ended with a decision to decontrol oil prices. A proper understanding of American energy policy requires that we pay atten­ tion to the activity of executive officials as they are influenced and constrained by' larger international and domestic structures . In ex­ ploring the contours of energy adjustment, therefore, we are examin­ ing the larger logic of national adjustment to international change. In this book I develop an institutional approach that advances sev­ eral lines of analysis. First, I situate the organizational position of executive officials in the 1 970s in the larger historical trajectory of state formation. Politicians and bureaucrats labor under the weight of prior state building. The institutions in which these officials operate and the legacies of previous policy inhibit opportunities for policy action. Second, I relate adjustment strategies to the broad international and domestic position of states. Energy adj ustment is part of a larger set of challenges that arise in the course of international economic change . The challenge of adjustment can be met through the pursuit of either domestic or international policies, and in both domains pol­ icy can entail restructuring or protecting the existing order. At this general level, the strategic choices made by executive officials depend on state capacity ; officials in a state that finds it difficult to impose change on its own domestic system will emphasize international strat­ egies. This logic of domestic and international strategies played itself out in the early years of the 1 973-74 crisis and helps explain the failure of international cooperation on energy adjustment. Finally, I develop my institutional approach by paying attention to 46

Explaining Energy Adjustment Policy

the manner in which the organization structures of the state shaped the domestic sequence of American adjustment policies. Organiza­ tional structures of the state are crucial not only in which executive officials seek to accomplish but also in how they articulate what is at stake. They limited the types of policies executive officials could suc­ cessfully pursue and help explain the sequence of energy adj ustment strategies. This focus on executive officials shaping strategy but being constrained by the organizations they occupy orients my analysis.

47

CHAPTER THREE

The American State and Energy Policies Our energy resources are not inexhaustible, yet we are permitting waste in their use and production. In some instances, to achieve apparent economies today future generations will be forced to carry the burden of unnecessarily high costs and to substitute inferior fuels for particular purposes. National policies concerning these vital resources must recognize the availability of all of the m ; the location of each with respect to its markets; the costs of transporting the m ; the technological developments which will increase t h e efficiency o f their production and use; and t h e relationships between t h e in­ creased use of energy and the general economic development of the country. It is difficult in the long run to envisage a national coal policy, or a national petroleu m policy, or a national waterpower policy without also in time a national resources policy. Franklin D . Roosevelt, 1939

Such a statement could have come from any embattled American president in the 1 97os. It was actually made by President Roosevelt in February 1 939, in a message to Congress transmitting the report and study of the N ational Resources Committe of Harold lckes. 1 As FDR's message indicates, American public officials were concerned with en­ ergy supply and security issues long before 1 97 3 . Important episodes of government involvement punctuate the long history of interna­ tional and domestic energy markets . The policy outcomes of these earlier struggles created the institutional terrain for energy adjust­ ment policy in the 1 970s. I franklin D. Roosevelt, The Public Papers and Addresses of Franklin D. Roosevelt (New York : Macmillan, 1 94 1 ) , February 1 6, 1 939, p . 1 3 8 .

The American State and Energy Policies

In this chapter I sketch the origins and evolution of the American state-both its general organization and those structures related to energy policy making. Although state organization puts important constraints on the activities of executive officials , it is itself explicable in terms of distinctive phases of political and economic development. The pattern of energy adjustment policy in the 1 970s can be under­ stood only through a specification of the institutions and policy tools that accumulated in the fifty years prior to 1 97 3 .

ORGANIZATIONAL STRUCTURES O F THE STATE

The organizational structures of the American state were shaped by the grand forces of political and economic development. From a com­ parative perspective, the most powerful state bureaucracies are to be found in those advanced industrial nations where monarchical state building preceded the emergence of representative institutions .2 Bu­ reaucratic organization became one of the accessories of state making in Continential Europe . The building of states involved the territorial struggles of kings, the incorporation of existing political structures, the extraction of resources from a local population . State makers first had to raise taxes and deploy military forces , precisely the activities facilitated by bureaucratic staffs. Those political leaders in early mod­ ern Europe who developed specialized staffs and bureaucracies gained an "organizational advantage" over their rivals, and so na­ tional bureaucracy-relatively autonomous and powerful-attended the successful emergence of the first nation-states. 3 American national political institutions, but contrast, were estab­ lished without a strong or centralized state bureaucracy. The absence of an aggrandizing state maker and hostile external powers goes far to explain the modesty of the organizational center of the American state, which has remained "underdeveloped" because of the per­ sistent prominence of other political mechanisms, such as political parties and the judiciary. As one author notes, "When the new nation was established in 1 789, there was a very weak bureaucracy. And 2See Barrington Moore, J r . , Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston : Beacon, 1 966) ; Reinhard Bendix, Kings and People: Power and the Mandate to Rule ( Berkeley : U niversity of California Press, 1 97 8 ) ; and Hans Rosenberg, B ureaucracy, Aristocracy and A utocracy: The Prussian Experi­ ence, 1 660- 1 815 (Boston: Beacon, 1 958). 3So argues Charles Tilly in "Reflections on the H istory of European State-Making," in Tilly, The Formation of National States in Western Europe (Princeton: Princeton U niver­ sity Press, 1 975) , p. 3 0.

49

REASONS OF STATE

because of the decentralized federal system, political parties were essentially locally oriented . Indeed , throughout the nineteenth cen­ tury, most of the federal bureaucracy was dominated by a locally oriented party system, thus reducing the ability of the central govern­ ment to penetrate the society . "4 A system of courts and parties, Stephen Skowronek argues, pro­ vided a powerful bulwark for political order in nineteenth-century America. In the last decades of the century a highly competitive na­ tional party system set constraints on administrative development. Electoral struggle was the dominant mechanism for the dispensation of political goods and power ; politicians divided the spoils of office, and public policy fed the imperatives of state and local patronage systems. "The creation of more centralized , stable, and functionally specific institutional connections between state and society was imped­ ed," as Skowronek notes, "by the tenacity of this highly mobilized , highly competitive, and locally oriented party democracy."5 While political parties were emerging in European countries to challenge national administration, American reformers were seeking institu­ tional alternatives to party dominance. State building in its American setting moved along a unique trajectory. Much of the history of political reform around the turn of the century involved an effort to forge new bases for government author­ ity. In its early phase, between 1 8 7 7 and 1 g oo, this reform struggle , involved an ultirµ ately unsuccessful atterript to establish a national administrative apparatus. Later, between 1 900 and 1 9 20, coalitions of reformers were able to break into national office and establish some forms of administrative power. These institutional breakthroughs , established within a rapidly growing and increasingly complex indus­ trial order, brought bureaucratic administration into the politcal sys­ tem. But the political strategies for reconstituting national political authority shifted with each presidential administration, and as a result bureaucratic administration remained dispersed and fragmented . The opportunities for state building were met with new forms of administrative authority, but in such a way as to encourage institu­ tional disarray within the state .6 The most important new form of administrative authority was the regulatory commission. This institu4j . Rogers Hollingsworth, "The U nited States," in Raymond Grew, ed. , Crises of Political Development in Europe and the United States ( Princeto n : Princeton University Press, 1 978), p. 1 65 . 5Stephen Skowronek, Building a New American State: The Expansion of National Admin­ istrative Capacities, 1 87 7 - 1 9 2 0 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1 98 2 ) , pp. 3940. 6Jbid . , pp. 1 65-76.

50

The A merican State and Energy Policies

tional creation provided a new center for public authority,but it did so at the expense of centralized bureaucratic capacities. The modern growth of executive administration has seen a con­ tinued layering and specialization of government bureaucracy. The postwar expansion of policy issues has greatly enlarged the scope of the federal bureaucracy but has further attenuated presidential con­ trol of administration. The growth in administration, H ugh Heclo observes, has occurred at the middle level of government, where nar­ row professional experts, organized in webs of associations that blur public and private boundaries, have gained increasing prominence and autonomy. The lines of power are arranged in complex "issue networks" that cut across government and societal organizational structures : "Participants move in and out of networks constantly . Rather than grou ps united in dominance over a program , no one, as far as one can tell, is in control of the policies and issues."7 The American federal organization is distinctive because of its frag­ mentary, shifting, and narrowly specialized institutions. Bureaucracy within the executive establishment has grown, yet its authority and capacities have remained strikingly delimited . Obviously these per­ sistent institutional conditions inhibit broad-scale policy planning. Bu­ reaucratic organization remains a matter of small units, and admin­ istrative authority has been built on the basis of short-term political control of specialized expertise that is not attached to bureaucratic organization. Programmatic policy planning and the capacity to bring that policy into decision-making realms remain elusive in such a context. This sketch suggests the American state is a continually trans­ formed, internally differentiated area of conflict rather than an inte­ grated institution . Andrew Shonfield has already noted the implica­ tion of the U.S. administrative structure-a "loose confederation of more or less hostile bodies"-for policy coherence. Whereas in other Western nations, "the general trend is to use the aggregation of pub­ lic power in order to create a coherent force whose significance will be greater than the sum of its individual parts, " in the UnitedStates, a "curious disorder" resides at the "heart of the American admin­ istrative process. " Skowronek depicts the modern American admin­ istrative state as a "hapless giant," a state that could "spawn bureau­ cratic goods and services but that defied authoritative control and 7 Hugh H eclo, "Issue Networks and the Executive Establishment," in Anthony King, ed. , The New American Political System (Washington, D.C. : American Enterprise I nstitute, 1 978), pp. 87- 1 24 , quotation at p. 1 0 2 .

51

REASONS OF STATE

direction."8 Such patterns of state organization can be found in gov­ ernment-business relations as well.

PATTERNS OF GOVERNMENT-B U SINESS RELATIONSHIPS

The distinctive political development of the nineteenth century gave shape to an American state in which a centralized and weighty bureaucratic core was striking by its absence. That sequence of politi­ cal development, when juxtaposed with the phases of economic devel­ opment, also provides a powerful explanation for patterns of state involvement in the economy. Early industrializers did not face an established, competitive world industrial order, nor were the first industrial sectors, such as textiles , as capital-intensive as the later sec­ tors. Accordingly, private entreprenuers did not have the same re­ liance on government for investment needs. As new industries emerged , moreover, already accumulated capital kept investment re­ sources and industrial decision making beyond the realm of state control. Those nations which industrialized relatively late ( "backward coun­ tries") faced larger and more complex problems of economic develop­ ment.9 The types of industries that backward nations needed to en­ courage, such as steel, required large-scale and intensive industrial , banking, and state organizations . Large investment and export pro­ motion served to bring the government into a close relationship with industry, and industry's economic dependence on government brought political dependence with it. In late-industrializing Germany, for instance , relations between banks and industry were close. The investment needs of German industrialists, requiring rapid and mas­ sive capital expenditures, differed substantially from those of Britain . As Alexander Gerschenkron argues, the industrialization of England had proceeded without any substantial utilization of banking for long-term investment purposes. The more gradual character of the industrializing process and the more consider­ able accumulation of capital, first from earnings in trade and modern­ ized agriculture and later from industry itself, obviated the pressure for B Andrew Shonfield, Modern Capitalism: The Changing Balance of Public and Private Power (London : Oxford University Press, 1 965), pp. 3 1 8- 1 9 ; Skowronek, Building a New American State, p. 290. 9Alexander Gerschenkron , "Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective," in Gerschenkron, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book of Essays (Cambridge : Harvard University Press, 1 96 2 ) , pp. 5-30.

52

The A merican State and Energy Policies

developing any special institutional devices for provision of long-term capital to industry. By contrast, in a relatively backward country capital is scarce and diffused, the distrust of industrial activities is considerable, and, finally, there is greater pressure for bigness because of the scope of the industrialization movement, the larger average size of plant, and the concentration of industrialization processes on branches of relatively high rates of capital output. I O

Late industrializers will have more concentrated financial and in­ dustrial institutions , and the state is likely to be more directly involved in industrial development. State dominance does not simply reflect the level of economic backwardness, however, for complex historical antecedents conditioned the state's involvement. For example, the Russian state, without large-scale banking institutions, sought rather unsuccessfully to use direct government intervention in order to force industrialization. German state involvement, on the other hand, was directed at infrastructural investment and the maintenance of politi­ cal stability . 1 1 It was not simply the demands of national economic welfare or efficiency that led the state directly into the economy of late-indus­ trializing countries. A geopolitical logic made national defense impor­ tant to European state involvement in the economy. As one analyst notes, "only the perception of external threat from the prior presence of already industrialized countries prompted considerably enhanced State involvement with industrialization, and explains the rapidity of progress. " 1 2 Geopolitical pressures created incentives for the state to speed up industrialization and encourage industries of strategic im­ portance to the national economy. This geopolitical logic and the unique capital and technological needs of late-arriving industries gave the state an added presence in the economy. 1 0lbid . , p. 1 4 . T h e argument has been developed by James R . Kurth, "The Political Consequences of the Product Cycle : I ndustrial History and Political Outcomes," Inter­ national Organization 33 (Winter 1 979), 1 -34, and Kurth, " I ndustrial Change and Politi­ cal Change: A European Perspective," in David Collier, ed. , The New Authoritariansim in Latin America (Princeton : Princeton University Press, 1 979) . The theory has been ex­ tended to Latin America also. See Albert 0. Hirschman, "The Political Economy of I mport-Substituting Industrialization in Latin America," Quarterly Journal of Economics 82 (February 1 968), 2-3 2 , and Philippe C. Schmitter, "Paths to Political Development in Latin America," in Douglas A. Chalmers, ed . , Changing Latin America: New Interpreta­ tions of Its Politics and Sociology (New York: Academy of Political Science, Columbia University, 1 97 2 ) , pp. 83- 1 05 . 1 1 Gerschenkron, "Economic Backwardness," pp. 1 6- 2 1 . See further Peter Gourevitch, "The Second Image Reversed," International Organization 32 (Autumn 1 978), 88 1 -9 1 2 . 1 2Gautam Sen, The Military Origins of Industrialisation and International Trade Rivalry (New York: St. Martin's, 1 984), p. 79.

53

REASONS OF STATE

In the U nited States the early growth and maturation of big busi­ ness and the strikingly late growth of national public administrative institutions were, Alfred Chandler argues, crucial for the distinctive American relationship between government and business. 1 3 Unlike in Continental Europe, where a state bureaucratic apparatus appeared before large-scale industrialization, in America business growth pre­ ceded national institutions. In the crucial early period of industrial development the federal government remained outside the emerging institutional realms of economy and society . Also of importance to American business-government relations, ac­ cording to Chandler, was the substance of economic growth. External trade was of early importance to European industry, which rein­ forced collaborative relations with the state by creating incentives to seek government assistance in securing overseas markets . Further­ more, the emerging large firms in Europe tended to be in heavy industry, such as chemicals, metals, and machine tools , and did not have smaller entrepreneurial rivals. In the United States, however, the demands for government involvement were quite different. With large domestic markets and intense conflicts between large business and small merchants and wholesalers, the state played a peacekeeping rather than a promotional role. I nternal conflicts in American business and the limited organiza­ tional capacities of the state made antitrust and regulatory tools the state's dominant means of intervening in the turn-of-the-century na­ tional economy. Regulatory institutions grew in reaction to rapid growth of large business, first the railroads and later industrial manu­ facturers, and in a context shaped by contention over vertical integra­ tion and intrabusiness hostilities. Between 1 88 7 and 1 9 1 4 an institu­ tional framework was established through the Interstate Commerce Act, the Sherman Anti-Trust Act, and the Federal Trade Commission Acts. As Chandler argues, "when the large government bureaucracies did come in this country, the basic role of government toward busi­ ness had already been defined ; and that definition developed largely as a response to an influential segment of business community to the rise of modern big business. A comparable response did not occur abroad . " 1 4 I3Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., "Government versus B usiness : An American Phe­ nomenon, " in John T. Dunlop, ed . , Business and Public Policy (Cambridge : Harvard University Press, 1 980) ; also Chandler, The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business (Cambridge : Harvard University Press, 1 97 8 ) ; and Chandler, "The Coming of Big B usiness," in C. Vann Woodward , ed . , The Comparative Approach to American History (New York: B asic Books, 1 968), pp. 2 20-35. I4Chandler, "Government versus B usiness," pp. 4-5, 1 0- 1 1 .

54

The American State and Energy Policies

Regulation in Comparative Perspective The unique centrality of regulatory mechanisms to American gov­ ernment-business relations reveals much about the conjunctures of political and economic life at a crucial stage of industrial develop­ ment. One school of thought argues that American regulatory bodies have advanced "public interest" claims in the face of uncompetitive business practices. Others have emphasized the "capture" of regulato­ ry agencies by business itself or, more strongly, claim that regulatory mechanisms emerged as instruments of ind us trial interests. 1 5 The complexity of the regulatory process, the variety of agencies and in­ dustries involved, and the long expanse of regulatory history inhibit a settling of this argument. 1 6 It is clear that regulatory institutions emerged in response t o indus­ trial and political conflict, usually conflict within a particular industry. Furthermore, the important issue that informed public, legal, and government debate-and the conflict that called for a public re­ sponse-was the emergence of the large, integrated business enter­ prise. Between 1 897 and 1 900, 1 83 large industrial firms were formed, commanding one-seventh of all industrial manufacturing ca­ pacity. 1 7 Unlike European states, which in different geopolitical and economic settings actively sought to encourage cartelization of major leading industries, the American state became involved in the econo­ my because of internal business conflicts over size and competitive­ ness. Regulatory bodies were established in response to pressures from clusters of vocal small businessmen, progressive reformers, and politi­ cians using antimonopoly and procompetitive ideological appeals . The style of regulation evolved in the early decades of the twentieth century. The first industries subject to regulation were capital goods industries : railroads, steel, oil, coal . After World War I regulation expanded to include consumer goods : automobiles, appliances, pack­ aged foods. The evolution of regulatory control followed a stream of 1 5 For an overview, see Thomas K. McCraw, "Regulation in America : A Review Article," B usiness History Review 49 (Summer 1 975) , 1 59-83 . The classic statement of this public interest position is James Macauley Landis, The Administrative Process (New Haven: Yale U niversity Press, 1 938) . On capture see especially Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservatism: A Reinterpretation of American History, 1900- 1 9 1 6 (Chicago : Quadrangle, 1 963). 1 6 See J ames Q. Wilson, ed. , The Politics of Regulation (New York : Basic Books, 1 980) . 1 7See Thomas K. McCraw, "Regulatory Agencies, " in Glenn Porter, ed . , Encyclopedia of American Economic History (New York : Scribner's, 1 980), p. 788, and Morton Keller, "The Plurali � t State : American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1 900- 1 930," m Thomas K. McCraw, ed . , Regulation in Perspective (Cambridge : Harvard University Press , 1 98 1 ) , p. 68.

55

REASONS OF STATE

Supreme Court decisions that delinated the proper sphere of reg­ ulatory action in setting standards and rates, in market conditions, and in antitrust. 1 8 The regulatory approach was particularly compelling in the U nited States. In a rapidly expanding economy with large internal markets, the government was not confronted directly with a need to cartelize basic industry for purposes of international competition. Rather, its central task was the incorporation of public interest goals into con­ flicts among businesses and between business and society. Strong col­ laborative relationships between business and government were not necessary. Just as important, the slowly evolving set of federal and state-level political institutions limited the opportunities for government inter­ vention. The regulatory system created new realms of public authori­ ty, based on regulatory commissions staffed by experts and with the competence to apply administrative law as defined by the American j udiciary. I nstitutional structures were created to bring government and business together, but the relationship remained at arms' length, delimited by the courts, and substantially beyond direct congressional or bureaucratic reach. 1 9 The regulatory mechanism was a modest tool of government, and around it reformers and capitalists frequently struggled . This form of articulation between government and business has retained a du­ rability that stems partly from its flexibility. New Deal policy innova­ tions, for instance, were built upon established regulatory controls : temporary industrial commissions were established to supervise regu­ lated industries and to adj ust the combinations of public and private officials charged with administering guidelines. But this adaptability of institutional form has also had a stunting effect on the competence and capacity of central government bureaucracies. The hallmark of the regulatory mode is dispersed centers of government competence, deployed in a reactive manner and directed at defining market shares and competitive practices. The mode does not include organizational incentives for added levels of planning and programmatic govern­ ment policy. When the institutional structures defining business and govern­ ment relationships were formed, American government was left with I BSee Keller, "The Pluralist State," pp. 74-94. I 9This logic can be found in social policy as well. See Theda Skocpol and John I kenberry, "The Political Formation of the American Welfare State in H istorical and Comparative Perspective," Comparative Social Research 6 (Greenwich, Conn . : JAI Press, 1 98 3 ) , 359-8 1 .

The American State and Energy Policies

primarily reactive, peace-keeping responsibilities. The prevailing or­ ganizational structures of the state positioned public authority in pe­ ripheral regulatory commissions. 20 Macroeconomic Governance Other methods of government intervention evolved in the 1 930s and after, but the types of policy tools that emerged remained rela­ tively indirect and undifferentiated by sector or industry. Policy was directed at the influencing of aggregate economic performance through gross fiscal expenditures and monetary policy.2 1 I n 1 968 the American delegation to the OECD explained the im­ portance of what it called "global steering" as industrial policy : "The United States Government has come to recognize to a greater extent than ever before that its objective of steady economic growth without significant inflation requires it to co-ordinate its programmes with respect to Government spending, taxation and Federal Reserve dis­ count rates and reserve requirements . . . When the fiscal and mone­ tary policies of the Government are co-ordinated they constitute very powerful tools for providing systematic guidance to the economy as a whole." The report noted that American government structure did not allow for systematic and industry-specific interventions. "The Federal administrative structure is not designed to carry out an active, co-ordinated policy of promoting industrial growth . . . Intervention has normally been ad hoc. Our actions are developed as the problem and the occasion arise : the structure for dealing with such matters is thus a reactive one rather than a formal planning structure."22 These aggregate economic measures allowed the federal govern­ ment to assume control of the economy without altering the struc­ tures-private, corporate decision making and arms-length public­ private relations-themselves. This was the genius of Keynesian eco20As one analyst notes: "While most other states in capitalist societies increased their role and power as industrialization proceeded, the authority of the American state declined and its size remained relatively small. When seen in comparative terms, it simply had a less necessary role to play. " David Vogel, "Why B usinessmen Distrust Their State : The Political Consciousness of American Corporate Executives," British Journal of Political Science 8 ( 1 978), 5 7 . Also see Thomas K. McCraw, "Business and Government: The Origins of the Adversary Relationship," California Management Re­ view 26 (Winter 1 984), 33-5 2 . 2 1 See Herbert Stein, The Fiscal Revolution in America (Chicago : University of Chicago Press, 1 969) . 22 United States Industrial Policies, Observations presented by the U.S. Delegation be­ fore the Industry Committee of the OECD at its 6th Session ( Paris: OECD, 1 968) pp. 2 7 , 35· ,

57

REASONS OF STATE

nomics, for within the prevailing capitalist system government offi­ cials could fashion fiscal and monetary policy to influence aggregate spending, thereby influencing the investment climate and incentives for economic growth. Only modest levels of government autonomy were needed for this form of economic control. And among the vari­ ants of Keynesian economics, the least interventionist forms were incorporated into government activity. 23 Since the 1 930s American government has developed the mac­ roeconomic tools and a modest planning apparatus to make "global" economic policy. These new economic tools were built upon institu­ tions that did not involve direct and selective interventions. The result was a style of government activity that conformed , in H ugh Heclo's phrase, to the "idea of government by remote control. " Heclo argues that "political administration in Washington is heavily conditioned by an accumulation of methods for paying bills and regulating the con­ duct of intermediary organizations. This pattern is consistent with a long tradition of fragmented and decentralized administration. "24

THE EMERGENCE OF THE PETROLEUM I N DUSTRY

The historical shaping of the American state and the patterns of government-business relations are also revealed in the petroleum business. The timing and phases of industrial development and state building are again crucial to an understanding of the larger historical patterns. The petroleum industry had become a major domestic and international industry before the state actively became concerned with national energy goals. When the state did get involved, it was pri­ marily in a reactive fashion, addressing domestic stability and security of international supply. The federal government did not develop a tutelary relationship with the industry, as occurred in other Western countries during the early decades of the twentieth century . Reg­ ulatory mechanisms typified domestic government intervention, and diplomatic initiative typified government involvement in the foreign operations of American-based international petroleum companies. 23See Robert Skidelsky, "The Decline of Keynesian Politics," in Colin Crouch, ed. , State and Economy i n Contemporary Capitalism (New York : St. Martin's, i 979), pp. 62-63 ; Robert Lekachman, The Age of Keynes (New York: Random House, i g66) ; Robert M . Collins, The B usiness Response t o Keynes, 1 9 2 9 - 1 9 64 (New York: Columbia U niversity Press, i 98 1 ) ; and Margaret Weir and Theda Skocpol, "State Structures and the Pos­ sibilities for ' Keynesian' Responses to the Great Depression in Sweden , B ritain, and the U nited States," in Peter B. Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Skocpol, Bringing the State Back In (New York : Cambridge University Press, i 985), p p . 1 07-63. 24 H eclo, " I ssue Networks," p . 92.

The American State and Energy Policies

Early Growth of the Petroleum Industry The American petroleum industry grew into a multinational system in the years following the turn of the century. The international growth of this American-centered industry accompanied its evolution into an oligopoly of firms, large in size and small in number, which divided and controlled production and distribution . The early modern discoveries of oil were in the United States and in Russian Caucasia. As these sources of petroleum were developed, and the economies of the industrialized world generated further de­ mand , a multitude of firms emerged to produce, refine, and market the new source of energy. In the United States the early years of the industry were characterized by intense competition among a large number of firms. The original sources of oil were in Pennsylvania and Ohio ; markets were concentrated in New England, the Middle West, and Europe. By the turn of the century discoveries had been made in the Dutch East Indies, Burma, and Venezuela, and in this period individual companies could secure the whole of a producing country's territory as a concession. 2 5 Very early in the development of the industry, however, large inte­ grated firms came to dominate. Characteristics unique to the indus­ try, involving economies of scale, geographical logistics of source and markets, and finite sources of supply, conditioned this concentration of industrial power. The story of the Rockefeller empire at Standard Oil has been told many times. 26 Prior to the restraint of trade action of 1 9 1 1 and the breakup of the empire, the Standard Oil company used its market power to consolidate a staggeringly large position within the industry. The monopoly position of the American industry changed in the years after World War I , owing both to the breakup of Standard Oil and the emergence of smaller competitors in Texas . The important point here, however, is that the American industry emerged under conditions that did not require the state to play an active role in its early growth . Yet the American state did come to play a role in the years between the world wars, when oil firms were expanding and stabilizing their operations . Several industry issues brought firms into the policy pro25See Harold F. Williamson and Arnold R. Daum, The American Petroleum Industry: The Age of Illumination (Evanston : Northwestern University Press, 1 959), p. 320, and Evan Luard, The Management of the World Economy (New York : St. Martin's, 1 983), p. 1 43 . 26See Ed Shaffer, The United States and the Control of World Oil (New York : St. Martin's, 1 983 ) , pp. _20- 2 2 . On Standard Oil see, for example, I ra M. Tarbell, The History of the Standard Ozl Company, 2 vols. (New York : Macmillan , 1 933), and Harold F. Williamson, Ralph L. Andreano, Arnold R. Daum, and Gilbert Klose, The American Petroleum Indus­ try: The Age of Energy, 1 899- 1 959 (Evanston : Northwestern University Press, 1 963).

59

REASONS OF STATE

cess. Independent firms sought government regulation to stabilize the wild fluctuations in production and prices. Others sought anti­ trust action to break up the dominant majors. International firms sought government action to gain access to new foreign oil fields. At the same time executive officials were concerned with two major issues that complemented some of the concerns of American energy firms. Government officials , wanting to encourage open and rela­ tively liberal markets in the sector, used regulatory and antitrust in­ struments. Also, federal government officials perceived at various junctures a need to encourage the expansion of American firms into foreign oil fields. Here diplomatic assistance was a key instrument. In Europe, by contrast, the patterns of state promotion in energy indus­ tries were somewhat different. Foreign Government Involvement in the International Oil System I n the years before World War I the European powers actively encouraged their national firms to develop operations in promising areas of petroleum production. Britain was an early leader. Winston Churchill, among others, argued that oil was superior to coal as a fuel for battleships , and with war in the offing he advocated government involvement in Persian oil fields through the creation of a "national champion" company. In 1 9 1 4 the British Parliament, by a vote of 2 54 to 1 8 , agreed to buy controlling shares in a petroleum firm , and thus the British government became partowner in the Anglo-Persian Oil Company.27 State involvement was understood to provide financial and political support for company operations. In return the contract stipulated that Anglo-Persian would remain a British concern, with the govern­ ment appointing two of the seven company directors . This decision to acquire a private petroleum firm became in many respects a model for subsequent governments. As one analyst notes, "it was a pro­ totype. Britain sought and gained command of secured 'tied' supplies of oil from a promising source that later turned out to be part of the richest oil-bearing region yet discovered ."28 Commercial and government activity quickened with the end of 27Louis Turner, Oil Companies in the International System (London : Allen & Unwin, 1 979), p. 25; Raymond Vernon, "Enterprise and Government in Western Europe," in Vernon , ed . , Big B usiness and the State: Changing Relations in Western Europe (London : Macmillan, 1 974), p. 1 1 ; Christopher Tugendhat and Adrian Hamilton , Oil-The B ig­ gest Business (London : Eyre Methuen, 1 975), p. 68. 2 8] . E . Hartshorn, Oil Companies and Governments: An Account of the International Oil Industry in Its Political Environment ( London : Faber & Faber, 1 962 ) , p. 2 3 3 .

60

The American State and Energy Policies

World War I , in the creation of an international petroleum system from the relics of the Ottoman Empire. European governments ac­ tively involved themselves in securing access to Middle Eastern ter­ ritories. In 1 920, for example, it was agreed among the parties that Britain would have control over Mesopotamia and the French would assume the erstwhile German interests in the Turkish Petroleum Company. France, which had been desperately dependent on foreign oil sources during the war, moved to create its own petroleum firm, the Compagnie Fram;aise des Petroles (CFP) . CFP, partially owned by the government, represented French interests in Iraqi and other Mid­ dle Eastern oil fields.29 In 1 92 8 the French government enacted ex­ tensive regulations in order to encourage the construction of inde­ pendent national refining capacity. By the late 1 920s a few international companies had come to domi­ nate the international production and trade in oil. The largest of these were the majors, also known as the "Seven Sisters" : Jersey Stan­ dard (later Esso and Exxon), Shell, Anglo-Iranian (later BP), Socony (later Mobil), Socal, Texaco, and Gulf.30 The large companies were involved in all of the industry stages-extraction, refining, and mar­ keting. Some had developed their own extensive supplies of crude. Gulf had supplies in the United States, Mexico, and Venezuela, and later Kuwait and Nigeria ; Socal had supplies in California, Bahrain, and eventually Saudi Arabia. Others, such as Jersey Standard, Shell, and Socony, did not have extensive supplies and had to buy from others to meet their refining and marketing needs.3 1 As the market for petroleum continued to grow, the various companies expanded their foreign exploration and acquired new concessions. Much of this expansion occurred in the Middle Eastern countries of Saudi Arabia, Iran, I raq, and Muscat and Oman. A renewal of state concern about oil security and development followed World War I I , and again governments became directly in­ volved in the petroleum industry. The French government, for in­ stance, created two public firms-the Bureau de Recherches de Pe­ trole (BRP) and the Regie Autonome des Petroles (RAP)-mandated to explore for and produce petroleum. These new French undertak­ ings were pushed forward by a senior French official, Pierre Guillaumat, who had strong ties among political, civil servant, and business groups. Guillaumat, who was directeur des carburants from 29See Turner, Oil Companies, pp. 2 6- 2 7 . 3°For background see Anthony Sampson, The Seven Sisters: The Great Oil Companies and the World They Shaped (New York : Bantam, 1 975). 3 1 Luard, Management of the World Economy, p. 1 45 .

61

REASONS OF STATE

1 944 to 1 95 1 , also became director of B RP in 1 945. Later, in the 1 950s, he would be instrumental in promoting the French civilian nuclear power industry . Moving from one top post to another in government and in oil and nuclear enterprises, Guillaumat reflected in his career the institutional possibilities for collaborative relations among public and private organizations. 32 The French state's postwar push into the petroleum industry was matched elsewhere. I taly and Norway also created new public enter­ prises or nationalized old ones. Several factors shaped the state's role in the oil industry. The most important determinant of initial govern­ ment involvement was the magnitude of national dependence on for­ eign oil. France, mo.re than Britain and Germany, for example , de­ pended heavily on imported oil that was outside the control of French firms. B ritain and Germany relied much longer than France on coal to supply a substantial portion of national energy needs. The pattern of involvement was further shaped by prevailing ideological and po­ litical conceptions of the proper role for public institutions to play in business activity-France and Italy had already developed an exten­ sive government presence in business development. Finally, the exis­ tence of established , large multinational firms gave certain coun­ tries-notably the U nited States , the Netherlands, and Britain-less reason for direct government involvement.33 Thus challenges of re­ source dependence combined with national objectives of political con­ trol to mold separate styles of state involvement in the petroleum industry. After World War I I , French, I talian, German, and Japanese government renewed their individual efforts to gain some measure of national autonomy in an international petroleum system dominated by the Americans and the B ritish. Nonetheless , between the late 1 9 2 0s and the late 1 960s a remark­ able stability was maintained within the international oil regime. Large , integrated companies extended and stabilized their sources of crude petroleum, and predictable marketing systems were developed. There was little competition between the major firms. A mutuality of interest between these companies allowed a sophisticated system of oil sharing, even collusion, to emerge. Competition, to the degree that it existed, was primarily focused on gaining access to supplies . This managed aspect of the international oil regime was epitomized in the so-called Red Line agreement of 1 92 8 , in which five of the multina32See Oystein Noreng, "State-Owned Oil Companies: Western Europe," in Raymond Vernon and Yair Aharoni , eds . , State-Owned Enterprise in the Western Economies (New York: St. Martin's, 1 98 1 ) , pp. 1 33-34, and Turner, Oil Companies, p. 5 7 . 33See Leslie E . Grayson , National Oil Companies ( N e w York : Wiley, 1 98 1 ) , p. 7 .

The A merican State and Energy Policies

tional companies involved in the Iraq Petroleum Company operation agreed not to seek further concessions in territories of the former Ottoman Empire. Under the "as is" agreement of the same year, moreover, the largest of the Seven Sisters agreed to specific pricing and market-sharing agreements .34 Later, combinations of integrated firms produced agreements jointly to exploit newly discovered reserves in Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, and elsewhere. The most extensive agreement came when five large firms jointly established Aramco to develop the massive Saudi Ara­ bian concession. The Red Line agreement was later challenged by the American government in order to allow U.S. company access to the area, but these various agreements revealed the essentially negotiated nature of the newly established international petroleum regime. American Government Involvement in the International Petroleum System State officials became actively involved in supporting access to sources of oil for their national companies after i 9 1 9 . The federal government in the United States, in contrast to the British and French governments , which favored direct corporate involvement, remained largely a source of diplomatic support. The United States by i 9 1 4 had a very large domestic petroleum industry, and problems of supply or security were matters of at most distant concern. Indeed , the first government involvement in the activities of American firms was the effort, culminating in i 9 1 1 , to break up Standard Oil. Nonetheless, American companies did seek support from the State Department to help gain access to the territories of the former Ottoman Empire. U.S. government involvement took the form of diplomatic protests, pri­ marily directed at the British, arguing for "open door" commerical conduct. In the end this pressure succeeded in convincing British, French, and Dutch interests to allow American corporate involvement in the Turkish Petroleum Company and in Mesopotamian oil . During the i 92os, despite postwar concerns about oil supply and security, the American state did not adopt the national champion approach. Five large American companies with foreign operations had already emerged, making direct government involvement through a national champion more problematic. After World War I government concern developed about the depletion of domestic re­ serves, leading at least one senator (Phelan of California) to call for the creation of a government-owned corporation, yet a sequence of 34Sampson, Seven Sisters, pp.

70- 1 03 .

REASONS OF STATE

Republican administrations in the 1 920s made such a notion unlikely. Finally, the commanding American position in world oil production, which was as high as So percent in 1 920, gave little force to calls for greater government involvement. 35 International and Domestic Firms Although involvement by the American state was limited to diplo­ matic initiatives within the emerging international petroleum regime, the domestic industry provided a basis for regulatory intervention. Other industrial nations had modest domestic resources ; The United States, on the other hand , had massive petroleum reserves . This dif­ ference created the basis very early in the industry's history for a diversified American industry ; diversified between producers, refin­ ers , " and marketers , and diversified in terms of large producers and small, independent operations. This latter division was particularly important in generating pressures for reactive government interven­ tion. The changing structure of the American petroleum industry after World War I, as new competitors emerged, stemmed in part from the breakup of Standard Oil. The energy problems perceived by Ameri­ can public officials and politicians were not as straightforward as problems were in Europe . Whereas the initial policy concerns for European governments involved access to and security of energy sup­ plies, American government officials initially worried about the loom­ ing size of the Standard Oil empire. The government's posture to­ ward to oil industry followed a general, national pattern : the use of regulatory and antitrust policy tools to restrain big business and en­ gage in industrial peacekeeping. The state's concern about the oil trust was buttressed by the pres­ ence of threatened small, independent firms. I ndependent oil firms occupied niches within the larger petroleum industry. These disad­ vantaged interest-local producers, refiners, and distributors-main­ tained pressure on government in its protracted antitrust delibera­ tions. 36 The niches they occupied were created in part, ironically, from Rockefeller's early corporate strategy. The Standard Oil Com­ pany made a corporate decision not to invest in new domestic sources of oil. It aimed , rather, to control the industry through dominance of downstream refining and marketing facilities. The discovery of large 35See Turner, Oil Companies, pp. 2 7 - 2 8 . 36Keller, "Pluralist State," p . 68.

The American State and Energy Policies

oil fields in Texas in 1 90 1 allowed new competitors to enter the indus­ try. In the year Standard Oil was broken up, the company owned only about i o percent of the new Texas production. As one analyst notes, "the new entrants, whose power was based on the ownership of crude rather than refining capacity, were able to breach Rockefeller's do­ mestic monopoly even before the Supreme Court acted. "37 The influence of the independents was (and still is) substantial. As Raymond Vernon notes, "the strength of the independents, then as now, rested in part on the fact that they were well distributed over the face of the United States and could rally formidable Congressional support for any position they took. The ability of the independents to provide a source of countervailing power would appear again and again in the shaping of U.S. oil policy during the decades to follow."3 8 The organizational structure of the state enlarged the leverage of such companies over policy making, and beyond what economic clout alone might explain. Following the early period , when antitrust was the central tool, executive officials became more concerned with influencing the man­ agement of an increasingly sprawling and dispa �ate industry. 39 In the midst of the diversity of petroleum interests, and with an influential domestic industry, the state adopted a style of involvement that em­ phasized tax and regulatory intervention. Special tax provisions be­ gan in 1 9 1 8 to encourage the development of coal, gas, and pe­ troleum resources. In the 1 930s the central problem for domestic petroleum producers was the overproduction of domestic oil, which led to a state-level regulatory response- "market-demand proration­ ing"-that acted to restrict production and preserve market shares.40 Federal government interest in regulatory intervention focused on the conservation of supplies, the maintenance of minimal levels of competition, and the insurance of secure sources of oil for military purposes. 4 1 Federal regulation of the natural gas market began in the 1 950s. The resulting regulatory institutions were a fragmented mix­ ture of decentralized and improvised mechanisms that left govern37Shaffer, United States, p. 30. 38Raymond Vernon, "The Influence of the U.S. Government upon Multinational Enterprises: The Case of Oil," in The New Petroleum Order: From the Transnational Com­ pany to Relations between Governments (Quebec : Les Presses de l'universite Laval, 1 976), p. 56. 39Gerald D. Nash, United States Oil Policy, 1 890- 1 9 64 (Pittsburgh : U niversity of Pitts­ burgh Press, 1 968), chap. 1 . 4°Cf. Arthur W . Wright, "The Case of the United States: Energy as a Political Good ," journal of Comparative Economics 2 ( 1 978), 1 68-69. 4 1 The narrative sketch of the next few pages is drawn from several sources; es­ pecially useful is Nash, United States Oil Policy. The quotation is from Nash, p. 1 20.

REASONS OF STATE

ment at the periphery of the industry and the conflicts between vari­ ous industry groups unsettled . During World War I , and at other moments of intense government concern over oil security and supply , the emphasis of federal pe­ troleum policy shifted. Rather than try to influence the structure and competitive status of the industry, executive officials sought to pro­ mote cooperative government-business relations and to make reg­ ulatory policy more effective. These new attitudes toward the pe­ troleum industry, which would characterize government policy well into World War I I , were developed in the Fuel Administration of Woodrow Wilson's government. With oil conservation and produc­ tion issues attracting high-level government attention during World War I, the Fuel Administration advanced regulatory policy that would further integrate the industry. This style of administration would become a basic feature of government intervention in the pe­ troleum industry during times of crisis : the government promoted self-regulation by industry leaders. Seeking to stabilize production, for example, the Fuel Administration organized producers from vari­ ous regions of the country to coordinate production levels. B ecause of the rising wartime need for petroleum, moreover, politicians and administrators advocated tax reductions for domestic producers. A consensus developed between government and oil producers-gov­ ernment would give the industry favorable tax treatment, and in re­ turn the industry would respond to the heightened petroleum needs associated with national defense. After wartime concern over production and security of supply waned, the federal government's influence dwindled, and industry leaders held on to their newfound tax and regulatory prerogatives while seeking to reestablish erstwhile levels of business autonomy. I n the late 1 920s new conflicts broke o u t between independent pro­ ducers and international firms, and the first major conflicts appeared between domestic independents and oil importers. The position favored by President Herbert Hoover involved voluntary intraindus­ try cooperation to restrain imports. Later, during the Depression, when oil prices fell dramatically, state-level regulatory schemes were introduced to stabilize production. But as one analyst notes, "even in the depths of the Depression, public authorities rarely assumed the right to determine production quotas for private industries." The early New Deal, within the National Industrial Recovery Act, inaugurated a new state involvement. The N RA administrator pro­ moted industrial collaboration to design industrywide codes. But gov66

The American State and Energy Policies

ernment actions even at this juncture were defensive, attempting to rescue regulatory practices to stabilize production and prices in the face of intense intraindustry disputes. The final Oil Code did grant the petroleum administrator, Harold Ickes, power to determine monthly production quotas on the basis of recommendations from an industry advisory committee. Ickes attempted to further centralize his administrative powers in 1 934 and 1 93 5 ; opposition within the indus­ try and in Congress prevented his doing so. Like the temporary wartime petroleum planning efforts that would soon follow, the N RA mechanisms of government-led industrial orga­ nization did not lead to enduring government powers or respon­ sibilities. As New Deal controls lapsed, Franklin Roosevelt in late 1 93 5 , over the objections of Harold Ickes, sent a message to the Inde­ pendent Petroleum Association urging industrial self-regulation and cooperation in order to prevent government involvement. Thus the New Deal did not bring policy innovations to the oil industry. Rather, it built upon the administrative and regulatory mechanisms founded in earlier decades, fashioning a more sophisticated and efficient im­ plementation of styles of intervention that had previously been ex­ perimented with. By the 1 940s a fairly well-established pattern of state involvement had survived dramatic variations in prevailing pol­ icy and industrial concerns. Congressional and executive officials responded , when they could, to the interests of both domestic and international companies. Thus Congress allowed tax deductions (a depreciation allowance) on do­ mestic producers which could exceed actual levels of investments . International firms were also allowed special provisions to protect large amounts of foreign-generated income from U . S . taxation. 42 When conflicts emerged between domestic and international pro­ ducers, however, domestic interests tended to win out, as the 1 959 Mandatory Oil I mport Quota illustrates. As foreign oil became more abundant and inexpensive, the 1 959 quota protected domestic producers.43 The pattern of U . S . policy before 1 97 3 was to accord special treat­ ment to mineral and resource exploration and production through tax subsidies, and to ensure adequate prices through regulatory 42Stephen L. McDonald, "Taxation System and Market Distortions," in Robert J . Kalter and William A . Vogely, eds., Energy Supply and Government Policy ( Ithaca : Cornell University Press, i 976), pp. 26-50; Wright, "Case of the United States," p. i 6g. 43Douglas Bohi and Milton Russell, Limiting Oil Imports: An Economic History and Analysis (Baltimore : Johns Hopkins University Press , i 978).

REASONS OF STATE

means. Investment decisions remained private, and the "unique role [of the state] in setting the rules of the game within which the energy market functions" was rarely considered .44

CRISIS AND THE LIMITS OF CHANGE

The emergence in America of a petroleum industry without signifi­ cant direction from state bureaucrats had important implications for subsequent industry-government relations. With limited policy in­ struments at its disposal, and with congressionally mediated pressures to attend to, the federal executive used regulatory means to promote competition and stability within the industry. When supply became a national concern, executive officials encouraged production through favorable tax arrangements . Foreign exploration and production were facilitated by diplomatic initiatives. Although the management of energy production and supply was left in private hands, executive officials did act to promote broader national energy goals. These goals included a national security in­ terest, which became pressing during World War I, in stable and secure supplies of oil. The military, particularly the navy , found pe­ troleum to be increasingly critical to its capacities .45 Other govern­ ment officials, with broader policy concerns, considered petroleum a strategic industry of importance to the general health of the economy. They understood stable supplies of energy at reasonable prices to be important for national economic growth, and the issue of economic growth frequently manifested itself as a concern for efficient markets in oil and energy.46 Finally, the level of national dependence on for­ eign petroleum raised issues of vulnerability to and manipulation by foreign powers . This fundamentally political concern arose from the general geopolitics of nationhood .47 Self-sufficiency, or at least some measure of national autonomy in critical industrial areas , remains a powerful underlying motivation of the state.48 Despite constrained institutions, U .S. executive officials found op44Robert J. Kalter and William A . Vogely, " I ntroductio n , " i n Kalter and Vogely ,

Energy Supply and Government Policy, p. 1 1 . 4 5 N a s h , United States Oil Policy, p p . 1 6- 2 0 . 46Craufurd D. Goodwi n , "The Truman Administratio n : Toward a N ational Energy Polic y , " i n Goodw i n , ed . , Energy Policy in Perspective (Washingto n , D . C . : B rookings, 1 98 1 ) , p p . 2 - 3 .

47See Sen , Military Origins of Industrialisation, chap. 2 . 4BSee Kenneth N . Waltz, "The M y th of N ational I n terdependence, " i n Charles Kin­ dleberger, ed., The International Corporation (Cambridge : MIT Press, 1 970).

68

The American State and Energy Policies

portunities to pursue national goals, most clearly in the government's encouragement of foreign exploration and production by American multinationals. Except briefly in wartime the limitations of the pre­ vailing system and the constraints on government officials were rarely revealed. The system was successful for several generations in meet­ ing broad national goals. The consistency of government goals and the apparent success of policy was indicated by John J. McCloy, an adviser to presidents from Franklin Roosevelt to John Kennedy, in 1 974. "Strategists in the Government and Congress," McCloy argued, "did everything they could to encourage American oil companies to enter into this new area [the Middle East] so as to protect and supple­ ment our own reserves which had been severely drained and, as a result of this foresight, oil did flow at reasonable prices, as I said, to the free world and it continued to do so for a long time. For a long period we had a stable period of supply and prices."49 Despite its consistency and "success," however, the American system did not go unchallenged by government officials. The Problem of State Ownership of Oil Production Challenges to the prevailing government-business system came pri­ marily at moments when public concern arose about petroleum sup­ plies. The most important such moment occurred in World War I I . Increasing reliance o n oil imports and the problem o f wartime energy shortages prompted government concern over resource availability and security. The seriousness of the perceived problem gave new weight to a government search for a national resource policy. Special wartime government planning institutions provided the opportunity for new forms of state involvement in the petroleum industry. The fate of those government initiatives provides insights into the pos­ sibilities for and limitations on institutional transformation at critical historical periods. By 1 94 1 the exigencies of war had brought the government into a dominant position in the petroleum industry. The chief challenge, in contrast to that of the previous decade, was to maximize production. Although Congress resisted authorization of new presidential powers to control petroleum production and distribution, Roosevelt resorted to executive action.50 As a result, the federal government gradually 49John J. McCloy, testimony in Hearings before the Subcommittee on Multinational Corporations of the Committee on Foreign Relations, U.S. Senate, 9 3d Cong. , 2d sess. , pt. 5 , January 24 , 1 974, p. 65. 50Goodwin, "Truman Administration," p. 5 2 .

REASONS OF STATE

put in place controls over prices and production, the allocation of supply, and the direction of refining, transportation, and distribu­ tion. Responsibility for coordination was established in the Petroleum Administration for War (PAW) . The central bureaucratic figure was Secretary of Interior H arold Ickes, who was appointed petroleum coordinator for national defense on the eve of the American entry into the war. Ickes was instructed to gather information, coordinate voluntary industry collaboration, and recommend policy . His initial responsibilities were ambiguous, his powers modest. Ickes struggled to expand his powers, however, and eventually the PAW developed into an influential agency with direct access to the president. The PAW was organized along functional lines. An industry com­ mittee was also created, the Petroleum Industry War Council (PIWC), to bring industry into policy deliberations. This organizational design, along with the staffing of PAW offices with knowledgeable industrial personnel, contributed to the agency's effectiveness. 5 1 The fear on the part of both industry and government leaders of a natonal oil shortage came to a head in mid- 1 94 3 . On July 1 4, Roose­ velt called a cabinet meeting to plan American international pe­ troleum strategy. At this juncture Ickes used his position to seek fur­ ther expansion of government coordination and control of petro­ leum. Ickes had for several years been stressing the seriousness of the decline in the discovery rate of American petroleum reserves. In 1 94 l , in a letter to Roosevelt, he had estimated that the United States had enough oil supplies for only fifteen years and that, if Germany were to gain control of the Persian Gulf, the Western hemisphere would fall behind Germany in petroleum production.52 Problems in increasing domestic oil production led industry leaders in the PIWC to urge higher prices in order to stimulate drilling. Government officials, however, turned their attention to the consol­ idation of access to foreign petroleum sources. In June 1 943 Ickes wrote to Roosevelt urging the administration to move immediately to acquire and develop foreign reserves. He proposed that the govern­ ment create a Petroleum Reserves Corporation for this purpose, drawing on earlier proposals for such a corporation which he had advanced in 1 935 and 1 940.53 5 1 N ash, United States Oil Policy, p. 1 59. 52John Frey and Chandler Ide, A History of the Petroleum Administration for War, I 94 I 45 (Washington, D.C . : GPO, 1 946) ; Nash, United States Oil Policy, p. 1 60. 53Nash, United States Oil Policy, p. 1 7 2 . See also David S. Painter, Oil and the American Century: The Political Economy of U.S. Foreign Oil Policy, 1 94 1 - 1 954 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1 986).

70

The American State and Energy Policies

Several circumstances made the Ickes proposal attractive. The first concern was with the seeming inadequacy of future American re­ serves. In addition, recognition was growing of the vastness of Middle Eastern petroleum resources, particularly in Saudi Arabia. Finally, and vital to the rationale for a government corporate initiative, U.S. officials and industry leaders were concerned that these petroleum deposits would come under British domination of the area.54 Ickes also noted in his letter to Roosevelt that petroleum shortages in the coming year could impinge upon both the military campaign in Eu­ rope and industrial performance at home.55 Indeed, the military strongly supported the proposal for direct government ownership of a petroleum firm. Although many in the State Department opposed the proposal, key proponents beyond Ickes and his Petroleum Ad­ ministration for War were the Joint Chiefs of Staff and members of the Army-Navy Petroleum Board.56 At this juncture the American government gave consideration to participation in the Saudi concession.57 Government support for di­ rect participation in Saudi Arabia came from President Roosevelt himself, as well as from Secretary Ickes and Undersecretary of the Navy William C. Bullitt. American options were considered within the State Department's special Committee on International Petroleum Policy, chaired by Economic Adviser Herbert Feis, and it was Feis who gained Secretary of State Cordell Hull's assistance (if not direct sup­ port) for the establishment of a Petroleum Reserves Corporation. The State Department proposed that the PRC acquire option contracts on Saudi oil. Ickes, supported by the military, urged that the PRC ac­ quire petroleum reserves directly, and do so by purchasing shares of the California Arabian Standard Oil Company. In June i 943 Roose­ velt agreed to the Ickes plan. 58 54I rvine H. Anderson, ARAMCO, the United States and Saudi Arabia: A Study of the Dynamics of Foreign Oil Policy, r933-r950 (Princeton : Princeton University Press, i 98 1 ) , P· 4 2 . 55Nash, United States Oil Policy, p. i 7 2 . 56Stephen Randall, "Harold Ickes and United States Foreign Petroleum Planning, i 939-45," Business History Review 5 7 (Fall 1 983), 3 7 3 ; see also Stephen ] . Randall, United States Foreign Oil Policy, r9 r9 - r 94 8: For Profits and Security (Kingston : McGill-Queen's University Press, 1 985). 57Anderson, ARAMCO, p. 4 2 . 58The board of directors o f the PRC was t o consist o f the secretaries o f state , interior, war, and the navy. The State Department was to have veto rights over PRC activity , retaining the responsibility to conduct negotiations with foreign governments. Al­ though the initial proposal for the PRC came from the State Department, the wartime concern over declining domestic petroleum reserves and the navy's assertive support allowed the bolder Ickes plan to be adopted. See Randall, "Harold Ickes and U.S. Foreign Petroleum Planning."

71

REASONS OF STATE

Secret negotiations were begun to buy shares in CASOC. After difficult talks, CASOC eventually proposed that the government should purchase a one-third interest in the company. In addition, the U.S. government would have a right to buy up to 5 1 percent of CASOC production during peacetime and l OO percent during war, and it could block the sale of company oil to third parties. Apart from these restrictions, CASOC would proceed under ordinary commercial rules. Most accounts of the negotiations, and the ultimate failure of gov­ ernment initiatives, have centered on opposition to the plan from CASOC itself.59 However, evidence indicates that opposition from other companies, namely Standard Oil of New Jersey and Socony­ Vacuum, was decisive.60 Industry opposition was centered in the For­ eign Operations Committee of the PAW. This wartime association of petroleum executives favored the private development of Saudi re­ serves, with American diplomatic support. I rvine Anderson notes that "this was formidable opposition, coming as it did from a bloc of companies that up to that point had contributed mightily to Ickes' success as Petroleum Administrator for War. Ickes' rather formidable power within the bureaucracy rested heavily on his close relationship with Roosevelt, which in turn was based on his proven ability to get results. If this corporate revolt were to undermine cooperation with the PAW itself, the consequences would be serious. "6 1 Although the formal reason for the withdrawal of the government purchase arrangement was inability to agree on terms, opposition within the loose affiliation of petroleum executives was crucial to the outcome. Yet a complete explanation for the demise of the Petroleum Reserves Corporation must go beyond business opposition. Opposi59Raymond F. M ikesell and Hollis B . Chenery, Arabian Oil: America's Stake in the Middle East (Chapel Hill : University of North Carolina Press, 1 949), pp. 9 1 -92 ; Nash, United States Oil Policy, p. 1 73 ; George Stocking, Middle East Oil (Nashville: Vanderbilt University Press, 1 970), pp. 98-99 ; Mira Wilkins, The Maturing of Multinational Enter­ prise: American B usiness Abroad from 1 9 1 4 to 1 9 7 0 (Cambridge : H arvard U niversity Press, 1 974), pp. 277-78; Sampson, Seven Sisters, pp. 96-9 7 ; Robert B. Kruger, The United States and International Oil: A Reportfor the Federal Energy Administration on U.S. Firms and Government Policy (New York: Praeger, 1 97 5) , pp. 50-5 1 ; Krasner, Defending the Na­ tional Interest, pp. 1 90-9 7 ; M ichael B. Stoff, Oil, War, and American Security: The Search for a National Policy on Foreign Oil, 1 94 1 - 1 9 4 7 (New Haven: Yale University Press, i g8o), pp. 84-86; and David Aaron Miller, Search for Security: Saudi Arabian Oil and American Foreign Policy (Chapel Hill : University of North Carolina Press, i 980), pp. 8 1 82. 60Anderson, ARAMCO, p. 56. See also Robert 0. Keohane, "State Power and Indus­ try I nfluence : American Foreign Oil Policy in the i 94 os, International Organization 36 (Winter 1 98 2 ) , 1 66-83. 6 1 Anderson, ARAMCO, p. 63. "

The American State and Energy Policies

tion within the administration, notably from the State Department, made the PRC problematic even within the context of the goals and interests of American foreign policy. Also, several investigatory com­ mittees-the Special Committee Investigating the National Defense Program and the Special Committee I nvestigating Petroleum Re­ serves-were skeptical about specific Ickes plans for government pe­ troleum projects in Saudi Arabia. What becomes evident is that an array of groups and agencies served to dilute Ickes's position within government and the legitimacy of his proposals. The failure of the Ickes initiatives takes on substantial significance from the vantage point of later decades-a significance not lost on officials and politicians in the midst of the oil shocks of the 1 970s. I n hearings on multinational corporations and American foreign policy, Senator Frank Church made this observation : Whether this idea [for a national oil company] was a good or bad idea is debatable, but the proposal for an independent U . S . Government ca­ pability to formulate a national petroleum policv. which was the objective of the Ickes' proposal, regardless of its form, never bore fruition. It was blocked by industry pressures. Thus was woven the basic pattern which has, since that time, formed the basis of Government-industry rela­ tions-the Government to provide the diplomatic and financial support for the industry in its operations abroad , but denuded of any institu­ tional capability to formulate a policy of its own or to oversee the opera­ tions of the American petroleum industry abroad . 6 2

Opposition both within the government and among leaders in the petroleum industry prevented the Ickes plan from inaugurating a new government role in oil and energy. Not until the 1 970s would such proposals again find their way into the mainstream of the policy process. And even in the midst of the energy crisis of the 1 970s, such proposals were wielded with much less conviction. In a study of gov­ ernment-industry relations in the petroleum area one analyst cor­ rectly concludes that the most significant consequences of this series of unsuccessful forays into international petroleum affairs was that the U.S. Government there­ after implicitly left the function of control and supervision over the international petroleum system to the multinational petroleum com­ panies. Unlike the British, French and Dutch, with their governmental interests in BP, CFP and Shell, respectively, the U . S . Government now, 6 2Hearings before the Subcommittee on Multinational Corporations of the Commit­ tee on Foreign Relations, U.S. Senate, 93d Cong., 2d sess., pt. 4, January 30, 1 974, p. 2 .

73

REASONS OF STATE

for the most part, divorced itself from the international petroleum in­ dustry. These events signified as well a virtual cessation of the Govern­ ment's efforts to obtain an information base independent of the com­ panies, which might help it to formulate petroleum policy and take independent action. 6 3

The 1 943 episode was a watershed in industry-government rela­ tions. At that historical moment a departure was contemplated at the highest levels of government from long-established patterns of auton­ omous public and private spheres . The government's impressive war­ time controls over domestic production and distribution were possi­ ble, however, only in the context of a national crisis. The administration of government control was effective primarily because the industry itself was brought into the formation and implementa­ tion of policy. Nonetheless, an aggressive bureaucratic leader was able to assemble an agency to advance extraordinary proposals to bring the government directly into the industry. The fate of his agency reveals the limits of that process, even in times most favorably dis­ posed to institutional innovation. Finally, the Ickes experience reveals another aspect of American state structure. The PAW and its planning pretensions were not suffi­ ciently established to survive the wartime emergency. The PAW, as one study notes, "functioned effectively . . . and . . . even manag[ed] to self-destruct when the war ended."64 The institutional growth and decline of the PAW, where little wartime government capacity sur­ vived the war itself, signals a broader administrative pattern.

ENERGY PLANNING AND ADMINISTRATION

Historically, American planning capacities instituted or augmented during times of war or crisis have been dismantled or radically cut back with the return to normality. This pattern is clear in the energy resource area, with its cycles of state concern and complacency over energy supply and security. At various junctures of perceived short­ ages or threat, and in particular during World War I I , executive officials have taken steps to develop resource planning capacities. These halting and ultimately unsuccessful efforts to develop compre­ hensive capacities within government left a fragmentary , ad hoc sys­ tem of administrative responsibility for energy . 6 3Krueger, United States and International Oil, pp. 5 1 -5 2 . 64Aaron Wildavsky and Ellen Tenebaum, The Politics of Mistrust: Estimating American Oil and Gas Resources (Beverly Hills, Calif. : Sage, 1 98 1 ) , p. 98.

74

The American State and Energy Policies

The most ambitious federal organization for resource planning, which dealt with energy issues but also ranged widely on issues of economic and industrial order, was the National Resources Planning Board. From 1 939 to 1 943 the N RPB consolidated and attempted to coordinate a variety of planning functions within the federal govern­ ment. The agency had its roots in earlier planning bodies that had sprung from the early emergency programs of the New Deal. Its first incarnation was as the National Planning Board. Sympathetic to pro­ posals for a national planning organization, Harold Ickes incorporat­ ed the National Planning Board into the Public Works Administration in 1 93 3 . This planning organization survived several more transfor­ mations to become the focal point for public policy planning, coordi­ nation, and research within the Roosevelt administration. The board received independent status from the Reorganization Act of 1 939, which situated it in the Executive Office of the President, formalizing the operations of the staff. Yet the N RPB still rested precariously within the executive establishment. The agency was not well received in Congress, and indeed it was established and maintained in its early years out of discretionary emergency funds held by the administra­ tion. 65 Composed of a small staff of professional economists and planners, the NRPB had as its central mission to produce reports on manpower, social, and resource policy. It operated as an island of analytic exper­ tise unrelated to the functional responsibilities of executive depart­ ments. Although the N RPB attempted to cooperate with established departments, its influence was manifest primarily in the reports it produced and in periodic meetings of its staff with the president. 66 In this body evolved the rationale and instruments of an interventionist, Keynesian, postwar economic program of full employment. The board also established itself as the most important federal agency involved in gathering information on and in analysis of energy and natural patterns. 67 In 1 93 8 the National Resources Committee, a special planning group under the direction of Secretary Ickes, prepared a comprehen­ sive study entitled Energy Resources and National Policy, which marked the first step toward comprehensive energy planning within the gov­ ernment.68 The report provided the rationale for the activities of the 05Barry D. Karl, Charles E. Merriam and the Study of Politics (Chicago : University of Chicago Press, 1 974), pp. 270- 7 2 . 66Marion Clawson, New Deal Planning: The National Resources Planning Board (Bal­ timore : Johns Hopkins University Press, 1 9 8 1 ) , p. 9. 6 7 I bid . , pp. 1 07-24; Charles E. Merriam, 'The National Resources Planning Board ," Public Administration Review I (Winter 1 94 1 ) , 1 1 6- 2 1 . 68 Clawson , New Deal Planning, p. 1 2 2 .

75

REASONS OF STATE

council. "It is time now to take a larger view," the report argued , "to recognize more fully than has been possible in the past that each of these energy resources affects the others, and that the diversity of problems affecting them and their interlocking relationships require the careful weighing of conflicting interests and points of view."69 In energy resources the N RPB provided a setting for the gathering and organization of expertise that otherwise was widely scattered. With the demise of the NRPB , that professional expertise would again be fragmented in disparate public and private organizations. The NRPB had recruited an impressive group of economists and policy analysts and articulated a strong appeal for planning and coor­ dination. It failed, however, to establish itself firmly in the permanent federal bureaucracy. The proximate cause of its demise was termina­ tion by Congress of its funding. But the more important reasons lay in its claims to policy responsibility, which competed with those of a functional and clientilistic federal bureaucracy that was already well entrenched. Consequently, toward the end of World War II the N RPB was divested of its responsibilities, which came to reside in fragmented form throughout the federal establishment. Economic reports on business and unemployment trends, for example, were placed with the Council of Economic Advisers in 1 946, and science policy found its way into the National Science Foundation in 1 950. As far as energy resources were concerned, production and conservation programs dealing with oil and coal were given to the Department of Interior. 70 The NRPB had responded to Roosevelt's long-standing interest in comprehensive natural resource planning, but it could not gain an institutional foothold to survive even the end of the Roosevelt administration. 7 1 The devolution and dispersion of planning went even further than this. The failure of federal administrative planning and coordinative responsibilities left these activities to organizations outside the estab­ lished structure. In energy and resource planning two developments were important. Long-range analysis of resource security and supply was handled through temporary commissions. The most important example was the president's Materials Policy Commission (the Paley Commission), which in the mid- 1 95os provided a systematic study and appeal for federal planning initiatives but failed to spur signifi69£nergy Resources and National Policy, Report of the Energy Resources Committee to the Natural Resources Committee (Washington, D.C. : GPO, 1 939), p. i . 70CJawson, New Deal Planning, pp. 245-46. 7 1 Arthur M . Schlesinger, Jr. , The Age of Roosevelt-The Coming of the New Deal (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1 959), p. 350.

The American State and Energy Policies

cant government action. The other development, following from the eclipse of the N RPB and a strong federal planning presence, was the growth of resource policy institutions and programs at private foun­ dations. I n fact the nonprofit institution Resources for the Future was a direct descendant of the N RPB and the Paley Commission. 72 The Paley Commission report, a landmark study of national energy problems, was a response to general concern over the depletion of domestic energy fuels. For over a year staff experts gathered from various government departments, business, and several universities. The assembled group of energy specialists, economists, and policy analysts gave the Paley Commission a unique capacity to develop broad , national, and long-term perspectives on energy problems and policy. Such a sustained gathering of professionals, resembling the expert resources brought together in the N RPB, would not be seen again until the 1 970s. Before and after the commission, however, energy policy resided primarily in the Interior Department and in several remote congressional committees. The Paley Commission concluded that demand for energy in the industrial world would vastly increase, doubling by the mid- 1 97os. Conventional sources of energy would fall short in the next few dec­ ades, it argued, requiring the introduction of new energy sources and technologies. While recognizing the unfolding of powerful historic forces, the commission did not recommend major new government powers or responsibilities. Precisely because it cast its analysis in terms of world energy markets and Western security interests, however, it did strongly urge a comprehensive energy policy : "The Commission is strongly of the opinion that the Nation's energy problem must be viewed in its entirety and not as a loose collection of independent pieces involving different sources and forms of energy."73 The com­ mission noted that "this implies no increase in Government activity ; it well might mean less. It does mean that the multiple departments, bureaus, agencies and commissions which deal with separate energy problems must be less compartmentalized . "74 The commission delivered its recommendations to President Truman in June 1 95 2 . Truman in turn gave the National Security Resources Board responsibility for evaluating the commission's find­ ings and making specific proposals. The NSRB and various govern72Clawson, New Deal Planning, pp. 250-5 2 ; Milton Russell, "Energy Politics Looking Back," in Martin Greenberger, Caught Unawares: The Energy Decade in Retrospect (Cambridge, Mass. : Ballinger, i 983), pp. 29-66. 73President's Materials Policy Commission, Resources for Freedom (Washington, D.C. : GPO, i 952), i : 1 29. 74 Ibid . , i : i 29.

77

REASONS OF STATE

ment agencies greeted many of the commission findings with ap­ proval. Disputes broke out over whether government should collect its own energy data or leave that task to the industries themselves. The Interior Department proposed that the commission's obj ectives could best be accomplished through an expansion of responsibilities within that department.75 With the impending departure of the Truman administration , however, substantive organizational reform was not accomplished. The expert professional capacities of the Paley Commission scattered back to separate public and private organizations. As this episode suggests, key U . S . executive officials and experts have called at important junctures for the expansion and centraliza­ tion of energy policy and planning. The most important attempts to establish a high-level, coordinated planning body have come at mo­ ments of public concern over energy supply and security. However, proposals such as those by the Paley Commission and organizational experiments such as the N RPB failed to gain institutional footholds.

CONCLUSION

The organizational structures of the state are explicable in terms of larger historical processes. The crucial explanation for both govern­ ment-business relations and state administration stems from the se­ quence of historical processes. The rise of large-scale business before that of large-scale government bureaucracy in the United States ex­ plains important aspects of subsequent relationships between the two. Also , and in contrast to the European experience, the establishment of representative institutions in the United States preceded the estab­ lishment of national administrative institutions. Although moments of crisis periodically generated proposals and institutional experimentation aimed at developing new state capaci­ ties, these changes did not become a permanent part of the organiza­ tional structure of national government. Existing institutional rela­ tions of business and government preserved a minimalist role for the state. National energy goals were pursued within a fragmentary orga­ nizational context that conferred little unitary power on policy makers and provided few instruments for shaping private behavior. Moments of crisis provided apportunities for executive officials to challenge this institutional regime. Such moments occurred primarily 75Goodwin, "Truman Administration,"

pp.

6o-6 i .

The A merican State and Energy Policies

during the two world wars and the years preceding the Korean War. However, obdurate congressional resistance to planning, the weak bureaucratic position of wartime planning organizations, and the fleeting perception of crisis conspired to debilitate and diffuse pro­ posals for institutional change. Consequently, institutional patterns in the energy area before 1 973 exhibited a striking continuity. There was no centralized administrative body charged with programmatic policy planning, and the instruments of national policy remained lim­ ited and indirect. These institutional circumstances provided the foundation for political maneuvering and policy change as state offi­ cials confronted demands for energy adjustment in the 1 970s.

79

C HAPTER FO UR

The Limits of International Cooperation In the short term, it is possible to conceive any number of bilateral deals that can be made between major consuming countries and major producing countries. In the short term, it is possible to see how particular producing countries can enrich themselves by an unrestrained use of their temporary strong bargaining position. But in the long term, it is bound to lead to disaster for everybody. It is particularly a case where the common interest is also everybody's selfish interest. Secretary of State Kissinger, January 3, 1974

The first line of action for American executive officials in the wake of the oil price shocks of 1 9 7 3 - 7 4 was diplomatic. Led by the State Department, administration officials sought to draw together the in­ dustrial consuming nations in order to confront OPEC and negotiate the rollback or stabilization of oil prices. Despite the persistence of American efforts , these cooperative schemes did not succeed. The I nternational Energy Agency ( I EA), an international organization of modest scope, was created, and it provided stand-by arrangements for emergency oil sharing. But it was unable to play the role American officials had envisaged for it. Programmatic cooperative agreements also failed to take hold during the second oil shock. Government leaders did make pledges in 1 97 9 to reduce oil import levels, but these collective statements of intention largely proved unavailing. Despite the magnitude of energy adjustment problems, and despite what appeared to be a basic mutuality of interests among the indus­ trial consuming nations, policy coordination remained elusive. This chapter seeks to account for the persistence of American efforts to achieve a common solution to those problems and for the failure of those efforts. In Chapter 2 , I argued that international cooperative agreements 80

The Limits of International Cooperation

(international offensive and defensive adjustment) are part of a larger set of adjustment strategies and that the attractiveness of each option is related to the state's domestic capacities for adjustment and the goals that arise from the state's international position. Applied to the case at hand, these considerations suggest that U.S. officials favored the cooperative adjustment strategy for two sorts of reasons. First, government leaders were constrained in their ability to impose the costs of adjustment on the economy, primarily by domestic price con­ trols on petroleum. These controls, enacted prior to 1 97 3 - 7 4 , shielded consumers from the full force of external price increases and gave price windfalls to some segments of the petroleum industry. In response to these interests, Congress preserved and extended price and allocation controls in the years that followed. Swift market-driven adjustment to escalating petroleum prices remained beyond the reach of executive officials. Second, the privileged international position of the United States uniquely favored international strategies of adjustment. Several fea­ tures of the American international position were important. By vir­ tue of its large absolute share of international oil imports , which satis­ fied a small relative share of domestic energy consumption, the United States was favorably positioned to lead Western importing nations in a response to OPEC. Its dominant international political position also gave the United States a broad set of objectives in the oil price revolution. Accepting higher petroleum prices in the West meant accepting slower growth, greater export competition, and bi­ lateralism, and encouraging demands by developing countries for a New International Economic Order-all of which ran counter to American postwar ideals. The United States, in sum , was interested not only in how it adjusted domestically but in how other advanced industrial states adjusted as well. Together, domestic constraints on energy adjustment and a commanding international position led to an initial American emphasis on international strategies of adjustment. The failure of U . S . cooperative proposals was rooted in the dif­ ferences among importing nations in the costs and objectives that attended energy adjustment. Whereas the United States found it par­ ticularly difficult to pass higher oil prices through its domestic econo­ my, other industrial states accepted those higher costs. Consequently, the United States put the pricing issue at the top of its foreign policy agenda, whereas its industrial partners were more concerned with access to supply and favorable diplomatic relations with the Arab states. By adjusting to higher prices and pursuing a different set of objectives, these countries in effect exited from multilateral adjust81

REASONS OF STATE

ment schemes, and what followed was the failure of the American grand design.

OPPORTUNITIES FOR COOPERATION

Prior to the 1 973-74 oil embargo, the industrial nations had not attempted formally to coordinate energy policies. The oil crisis of 1 956-57, for example, had been met by unilateral American action. In response to conflict with Britain, France, and the United States, Egypt nationalized the Suez Canal in July 1 956. This action led to an international crisis that culminated in the invasion of Egypt by Israeli, French, and British forces . Although the invasion was cut short by U.S. pressure, the Suez Canal was blocked, cutting the major trans­ portation route of oil from the Persian Gulf to Europe. The American government, although faced with initial resistance from the Texas Railroad Commission, was able to increase domestic production and, with cooperation from the international oil companies, ease Euro­ pean shortages during the winter of 1 956-5 7 . Because the United States had access to large, readily available domestic reserves, it could compensate for international dislocations and stabilize supplies . 1 By the early 1 970s, however, the American position in the world pe­ troleum market had changed. Domestic production had peaked , and the United States had begun to import larger amounts of foreign oil. In 1 973 the U .S. government was unable to match the shortfall in OPEC production with expansion of its own. The absence of a power capable of countering OPEC restrictions made cooperation among oil-consuming nations more vital if Western governments were to control supplies and prices of international pe­ troleum . A variety of opportunities for cooperation existed to lower or redistribute the costs of oil shortages and higher prices. Both pe­ troleum crises in the 1 970s began with the curtailment of a portion of OPEC production. In 1 973-74 the attempt by Arab OPEC member countries to embargo the United States created a shortfall of about 9.8 percent of available world supplies. 2 The scramble for crude oil by consuming nations, each concerned to maintain its access to imported oil, pushed prices on the spot market dramatically higher and gave ' See Robert 0. Keohane, After Hegemony (Princeton : Princeton University Press, 1 985), PP· 1 69- 1 74. 2Noncommunist production fell from 47.8 billion barrels a day to 43.2 million bar­ rels a day between September and November 1 97 3 . Philip K. Verleger, Jr., Oil Markets in Turmoil: An Economic A nalysis (Cambridge, Mass . : Ballinger, 1 982), p. 3 3 .

The Limits of International Cooperation

OPEC additional opportunities to raise its prices. In 1 979 the tighten­ ing of the world oil market started when Iran curtailed oil production in the wake of its revolution. The shortfall in late 1 978 was approx­ imately 6 . 3 percent of world supply.3 This tightening of supply was , as in the first crisis, followed by the bidding up of prices on the spot market and a rise in official OPEC prices. Competitive bidding by consumer nations on the spot market was even more consequential for OPEC pricing in the second crisis, because by the late 1 970s more international petroleum transactions were being conducted through the market and less through long-term contract.4 In both cases the supply shortfall was small, but the competitive actions it unleashed and the pricing actions it allowed disadvantaged all consuming na­ tions. These supply and pricing problems thus provided substantial opportunities for mutual gains through cooperation. The most immediate form of cooperation would have entailed agreement by the consumer nations to restrain import demand. By abstaining from unilateral efforts to increase supplies, or by going further and actually reducing current import levels, consumers could reduce pressures on already limited world supplies. In the absence of such an agreement, and with each nation pursuing its own short-term objective of gaining access to existing supplies, prices would rise high­ er than when nations agreed to moderate demand. Cooperation could also take the form of longer-term efforts by consumer nations to conserve energy and generate alternative sources of supply. Such efforts would also alter the supply and de­ mand pattern and, by so doing, undercut the pricing power of the cartel. Whereas the cooperative actions noted above involve immedi­ ate steps to limit oil imports, the plan here involves more gradual efforts to address the underlying structure of demand and supply. Collective agreement would increase the efficacy of individual actions by governments. In both cases-whether demand restraint or conservation and pro­ duction initiatives-consuming nations could pursue actions indi­ vidually. Yet unilateral actions would have less overall impact on prices and supplies. Indeed, without agreement each government was likely to pursue separate policies of national gain even as those actions left all nations worse off than they would have been if a collective agreement had been achieved . In this sense the problems of agree3Between October and November noncommunist world production fell from 6 2 . 9 million barrels a d a y t o 58.9 million barrels a day. Ibid . , p. 33. 4See Thomas Neff, "The Changing World Oil Market, " in David A. Deese and Joseph Nye, eds., Energy and Security (Cambridge, Mass . : Ballinger, 1 98 1 ) .

83

REASONS OF STATE

ment by consuming nations over energy adjustment were driven by the dilemma of collective action. 5 These forms of cooperation can be characterized as international offensive strategies of adjustment. The objective is to engage in coop­ erative actions that serve to counter or mitigate unwanted interna­ tional economic change by going to the source of that change . In this case, the strategies involved joint actions by consuming nations to roll back or moderate oil price increases or to engage in indirect bargains (between consuming nations and between those nations and OPEC) to stabilize oil prices and supply. Consuming nations could also take internationally defensive cooperative actions : emergency oil-sharing agreements that spread the burden of reduced oil supplies among industrial importing nations, and international financial agreements that cushion balance of payments problems generated by the higher costs of petroleum imports.6 Such actions do not go to the source of the international economic disturbance ; they aim, rather, at collec­ tively equipping the consumer nations with a means to cope with the most onerous consequences of the disturbance. The United States advanced cooperative proposals along both in­ ·ternational offensive and defensive lines after 1 97 3 . Not only did other consuming nations have strategies that addressed more imme­ diate political and security objectives, however, but the United States itself was unable to generate the domestic changes necessary to make the multilateral cooperative strategy successful .

AMERICAN I NTERNATIONAL ENERGY STRATEGY

The U.S. government was the most persistent and forceful advo­ cate of a cooperative response by industrial consumer nations to ris­ ing oil prices in the early 1 970s. This strategy, articulated by the State Department and Secretary of State Henry Kissinger, initially sought to salvage the world petroleum order by confronting OPEC directly. 5The seminal presentation of the dilemma of collective action is Mancur Olson , The Logic of Collective Action (Cambridge : Harvard University Press, 1 965). The extension of this logic to alliance cooperation is found in Olson and Richard Zeckhauser, "An Economic Theory of Alliances," Review of Economics and Statistics 48 (August 1 966), 266-79. Robert Keohane also presents the difficulties of cooperation by consuming nations after 1 973 as a dilemma of collective action. See l\fter Hegemony, pp. 2 2 3-37. 6 for a discussion of the full range of cooperative issues as noted by an observer at the time, see Walter L. Levy, "World Oil Cooperation or International Chaos," Foreign Affairs 52 (July 1 974) , 690-7 1 3 .

The Limits of International Cooperation

American efforts to counter OPEC directly were blunted by resistance from allies and intractable political constraints at home. Government officials sought to adapt their international strategy after its initial failure, but in due course they grudgingly abandoned it in favor of a sequence of domestic adjustment strategies. American officials showed an interest in an international solution to energy shortages before October 1 973. Urging a united front against OPEC , one State Department official wrote in early 1 973 that the Western importing nations should create an "international authority" that would "avoid cutthroat competition" for available energy sup­ plies. He argued that "such competition could drive prices far higher than we can presently imagine. "7 In April 1 973 the State Department disclosed an ongoing planning effort to establish an international organization of oil-importing countries whose primary purposes would be to allocate petroleum supplies in times of shortage and to develop practices to avoid an "international price war." Although State Department officials differed about the possibilities for a "buyers' cartel," most agreed that cooperative measures would im­ prove the joint bargaining position of industrial nations with OPEC. 8 In responding to the proposal, the French and Japanese governments foreshadowed the positions they would take in the months ahead . France acknowledged the need in principle for some cooperation but argued that European cooperation should come first. The Japanese insisted that producers not be provoked unnecessarily.9 The logic of the American position on the unfolding energy prob� lem was revealed in comments by the State Department's undersecre­ tary for economic affairs, William J . Casey. In a discussion of the energy predicament in June 1 973, Casey acknowledged that rising American consumption of imported oil was aggravating the situation by increasing world demand for Middle Eastern oil and thereby put­ ting upward pressure on prices. But the U.S. government, he main­ tained, favored international responses to the problem and , there­ fore, urged consultation and cooperation in areas such as energy conservation, production, and technology. In effect, Casey argued that although the United States was contributing to the problem, the 7 James E. Akins, "The Oil Crisis : This Time the Wolf Is Here," Foreign Affairs 5 1 (April 1 973), 486. 8See Edward Cowan, "US Plans World Group of Oil-Importing Nations," New York Times, April 1 6, 1 973, p. 28. 90n France see New York Times, May 24, 1 973, p. 75; on Japan, Alexander K. Young, "Energy : View from Tokyo," New York Times, July 2 2 , 1 973, p. 3 :6.

REASONS OF STATE

solution would need to be arrived at jointly among industrial consum­ ing nations. 1 0 Confronted by the October embargo, American officials redoubled their efforts to fashion a united response to OPEC. They emphasized the virtues of multilateral rather than bilateral or regional responses to problems of oil supply and pricing, and they did so for both politi­ cal and economic reasons. Politically, the movement toward deals by individual countries with oil-producing nations, according to State Department officials, threatened to fragment the liberal, multilateral trading system into rival blocks. Addressing his remarks to Euro­ peans, Kissinger argued in December 1 973 that unless cooperative measures were taken to alleviate the crisis , the industrial world would be faced "with a vicious cycle of competition, autarchy, rivalry and depression as led to the collapse of the world order in the thirties." 1 1 The United States, therefore, found itself opposing actions by other governments, particularly the French and the Japanese, to forge bilat­ eral deals with OPEC producers. Bilateral oil trading relationships threatened the postwar norms of nondiscriminatory trade and open markets. The United States agrued , moreover, that the prevailing higher oil prices were neither inevitable or necessary. If consumer nations coop­ erated to limit import demand and stimulate their own production, they could undercut OPEC pricing, and more moderate prices would prevail. This remained the core of American international energy policy throughout the Kissinger period. The American objective, as a senior State Department official noted in congressional testimony, was to "bring about a basic shift in the supply/demand balance in the world oil market. This will reduce our vulnerability to foreign supply disruptions, reduce the ability of a small group of countries to manip­ ulate world oil prices arbitrarily and enable prices to approach their long-term equilbrium level." 1 2 Only through collective action by con­ sumer countries could competitive bidding be avoided and oil prices be moderated or reduced. The American opposition to a fragmented consumer response to IOWilliam D. Smith, "Casey Urges World Group of Oil Users," New York Times, June 2 2 , 1 97 3 , P· 43· 1 1 Quoted in Dankwart A. Rustow and John F. Mugno, OPEC: Success and Prospects (New York: New York University Press, 1 976), p. 5 1 . See also Steven A. Schneider, The Oil Price Revolution (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins U niversity Press, 1 983), p. 257. 1 2Charles Robinson , Undersecretary for Economic Affairs , Department of State, "U.S. International Energy Policy," Hearings before the Subcommittee on Interna­ tional Resources, Food , and Energy , Committee on International Relations, U.S. House of Representatives, 94th Cong. , 1 st sess . , May 1 , 1 97 5 , p. 6

86

The Limits of International Cooperation

OPEC, exemplified in the pursuit of bilateral negotiations , was thus both political and economic. The connection between these arguments was articulated by the American secretary of state in February 1 97 4 : "What we believe is going to be disastrous for the world economy is if bilateral deals are made unconstrained by any general rules of con­ duct, because we believe that this will either stabilize prices at too high a level or bid prices up even higher and in general create a relationship among the major consuming nations of economic warfare-which inevitably will affect, in time, their political relationship." 1 3 Maintain­ ing the integrity of a multilateral approach to international economic problems, preserving political relations among Western industrial na­ tions, and developing a coordinated program to counter OPEC went hand-in-hand. The most public call by the United States for a united, multilateral response came in December 1 973 with Secretary of State Kissinger's speech to the Pilgrims of Great Britain in London. Kissinger argued that the crisis of supply was a long-term problem that would require collaborative programs by consuming nations to develop new meth­ ods of conservation and sources of supply. The secretary of state called for the formation of an Energy Action Group, composed of leading public officials and other representatives from Europe, the United States, and Japan. This group's mandate would be to "define broad principles of cooperation, and it would initiate action in specific areas" such as stimulating conservation and production of energy and joint programs in research and development. 1 4 Kissinger's declara­ tion made the goal of consumer unity a central element of American foreign policy. The Washington Energy Conference To put the American international plan into action, the Nixon ad­ ministration in January 1 974 called for a conference of the industrial consuming nations to meet in Washington the following month. Again Secretary Kissinger, in making the announcement, put for­ ward the arguments for cooperation. Importing nations, he argued, had a common interest in restraining competition for supplies, in collaborating to generate additional sources of energy, and in bar­ gaining with the producing nations not only on price but also on the 1 3 "Secretary Kissinger Discusses Washington Energy Conference," News Release, Bu­ reau of Public Affairs, Department of State, February 1 3 , 1 974. 1 4 "Secretary Kissinger Calls for International Energy Cooperation," Department of State, Selected Documents no. 3 (Washington, D.C., December 1 975 ), p. 4.

REASONS OF STATE

trade and monetary distortions that price increases were creating. In the absence of such cooperation, Kissinger warned of a severe world depression. Such an "economic disaster" would, he argued, be driven by unrestrained competition over limited supplies , the result of indus­ trial nations attempting to solve their problems individually. l s The central challenge Kissinger and other administrative officials confronted in early 1 974 was the movement by other importing na­ tions toward individual deals with producing nations to protect their supplies of oil. American efforts to forestall these developments were renewed after the French government announced it had completed the first phase of a bilateral deal with Saudi Arabia for long-term oil supply. While not directly criticizing that deal , Secretary Kissinger emphasized the American view that "unrestricted bilateral competi­ tion" would be "ruinous for all countries concerned ." He also intro­ duced an implicit warning of retaliation, noting that the United States might seek its own arrangements to protect energy supplies. It was an option, he emphasized , the United States wanted to resist taking. 1 6 The Europeans and Japanese were not eager to endorse the Ameri­ can plan of action if consumer cooperation was to serve as a "counter­ cartel" and thus antagonize the OPEC countries. The French objected most vigorously to the proposed Washington Energy Conference, choosing to pursue instead its own strategy of a European-Arab di­ alogue. Japan and most European governments maintained a middle position between France and the United States. Before the Wash­ ington conference the foreign ministers of the European Community adopted a joint position. Following the French lead, they held that the Washington conference was not to be used to confront the oil-produc­ ing countries, that no new consumer nation organization should be established, that European nations must remain free to establish di­ rect relationships with OPEC producers, and that a formal dialogue between developed and developing countries should be pushed for­ ward. 1 7 Government representatives at the Washington Energy Conference were able to agree upon a modest, collective course of action, its centerpiece an emergency oil-sharing plan. But agreement, modest as JSR. W. Apple, "Nixon ls Planning Appeal on Energy to 2 0 Countries." New York Times, January 4, 1 974, P· J . 1 6 "Global Aspects of Energy Crisis Discussed by Secretary Kissinger, William Si­ mon," News Release, Bureau of Public Affairs, Department of State, January 1 0, 1 974; see also " Kissinger Bids Nations Unite in Crisis," New York Times, January 1 1 , 1 974, p. 1 0 , and Henry Kissinger, Years of Upheaval (Boston : Little, B rown, 1 98 2 ) , p. 902 . 1 7See Robert Lieber, Oil and the Middle East War, Harvard Studies i n International Affairs no. 3 5 ( 1 976), p. 2 1 .

88

The Limits of International Cooperation

it was, was achieved only with substantial American concessions . The United States conceded, for the first time, that its domestic oil sup­ plies would be included in the emergency sharing plan. 1 8 American officials also agreed to delete references to the prohibition of direct deals between consuming and producing nations from the final reso­ lution. The U.S. delegation had proposed a code of conduct to govern bilateral agreements with OPEC producers, but this proposal was eventually dropped. 1 9 Most important, the United States abandoned its original view that an organization of consumer nations could be formed to articulate a common bargaining position and, by so doing, undercut the oil cartel. To get even this limited agreement the Nixon administration was forced to pressure the European governments to eschew the French approach. American officials warned that if the conference failed to reach agreement, U.S. markets and the security commitment to Eu­ rope could not be assured. Addressing the Washington conference, President Richard Nixon argued that "security and economic consid­ erations are inevitably linked and energy cannot be separated from either." Secretary of State Kissinger told German foreign minister Walter Scheel that the United States would reconsider its troop com­ mitment to the Federal Republic unless the Europeans supported the establishment of an Energy Coordinating Group and rejected the French position. 20 The Washington conference produced agreements in four areas. First, the countries agreed on joint action to allocate oil in times of emergency and to pursue energy conservation and R & D. Second, financial and monetary measures were to be developed to avoid com­ petitive currency depreciation and to strengthen international credit facilities. Third, an Energy Coordinating Group was established to implement the agreement. Finally, the countries agreed to engage in a dialogue with the oil-producing nations. In November 1 974 the sixteen-member International Energy Agency was established. Outwardly the Washington conference appeared to be a victory for the American multilateral strategy, yet the success was more one of form than of substance. The French refused to participate in the Energy Coordinating Group and did not join the IEA. Nor did the February conference diminish the movement toward bilateral and regional agreements between European and producing countries. In1 8See discussion in Rustow and Mugno, OPEC: Success and Prospects, p . 59. 1 9Schneider, Oil Price Revolution, p. 260. 20Nixon is quoted in New York Times, February 1 5 , 1 97 4 , p. 4 3 ; for Kissinger see Lieber, Oil and the Middle East War, p. 49.

REASONS OF STATE

deed, the following month the EEC Council of Ministers agreed to a program of economic, technical, and cultural cooperation with twenty Arab countries.2 1 The French strategy of a broad European-Arab accord still had support within the European Community. The gov­ ernments of Europe, particularly the British and the Germans, con­ tinued to pursue a middle course. They were unwilling to risk a breakdown of relations with the United States and therefore agreed to participate in the limited American program of multilateral coop­ eration. But they were also unwilling to abandon the opportunities for bilateral and regional agreements with Arab oil producers led by the French. 2 2 The result was a failure of the American strategy for a unified response by consumer countries to OPEC actions on supply and pricing. The French continued to insist on both the need for a dialogue with the producing nations and the legitimacy of separate oil agreements. The United States, though moderating its objectives to gain agreement on the I EA, continued through 1 974 to search for a unified way to challenge OPEC .

EUROPEAN AND

J APANESE

B I LATERALISM

The central threat to Kissinger's multilateral strategy was that in­ dustrial consuming nations might pursue bilateral deals with OPEC producers, thereby undercutting cooperative efforts at demand re­ straint and collective negotiations over price stability . As importing nations scrambled for separate deals with producing nations, they competed for unilateral advantage, strengthening the position of pro­ ducers and leaving the consuming nations as a whole less well off. Although the pursuit of national advantage was implicit in the French bilateral initiatives, Paris based its opposition to the American multilateral proposals on broader considerations, including a clif­ ference in view concerning the nature of the international petroleum problem. Whereas the United States thought world prices could be lowered , France believed that oil prices were likely to continue to rise and therefore sought to contract for supplies at prevailing prices. 2 3 Moreover, the French government attempted to strengthen its posi­ tion throughout the developing world by its conciliatory policy toward OPEC. French president Georges Pompidou was also able to strength2 1 Schneider, Oil Price Revolution, p. 26 1 . 22Lieber, Oil and the Middle East War, p. 2 3 . 23Schneider, Oil Price Revolution, p . 259.

The Limits of International Cooperation

en his domestic political position by pursuing an antagonistic policy toward the United States. Beyond these broader political considerations which informed the French position, bilateral deals were attractive to consuming nations because they secured sources of supply and , when part of a larger trade package, helped pay for the imports. In the immediate after­ math of the October embargo, for example , the French negotiated a three-year contract with the Saudi Arabian government at a price below the official OPEC price. At the same time the French govern­ ment began negotiations with the Saudis for a twenty-year contract that would guarantee access to enough oil to cover roughly a quarter of French consumption. Through its state-owned company, Elf-Erap, the French also negotiated deals with Libya and Iran. 24 Japan also pursued bilateral deals, seeking not only to gain secure sources of supply but also to promote larger economic projects with oil-producing nations. In early i 974 the Japanese agreed to lend Iraq one billion dollars and to initiate refining, petrochemical, and other industrial projects in exchange for a ten-year contract for crude oil and petroleum products. The Japanese, with an export economy de­ pendent on the maintenance of an open, multilateral system, were more hesitant than the French to compete for bilateral deals with Middle Eastern oil producers. Also, their oil supplies from the Persian Gulf were protected by the United States. Consequently, Japanese policy preserved bilateral access to oil producers but also moderated competition with other industrial countries for specific deals . Britain and West Germany also negotiated projects that exchanged participa­ tion in technical and economic development for oil contracts. 25 The major challenge, however, was from France. The French were pursuing both a national strategy, government-to-government deals for secure supplies of oil, and a European strategy, fostering a di­ alogue between the EEC and Arab countries. The Euro-Arab strategy did not make much headway. Although the EEC Council of Ministers approved a wide-ranging program of economic and technical cooper­ ation in March i 974, the British vetoed a proposal for EEC negotia­ tions with the Arab countries. Several meetings were held in an effort to institute a Euro-Arab dialogue, but they yielded no substantive agreements . 26 As oil supplies became more available and prices stabilized in 24Lieber, Oil and the Middle East War, p. 30 ; Schneider, Oil Price Revolution, 25Schneider, Oil Price Revolution, pp. 255-56. 26Lieber, Oil and the Middle East War.

p.

255.

REASONS OF STATE

mid- 1 974, the rush to secure direct contracts with producers slowed . Even the French, by the end of the year, were not eager for additional bilateral contracts, which had become in many instances more costly than oil purchased through the multinational oil companies. Bilateral agreements increasingly became a means to address balance of pay­ ments problems, with consuming nations looking for opportunities to market their goods among OPEC producers. In June 1 974, for exam­ ple, the French signed a ten-year, $4 billion agreement (later in­ creased to $7 billion) with Iran for a package of economic and pe­ troleum development projects. Oil was not directly involved in this deal.27 Although the threat of bilateralism was declining, U.S. executive officials continued to seek to put pressure on OPEC in order to mod­ erate oil prices. Some success was achieved, not by collective restraint on the part of the consumer countries but through direct American pressure on Saudi Arabia. By September of 1 974, however, Saudi efforts to continue a price moratorium had collapsed , and surpluses were countered not by a reduction of prices but by a lowering of production. At this juncture the United States again sought to bring consumer pressure on OPEC to moderate oil prices. As before, the only leverage American officials were able to exert was the threat of collaborative actions by consumer nations to alter market forces through conservation and the development of alter­ native sources. In November 1 974 Kissinger proposed new measures for cooperation among consumer nations. The first element of Kiss­ inger's proposal was a set of safeguard measures to protect consumer nations from financial adjustment problems as well as to provide stand-by emergency oil-sharing arrangements. These measures were incorporated into the I EA. Second, Kissinger proposed a new set of conservation goals for the consuming nations. He proposed that the industrial nations take steps to reduce consumption of imported pe­ troleum by 20 percent. Indicating that the United States was still intent on undercutting the pricing power of OPEC, Kissinger noted that his proposals could provide the conditions in two or three years that would make it "increasingly difficult for the cartel to operate."28 A year after his original London speech, then, Kissinger was still pursuing an international strategy that sought to unite the consumer nations. The original American position had envisaged immediate 2 7 Schneider , Oil Price Revolution, p. 2 6 2 . 2B Quoted in B usiness Week, January 1 3 , 1 9 7 5 , p . 6 7 .

92

The Limits of International Cooperation

steps to confront OPEC and hinged on consumer nations not nego­ tiating bilateral agreements with oil producers. The new American position was directed at a longer-term effort to alter the underlying patterns of production and consumption. This shift in emphasis led State Department officials to accept a broader dialogue between pro­ ducers and consumers over the stabilization of prices.

B ROADENING THE DIALOGUE

American officials now emphasized the need for an agreement be­ tween consuming nations and oil producers on a long-range floor price or minimum selling price (MSP) . The price of oil would come down, these officials now argued, only with long-term efforts in con­ servation and the development of alternatives to oil. Efforts of this sort would require massive investments by the industrial countries. Such investments, however, could be jeopardized if OPEC manipu­ lated prices : oil prices could be brought just below the level necessary to encourage the production of alternatives. To take the extraordi­ nary investment measures needed to shift production and consump­ tion patterns, therefore, the industrial nations needed to agree among themselves, and with OPEC , to stabilize prices.29 The United States would facilitate a dialogue between consuming and producing nations in order to establish stable international oil prices. To protect Western investments in energy development, Kiss­ inger proposed a common floor price for oil. "Paradoxically," Kissin­ ger argued, "in order to protect the major investments in the indus­ trialized countries that are needed to bring the international oil prices down, we must ensure that the price of oil on the domestic market does not fall below a certain price. " He also proposed an international consortium, to pool capital for energy investment as well as to conduct joint research and development. With these agreements among con­ suming nations, Kissinger envisaged more constructive negotiations with OPEC on prices, stable markets, and petrodollar recycling. The bargain Kissinger sought to strike with OPEC turned on this logic : OPEC should "accept a significant price reduction now in return for 29See discussion of this policy shift in Rustow and Mugno, OPEC: Success and Pros­ pects, pp. 56-57. The scheme was championed by the State Department's assistant secretary, Thomas 0 . Enders, and presented by Enders at a meeting of OECD repre­ sentatives in April 1 975. Its rationale is presented in Enders, "OPEC and the Industrial Countries : The Next Ten Years," Foreign Affairs 53 (July 1 975), 625-37.

93

REASONS OF STATE

stability over a longer period , or they can run the risk of a dramatic break in prices when the program of alternative energy sources be­ gins to pay off."30 American officials began to campaign for a floor price on oil, but the proposal met with protracted debate in the I EA . Europe (except the United Kingdom) and Japan worried that an effective minimum selling price would thwart any long-term erosion in oil prices. They also feared that OPEC might construe such a proposal as political confrontation . With this consideration in mind , for instance, the J apa­ nese foreign minister claimed that the price plan was "beyond the bounds of reason."3 1 Disagreements also broke out over what the floor price would ac­ complish. Behind the guarantee of a minimum selling price for oil, governments were to proceed to develop major new sources of ener­ gy. Yet the sources of energy to be developed and the effectiveness of the investment programs remained uncertain. Most important, con­ flict over the MSP hinged on the divergent gains that would accrue to energy-rich and energy-poor countries within the IEA. In effect, the MSP was a potential transfer of income to the energy-rich in return for the expectation of diffuse collective benefits : a better energy bal­ ance with OPEC. This conflict became more pronounced with the refusal of the United Kingdom and Norway to offer pledges of good faith concerning access by others to their domestic oil resources in return fo r agreement on the MSP. 32 Meanwhile, the credibility of the U . S . bargaining position was undercut by the continuing presence of American price controls on domestic oil. The I EA eventually hammered out agreement on an MSP in Sep­ tember 1 976. The agreement, however, was largely devoid of signifi­ cance. The floor price for oil was set at $7 a barrel, far below prevail­ ing world market levels. While proponents of the MSP could claim victory, few countries believed that prices would ever fall to such a low level, and though the agreement contained provisions for review of the program's implementation, such reviews have not taken place. Nor have there been efforts to move the price floor upward to reflect 30Address by Henry Kissinger, News Release, Bureau of Pu blic Affairs, U .S. Depart­ ment of State, February 3, 1 97 5 · 3 1 Arabinda Ghosh, OPEC, the Petroleum Industry, and United States Energy Policy (Lon­ don : Quorum, 1 983), p. 1 55 . 32See Peter F. Cowhey, The Problems of Plenty: Energy Policy and International Politics (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1 985), pp. 253-54. See also Ann-Margaret Walton, "Atlantic Relations; Policy Coordination and Conflict : Atlantic Bargaining over Energy," International Affairs 5 2 (April 1 976), 1 80-96 ; and Robert 0 . Keohane, "The I nternational Energy Agency : State Power and Transgovernmental Politics," International Organization 3 2 (Autumn 1 978), 939- 4 0.

94

The Limits of International Cooperation

current costs of production . 33 An agreement may have been reached , but it could not mask basic disagreements among IEA members over the proper course of energy adj ustment. As the I EA continued to search for a meaningful agreement on a floor price plan, American officials shifted their strategy yet again. I n M a y 1 97 5 Kissinger placed oil price and supply issues on the agenda of the proposed dialogue between developed and developing na­ tions. 34 Since the earliest moments of the October embargo , Ameri­ can executive officials had resisted efforts to place energy issues with­ in a larger set of global economic negotiations . U . S . officials, while agreeing in principle to France's call for a dialogue with the oil-pro­ ducing nations, argued that prior cooperation by consuming nations was necessary. I n the wake of OPEC's success, however, government representatives from developing nations had begun to articulate an agenda for negotiations that would include other raw materials and broader international economic issues. Consequently, when the State Department's floor price initiative failed to attract support among consuming nations, the United States became interested in using the evolving N orth-South dialogue as a device for engaging OPEC on issues of price and supply.35 The American floor price proposal gave legitimacy to the demands of other commodity producers for cartel pricing agreements. In an­ nouncing the shift in American position in May 1 97 5 , Kissinger ac­ knowledged that international agreements covering other raw mate­ rials would be considered on a "case-by-case basis. " In this regard the American secretary of state proposed the creation of three separate commissions to cover energy, nonenergy raw materials, and economic development aid. This proposal met with resistance from OPEC gov­ ernments ; later in the year Kissinger, in a major UN address, pro­ posed an elaborate set of global economic initiatives ranging from financial aid programs and commodity agreements to a new, special $ 1 0 billion I M F lending facility to stabilize the export earnings of 33Cowhey, Problems of Plenty, p. 254 . 34The willingness of the United States to participate in a preparatory conference between producers and consumers was linked to an American-European understand­ ing that steps would be taken to increase consumer solidarity. The change in the U.S. position, however, was not dependent on the promise of specific agreements within the I EA . See Walton, "Atlantic Bargaining over Energy ," p. 1 93 . The new American posi­ tion was outlined by the secretary of state in two speeches on May 27 and 28, 1 97 5 . See Clyde H. Farnsworth, "Kissing er Offers New U . S . Aid Plan," New York Times, May 29, 1 97 5 , pp. 1, 1 9. Domestic debate over the merits of engaging in the so-called North­ South dialogue is discussed in Geoffrey Barraclough, "Wealth and Power: The Politics of Food and Oil," New York Review of B ooks, August 7, 1 975. 35Schneider, Oil Price Revolution, pp. 268-69.

95

REASONS OF STATE

developing countries. These various programs were to be financed jointly by OPEC and the industrial countries. Talks got under way in Paris as representatives of developed and developing countries met at the Conference on International Economic Cooperation (CIEC). 36 These efforts to manage commodity markets internationally did not, however, provide any headway on the American effort to induce OPEC to moderate or reduce oil prices. The United States opposed commodity schemes involving the maintenance of prices at levels nec­ essary to achieve significant transfers of wealth. Nor would the con­ sumer nations accept OPEC's proposal for the indexation of oil prices to the price of producer goods. The demise of the U.S. international adjustment strategy came in November 1 976. On the eve of a meeting of the CIEC, Kissinger sent word to the representatives of other in­ dustrialized countries conceding that "there is no negotiable package which the industrialized countries could accept and which would also present sufficient inducement to OPEC to refrain from a substantial oil price increase over several years, given the lack of leverage by consumers over oil prices."37 American efforts to orchestrate a united response to OPEC by consumer countries, which had evolved over the preceding three years but had constantly sought the moderation or rollback of cartel prices, were at an end.

THE

IEA

AND THE SECOND

OIL CRISIS

In the three years following the October 1 973 embargo American administration officials pursued an international offensive strategy that sought to unite the consumer nations and, by so doing, develop the economic and political leverage to return oil prices to more mod­ erate and stable levels. At the center of consumer unity was to be the International Energy Agency. The IEA, however, did not play the role that American officials had envisaged . Governments in Europe and Japan resisted efforts to use it as a vehicle to confront OPEC . The IEA did manage to develop a more modest mission that revolved around agreements on emergency oil sharing and energy informa­ tion sharing. In effect, the agency came to represent consumer coun­ try efforts to develop international defensive measures to guard 36The background and evolution of international bargaining over commodity price stabilization schemes and other issues within the North-South dialogue are covered in Robert L . Rothstein, Global Bargaining: UNCTAD and the Quest for a New International Economic Order (Princeton : Princeton University Press, 1 979). 37New York Times, December 14, 1 976. See also Rothstein, Global Bargaining, p . 47 n. 1 6.

The Limits of International Cooperation

against future emergencies. Yet as we shall see, in 1 979 cooperation between the consuming nations remained, for the most part, elusive. A central mission of the IEA was the development of an emergency oil-sharing agreement. The task was to develop an agreed set of pro­ cedures between the major international oil companies, the IEA, and member-governments for the sharing and management of oil sup­ plies at moments of extreme shortage. The I EA also began to develop the organizational capacity to monitor international oil markets and to set aggregate oil-import targets for member-countries as a whole. 3 8 The stand-by agreements and monitoring activities of the IEA did not significantly moderate the scramble for supplies in the midst of the 1 979 oil crisis. This crisis, triggered by the cutback of .Iranian production, resulted in a reduction of about 2 million barrels per day on international oil markets in late 1 97 8 . Although the aggregate loss of production was modest, approximately 6.3 percent of the noncom­ munist world total, the rush by governments and companies to secure supplies was even more intense than in 1 973-74. International oil companies, independent refiners, and governments all acted to in­ crease their stocks. In the face of uncertainty, demand for oil on the spot market rose quickly, pushing prices to extraordinary levels, far out of proportion to actual shortages. 39 As in the earlier oil crisis, prices were driven by short-term, com­ petitive responses to very small shortfalls in production. The Iranian cutback, which caused prices to climb on the spot market, was fol­ lowed in January 1 979 by the announcement that Saudi Arabia would reduce production to meet a ceiling set by the government. Produc­ tion dropped only slightly (by approximately 500,000 barrels a day for several weeks in February) and was restored in March, but the effect on prices was dramatic. The spot price for Saudi Arabian crude rose 64.5 percent, from $ 1 9.09 to $3 1 .40 a barrel, during February and dropped back to $25 .04 a barrel in late March40 (see Table 4). 38Keohane, " I nternational Energy Agency, " p p . 929-5 2 , and Keohane, After Hegemony, pp. 2 24-3 7 . Other discussions of I EA activities include Cowhey, Problem of Plenty, chap. 8 ; Walton, "Atlantic Relations" ; Wilfred Kohl, "The International Energy Agency : The Political Context," in J. C. Hurewitz, ed. , Oil, the Arab-Israel Dispute and the Industrial World (Boulder, Colo . : Westview, i 976); Mason Willrich and Melvin A. Con­ ant, "The International Energy Agency: An I nterpretation and Assessment," American Journal of International Law 7 1 (April i 977), i 99- 2 2 3 . 39See Daniel B. Badger, Jr., "The Anatomy of a 'Minor Disruption' : Missed Oppor­ tunities," in Alvin L. Alm and Robert J. Weiner, Oil Shock: Policy Response and Implemen­ tation (Cambridge, Mass . : Ballinger, i 984), pp. 33-53. See also Badger and Robert Belgrave, Oil Supply and Price: What Went Right in 1980 ? Energy Paper no. 2 (London : Royal I nstitute of International Affairs, i 98 2 ) , p. 1 07 ; Keohane, After Hegemony, pp. 2 2 6-2 8 . 40Verleger, Oil Markets i n Turmoil, p p . 34-35.

97

REASONS OF STATE

Table 4. Spot market and official oil prices, January 1 978-April 1 980 (cost per barrel in U . S . dollars)

1 978 Jan. April July Oct. 1 979 Jan. April July Oct. 1 980 Jan. April

Spot Market Value

Official Contract Price

$ 1 3.7 1 1 4. 1 3 1 4. 1 4 1 5 .42 1 9. 7 1 2 7 .65 34·35 35.79 38.32 32.27

$ 1 4. 20 1 3 .95 1 3 .90 1 3 .95 1 4 .73 1 8.42 2 3 .4 1 24. 1 9 33 · 1 0 35.65

SouRcE. Petroleum Intelligence Weekly, Special Supplement, Febru­ ary 2, 1 98 1 .

Although supply-side changes were small, they triggered demand­ side actions that were large and consequential. The uncertainty cre­ ated by the suddenness of the cutbacks and the relatively low inven­ tories that oil users possessed at the moment of the disruptions en­ couraged competitive bidding for supplies. At the moment that sup­ plies were tightening up, short-term demand for those supplies increased . Efforts b y individual buyers t o increase inventories escalated prices out of line with the loss of production . I ndeed, the shortfall in pro­ duction was very brief. By the third quarter of 1 979 world oil produc­ tion was actually higher than it had been the previous year, and con­ sumption was only marginally higher. Iranian production did decline in late 1 978 and in 1 979, but other Middle Eastern oil producers, particularly Saudi Arabia (in the third and fourth quarter of 1 979) and I raq, raised production over the previous year's level.4 1 Efforts by the IEA and its member-governments to address the collective dilemma of competitive bidding were unavailing.42 The I EA urged in March 1 979 that consumer countries cut their imports by 2 million barrels a day. Yet individual governments were not held to specific targets, and the incentives for demand restraint were not 4 1 U.S. Department of Energy, Energy I nformation Administration, " 1 979 I nterna­ tional Energy Annual" (Washington, D.C., August 1 980) , p. 1 1 . 42Indeed , many actions by governments tended to increase market pressures. The United States, in May 1 979, imposed a $5 per barrel subsidy for distillate imports. This subsidy, imposed without warning, was roundly criticized by IEA member-countries and immediately drove up prices on the spot market. At the same time, oil stocks under the control of the governments of the consuming nations could have been released on to commercial markets, mitigating the competitive scramble for supplies. See Badger, "Anatomy of a Minor Crisis."

The Limits of International Cooperation

strengthened. Imports by IEA countries in fact increased in i 979, by about i percent over i 978 levels. Nor was the IEA's emergency shar­ ing agreement of use. That agreement, to redistribute oil supplies to IEA members with more than a 7 percent shortfall of supply, was designed to protect countries from selective embargoes. In 1 979 shortfalls for individual countries hinged on such circumstances as the existence of price controls and stockpile arrangements. The shar­ ing of oil would at least partially have rewarded countries with less efficient import policies.43 The consuming nations also used the occasion of their annual eco­ nomic summit meeting, held in Tokyo in June i 979, to agree to country targets for oil imports. Prior to the summit the French gov­ ernment, in contrast to its actions in i 974, called for quantitative limits on oil imports, coordination of emergency stockpiling pro­ grams, and joint control of prices on the spot market. At a meeting of the European Council, however, government representatives could agree only on the monitoring of the spot market and refused to commit themselves to national import targets. During the Tokyo sum­ mit and in later negotiations, Japan and West Germany forcefully opposed controls on spot market purchases and national import lev­ els. Japan was eager to avoid international obligations that might prevent it from finding new supply contracts, which it needed as contracts with the major oil companies terminated . West Germany was suspicious of controls on the market and was convinced that the inevitable cheating on any agreement would be sufficient to drive prices up anyway.44 Agreement at the Tokyo summit on national targets to limit oil imports was possible only when pledges gave governments large mar­ gin for discretion. A compromise was eventually concluded : the United States, Canada, and Japan agreed to national ceilings, and the European governments agreed to reach individual national targets later. Following the summit the United States continued its attempt to persuade other consuming nations to share the burden of supply reductions.45 Yet the United States itself was having difficulty reduc­ ing imports, and the target agreements were of limited effectiveness in coping with the immediate problems of OPEC supply reductions. 43See Keohane, After Hegemony, pp. 2 2 8-29. 44Cowhey, Problems of Plenty, p. 274. 45See George de Menil and Anthony M . Solomon, Economic Summitry (New York : Council on Foreign Relations, 1 983), pp. 28-29. Subsequent U.S. efforts took place primarily through the IEA. See "A Push for Unity against OPEC," B usiness Week, December 3 , 1 979, pp. 36-3 7 .

99

REASONS OF STATE

The IEA and member-governments were ill-equipped to deal with the problem of collective action. As a result governments, oil com­ panies , and marketers followed the incentives of the moment. Short­ term demand had the effect of doubling oil prices. The OPEC cartel followed the spot market, moving official prices higher as well. After the disruption ended and supplies had been stabilized, the price of oil remained at the higher level. 46

CONCLUSION

The rise in oil prices in 1 973-74 and in 1 979 began with the curtail­ ment of a portion of OPEC production. The manner in which con­ sumer nations responded to these disruptions in supply had a decisive impact on the magnitude of the price increases. The scramble by state officials and oil companies to ensure supplies pushed prices higher and reinforced the market position of the oil cartel. Opportunities for cooperation existed at both moments of crisis , but cooperation re­ mained elusive. The interests of states in a multilateral strategy to cope with oil shortages diverged, and these divergences were related to differences in the capacities of those governments to pursue other strategies . The interest in and fate of international strategies of adjustment can be understood when those strategies are j uxtaposed with the other oppor­ tunities states had for action. In the American case , other oppor­ tunities were not immediately available. Price controls constrained the ability of American executive officials to impose higher costs of import­ ed oil on the domestic economy. Moreover, foreign policy officials could conduct an international strategy of adjustment without getting immediately involved in the larger and unwieldy decision-making process. At the same time the international position of the U nited States provided opportunities to seek international adjustment solu­ tions-solutions that accorded with a broader set of hegemonic politi­ cal objectives. Other consuming nations, however, were able to pass 46A third oil supply disruption, precipitated in 1 980 by the I ran-Iraq war, did not have the same effects on prices as the two previous disruptions even though the fall in the world production involved was actually greater than the production losses of 1 979. Over a two-month period, world oil production fell by 3.6 million barrels a day from 59.5 to 55.9 million barrels a day. Yet oil prices did not increase as in the earlier crises. Although an increase in Saudi production was important in offsetting these losses, Verleger argues that the most important factor was the high level of consumer stocks. "Stocks were high in the fall of i 980, and oil companies probably welcomed the oppor­ tul'lity to work them off." Oil Markets in Turmoil, p. 38.

I OO

The Limits of International Cooperation

prices through their economies and were better equipped to pursue separate deals with oil producers. The construction of multilateral schemes to share the costs of adj ustment and to moderate price in­ creases, at least in the 1 973-74 crisis, was less pressing than other objectives : access to supply and favorable diplomatic relations with Arab states. Moreover, while U.S. officials had stronger incentives and a favorable international position from which to pursue an interna­ tional offensive strategy, their inability to adjust to higher prices do­ mestically prevented them from satisfying their international obliga­ tions. The persistence of price controls indirectly encouraged the growth of oil imports. Even if other nations had agreed to a collab­ orative program of import restraint, the United States could not have lived up to its part of the bargain. This argument is not a complete theory of the determinants of international collaboration. The industrial importing nations con­ fronted divergent international and domestic constraints and oppor­ tunities , which in turn influenced national preferences for specific forms of international agreements. But states with different interna­ tional and domestic capacities may still participate in multilateral co­ operative schemes. The French, for example, were much more in­ terested in coordinating national oil-import levels during the second oil crisis than during the first. Moreover, some of the conflicts be­ tween the industrial nations over energy adjustment were rooted in differences only indirectly related to state capacity. Lines of conflict over the MSP, for instance, were primarily drawn between countries with and those without significant indigenous sources of energy. I focus here, that is to say, on a particular set of constraints and oppor­ tunities-variables that cannot explain the entire course of coopera­ tion and noncooperation in energy adjustment during the 1 970s. These variables are helpful, however, in explaining important ele­ ments of the international struggle over energy adj ustment: the initial interest of American officials in an international solution to OPEC petroleum pricing; the opportunities for other industrial nations, particularly France, to "exit" from these multilateral schemes; and the inability of the United States to fulfill its leadership role by controlling domestic imports of petroleum. I t is difficult to disentangle the conflicts over energy among indus­ trial nations in the 1 970s from larger foreign policy and economic circumstances. American international strategy sought to advance goals beyond the immediate problem of energy adjustment. French opposition to that strategy was also wrapped up in a larger and well­ established objection to American leadership. Differences among IOI

REASONS OF STATE

states concerning the nature of relationships with the countries of the Middle East served to widen the breach between Washington and other Western capitals. The international strategies that American officials articulated and reformulated between 1 973 and 1 976 were only a subset of a larger variety of strategies available to states. U . S . officials were drawn to the multilateral approach because, if successful, it would have the virtue of lowering and distributing the costs of acljustment across the indus­ trial world-an option all the more attractive for executive officials ill­ equipped to impose costs on their own economy. At the same time Secretary Kissinger was intent on removing OPEC from a position of prominence in the international system. OPEC had challenged the West with higher oil prices. With higher energy costs came slower growth, export competition, greater bilateralism, and unprecedented demands by developing countries for fundamental reform of interna­ tional economic relations-all events that ran afoul of the principles upon which American postwar leadership was based. The failure of the international collaborative proposals advanced by the State Department during the 1 973-74 crisis was rooted in the "exit" by the Japanese and the Europeans, particularly the French, from those agreements. French opposition to the American strategy was informed by a variety of factors. The larger issues of political leadership within the Western alliance, divergent foreign policy posi­ tions on the Middle East conflict, and European regional goals all formed part of the backdrop for French intransigence in the face of American multilateral initiatives.47 Beneath these political considera­ tions were divergent national economic and political capabilities. While imports in the United States continued to rise, the French government in 1 975 moved to limit annual oil imports to about 1 0 percent below the level o f the previous year.48 The Ford administra­ tion, in the same year, sought to limit oil imports by use of a tax ; this import fee was an attempt to pressure Congress into decontrolling oil prices, but the effort did not succeed and imports continued to rise. The French were also well-equipped to negotiate bilaterally with oil producers. Through state-owned oil companies the French govern­ ment could negotiate secure contracts of oil directly, even in the face of overall shortages and dislocations in world markets. Because of 47The most telling presentation of the French view on American international ener­ gy strategy came in the remarks by Minister of Foreign Affairs Michel Jobert at the 1 974 Washington Energy Conference. See Embassy of France, "Statement by His Ex­ cellency Michel Jobert" (Washington, D.C., February 1 1 , 1 974) . 4 B Rustow and Mugno, OPEC: Success and Prospects, p. 55 .

1 02

The Limits of International Cooperation

these and similar differences in political objectives and national ca­ pabilities, the Europeans and the Japanese did not find compelling the multilateral schemes pursued by the United States during the 1 973-74 oil crisis. Finally, the United States itself was not able to develop the domestic responses that would have given its international strategies more credibility.49 In particular, the United States was not able to curb its own consumption of imported oil. 50 European demand for oil dropped from an average of 1 5 .4 million barrels a day in 1 973 to roughly 1 3 million barrels a day in 1 978, the year preceding the second oil shock. During the same period Japanese consumption of imported oil also fell, if slightly less. U.S. oil consumption, however, rose substantially : oil imports went from an average 6.3 million bar­ rels a day in 1 973 to 8 . 2 million in 1 97 8 (and rose again in 1 979) . 5 1 American executive officials attempted to redress the nation's prob­ lems of adjustment by confronting OPEC directly over the pricing issue. Other industrial importing countries, with different capabilities and policy objectives , found alternative responses, and in the end the United States was also forced to look for other responses . When the oil shortages and dislocations of 1 973-74 receded, the price conse­ quences remained , and the United States found itself looking for domestic (as well as international) means to adjust to the new reality . 49Kissinger noted this failure. "When I was in office, we helped develop the I nterna­ tional E nergy Agency, which was supposed to bring together the industrial democracies in a program of conservation, alternative su pplies and emergencies against embargoes. [He went on to argue that) I think it is safe to say that this agency has not been able to achieve the goals set for it, largely because the United States did not carry out its share of the necessary conservation . " U . S . Senate, Committee on Energy and Natural Re­ sources, Subcommittee on Energy and Regulation, "Status of Federal Energy Conser­ vation," Hearings, April 4, 1 97 7 , 95th Cong. , 1 st sess . , p. 5 . 50An analyst writing in 1 976 noted the influence of domestic constraints o n the waning vigor of American energy diplomacy. The retreat of U . S . international efforts "lies in the relatively weak position of the United States regarding the development of its domestic energy policy. Domestic linkages, the political constraint which stops gov­ ernments from purusing a policy of restraint through pricing, have been particularly apparent in the United States." Walton, "Atlantic Bargaining over Energy ," p. 1 95 . 5 1 BP Statistical Review of World Energy, June 1 984, p. 1 6 .

1 03

CHAPTER FIVE

The Limits of State Building Only the expert knowledge of private economic interest groups in the field of "business" is superior to the expert knowledge of the bureaucracy. This is so because the exact knowledge of facts in their field is vital to the economic existence of businessmen. Errors in official statistics do not have direct economic consequences for the guilty official, but errors in the calculation of a capitalist enterprise are paid for by losses, perhaps by its existence. The "secret," as a means of power, is, after all , more safely hidden in the books of an enterpriser than it is in the files of public authorities. For this reason alone authorities are held within narrow barriers when they seek to influence economic life in the capitalist epoch. Very frequently the measures of the state in the field of capitalism take unforeseen and unintended courses, or they are made illusory by the superior expert knowledge of interest groups. Max Weber, 1 946

The initial American response to the 1 97 3 price shocks was an attempt led by the State Department to forge a common front among Western industrial nations. As these international efforts increasingly were frustrated, executive officials sought a second avenue of adjust­ ment that entailed redefining the responsibility of the state for do­ mestic energy planning and production. In effect, various sets of executive officials and politicians attempted to break out of the in­ stitutional constraints that left the state with few instruments or capac­ ities within the energy sector. In this chapter I analyze the various attempts by government offi­ cials to redefine the state's role in the energy sector. I look at the problem of information gathering and competence in the energy area ; at the attempts to impose a government presence in the energy sector through a federal petroleum corporation ; at attempts to create

The Limits of State B uilding

mechanisms for energy financing; and at the establishment of the synfuels corporation. These efforts were largely unsuccessful. At each juncture, and in ways reminiscent of failed state-building proposals of earlier historical periods, the proposals were blocked-by Congress, by interest groups, and by divisions within the executive branch itself. The failure to build additional state capacity to cope with the ener­ gy dilemmas of the 1 970s was not due to the absence of imaginative proposals. I nitiatives to expand the state's role quickly became part of the politics of energy adjustment. These initiatives sought both to create new realms of government planning capacity and to establish a direct state presence in the energy sector. Three important proposals came from various sets of . executive officials. The earliest effort, during the Nixon administration , sought to increase the energy information and expertise available to policy makers. This was Proj ect Independence. Another was the Ford ad­ ministration's $ 1 00 billion Energy Resource Finance Corporation, which attempted to create a capacity for the direct financing of ener­ gy production and exploration. The final proposal, the Carter admin­ istration's Synfuels Corporation, drew on similar initiatives advanced in earlier decades and had a legacy of congressional sponsorship. This earlier history helps explain why the Synfuels Corporation was the only proposal to be implemented . A final proposal , to create a state­ owned petroleum corporation , came from several members of Congress. The constraints on state building can be understood at several lev­ els. These proposals provoked opposition from a wide variety of in­ terest groups and officials. Executive officials and congressional pol­ iticians, maintaining a commitment to market mechanisms, resisted them, and groups within the energy industry itself actively registered their opposition as well. Opposition within the executive policy estab­ lishment undercut passage on several occasions. In the policy battles that were waged, the proponents of an expanded state role in energy planning, financing, and production consistently lost. It is important to situate these policy stuggles within a broader historical and institutional setting. In the first place, the scarcity and fragmentation of bureaucratic expertise and operational capabilities provided few bases on which to build new government powers and responsibilities. Proponents of the various state-building designs were scattered across the federal establishment and only infrequently en­ joyed strong presidential support. Moreover, the earliest state-build­ ing efforts centered on the development of analytic or informational capacities, without which ambitious programs that involved a direct 1 05

REASONS OF STATE

government role in energy financing or production could not pro­ ceed . I ndeed, the struggle over a greater state role within the energy sector hinged in many respects on disagreements over the nature of energy markets, particularly supply and demand elasticities. P ROJECT

I N DEPENDENCE

On October 1 7 , 1 973, the Arab oil producers announced their boy­ cott of American and Dutch markets. On November 7 President Rich­ ard Nixon addressed the nation on the subject of the emerging energy crisis. He announced immediate steps to help mitigate fuel shortages and stimulate domestic energy prod uction . He also an­ nounced a large, long-range program . Project independence, draw­ ing on the spirit of the Manhattan and Apollo projects, had the goal of developing "the potential to meet our own energy needs without depending on any foreign energy sources" by the end of the decade. 1 Project I ndependence articulated a goal more than it set out concrete proposals. The program was to include both technological and non­ technological initiatives, incorporating the proposals N ixon had made in June 1 973 for a massive program of energy research and develop­ ment. Short on specifics, the project held out the intention of a more inclusive energy policy, giving research and development a role in this larger strategy. The key proposal was a major, wide-ranging analytic study to guide national spending and allocative decisions. The Project Independence Evaluation System While statutory authority for the creation of a Federal Energy Ad­ ministration was pending, and while the larger proposal for a Depart­ ment of Energy and Natural Resources was blocked in Congress, Nixon established a small Federal Energy Office to begin initial policy analysis. Although organizational changes were constant, officials from executive agencies were brought together in the FEO, and later the Federal Energy Administration , to launch analytical studies. The major study, known as the Project I ndependence Evaluation System (PIES) , was an attempt to create a broad-based and systematic model of energy demand and supply, with the intention of making projec' President Richard M. Nixon, "Address on the E nergy Emergency," November 7 , 1 97 3 , i n Presidential Energy Statements, Committee Print, Committee on I nterior and Insular Affairs, U . S . Senate (Washington, D . C . , 1 97 3 ) , p . 86.

1 06

The Limits of State B uilding

tions of the nation's energy future. Led by John Sawhill, recruited from the Office of Management and Budget, and Eric Zausner, re­ cruited from the Department of I nterior, the system became the first full-scale energy study undertaken within the American government. The task was to evaluate the nation's energy problems and specify alternative policy options. 2 The Project I ndependence study was set in motion under severe time constraints. Its analysis was to undergird a national energy pro­ gram, and the pressure for such a program was very great. The report was to be completed by the fall of 1 9 74. With a premium on time, the project gathered experts and specialists from all quarters of the federal establishment. Represented in the project, for example, were officials recruited from the Office of Management and Budget, the Environmental Protection Agency and the departments of Labor and Commerce. Altogether officials from over twenty-five agencies were involved, and their recruitment was seen as a move to increase both the coordination of the subsequent energy policy and the accep­ tance of analytic modeling within the bureaucracy. 3 A s model building proceeded , analysts began t o play down the political goal of complete self-sufficiency. At the same time they at­ tempted to broaden the proj ect so as to provide projections on the implications of the wide array of possible presidential energy ini­ tiatives. Although their original mandate was to produce specific pol­ icy recommendations, the analysts soon redefined their mission more generally; as Sawhill remarked, "it was not the intent of this specific report to recommend a total national energy program. Energy policy is a complex issue and the formulation of appropriate Federal pro­ grams and policies can entail many paths and choices . The Project I ndependence report was intended to present a comprehensive framework within which the public, Congress, and the Executive Branch could evaluate individual issues."4 Zausner notes that the shift in mission from policy recommendation to the creation of a general analytic framework resulted from a desire to protect the authoritative nature of the enterprise. His central objective was an "institutional upgrade" in energy information and analysis. If the project moved 2See Federal Energy Administration, Project Independence: A Summary (Washington , D.C. : GPO, November 1 974); Martin Greenberger, Caught Unawares: The Energy Decade in Retrospect (Cambridge, Mass. : Ballinger, 1 983), p. 1 1 0. 3See Thomas H. Tietenberg, Energy Planning and Policy: The Political Economy of Project Independence (Lexington, Mass . : Lexington Books, 1 975), p. 46. 4John Sawhill , "Project Independence," Hearings before the Committee on Interior and Insular Affairs, U.S. Senate, 93d Cong., 2d sess. , November 2 1 , 1 974, p. 1 64.

REASONS OF STATE

immediately to recommend policy , subsequent attacks could under­ mine its larger purpose. 5 The PIES project snowballed into a massive administrative under­ taking involving over five hundred analysts and numerous task forces. Proj ect I ndependence staff conducted hearings across the country, attempting to find areas of consensus. Also attached to the project was an Advisory Committee, which drew its twenty-eight members from industry, labor, and state and local government, as well as public interest groups.6 The actual significance of the hearings and the committee is disputed. Nonetheless, these additional activities do reflect the centrality FEA officials understood their Proj ect to possess for the eventual decision on a national energy policy. The project involved many individuals , but the bulk of the report was generated by a core staff of several dozen. The task forces, Zausner notes, were designed to "bring other administrative officials into the tent." The task forces were not crucial to the analytic work but rather were used for two purposes. One was to provide data resources. Even as late as 1 976, after all, twenty-three executive de­ partments and independent agencies operated 2 3 8 major energy data-gathering programs. Zausner notes, for example, that the Inte­ rior Department had important coal data but did not have the analyti­ cal sophistication to use them. The task forces mobilized this informa­ tion. Second, the project staff sought to bring other administrative officials into the enterprise at an early stage so as to protect the subse­ quent analytical product. The typical method of bureaucratic attack is to challenge the assumptions of a study, and so proj ect staff at­ tempted to get other bureaucratic players to agree on assumptions early on, coopting them and thereby foreclosing potential conflict. 7 The final report was produced in November 1 974, one year after N ixon had declared Project Independence. It provided models of energy demand and supply, as well as larger models that related energy shifts to macroeconomic, environmental, and other variables.8 5J nterview, Eric Zausner, J u n e 26, 1 984. 6 See Neil De Marchi, "Energy Policy under N ixon : Mainly Putting Out Fires," in Craufurd D. Goodwin, ed . , Energy Policy in Perspective: Today's Problems, Yesterday's Solu­ tions (Washington: Brookings, 1 98 1 ) , pp. 458-66 ; Greenberger, Caught Unawares, p. 1 1 1 ; and Joel Havemann and James G. Phillips, "Energy Report/ I ndependence Blue­ print Weighs Various Options," National journal Reports, November 2, 1 974, p. 1 636. 7Interview, Eric Zausner, June 26, 1 984. The count of data-gathering programs is from General Accounting Office, Report to the President and the Congress: Performance Evaluation of the Energy Information Administration (Washington, D.C., June 1 5 , 1 984), p.

1-l.

Sfederal Energy Administration, Project Independence Report (Washington : GPO, N ovember 1 974).

1 08

The Limits of State B uilding

It generated both a massive substantive study of energy demand and supply and a complex, computer-based set of models to guide subse­ quent analysis of policy options. This analytical framework marked a new level of sophistication in energy policy analysis. As one FEA official argued, "the FEA model is an order of magnitude more so­ phisticated than anything done before. Whereas we had sweeping generalities before, we can now look at regional energy flows in de­ tail. . . No matter what happens to the policy scenarios laid out in the blueprint, we've taken a major step forward in developing analytical tools for looking at energy problems."9 The project's list of various steps to promote domestic energy pro­ duction tended to underline constraints on production. The report argued, for example, that the acceleration of nuclear power plant construction would not significantly reduce oil imports. Nor would a massive effort to produce synfuels, bypassing important research steps, be very practical or efficient. Although the report cast doubt on the possibility of significant short-term gains in energy independence, it stressed that increases in self-sufficiency would have an impact on world oil prices. The study concluded that with a reduction of U.S. imports, OPEC would find it hard to maintain a price of even $7 a barrel. But price reductions, it noted , would harm new domestic ener­ gy investment, perhaps requiring government price guarantees and supports. 1 0 Project Independence and the Policy Process The PIES analytical models had more than a modest impact in government during the Ford administration. As one study notes, "for the first time, the government appeared to have its own source of energy information and analysis-reasonably integrated, i ncreasingly rationalized , and operated and maintained in-house. " l l The chief architect of the modeling project, FEA assistant administrator Zausner, also noted the importance of the massive study. "Until the blueprint," Zausner claimed , "we really had a clean slate. " 1 2 The implication was that the project reflected a dramatic departure in government capacity for planning and analysis. Zausner has since noted that there was a "tremendous lack of information and analysis" 9Unidentified official quoted in Havemann and Phillips, "Energy Report," November 2, 1 974, p. 1 640. 10Project Independence Report, November 1 974, pp. 8, 1 5 . I I Greenberger, Caught Unawares, p. 1 1 2 . 1 2Quoted in Havemann and Phillips, "Energy Report," November 2 , 1 974, p . 1 636.

1 09

REASONS OF STATE

prior to Proj ect I ndependence. Nixon's proj ect opened up the oppor­ tunity to "build a body of experts," to build an analytical model, and "put some important facts on the table. " 1 3 The models were used a t various points t o calculate the impact of oil decontrol on inflation and energy supply. In December 1 974, while President Ford was preparing new energy proposals, the FEA modeling system was brought into the process . The FEA prepared briefing materials for a Camp David policy meeting during this peri­ od. "The Proj ect I ndependence analysis," one author argues, "was the major source of information consulted in preparing these briefing books. I n retrospect the role it played was to point out that this histor­ ical policy package was not sufficient to meet the administration's goal either in the immediate future or in the long run , if world prices were to fall." 1 4 Another account suggests that the Project Independence analysis played a less central role in those December policy delibera­ tions. Some of the issues brought before Ford in December "specifi­ cally call[ed] for critiques of the Project I ndependence Report or for development of additional data." 1 5 Zausner indicates that the proj ect analysis "dominated the process" ; the project did not have all the information Ford needed for decisions, but the Camp David policy review "spoke to" the project findings. 1 6 I ndeed , as the Ford energy package took shape, initiatives came directly or indirectly from the PIES analysis, among them financial support for the electric utilities industry, the establishment of a strategic petroleum reserve, and tax measures and voluntary standards to promote conservation . Yet the P I E S analysis d i d n o t have a sustained impact on admin­ istrative decision making, thus falling short of the hopes of its au­ thors. The influence of PIES analysis and its FEA sponsors did not extend far within the administration . The project had brought into its ranks specialists from all reaches of the executive bureaucracy, but the report's analysis and methodology did not follow those officials back to their respective agencies. Because of the short period of time available to the proj ect, the final report did not circulate widely within the administration before publication. Many agencies had only a week to review the document. Thus many administrative units may have had a substantive stake in the report's findings, but they did not have 1 3 I nterview, Eric Zausner, June 26, 1 984 . 1 4Tietenberg, Energy Planning and Policy, p. 88. 1 5Joel Havemann, "Energy Report/ Federal Planners Study Ways to Cut Reliance on I m ports," National journal Reports, December 14, 1 974, p . 1 86 3 . 1 6 Interview, Eric Zausner, June 26, 1 984.

IIO

The Limits of State Building

an organizational stake in its production. As a result, the modeling project was not well received in the executive establishment. 1 7 The problem o f bureaucratic agreement was tied u p with a variety of battles over turf. The Project Independence report was in effect a claim by the Federal Energy Administration to a dominant role in policy making. For the FEA to claim the preeminent role, it had to have the best analytical unit in the executive establishment. "He who has the data base and the analytic model," Zausner argued , "has the bureaucratic muscle." 1 8 The influence of the model and analysis depended heavily on the status of Project Independence officials in the policy process, a status that changed frequently under the Ford administration. FEA offi­ cials, one author notes, "were not effective in integrating it [PIES] into the policy-making process. " During the formulation of President Ford's first major speech on energy and the economy, in early Oc­ tober 1 974, for example, the Federal Energy Administration submit­ ted options based on Project Independence analysis, among them a proposal for a gas tax. However, the FEA's chief, John Sawhill, was not well placed in the administration (and later that month was forced to resign). Consequently, FEA and the PIES analysis did not play a major role in Ford's October energy proposals. 1 9 I ndeed, Project In­ dependence officials did not present their November report directly to the president, as they had anticipated doing. I nstead, top officials instructed FEA to submit the report to the Energy Resources Council. This executive council, under the direction of Rogers Morton, had maneuvered at FEA's expense to become the chief body for policy recommendation. Morton's unsympathetic attitude toward the Pro­ ject I ndependence analysis removed that material and its officials from the direct formulation of policy. Later, with the appointment of Frank Zarb as FEA chief, the analysis was brought into high-level policy planning more frequently, but the influence came from Zarb, an administrative insider, not from the independent authority of the PIES analysis. During this period it was the FEA that "staffed" the Energy Resources Council, where Zarb was executive director. Dur­ ing Zarb's tenure, as a result, all the important decision memoranda went through Zausner and the FEA. 2o 1 7Havemann and Phillips, "Energy Report," November 2 , 1 974, p. 1 65 3 ; Tietenberg, Energy Planning and Policy, pp. 46-47. 1 8 Interview, Eric Zausner, June 26, 1 984. 1 9Tietenberg, Energy Planning and Policy, pp. 63, 87. 2 0Edward Cowan, "Zarb Is Praised as Man in Middle on Oil Price Dispute," New York Times, July 2 3 , 1 97 5 ; interview, Eric Zausner, June 26, 1 984.

III

REASONS OF STATE

After Zarb's departure, however, Rogers Morton again removed project officials from policy deliberations. 2 1 Finally, with the depar­ ture of key FEA officials in 1 976, the PIES operation began to lose what role it had achieved in the policy process. The analytical frame­ work survived into the Carter administration , and PIES evaluation and forecasting models were used in the preparation of the first Car­ ter energy program. By this time, however, the reputation of PIES as an authoritative device had diminished considerably . The Elusiveness of Authoritative Information Attempts to establish an authoritative body for energy analysis and information continued beyond the failure of Proj ect Independence. In August 1 976 Congress passed the Energy Conservation and Pro­ duction Act, authorizing the establishment of a separate information and analysis unit within the FEA. Congress intended to separate anal­ ysis from the staff and policy-making units within the agency : the act called for the information bureau to be "insulated from FEA's role in formulating and advocating national policy. "22 When the Depart­ ment of Energy was established in 1 97 8 , this independent bureau became the Energy I nformation Administration. The legacy of Proj ect I ndependence, therefore, was an initially ambitious effort to bring new analytical capacities to the center of policy formation. The analysis concerned had its limitations, however. The data remained quite aggregated , and many policy participants found the direct relevance of the analysis to policy elusive. Proj ect I ndependence was the first major effort to develop in-house expertise on energy supply and demand and other macroeconomic variables, yet the modeling effort and its experts were unable to remain at the center of policy. Challenges to the authority of PIES followed its initial report-challenges from Congress and from various quarters within the administration. When an agency-the Energy I nformation Administration-finally was established , its organizational mandate consigned it to the peripheries of the formulation of national energy policy. The FEA controlled most phases of information and analysis prior to the establishment of the Department of Energy. Its three impor­ tant divisions were data collection, analysis, and policy. The creation 2 1 Edward Cowan, "Ford Calls Aides to Weigh Energy and Economy," New York Times, December 2 6 , 1 974, P· 4 5 · 22£ nergy Conservation and Production Act, U . S . Public Law 94-385, enacted August 1 4 , 1 97 6 , secs. 5 1 a, 1 4 2 ; d iscussed i n Greenberger, Caught Unawares, p . 1 1 6.

112

The Limits of State B uilding

of the Energy I nformation Administration separated data collection and analysis from policy formulation. The E IA's information respon­ sibilities, one study notes, "included carrying out a unified program to collect, process, and publish data and information relevant to ener­ gy resource reserves, production. demand, and technology. "23 Using as its model the Bureau of Labor Statistics, Congress successfully established the information fu nction independent of administrative policy making. In effect, executive and congressional officials alike had suspicions about energy information and analysis , and as a result created a new institution in such a way as to make it peripheral to the policy process. The goal of an apparatus that would generate authoritative plan­ ning and analysis, and be located in a powerful and centralized ad­ ministrative unit, remained elusive. Even basic information about en­ ergy supplies and flows was in dispute.24 This absence of authorita­ tive knowledge was reflected in a sense of uncertainty on the part of officials within the policy process. One senator expressed this senti­ ment in the fall of 1 974: "When we first started debating this prob­ lem, after the Middle East crisis, one of the most serious problems we encountered was a tremendous lack of information regarding the facts. There were figures quoted as to how much we were importing and, at that point in time, figures ranged from as little as 1 5 to as much as 40 percent. As far as true information to our future potential supplies, I understand that is difficult to come by, but it was almost impossible to even gather the basic facts to base a national policy on. "25 Administrative and congressional debate over energy policy after 1 973 was manifestly political and centered on substantive policy op­ tions. But it was fed by great uncertainty both as to the availability of data and analysis and as to their source. At the very outset govern­ ment was highly dependent on the energy industries themselves for information. O ne report in early 1 974 noted : "By and large, the 23General Accounting Office, Report to the President and the Congress: Performance Evaluation of the Energy Information Administration (Washington , D.C., June 1 5 , 1 984), p. 1-I. 24Basic information was not available on oil flows in the midst of the October 1 973 embargo. For example, after the embargo William Simon asked Eric Zausner, in charge of data and analysis in the Interior Department, for figures on current oil import levels. The one agency with energy information was the Bureau of Mines, in the I nterior Department. That bureau reportedly told Simon it would have available data on import levels for 1 97 1 in another six months. Interview, Eric Zausner, June 26, 1 984. 25Statement by Senator Pete V . Domenici, "Project I ndependence ," Hearings before the Committee on I nterior and I nsular Affairs, U.S. Senate, 93d Cong. , 2d sess. , November 2 1 , 1 974, p. 5.

I IJ

REASONS OF STATE

industry's own figures-unverified by independent audit-are the only ones presently available to guide federal energy policy deci­ sions. "26 The government's ability to gather energy information had evolved piecemeal prior to the 1 970s. At the moment of the 1 973 embargo at least seventeen federal agencies were involved in compiling and re­ porting information, most of it obtained from industry on a voluntary basis.27 The Bureau of Mines in the Department of I nterior, for instance, obtained much of its data from the annual reports of the American Petroleum I nstitute and the American Gas Association. This voluntary information was difficult to check because industry feared the release of proprietary information, and so what informa­ tion was published tended to be very highly aggregated .28 The government's problem in gathering information about energy matters was presaged in 1 96 2 in a report by the Kennedy administra­ tion's Petroleum Study Committee. The report argued that "satisfacto­ ry information concerning petroleum reserves, productive capacity, and deliverability, and their expansibility under normal conditions is seriously lacking. Suitable cost information is even more seriously lack­ ing. A great deal of fragmentary and sometimes contradictory data is available. " The report concluded that "corresponding data and analyt­ ical shortcomings are to be found in regard to the interrelationships of different segments of the economy. There is, in addition, a related in­ adequacy in analytic studies. These undesirably limit the con­ clusiveness of any petroleum study under existing circumstances. "29 26B ruce F. Freed , "Energy Report/Government Seeks Ways to Verify Energy Data," National journal Reports, February 2 , 1 974, p. 2 7 8 . 27The problem of government dependence on industry information runs through many congressional hearings on energy. In testimony before the Church Subcom mittee on Multinational Corporations and American Foreign Policy, James E. Akins, from the Office of Fuels and Energy, Department of State, prefaced his remarks on U.S. oil company negotiations with Libya : "We were relying on the companies for information and we still are. We possibly are going to be in a position sometime to require them to give us information but we have not been in that position in the past and we are not there now and I can be excused from talking about specific company positions inside these negotiations." Senator Church asked : "Why is it that the U . S . Government is in this position with respect to the oil companies ? Why can't we obtain information as a matter of right?" Atkins retorted : "Well, I think is it probably the way the Government works. " "Multinational Petroleum Companies and Foreign Policy," Hearings before the Subcommittee on Multinational Corporations, Committee on Foreign Relations, U . S . Senate, 9 3 d Cong. , 1 st sess . , Vol. 5 , October 1 1 , 1 97 3 , p. 9· 28See Freed , "Energy Report," February 2, 1 974, p. 2 79, and more generally Neil De Marchi, "The Ford Administration: Energy as a Political Good ," in Goodwin, Energy in Perspective, p. 292 . 29Quoted in B ruce F. Freed , "Energy Report/Government Seeks Ways to Verify Energy Data ," National journal Reports, February 2 3 , 1 974, p. 2 8 2 .

The Limits of State Building

Twelve years later another major report echoed these findings. The General Accounting Office prepared a report, published in Feb­ ruary 1 974, for Senator Henry Jackson's Interior Committee . The study listed such problems in the energy area as the voluntary report­ ing of industry information , which does not "provide the federal government with the assurance that needed data will be available," and questions about its credibility. The report noted that the "federal government has been unable to demonstrate convincingly the nature and extent of the energy shortage, in large measure because of the lack of independently developed or independently verified data." I n addition , the adequacy of information also caused problems. The absence of basic data on petroleum inventories, as well as energy distribution and consumption patterns, impeded government plan­ ning. Finally, until the establishment of the Office of Energy Data and Analysis in the Interior Department, which was later moved to the Federal Energy Office, there existed no agency empowered to ana­ lyze data on a continuous basis . "Perhaps the most crucial need ," the report concluded, "is for analyses of energy data from the perspective of identified energy problems, rather than from the vastly different perspective of individual agencies and programs."30 The administrative response to this information problem led di­ rectly to the data modeling and analysis of Project I ndependence. Project officials themselves aimed to bring authoritative information to the center of policy deliberations; as I have suggested, this enter­ prise was ultimately unsuccessful. Project officials were not well re­ ceived within the executive bureaucracy, nor did they have regular, direct access to the president. Congressional politicians, wary of both executive and industry data and analysis, also sought to establish a source of authoritative information, but unlike that of Federal Energy Administration officials, congressional sentiment favored an inde­ pendent agency sheltered from policy planning. This idea was em­ bodied in a bill proposed by Senators Gaylord Nelson and Henry Jackson in 1 974. The bill's approach was not welcomed by the Federal E nergy Office (or later by the FEA) . FEO assistant administrator Eric Zausner, in the midst of Project I ndependence preparations, argued : "We don't want a separate information agency established. We need a lot of informa­ tion for the operation of our programs and we want to collect it 30"Energy I nformation N eeds-Study by the General Accounting Office," Prepared at the request of the Committee on I nterior and I nsular Affairs, U.S. Senate, February 6 , 1 974 . pp. 4-6.

1 15

REASONS OF STATE

ourselves. We have the expertise to collect the information and we know what to collect and assess . "3 1 Proj ect I ndependence sought to provide an authoritative body of experts and analysis, but it failed . In its place an independent body, separated from planning and policy deliberations, eventually became the government's response to information shortcomings. The organi­ zation of government thus adapted to the call for new sources and forms of information and expertise, but it adapted in a way that left the specialists outside the core of the policy process. E NERGY

I N DEPENDENCE A UTHORITY

Nixon's energy independence proposal met with skepticism almost at the moment of its unveiling.32 In many respects the articulation of the goal was designed to support international efforts by the admin­ istration to get industrial consumer nations to cooperate in undercut­ ting OPEC's oil-pricing power. It also reflected the attempt of a presi­ dent, under seige by the Watergate investigation, to rally the public and Congress to a major national cause. The proj ect did, however, produce an ambitious modeling effort to develop the policy sophis­ tication necessary to deploy state resources and stimulate domestic production. Yet the meager payoff revealed not only the limitations of policy competence within the administration but also the limita­ tions on the government's ability to gain that competence. Nixon's officials soon began to concede that the national economy would remain dependent on foreign sources of energy for some time to come. Energy research and development got under way as the newly established Energy Research and Development Administration (ERDA) geared up to propose projects and spend money on promis­ ing energy technologies for the long term . However, support per­ sisted within the N ixon administration, and in the Ford administra­ tion to follow, for direct government sponsorship to stimulate the immediate production of domestic energy. The Rockefeller Proposal Within the Ford administration the most ambitious proposal for government involvement in energy production came from Vice-Presi3 1 Quoted in Freed , "Energy Report," February 23, 1 974, p. 2 8 2 . 32£.g. , Ernest Holsendorph, "Oil Independence-I t Seems U nlikely," New York Times, December 2 , 1 973 , sec. I I , pp. 1 , 1 5 .

II6

The Limits of State Building

dent Nelson Rockefeller. In the summer of 1 975 Rockefeller pro­ posed within administration councils a $ 1 oo billion Energy Resources Finance Corporation. This corporation would signal a major depar­ ture for the public role in the energy sector. At the heart of Rockefel­ ler's proposal was a new commitment by the federal government to underwrite, through loans and loan guarantees, energy projects that the market would not sustain on its own. As Rockefeller's staff pre­ pared the proposal, the vice-president began asking administration officials to identify energy projects that were being held back in the private sector because of financial problems. 33 Although considerable opposition developed within the admin­ istration, Ford eventually agreed to the proposal. In a speech on September 2 2 , 1 975, to an AFL-CIO convention, Ford said : "You and I know we can produce our own energy. You and I know we can protect ourselves against increases in price by foreign nations. You and I know we can provide more jobs. And you and I know we can bring an end to the intolerable situation in which America exports more than $ 2 5 billion annually to pay for imported oil while plenty of energy is potentially available right here at home." Noting that Con­ gress had failed to act on earlier energy proposals, Ford proposed the $ 1 00 billion government corporation. The corporation would be em­ powered to "tal