Freshwater Politics in Canada 9781442609280

Freshwater is in great supply across much of Canada. However, competing and changing demands on its use are leading to e

219 42 3MB

English Pages 256 [248] Year 2014

Report DMCA / Copyright

DOWNLOAD FILE

Polecaj historie

Freshwater Politics in Canada
 9781442609280

Citation preview

Freshwater Politics in Canada

This page intentionally left blank

Freshwater Politics in Canada PETER CLANCY

Copyright © University of Toronto Press Incorporated 2014 Higher Education Division www.utppublishing.com All rights reserved. The use of any part of this publication reproduced, transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, or stored in a retrieval system, without prior written consent of the publisher—or in the case of photocopying, a licence from Access Copyright (Canadian Copyright Licensing Agency), One Yonge Street, Suite 1900, Toronto, Ontario M5E 1E5—is an infringement of the copyright law. library and archives canada cataloguing in publication Clancy, Peter, 1949–, author Freshwater politics in Canada / Peter Clancy. Includes bibliographical references and index. Issued in print and electronic formats. ISBN 978-1-4426-0927-3 (bound).—ISBN 978-1-4426-0926-6 (pbk.).— ISBN 978-1-4426-0928-0 (pdf  ).—ISBN 978-1-4426-0929-7 (epub)   1.  Watershed management—Political aspects—Canada—Case studies.  2.  Fresh water—Political aspects—Canada—Case studies.  3.  Integrated water development— Government policy—Canada—Case studies.  4. Water use—Government policy— Canada—Case studies.  I. Title. TC426.C63 2014  333.730971   C2013-908644-7 C2013-908645-5 We welcome comments and suggestions regarding any aspect of our publications— please feel free to contact us at [email protected] or visit our Internet site at www.utppublishing.com. North America 5201 Dufferin Street North York, Ontario, Canada, M3H 5T8 2250 Military Road Tonawanda, New York, USA, 14150

UK, Ireland, and continental Europe NBN International Estover Road, Plymouth, PL6 7PY, UK orders phone: 44 (0) 1752 202301 orders fax: 44 (0) 1752 202333 orders e-mail: [email protected]

orders phone: 1–800–565–9523 orders fax: 1–800–221–9985 orders e-mail: [email protected] Every effort has been made to contact copyright holders; in the event of an error or omission, please notify the publisher. This book is printed on paper containing 100% post-consumer fibre. The University of Toronto Press acknowledges the financial support for its publishing activities of the Government of Canada through the Canada Book Fund.

To the ISAR community that spurred the idea

This page intentionally left blank

Contents

List of Illustrations  ix Introduction xi

Part One: Freshwater Politics 1 Water Politics as Diversity  3



Case Study: James-West River Watershed  12

2 Power and Freshwater  18



Case Study: Boat Harbour Watershed  26

3 Group Politics and Water  36



Case Study: Athabasca River Watershed  45

4 The Freshwater State  57



Case Study: Souris River Watershed  72

Part Two: Fields of Engagement 5 Fisheries and Pollution  81



Case Study: Miramichi River Watershed  91

6 Irrigation Politics  104



Case Study: Oldman River Watershed  113

7 Flooding and Flood Control  122



Case Study: Red River Watershed  130

8 Hydro-power 140



Case Study: La Grande River Watershed  147

9 Groundwater Politics  159



Case Study: PEI Groundwatersheds  172

10 Emerging Trends in Canadian Freshwater Politics  182



Case Study: Mackenzie Basin Watershed  195 Conclusion 203 References 213 Index 227

This page intentionally left blank

Illustrations Figures 1.1 A Watershed in Four Dimensions  8 5.1 The Salmon Policy Network for Miramichi  102 9.1 Possible Sources of Shale Fracturing Contamination  171

Maps 0.1 Drainage Basins and Watershed Case Study Sites  xvii 1.1 James-West River Watershed, Nova Scotia  13 2.1 Boat Harbour and Pictou Watersheds, Nova Scotia  27 3.1 Athabasca River Watershed, Alberta  46 4.1 Souris River Watershed, Saskatchewan  73 5.1 Miramichi River Watershed, New Brunswick  92 6.1 Oldman River Watershed, Alberta  115 7.1 Red River Watershed, Manitoba  131 8.1 La Grande Watershed, Quebec  149 9.1 Prince Edward Island Watersheds  173 10.1 Mackenzie Basin Watersheds  196

Tables 3.1 Continuum of Interest Groups  43 8.1 Canada’s Largest Hydro Stations  147

This page intentionally left blank

Introduction

T

of freshwater politics, defined in the broadest sense. I hope that it speaks to the concerns of citizens, students, policy makers, and administrators. In addition, I hope that it offers some new perspectives and some practical tools that can be applied to the understanding of local settings across Canada. First and foremost, the book poses questions about water politics. Where should we search for the political dimensions of this resource and what can we learn from past practice? What issues, problems, and trends point the way to our water future? There are excellent studies available on water politics in Canada. Two fine edited collections offer valuable thematic surveys (Bakker 2007; Sproule Jones et al. 2008). The list of river histories is also mounting (e.g., Armstrong et al. 2009; Evenden 2004; Wood 2013). Another thread of study is group politics, where monographs on Aboriginal peoples (Harris 2001), irrigated farms (Glenn 1999), and big hydro-power (Salisbury 1986; Waldram 1988) point the way. In this book I plan to add another perspective by building a framework for understanding the practice of water politics, a framework that can be applied to a range of policy subsectors and illustrated in particular watersheds. The fit between watersheds and politics is a central theme in the chapters below. Until recently, freshwater was often portrayed as a neglected natural resource— taken for granted in social terms, treated as an open-access product in economic terms, and (partly as a result of the previous factors) languishing on almost everyone’s political agenda. By this account, water is assumed to be in inexhaustible supply in Canada and it has been treated as a virtually free good in pricing terms. Little wonder then that governments pay less attention to freshwater than they do to farmland, minerals, oil and gas, and forests. Of course there are episodes to the contrary. Acute flood events remind Canadians of the extraordinary physical force and destruction that can be visited on riverside communities. Regional water shortages remind us that there are physical limits on supply and that withdrawals need to be managed as social demand grows. Anglers are keenly aware of the fragility of freshwater fish stocks in the face of habitat degradations ranging from factory effluent to acid rain. Anxieties about drinking-water safety have spread similarly across the country since the Walkerton fiasco in 2000, and the particular crisis of First Nations communities is increasingly evident in this regard. In short, the freshwater resource plays a part in many contemporary policy fields. his is a book for students

xii   int roduc t i on Even there, however, the issues are often framed to highlight an absence of political attention and a condition of governmental laxity. Many of these very real failures in water resource management are attributed to political neglect—to a vacuum of authority. This accords with the premise that the water resource remains marginal and underattended, relative to other natural resources and in an absolute political sense. The thrust of this book is different. It argues that water, far from being neglected, has been the object of extended political attention in Canada. Such concern is driven by a variety of interests and is evident in a multitude of spatial and temporal settings. Cumulatively, these forces have resulted in a highly regulated resource, though not necessarily regulated in the directions and for the purposes that serve it, or the public interest, best. This is a political attribute worth pondering. If “organized water” is the domain of lawyers, technocrats, and consultants more than of voters, consumers, and the public at large, what does this say about the texture of public life in the freshwater sector? My argument is not that freshwater is too little organized but that its organization is more often than not uneven and dysfunctional, with a discernible tilt toward partial and vested interests. Policy and management failures are less a result of “absence of mind” than a result of fixed commitments, prior interventions, and deliberate choices whose imperfect functioning exacerbates our problems. Consequently there is an urgent need to acknowledge and correct these tendencies. Several concepts will play important roles in the interpretation that follows. Central to the discussion is the notion of power, or the capacity to realize defined interests in the face of rival claimants. In its raw physical form, freshwater is the target of multiple interest holders, and the conflicts that this engenders go a long way toward determining how water is regulated in Canada. It is important to recognize different faces of power. Another key concept is group politics—an essential link between identifying an interest and advancing that interest through collective organization or group action. In the water field, groups come in many shapes and sizes, and it is important to be able to identify them and assess their performances. A third concept is the state, the political authority that takes key decisions under the force of law, setting the rules of water use and management and making key allocative choices among contending interests. States are complex structures that must be charted and appraised in terms of their key decisions. Here we will build a model of the “freshwater state” in Canada. An important insight in modern policy studies is that organized groups and state authorities tend to coalesce according to specialized subjects of concern. So while we can speak of public policy at large, the arenas in which decisions are taken are usually more restricted policy fields. For this reason we talk about mineral policy or foreign policy or health policy, each with its own constellation of organized interests, state actors, ways of thinking, and central issues. Policy fields can be highly structured and display high levels of continuity in the ways that groups and state actors interact. This can be captured in the notion of policy

I ntr o d uc ti o n   xiii networks that link groups and state actors in particular ways. The notion of governance centres on the study of such interactive relationships. Freshwater politics is one policy field that can be profitably approached from a governance perspective. It can be grasped as a whole and it can also be disaggregated into a series of subsectors with distinctive group/state patterns. The recognition of policy subsectors within the freshwater domain is an important tool in advancing our understanding. First, it fits with the reality that the water resource has been viewed and treated in different ways according to prime concern. A set of group and state interests may coalesce for purposes of fishing. Another may take form for purposes of irrigated farming or flood control or hydro-power generation or drinking water supply. The sequence in which water policy subsectors appear can be a key influence on the shape of freshwater politics. Early actions can set a template for policy thinking that infiltrates subsectors formed later. Alternatively, each subsector may be framed according to its own core interests and problems, displaying a distinct policy logic and power structure. Many of the inconsistencies and contradictions that emerge in a policy sector can be rooted in the relative autonomy enjoyed by subsectors. First there are issues of spill-over, when actions in one subsector generate problems that surface in another. Then there are problems of high-level coordination, since any effort to frame an overall strategy or an integrated approach bumps into existing power structures at the intermediate level. There are further questions worth posing about the freshwater sector. Among the various functioning subsectors, does one hold a place of priority or dominance over others? If so, can a dominant subsector imprint its template on the freshwater field as a whole? Even if subsectors are largely autonomous within their own boundaries, which ones prevail when cross-sectoral issues must be addressed? These questions are especially intriguing in the present context, since it can be argued that the freshwater field has been relatively decentralized in structure in the past. Today, when cross-sector problems are increasingly being exposed, solutions are elusive and new governing patterns are urgently being sought. This involves grappling with the legacy of freshwater power structures forged in the twentieth century. Prior political and policy choices constrain today’s options but never entirely dictate them. It is more accurate to say that water politics today is shaped jointly, by inherited power structures on the one hand and new water values and policy problems on the other. Ongoing commitments to established ways of operating reflect the weight of past choices. Contemporary controversies, crises, and newly emerging perspectives pose challenges to the water establishment. As a result, ongoing political relationships and policy arrangements can either facilitate or block the evolution of new water politics. In this book we will draw upon diverse materials. Any successful encounter with the politics of natural resources or environments must be willing to cross boundaries, and an encounter with freshwater politics is no exception. Its study is enhanced immeasurably by the extensive knowledge that has been generated in the natural and applied sciences, particularly in the fields of hydrology, aquatic

xiv int roduc t i on ecology, and hydraulic engineering. It is not by accident that these specialties figure prominently among researchers, consultants, and advocates. Indeed, to the extent that a science establishment shapes freshwater policy choices, it tends to be based in these fields. However, at the same time our central subject involves communities, societies, and governments and the way in which collective choices are organized. This is the domain of anthropology, history, economics, and political science. Here too we encounter a rich field of prior study that can be repointed for freshwater insights. How, then, to proceed? Students of water politics need to grasp each of these two major constitutive domains—the biophysical and the socioeconomic—and, equally important, to grasp their interplay. Often this involves pushing against familiar tendencies. The challenge arises, in large part, from the conventional organization of academic knowledge and in particular the longstanding division between natural and social sciences. This was not always the case. In the early nineteenth century, natural history and moral philosophy were broad synthetic endeavours in which aspiring scholars were versed. The subsequent rise of specialist disciplines doubtlessly advanced the power of our understanding but often at the cost of fragmentation. The incentives for cross-disciplinary dialogue gave way to parallel solitudes, sometimes fuelled by mutual doubts as to method and relevance. Physical and biological researchers asked whether social study could ever truly attain the rigour of science, and social researchers complained about the natural disciplines being tone-deaf to societal needs. One answer to the problem of such knowledge divides is to build new bridges between them. This offers a way to broaden and deepen explanatory reach and is captured in the call for interdisciplinary effort. The growing complexity of central problems in modern life, along with the urgency for generating responses, has accelerated this process in recent decades. It is reflected in the diversified composition of research teams, the sanctioning of new fields of cross-specialty training, and the concentration on applied problems as an organizational fulcrum. At this point some of the exciting new themes can be previewed. Not only is it important to appreciate the significance of the hydrologic cycle, but that cycle must also be fitted with a social and political framework. Not only can we recognize the renewed importance of the values of nature, but we must develop appropriate tools to deal with the aquatic part of nature’s estate. Not only is there growing acceptance of the need for structured environmental appraisals and reviews, but the participative and deliberative scales of such processes must broaden beyond the professional and technical classes. Integral to this is the proliferation of civil society interests as a critical third pillar of freshwater politics, alongside corporate and state institutions. Finally, there are complicated jurisdictional challenges to effective water management in Canada, including the need to tackle cross-jurisdictional water systems. As indicated above, the purpose of this book is to highlight a dimension of freshwater systems that is sometimes neglected in Canada. To this extent it is a study in social science that harbours interdisciplinary ambitions. One of the most

I ntr o d uc ti o n   xv effective ways to achieve this is through a focus on examples of freshwater issues as they are manifest in concrete settings. Fortunately we have available an organizing concept that respects complexity, particularity, and variability. This involves a watershed focus. A watershed is a territory in which water drains into a connected set of streams, rivers, and lakes. It combines spatial, water flow, and social occupancy dimensions. The challenge is to explore the connections between these several dimensions. One of the most powerful expressions of conservation and ecological ethics is Aldo Leopold’s essay “Thinking Like a Mountain” (1970). Leopold was a forester and biologist in the first half of twentieth-century America. He worked for the US Forest Service at the field level in its southwest region. This is a mountain and desert ecology where Leopold’s understanding led him to differ with many accepted government policies. “Thinking Like a Mountain” is a powerful piece that calls on us to view the natural and physical world from a nonhuman perspective. The first necessary change is in time frame, since the mountain has been in place for millennia. It is solid and stationary and changes happen slowly. Only the mountain can see the full picture, for as people we concentrate on the selective parts that we need and value. The howl of the wolf is a signature sound on a mountain, where that species is a key to the mountain ecosystem. In the culture of ranchers, hunters, and government game officers, however, wolves were seen as destructive predators that threatened deer or cattle populations. In effect, wolves competed with human hunters and, should deer numbers decline or more humans arrive, wolves were treated as an expendable variable that could be reduced or eliminated by cash bounty or poison bait schemes. The outlook here was an instrumental one that seized on the wolf/deer relationship and accepted the equation that fewer wolves equalled more deer. Leopold contends that the mountain, home to a complete natural system unfolding over centuries, would disagree and see things differently. Deer are not simply a stock of wild animals in forests and meadows that offer a challenge to hunters. Deer browse on mountain vegetation like bush and tree leaves. Similarly wolves are not just fierce predators that deplete grazing herds. Rather, wolf predation shapes deer populations by culling weak or old or excess animals from the range. They are both, in short, elements of an interdependent system. The removal of wolves serves to intensify the grazing pressure on natural vegetation, Leopold says. “While a buck pulled down by wolves can be replaced in two to three years, a range pulled down by too many deer may fail of replacement in as many decades” (Leopold 1970, 140). In sum, the exclusive focus on one species aims to make safe that species (deer) but in so doing it can threaten the wider web of life. Only the mountain appreciates when the web is skewed too sharply. Like a mountain, a watershed is both a space and an ecosystem. It links and sustains many elements of land, air, and water, both above and below ground. A watershed is not static, but persists within certain limits by adapting to change and rebalancing internally. At the same time, there is danger in elevating any

xvi   int roduc t i on single element or relationship. To focus on one species or use, in isolation from habitat or ecology, is as deeply flawed in the watershed as it is on the mountain. Leopold remarked that the impulse behind many resource management projects is increased resource security. Paradoxically, this can be counterproductive, as “too much safety yields only danger in the long run” (Leopold 1970, 141). For example, building a levy to protect low-lying lands against flood can also prevent the nutrient replenishment that comes with floods. Constructing a dam to impound water for irrigation or electricity will in the process block or alter downstream flows and aquatic conditions. A landowner who chooses to cut trees right down to the stream’s edge can maximize his or her harvest of timber but destabilize riparian banks and alter water conditions and fisheries. Such practices are the watershed equivalents of the war on wolves. In sum, before we can think like a watershed (or a river) we have to look at what the river sees. It is a unique perspective and far more comprehensive than that of single-purpose users or managers (Worster 1993). This kind of thinking is not just a diagnostic tool but an important part of politics and decision-making. In a social context, who will speak for a watershed and ensure that watershed needs are not neglected? Certain interests—individuals, groups, and institutions—tend to be well represented. But biophysical systems need representation as well, and this is where the watershed offers a distinct scale for politics. Watershed politics is far from new but it remains a work in progress. Watersheds can be visible or invisible, organized or unorganized, powerful or powerless. To this end I illustrate each chapter with a brief watershed case study. These are intended to ground the political relationships under discussion while also offering a unifying thread within the book. Overall, my approach is to follow the freshwater politics in whatever form they take, remaining faithful to disciplinary fundamentals while pushing their implications further than is normally done within the familiar and traditional paradigms. The watershed case study sites are illustrated in Map 0.1. The book is organized in the following way. It begins with an exploration of how political activity arises in Canada’s freshwater sector. Part One raises questions about the nature of politics, the role of power, and the significance of group organization. Here we introduce the key concepts that can advance the analysis. Freshwater politics is shown to be rooted in the diversity of interests that characterize communities and societies. Power is linked to the capacity to realize preferred interests, particularly in the face of rival or contrary interests. Group politics offers a means for defining, and mobilizing support for, such interests. Another essential framework involves the state structures that impinge on freshwater decision-making. Modern states take a variety of forms, but they share the quality of institutional complexity (i.e., they are made up of many parts). In Canada, the freshwater state involves several jurisdictional levels—national, provincial, regional, and local. In the chapters below we inquire into the roles of

I ntr o d uc ti o n   xvii Map 0.1  Drainage Basins and Watershed Case Study Sites Mackenzie River

ARCTIC LaGrande River MACKENZIE

PACIFIC

HUDSON BAY ATLANTIC

L

RCHIL

CHU

HU

DS

NELSON

Athabasca River

Oldman River

GULF OF MEXICO

ON

PEI BA Y

Souris River

. ST

Red River

E

NC

RE

W LA

Miramichi

West River Boat Harbour

each actor: the centrality of provincial powers for water administration; the rise and fall of federal freshwater initiatives in the decades since 1950; the roles of regional authorities in dealing with conservation management; and the potential for municipal governments to exert greater prominence. Part Two addresses five leading policy issues affecting freshwater politics— fisheries and pollution, irrigation agriculture, flood control, hydro-electric development, and groundwater management. Each policy subsector has a revealing historical past and each one remains pressing today. The subsectors will illustrate how political power is manifest in public policy and how political issues shape water use patterns. Here we see compelling evidence that Canadian freshwater policy has been driven more by purpose than by neglect, even if the traditional purposes are under intensifying dispute today. Also evident is the challenge of dealing, simultaneously, with multiple water uses. In fact, the limits of traditional administrative tools have propelled a creative new discussion of water politics, drawing increasingly on ecology, governance, and sustainability. Part Two closes with a discussion of emerging trends in freshwater politics. A final ambition of this book is to encourage the study and practice of freshwater politics at the local and regional levels. The concepts and propositions advanced in the chapters that follow can offer tools for political action. The watersheds and sub-watersheds where readers live can be the settings for observation, exploration, and intervention. The discussions in this volume can stimulate parallel investigations and applications in the thousands of sub-watersheds and local drainages where people live across Canada. I hope that this book helps readers to think differently about the freshwater resource and what we do with it.

This page intentionally left blank

1

Water Politics as Diversity

T

as political phenomena. It begins with some comments on politics as an activity. Next, the watershed is introduced as a unit that can demarcate water constituencies and highlight water interests. Watersheds range from the very large to the very small and are often nested within one another. Here we consider a range of watershed scales, from the continental drainage to the major river basin to the tributary basin and the sub-watershed. For the purposes of this chapter, four types of watershed relationships deserve particular attention—in-stream interests, riparian (shoreline) interests, surface to subsurface interests, and changing historical interests through time. To illustrate the shape of watershed politics, this chapter’s case study is based on the James and West River drainage in Nova Scotia. Politics is about shared social concerns and can arise anywhere beyond the private world of the individual. In groups, people must deal with both personal and collective matters. This generates complicated challenges, and when ideas, interests, or behaviours collide, the question is how to deal with them. One answer is to impose a unilateral solution that is enforced on all parties. This is the standard response for dictators and authoritarians: in the face of social diversity, they opt to ignore, deny, or suppress it. An alternative is to acknowledge differences as legitimate and seek ways to bridge or reconcile them. In liberal democracy, for example, the classic method is to follow the majority principle while at the same time protecting the interests or rights of minorities. This generally involves open discussion, persuasion, bargaining, and compromise—all classic “political” activities. Problems may not be settled for all time, but they can be resolved for a while. Sometimes this works well and one fault line recedes to be replaced by another. Other times the process fails and conflicts can recur and deepen. Many of these preferences and differences are rooted in our backgrounds. The American political scientist E.E. Schattschneider remarked that much of the raw material of politics can be found in the content of the census rolls. He meant that every nation’s census recorded a series of social distinctions with the potential to fuel political difference in modern life: religion, language, ethnicity, locale, class, gender, and age to name a few (Schattschneider 1967). This is precisely what makes society complex—the myriad affiliations that unite and divide peoples. At any given time and on any given issue, the political battle assumes a particular shape. Water politics is no exception. So we might say that politics arises out of conditions of social diversity and the need to meet challenges of different ideas, interests, and behaviours. In addition, politics involves the activity of managing this complexity and the conflicts it generates. Notice that, by this account, conflict is natural, inevitable, and possibly his chapter introduces freshwater and watersheds

4   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s even creative. There are a variety of techniques and practices available to meet this challenge and many of them will be explored in future chapters. How might we approach the role of politics in the freshwater resource? No one denies that water is one of the vital elements supporting life on earth— animal, vegetable, and human. There is an impressive global supply of freshwater, but it is very unevenly distributed. Many nations and societies are water-rich while others are water-poor. Nor is there any necessary correlation between areas of ample or surplus supply and areas of intense human habitation. Indeed the struggles to survive in circumstances of water shortage, or to secure adequate water access, drives politics on many scales. Looking beyond humans to the wider natural world, ecosystems are closely framed by water regimes that can determine their range of viable species, habitats, and environmental adaptive patterns. Even in the immediate absence of humans, water catchments and water flows directly influence the conditions of life. So it is not surprising that the interests of nonhuman life can occupy a significant place in water politics. Modern concerns with protecting biodiversity and habitat health are cases in point.

The Watershed Unit Such factors underline the need to look beyond the individual constituents to highlight water systems. In the 1300s the Germans fashioned the term wasserschiede, which translates into English as “water partition.” It underlines the fact that when water falls to the earth’s surface as precipitation, it flows according to gravity within topographic landforms. Part of this flow is absorbed at the earth’s surface and may enter a subterranean groundwater complex. Another part flows across surface land, feeding streams and rivers that follow contours of declining elevation. Thus wasserschiede and its English derivation watershed are defined spatially to encompass an inclusive territory between heights of land. A watershed is of primary importance in both a physical and a political sense. Physically, it delineates a landscape connected by a shared water system. Given the centrality of flow, it makes sense to think of the drainage area as an interdependent unit. Politically, a watershed defines a community of residents with a shared social experience. Part of this experience involves activities that impact the watershed. As Schattschneider might say, the census data in a watershed offer clues to the shape of the water constituency. This is not to say that a community always consciously defines itself this way, or that the watershed is the overriding scale of community. Nevertheless, the shared circumstance of life in the watershed is an underlying physical and social reality. As an example, take the major social and economic consumptive uses of Canadian freshwater. In 2005 the largest use-category nationally was for thermalelectric power generation (Statistics Canada 2009). Here fossil fuel and nuclear plants use two-thirds of all water withdrawals, for steam production and cooling. The next largest category is manufacturing with 14 per cent of all withdrawals. Pulp and paper is the leading sector, followed by primary metals and chemical production. Residential water consumption comes next and accounts for 9 per cent.

1 Wat e r P o l i ti c s a s Di ver s i ty   5 The final 10 per cent is shared between agriculture, commercial, public water distribution systems, mining, and oil and gas. It should be noted that these aggregate uses only begin to chart the shape of the water constituency. Most flowing water in Canada is not directly consumed each year, and a far wider set of interests have stakes in its nonconsumptive uses. Looking at them more closely, most watersheds are not just single linear systems so much as networks of nested systems. The most elementary are the small streams that first collect flowing water. These feed, in turn, into ever larger rivers as the system unfolds. River ecologists capture these relations in the notion of “stream ordering.” When several primary or originating streams converge, they create a stream of a second order. Similarly several secondary streams join to create one of a third order. Any river system can be mapped in this way, with complex watersheds involving up to a dozen or more orders. Within this sequence, physical conditions can be expected to range along a continuum, so that the river not only means different things to different persons but is objectively different from place to place (Vannote, Minshall, Cummins, Sedell, and Cushing 1980). There is also a social dimension of stream ordering that has not received as much attention. Where and how people live within a watershed—on the main stem, on a tributary, in a catchment basin but away from the stream flow—matters in shaping political interests and alignments. A watershed, then, is a geopolitical drainage unit that figures at several levels. In Canada the largest scale involves the five great continental drainage areas that empty into oceans. In order of size of area drained, these are the Hudson Bay, the Arctic, the Great Lakes-St. Lawrence, the Pacific, and the Gulf of Mexico drainages (whose headwaters include modest stretches of river in southern Alberta and Saskatchewan). In an effort to remind us about our cultural as well as physical aquatic heritage, Hugh MacLennan wrote a book about seven great Canadian rivers—the Fraser, Mackenzie, Saskatchewan, Red, St. Lawrence, Ottawa, and Saint John (McLennan 1961). While these figure prominently in the great historical sweep of the nation, they are not alone. In total, Statistics Canada (2009) identifies 25 major river basins or drainage regions. Some of these, particularly in the Arctic and Hudson Bay drainage areas, remain in their wild form today. Most others, however, have been heavily modified by the combined forces of habitation and engineering. There was once a time when river basins provided a basis for social organization—for Aboriginal peoples, commercial fur traders, and colonial timber merchants. This declined sharply, however, with the rise of state sovereignty and industrial capitalism. Furthermore, drainage geography does not coincide with units of government. Three-quarters of the 25 major river basins straddle either provincial or international boundaries. This asymmetry adds yet another layer of political complication that is taken up in chapters below. A third scale of watershed function is the tributary basin or subdrainage that is enclosed within one of the major river basins. Here Statistics Canada lists 164 separate units. In southern Alberta, for example, the Bow, Red Deer, and

6   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s Oldman Rivers are all significant tributaries to the South Saskatchewan River system. In Manitoba, the Assiniboine and the Souris have a similar relation to the Red River. Often it is the tributary basin that delimits the scope of a regional water community most accurately, since it is here that people share a regional and local awareness of basin interdependence. Accordingly, an important challenge in watershed analysis is to clarify the modes of linkage between tributary and main river systems. The Athabasca watershed that is explored in chapter 3 hosts 11 tributary basins. Such tributaries also tend to be the base units for the studies of river stress and river health that figure prominently in “state of the watershed” reporting. A fourth scale, numbering in the thousands across the country, is the subwatershed. It is difficult to specify exact proportions here. In Alberta, the Milk River might be considered a sub-watershed in the vast Missouri River system, which is itself a tributary of the Mississippi.Yet the Milk River drainage encompasses 61,000 km2 (in Alberta and Montana) with 30 tributaries of its own. This is an area larger than the entire province of Nova Scotia where, incidentally, there are no unifying river basins on a larger scale. Instead, Nova Scotia contains 44 primary watersheds, of which the Mersey River is the largest at a modest area of 2,800 km2. Parts of Atlantic Canada are sometimes characterized as “maritime coastal” to capture a distinct pattern of small sub-watersheds and microcatchments that represent genuinely “local” river flows. One of these, the West River of Antigonish County, Nova Scotia, is described in greater detail below.

A Watershed in Four Dimensions While the physical watershed is a necessary starting point, it is human habitation that fuels freshwater politics. This is a world of extraordinary variation, raising questions of culture, economy, and society. For this study, however, we begin with a simple premise. People’s underlying interests in water tend to be activitycentred and site-specific. It is the surprising range of these commitments that drive the politics. So, recalling Schattschneider’s observation, we need to start by asking who makes up a watershed community or population. Earlier in the discussion we surveyed the territorial dimension of water systems. While a focus on water does not necessarily require an awareness of watersheds, it tends eventually to lead back to them. It is the fixed character of the water supply variable that initially dictates the spatial focus. But it is the social activity that dictates the nature of an interest or claim. Indigenous fishers know the prime pools and river reaches to exploit and the prime times of year in which to do so. Cattle drovers followed “trails” that were devised to ensure their herds had periodic access to watering holes and rivers. Fur merchants built their trade posts at the confluence of river systems that maximized canoe traffic flows. Farmers prize lands that are adjacent to waterways, as do commercial towns and industrial mills. Hydro-electric businesses seek out sites where large volumes of water can be impounded behind dams, creating substantial hydraulic heads to drive turbines. While each may be fashioned in terms of its specific rationale, such activities eventually interact with one another. Consider a simple example. We know

1 Wat e r P o l i ti c s a s Di ver s i ty   7 that people rely upon freshwater for a variety of purposes, the most basic of which might include personal consumption, support for vegetative cover (forests to fields), support for animals on land (wild and domestic), support for aquatic wildlife, transportation, and kinetic energy (mill wheels and turbines). These are diverse and potentially incompatible claims. Given the finite and uneven supply of water, rules of access are required to guide the consumption, production, and distribution of this resource. Clearly water access has a value. It can be captured, possessed, used, stored, sold, and licensed. In short, its finite quantity and uneven availability makes water socially and politically contestable. Many diverse and innately political questions arise from the collision of uses and interests. Is there sufficient drinking and sanitary water, in quantity and quality, and should this assume priority status? This is a distributive question that turns on a single use. Should that water be treated as a basic entitlement or a scarce commodity? What, then, about in-stream water uses for fishing or transportation? Each can entail modifications in the streamflow, in the form of weirs and fish nets or channel dredging or straightening. Who can capture aquatic animals and in what measure? Then there is the question of water diversion away from its natural flow, to irrigate fields for crop cultivation or to water livestock. Are there limits as to the manner of appropriating and diverting flows away from the stream? Similarly, what regulates the impoundment of water to harness hydraulic energy to power machinery? It is clear that many if not most of these water-centred interests have the capacity to facilitate or detract from other interests. Many of the complications arise from the characteristics of  “flow,” which links interests at different sites along the watercourse. Upstream residents are in a position to alter the prospects of downstream users, both in quantitative (water withdrawal) and qualitative (water pollution) terms. Downstream residents can reverse the effect, by damming a river and flooding upstream lands. Finally, we must factor in the variable of time. Do early entrants enjoy a superior claim to late arrivals? What about the shifting historical profiles of water demand? Do new ways of thinking (science studies or technological applications, for example) modify the uses, practices, and regulations of earlier eras? How will changing philosophies on the role of the state and the market affect freshwater regimes? Taking all of this into account it is evident that, regardless of size, any watershed can be usefully approached through a four-dimensional framework, set out in Figure 1.1. As Stanford and Ward put it, “rivers are four-dimensional environments that involve processes that connect upstream-downstream, channel-hyporheic (groundwater) and channel-floodplain (riparian) zones or patches, and these differ temporally” (Stanford and Ward 1992, 91). This can be applied for social as well as ecological purposes. The sections that follow will address each in turn. The Water Channel: Upstream/Downstream Relations For most people, the most readily recognizable aspect of a watershed system is flow. A river rises at a source, proceeds downstream, may be joined by tributaries

8   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s Figure 1.1  A Watershed in Four Dimensions Divide Tributaries

Divide

UPSTREAMDOWNSTREAM

Sub-basin

Hill Slope

SURFACESUBSURFACE Valley RIPARIAN Groundwater

TEMPORAL 1850–

1900–

1950–

2000

or interrupted by lakes and waterfalls, and eventually reaches its end. It travels in what hydrologists describe as the water channel, the area between banks where the stream normally runs. Water channels are dynamic, with speed and temperature varying within the stream. The channel footprint can also be altered by natural forces over longer time frames, carving out new directions, depths, and borders. In various phases of culture, humans can make differing imprints on the channel. Hunters and gatherers step lightly, taking fish, riding the current, and adapting to seasonal change. This is not to suggest that their water technologies were crude—in fact quite the opposite. A stone weir constructed across a stream holds up migrating fish long enough for spearing or basket dipping, while the weir can be repaired or rebuilt in each new season. Equally, the bark canoe that was perfected by Amerindians proved to be the most effective mode of travel for centuries and was a critical underpinning of the European fur trade (Morse 1969). As the colonial economy shifted from fish and fur to timber, however, the water needs changed. The eastern Canadian forests offered potentially valuable commodities if the logs could be transported from stump to mill. Since this distance could be dozens or hundreds of kilometres, however, the timber trade looked to rivers as the only available transport medium. Trees were felled in the bush and the logs hauled to a river bank. When streamflow surged with the spring melt, the logs were dumped in to float downstream where they would eventually be recaptured by the producer (Lower 1938).

1 Wat e r P o l i ti c s a s Di ver s i ty   9 The orderly conduct of a log-drive, however, required that the river be engineered for the purpose. Part of this involved the construction of splash dams on feeder streams, to hold back spring waters until a timed release that augmented the flow and extended the drive period. Another part involved the elimination of chronic bottlenecks to the timber flow. Nothing was more disruptive than a log jam at a tight meander in the channel or a set of rock outcrops or rapids. A common response was to straighten the river by digging an alternate channel that cut out the meanders to make a less obstructed run. In the face of more dramatic physical obstacles such as falls and canyons, an artificial flow route could be constructed by building an elevated flume or canal to bypass the problem or even to switch the log flow between rivers. None of this could eliminate all difficulties, though, and the skills of the river driving crews that rode the logs downstream to release the jams were critical to delivering an entire year’s log harvest (MacKay 1978). It is interesting to note that on major driving rivers such as the Ottawa, where logs flowed from dozens of tributaries toward a common stem stream, rival companies often recognized the need for collective action. In effect, they negotiated formal understandings to coordinate their driving efforts and reduce the mutually destructive rush for primacy. This could involve the joint financing and operation of river works among the crews sharing a watercourse, the pooling of (marked) logs in common drives, and the eventual sorting of the product at the lower end (Lower 1938). In effect, the timber barons fashioned an early governing structure for single-use river management. None of this was without costs to the natural functioning of the river ecology. Log drives were notorious for scarring the beds, and the various engineering works could alter the natural services of the channel. But this was just the beginning. The industrial era depended on the ability to tap reliable energy sources to drive machines. Flowing water was an early candidate, as kinetic energy could be captured by water wheels and could be geared to power machines in a factory. While run-of-the-river mills had modest effects upon stream conditions, mill-pond water storage was the first step toward the dams and reservoirs that would dramatically transform river flows. Industrial manufacturing also treated freshwater as a plumbing system by discharging wastes that the current would sweep away. From sawdust and wood chips to toxic chemicals and mine tailings, the industrial economy exploited streamflow for private profit. As the old slogan put it, “the solution to pollution is dilution.” By the 1960s, such sentiments came under increasing challenge. The Riparian Transect: Stream/Bank Relations The second dimension highlights the complicated interactions between streamflow and the land-based features that confine it. This is often described as “riparian” and captures the interplay between shore activity and water. As a result, ecologists speak of a riparian zone as the transitional space along a bank, and lawyers deal with riparian law as the rules governing shore-based access to water

10  fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s flow. In this section we consider how designs on water trigger complications among shore-based political interests. A distinct pattern of instream transformations attended the new industrial towns of nineteenth-century New England and eastern Canada. For the early factory manufacturer, one of the greatest challenges was a source of motive power to drive machines. A flowing river offered a potential answer if it could be brought under control. This was far from straightforward, however. In particular, the law of the time guaranteed many rights of use in the rural economy that ran along the streamflows and prevented any single “owner” from seizing control. In a now classic study, Steinberg describes the political transformation of the 186-km Merrimack River that rises in New Hampshire and flows first south then east, emptying into the Atlantic north of Boston. Between 1825 and 1850 four significant factory towns grew up along its lower reaches. In Lowell, Mass., for example, a series of textile mills became the backbone to the town and water energy was commodified and sold. This required the town to change its approach and treat water power as an overriding priority, to help finance the major dams required to impound water and in so doing to block the river at multiple points. Once business interests were licensed and in possession of water power, they could sell it to energy consumers. At Lowell, a series of canals delivered water through the town where mills bought it on a flow-through basis. Here power was denominated in the new economic unit of  “mill power,” that measured the energy needed to drive a quantum of spindles and looms (Steinberg 1991). Of course these measures had echo effects on other riparian interests along the length of the Merrimack valley. In addition to the many dams that were built to impound water for the industrial towns, the power developers faced another challenge. Precipitation and waterflow varied seasonally while factory operations were constant, and as a result the demand for water tended to outpace the river supply, especially during the summer. This led power developers to acquire land and water rights at points upstream where water could be held back to supplement flows during the low season (an amplification of the timber cutters’ splash dam system). By the 1850s the dams had reached the headwaters of the river in a lake system in New Hampshire that fed the Merrimack River. The Lake Company acquired the necessary rights and closed the flow with a new dam at Lake Village in 1851. The lake waters then rose above the shoreline, inundating farm and pasture lands and disrupting the businesses of ferries and log rafters. The growing political conflict exploded in September 1859 when a group of 50 men attacked the dam and sought to destroy it (Steinberg 1991). Here we see an example of a common syndrome, in which political grievances between community and outside interests accumulate until they reach a trigger point when local resistance breaks out. In this case we see how the social watershed defines both the protagonists (farmers, loggers, pastoralists, power generators, mill owners, and town leaders, among others) and the political fault lines (agrarian alliance and industrial alliance) between new and prior users.

1 Wat e r P o l i ti c s a s Di ver s i ty   11 An aggravating feature in riparian politics is that the property and tenure rules for streams, stream beds, and adjacent lands seldom coincide. It is possible to have private property along stream banks, and crown or public property in the water channel, while stream beds may be private or public, as specified in law. A further complication comes from residents and potential water users not immediately adjacent to waterflows. This brings in questions of right-of-way and easements for public works that serve communities set back from the waterfront. The Groundwater Resource: Surface/Subsurface Relations Water stored below ground is the hidden face of the hydrologic cycle. Even today, many people find it impossible to conceive the scale or the structure of this resource. Indeed, for much of human history it was mysterious—bubbling to the surface as springs or pooling at the bottom of dug wells that seemed to go dry as often as not. Many early cultures developed a sophisticated approach to groundwater. Despite the severity of desert landscapes, people maintained wells along their travel routes. This was possible because of ancient water deposited in former river strata from glacial times. In parts of the Middle East and North Africa, quite elaborate systems of groundwater supply known as qanats were constructed as early as 1000 BC. Each consisted of a central supply (or “mother”) well dug, if possible, in foothills that were amply endowed with groundwater. Then an underground tunnel ran out from this point to villages at lower elevations, with periodic access shafts along the way. Qanat tunnels could run for 40–45 km (Cech 2003). A modern understanding of groundwater emerged in the geological science of the nineteenth century. Scientists showed that water seeped into the ground where it lodged in the porous spaces of sedimentary deposits. A water table marked the boundary between saturated sediments and aerated ones, a dynamic frontier that rose and fell according to precipitation and absorptive capacities (and was reflected in those shifting well water levels). Along with this came a new understanding that surface to subsurface flows went both ways. Surface water can infiltrate the substrate to enter the groundwater. Equally, groundwater can re-enter surface streams, particularly on sloped surfaces where the water table rises above the channel level. In North America, the agricultural frontier expanded along waterways wherever possible. Eventually, however, a rush of western settlement was set loose by the US Homestead Act of 1862 and the Dominion Lands Act of 1872 in Canada. In time, river valley lands were fully taken and late arrivals had to contend with prairie drylands. Here the rural well became the first necessity for a viable livelihood, and by the 1870s windmills dotted the prairie horizon, lifting well water for surface use. While the farm windmills are now largely gone, groundwater dependence is still a defining feature of country life and distinguishes it from urban culture. When rural neighbours ask one another “How’s your water?” they are acknowledging the pivotal role of residential wells in supporting habitation. The law also has been challenged to arbitrate groundwater titles, rights, and obligations. One doctrine known as the rule of capture gave landowners

12

fre shwate r p ol i t i c s

the right to extract groundwater without limit from beneath owned lands. In nineteenth-century England, judges conceded their ignorance of how groundwater worked while endorsing a “capture” doctrine for groundwater appropriation, usually with some rules of priority. When competition for groundwater intensified, other rules such as reasonable use (by neighbouring users) were factored into some laws while in others, sharing criteria were defined to achieve minimum levels of entitlement. The Temporal Dimension: Cumulative and Successive Development The factor of time belongs, in some ways, to historians whether they study natural or social life. Some of the most insightful contributions to water politics have come through histories of particular rivers or basins. In recent years the Fraser and the Bow in Canada, and the Colorado and the Columbia in the United States, have all been presented in this way (Evenden 2004; Armstrong et al. 2009; Fradkin 1996; White 1995). An essential element in the understanding of water politics involves the structural “layering” of physical and social changes from past to present. Geographers and political economists sometimes speak of the phenomenon of “uneven and combined development.” This highlights the fact that spatial areas evolve at different paces, and their profile at a particular point in time is a product of successive changes. In this sense, the watershed unit involves a complicated dialectic of time, place, and activity. There is one more preliminary point to be made about watershed politics. In sociopolitical terms, watersheds are never completely self-contained. While the resident population demarcates a political constituency, there are higher order systems that inevitable impinge. Two of these are the nation state and global capitalism. Ever since the age of European empire, outside forces have treated lands and waters as sources of potential wealth. The fur merchants of the 1700s and the timber barons of the 1800s did not hesitate to transform the Canadian hinterland into engines of commercial profit. Neither did the immigrant settlers arriving on the prairies in the early 1900s or the electricity magnates who drove the hydro-power revolution in the twentieth century. It is important to realize that the political polarities of watershed politics often involve forces and interests “external” to the watershed itself. Even if such interests have a local presence, a full understanding of their behaviour requires that wider horizons be factored in.

CASE STUDY: THE JAMES-WEST RIVER, NOVA SCOTIA Local rivers and streams are the most familiar manifestation of watersheds. Consider a small but representative Canadian example of a local watershed that still awaits the writing of its history. In rural Nova Scotia, the West River and its tributaries flow through the western half of Antigonish County. The river drains an area of approximately 900 km2, an intermediate size among the province’s 44 small watersheds. The system begins in the highlands where three main tributaries are sourced: the James, Beaver, and Ohio Rivers. Each flows easterly as it

1 Wat e r P o l i ti c s a s Di ver s i ty   13 descends and they converge near the midpoint of the basin to become the West River, which continues for 12 km before emptying into the sea at Antigonish Harbour. Map 1.1 illustrates the West River, its tributaries, and the adjacent local watersheds. Overall the territory offers striking variations, from the forested uplands where the source waters rise, to the alluvial floodplains of the lower river and the broad estuary at the river’s mouth at Antigonish town. The area was extensively traversed by Aboriginal Mi’kmaq people for millennia before the arrival of European immigrants in the late eighteenth century. Scots settlers took up coastal lands from the 1780s, and a group of decommissioned colonial soldiers received land grants around the river estuary in 1784.

Map 1.1   James-West River Watershed, Nova Scotia

Rig

hts

GEORGES BAY

R

iv

So

er

u t h R i gh t sR

ive

r

ANTIGONISH HARBOUR

ANTIGONISH

es

Ri v

B r i e r ly B r o o k

e

r

m

Ja

es

tR

er

iv

W

Be av

er

Ri v e

r

0

O

hi

o R iv

er

1

2

3

4 km

14  fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s A town emerged to service the commercial needs of this frontier society. As settlement accelerated over the next half century, pioneer farms and villages dotted the land, first as subsistence producers and later as mixed domestic and commercial farming operations. The earliest land titles were taken out along the coast and on river banks along the lower reaches of the West River. By the 1870s and 1880s, even the more remote interior was intensively occupied. In fact, this was the time when the county population peaked. Thereafter, small farms were increasingly abandoned, beginning with the marginal upland properties where the soils were poorer, the growing season was shorter, and the yields were lower. Typically such cleared farmland grew back into forest over a period of 30–40 years, leaving little evidence, beyond the crumbling stone foundations, of the extent of frontier agriculture. In the 1800s pioneer logging was an important seasonal activity as well, with small sawmills located along numerous waterways. As elsewhere in the country, the channels of the upper tributaries were in some cases straightened for timber driving, by cutting off the meanders to facilitate more direct water flow. In the lower reaches of the watershed, the county town was incorporated in 1889 at the mouth of the West River. In fact, three small watersheds converged at this point to empty into Antigonish Harbour. The townsite proved to be highly functional as an entrepôt, linking upland farms to commercial marine traffic and trade in the Gulf of St. Lawrence. However, the convergence of local drainages meant that the town was highly vulnerable to seasonal floods, both during the spring melt and as a result of sudden summer storms. Indeed, the history of Antigonish town can be written in part through the 27 major flood events that were recorded over the century before 1982 (MacLaren Plansearch 1983). In Antigonish County, as elsewhere in Nova Scotia, the rural land base was predominantly privately owned by 1900. This was a result of a century of land grants and sales of rural property that left the provincial crown with less than 15 per cent of the total. It did, however, facilitate a farm, village, and small town social structure in the West River watershed and few legal rules on water use. In the early twentieth century the social access to the watershed was extremely decentralized. In addition to farm properties, clusters of houses sprang up along stream paths adjacent to mills or local stores, and dozens of local communities dotted the landscape. Grist- and sawmills required permits, but otherwise water politics, to the extent that it arose, was either settled by private arrangements or by the courts and common law. The 1919 Water Act vested streams in provincial crown title to facilitate hydro-electric development and curtail rural resistance to such projects. But in Antigonish County, the first major dam and reservoir project was probably the town water supply scheme built on the Rights River at Clydesdale. Not until the 1970s and 1980s did state authority begin to impinge on the watershed in significant ways. When this happened, it took a revealing form. A variety of federal and provincial administrative agencies drew on separate

1 Wat e r P o l i ti c s a s Di ver s i ty   15 pieces of legislation to make their marks. As a result, watershed regulation tended to be segmented by function, institution, and spatial focus. In some sections the predominant concern was flood control, in others fish habitat protection, and in still others farm practices, timber harvesting, drinking water supply, or wilderness protection. One of the first emerging policy concerns was flood control. Under the terms of the new Canada-Nova Scotia Flood Damage Reduction Program of 1975, Antigonish town was one of five designated sites within the province. A dam was built on the Brierley Brook in 1976 to slow the flood surge from this very “flashy” river before it reached the town. Flood mapping was also done in conjunction with municipal zoning, and funds were provided to modify bridges that aggravated ice flow build-up in spring. In the 1980s the federal Department of Fisheries and Oceans announced a major turn toward fish habitat protection. This broke new ground with the mandate to regulate “harmful alteration, damage or destruction” of fish habitat. It gave federal officials leverage to monitor river flow rates and establish base flow rates when dams and reservoirs were involved. When Antigonish town demand for drinking water exceeded the storage capacity of the Clydesdale reservoir located on the Rights River, a new location was chosen in the middle reaches of the James River. This represented the most significant historical alteration of a tributary basin to date. It altered the flow characteristics by impounding approximately 9 million gallons (50 million litres) behind an earth-filled concrete dam. A water treatment facility was installed below the new dam and the water moved by gravity pipe to the town storage towers. A decade later, in the face of further shortfalls and the need for dam upgrades, the dam height was raised by more than 2 metres and the reservoir storage enlarged to 22 million gallons. This included a maintenance flow passage for downstream fish habitat (CBCL Ltd. 2003). Almost immediately the supply situation tightened again, and the prospect of further impoundments, perhaps by way of a second dam further upstream, has been considered. In 1988 the Nova Scotia Department of Environment designated the James River drainage above the dam as a protected source area. As a result, land use was curtailed within this former timbershed, to minimize the likelihood of contamination. In the 1990s, the provincial Department of Agriculture began to promote environmental farm practices that included excluding livestock from river access and limiting fertilizer applications in riparian zones to protect against manure and chemical runoffs. This applied particularly to the West River between the confluence of tributaries and the river mouth. Forestry science has long recognized the links between rainfall, vegetative cover, and erosion. However, in a private land culture such as Nova Scotia’s, where farm and woodlot owners have long harboured suspicions about government intent, the provincial government has been reluctant to exercise its water title powers. Best practice management “guidelines” have been far more frequent than legal rules when it came to timber harvesting in riparian zones. In 2002,

16  fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s however, the province enacted Watercourse Forest Protection regulations that defined a protected corridor along stream flows. While this applies throughout watersheds, its particular impact on the West River system is in the upper tributaries. Late in the 1990s the Eigg Mountain area, including parts of the upper James River watershed, was nominated as a candidate wilderness area under the Nova Scotia protected areas scheme. It was sponsored by several environmental NGOs (nongovernmental organizations) campaigning for a highland wilderness to be set aside in eastern Nova Scotia. The fact that the area was one of the few crownowned areas in Antigonish County eased the land tenure sensitivities, though it also contributed to the irregular (patchwork) shape of the Eigg Mountain wilderness. The result is that commercial activity is significantly curtailed in the designated areas. A final phase of basin regulation involves the mouth of the West River where it empties into the estuary at Antigonish Harbour. Here the freshwater from the river mixes with saltwater from the ocean to create a distinct ecosystem. Estuaries tend to be rich in species and highly productive. They also tend to be vulnerable to upstream pollution, whether it involves wood chip wastes, soil deposition, fertilizer leaching, dam and reservoir constraints, or urban pollution. Traditionally it was assumed that tidal flushing could remedy many of these problems. More recently, however, water monitoring programs have been imposed by federal and provincial authorities, often unevenly and in response to particular concerns. One agency might sample shellfish beds while another might sample water chemistry. In sum, at least seven distinct government regulatory regimes now impinge on the West River watershed. It is hard to argue that instruments for watershed management are lacking. Indeed, their accumulation marks a qualitative shift in public sector involvement. Equally striking, however, is the pattern of administrative overlay. This is extremely segmented, with multiple agencies exercising distinct tools for separate policy purposes. There is little formal coordination or integration among them, though local officials do tend to talk to one another and certain enforcement powers can be delegated among different services. It is best described as an unplanned accumulation of programs that arose in response to different problems. From mouth to source, this includes federal water monitoring in the estuary (Environment Canada), federal-provincial-municipal flood planning in the town and provincial farm activity rules (Department of Agriculture), provincial watercourse timber rules (Department of Natural Resources), federal fish habitat protection (Fisheries and Oceans), provincial drinking water supply regulations (Department of Environment), and provincial wilderness protected areas (Department of Environment). The interests of municipal government have already been addressed. The West River regulatory profile is not unusual in Canada and it helps explain today’s calls for more integrated watershed management.

1 Wat e r P o l i ti c s a s Di ver s i ty   17

Conclusion We have seen above that freshwater politics is driven by ideas and interests that are diverse and complex. Each community has a particular pattern of social and political interests and this pattern evolves over time. Watersheds provide a promising framework for the study of freshwater politics, by delineating social geographies with a shared interest in the water resource. Among the watershed dimensions that can structure water politics, it is useful to consider stream flows, riparian relations, surface to groundwater, and the temporal dimension. However, freshwater politics also extend well beyond the watershed scale. The centralized state and the globalized market are two cases in point. Here key decisions are made externally even though the impacts will eventually register locally. Indeed, it may be that the interplay of these different scales—regional, national, and global—drives the course of freshwater politics. The West River history helps to illustrate the cumulative and connected nature of human activities, with the potential to affect any or all levels of the watershed. The nineteenth century saw the first significant social transformation, as Euro-Canadian immigrants occupied small rural properties for farming and timber cutting. This socially decentralized economy, which peaked in the 1880s, was closely aligned with watercourses. The turn of the century saw a decline of the rural economy. Not only was land abandoned but new rail and highway modes of transport made watercourses less central to rural life. In the late twentieth century state authorities began to grasp the importance of watersheds in a multidimensional way, with separate agencies extending their mandates to different aspects of the West River system. By the turn of this century at least seven distinct programs played a role. The James River tributary was the most dramatically affected when the town of Antigonish established its new drinking water supply system. The potential for overlaps, contradictions, and complications is substantial and capable of triggering differing degrees of state intervention. We see the growth of a mosaic of social habitation, water use constituencies, and water regulatory programs, though it often occurs with little appreciation of the watershed as an integrated system. As in most of Canada, holistic watershed planning remains a challenge for the future. There is probably no such thing as a “typical” watershed in Canada. The rural and small-town character of the West River system seems a long way from the Credit River watershed of the city of Toronto or the Wascana River watershed in Regina. However, each corresponds to a representative type. Of the 164 drainage sub-basins identified in a recent study, over half are classified as “highly rural.” (It should be noted that over half of the highly rural sub-basins are in the three northern Territories.) However, only one-fifth of the rural population lives in watersheds where rural residents form a majority. In other words, the social and political interaction of rural and urban elements is an animating factor in Canadian watersheds (Rothwell 2006).

2

Power and Freshwater

T

political power and its place in water politics. We begin with a discussion of power and a breakdown of its various dimensions. There are several types of power relations that are usefully distinguished from one another. To make this more concrete, the concept is linked with the history of the Mi’kmaq Aboriginal peoples of Maritime Canada, from precontact times to the present. After this, a case study is presented in the watershed surrounding Boat Harbour, Nova Scotia. This is a little-known but very important story of industrial pollution, imposed on a small Aboriginal community on questionable terms and perpetuated for more than half a century by an alliance of corporate and governmental interests. The power relations underlying this case are particularly revealing. his chapter explores the concept of

Faces of Power Politics is rooted in the diversity of interests that is found in social situations. Should diversity give rise to conflict, clearly not all can win. Political “power” can be described as the capacity to prevail in situations of conflict. The concept is useful in understanding the potential pathways to reconcile differences. Power, then, is a relational concept. In one classic formulation, Steven Lukes describes it as the capacity to achieve preferred goals in a contested setting, that is the capacity to prevail over rival claimants. A has power over B and C if A’s preferred goals are achieved while B’s and C’s are not (Lukes 1974). It is not difficult to see the relevance of this perspective to freshwater resources. Indeed, it should be clear that conflicting claims to water use arise continually. Upstream residents may impound, divert, or degrade the flows of water to downstream residents. Riparian landowners may block or restrict access to stream flows by residents who are set back from the banks. High-volume commercial extractions of groundwater can lower the water table and thereby deprive residents who depend on rural wells. What about the natural flow needs of a river to support aquatic life and riparian landscapes? How best to protect the interests of future generations that have no ready advocates when yesterday’s and today’s water users lock up preferential access? The natural flow structure of a drainage system cannot be assumed constant, either. With modern hydrological engineering it is possible to physically transform watersheds in the most fundamental ways. Dam and reservoir systems block natural flow patterns and turn rivers into segmented systems. Also, by means of canals and pipelines it is possible to divert waterflows between adjacent basins, creating permanent discrepancies. Physical alterations, large or small, have the potential to reorder the terms of advantage and disadvantage among interests. All of these tensions drive the water policy agendas of public life.

2 P o w er a nd F r es hwa ter   19 The powerful, then, are those that can realize their goals. The powerless are those who cannot prevail, those who try and fail or who never get the chance to engage at all. The last comment alludes to more subtle variants of power that go beyond visible decision-making. For example, Peter Bachrach and Morton Baratz advanced the concept of the “non-decision.” This refers to the capacity to block or suppress an issue before it can become part of the public debate. Thus a question or concern that might reasonably be expected to arise in light of the alignment of interests fails to register in political discussion (Bachrach and Baratz 1962, 1970). Non-decision-making involves keeping an issue off the public agenda. It implies that there are gatekeepers and veto-agents in the policy process who can, either on their own account or on behalf of others, exercise a subtle form of control in the early stages of a power sequence. Such absences are politically telling, as they can reflect a capacity by dominating interests to control the policy agenda to the point of preventing certain issues from even being raised. For example, when the government of British Columbia decided to control the headwaters of the Peace River by means of a massive hydro-electric dam and reservoir installation, it carried major consequences for communities downstream in the province of Alberta. By law, the federal government of Canada holds responsibilities for regulating navigable waters such as the Peace, and could have intervened to influence the project at the design stage.Yet Ottawa opted not to step in. This is an example of a non-decision, in which the federal government deliberately chose not to raise an issue after weighing the balance of rival interests. John Gaventa pushes beyond the circumstances of observable situational conflict to explore other nuanced dimensions of power. In particular he questions the significance of missing political interests—those that would be expected by virtue of their social circumstances to be active in politics but are not. There are several possibilities here. It may be that after repeated but unsuccessful attempts to shape issue outcomes, powerless interests conclude that the deck is stacked against them, accept their fate, and simply withdraw. This retreat from politics, it could be argued, is a rational response based on experiential outcomes. It does, however, leave a gap in the universe of organized interests. Another variation is a cultural or subcultural bias that tilts the social awareness of the powerless in directions compatible with the status quo and away from directions that entail challenge (Gaventa 1980). For example, in a patriarchal society, women are unlikely to be recognized as legitimate actors and their issues are unlikely to find voice. In a devoutly Catholic country with an extensive church hierarchy, issues of socialism, poverty, and modernity may be similarly repressed. In a culture where private property and profit-seeking are predominant, claims for community or public interest priorities will get short shrift. Within the general notion of power, several significant variations are commonly observed. For Lukes (1974), one of these is force, defined as the imposition of a desired outcome by physical domination, including violence. The colonist driving Indigenous peoples off traditional lands, the industrial capitalist hiring thugs to eliminate union organizers, and the dictator murdering or imprisoning

2 0   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s political rivals are all cases in point. It is one of the most common forms of power in human history, within and between families, tribes, kingdoms, or nations. Related but distinct from force is coercion. Here the anticipation of the threat of physical force is sufficient to induce compliance. This may be a function of past experience or awareness, where the memory of physical repression lingers on. Amerindian peoples may retreat from their traditional lands rather than face the ruthless suppression that they have seen already from the army, workers may opt not to organize unions in the workplace after witnessing the brutality of the Pinkerton agents or police, and reformers may abandon public protest in the face of abductions of the “disappeared.” Some agents of power understand the crucial significance of the bloody, violent deed in establishing a context of credible threat. Authority is another variant of power that is distinguished by securing compliance by consent. Here rivals are willing to accept political choices, even when they run against preferred outcomes, by virtue of the processes that have been followed. “Legitimacy” refers to an acceptance of a state of affairs as appropriate or necessary. This contrasts sharply with the earlier variants. Now B and C are willing to tolerate their relative subservience to A on an issue because, rather than simply being imposed by force, it has been decided in an acceptable way. It often turns on the institutional channels by which decisions are made. If such procedures are accepted as appropriate and reasonable, then the ensuing outputs can be treated the same way. If the Indigenous group has access to the courts but cannot convince a judge despite an opportunity to argue its case, if union organizers fail to sign up most workers in a secret workplace ballot mandated under labour laws, or if the authoritarian leader wins power by means of a relatively fair and open election—the outcomes reflect relations of authority. Finally, there is a relationship of influence. This can be described as a capacity to affect the flow of decision without fully controlling it. Here political interventions make a difference but do not render the desired results. The ensuing outcome is different than it would be without that agent’s involvement, but not so different that the agent in question fully succeeds. In this case, the Indigenous group succeeds in achieving limited land rights over only a part of traditional territories, the factory owner chooses to raise wages or improve shop conditions to head off union certification, and the dictator is obliged to concede an electoral voice to the people while continuing to exercise full executive powers. Because power relations are not necessarily “zero-sum” transactions where one party’s gain must be another party’s loss, it is quite possible to observe mixed results that point to influence as well as power. It can be useful to distinguish between these variants of power, as they point to specific mechanisms that can resolve conflicts.This can enhance our understanding of social and political control. The next section offers a more sustained example.

Mi’kmaq and Colonists: Dimensions of Power The Mi’kmaq peoples have considered the Atlantic region their homeland for millennia. In traditional life (i.e., before contact with Europeans), people followed

2 P o w er a nd F r es hwa ter   21 a seasonal cycle of movements between coastal and inland settings, drawing upon a variety of material resources based on hunting, fishing, and gathering. A large part of this involved freshwater resources on rivers, lakes, and estuaries. People congregated at such sites, often working together to capture and process fish during prime seasons. This could involve building a weir across a stream to slow the fish passage for spearing, or use of a net or basket, or fishing from a boat on the water (sometimes with torches) at night. These were significant social occasions where families or bands came together, staging a feast and curing and storing fish for later consumption. When European explorers such as Cartier and Champlain came ashore in the 1500s and planted the flags of French kings, the Mi’kmaq paid these visitors little initial attention. Latent in European claims, however, was a powerful transformative force. Beginning in the 1600s European immigrants began to arrive. Some were soldiers who opted to stay on after their military obligations were fulfilled while others were missionaries or traders or pioneer settlers. At first they had little impact on the Mi’kmaq. The Europeans were ignorant about how to survive and they relied heavily on the Indians for local knowledge and exchange. In fact they often sought “alliances” with Mi’kmaq as warriors or producers. The extended rivalries of English and French colonies, each with their own frontiers of influence, exacerbated this (Upton 1979). During this early phase, the advantage of force lay as much with the Mi’kmaq as with the immigrants. The Indians were an armed presence and often defeated Europeans, putting soldiers and settlers alike on the run. Put another way, territory was hotly contested. The mere threat of Mi’kmaq resistance (i.e., coercion) posed great problems to English colonial authorities. A common response after periods of open warfare was the negotiation of a treaty of peace and friendship. Equally frequent was the collapse of a treaty in response to subsequent provocations. Such volatile relationships suggest that power was far from stable in eighteenth-century Maritime Canada. However, the resort to treaties indicates a new stage of politics and power, where a negotiation between separate parties yielded a mutual agreement geared to regulating future relations. Certainly this is reflected in the language of the treaties with their undertakings and guarantees. Indians pledged to be amicable with settlers while the crown guaranteed Indian lands against encroachment and established truckhouses for regulated trade. For example, the Mascarene Treaty of 1725 assured the signatories continued rights to “hunting, fishing, gathering and all other their lawful occasions” (Mascarene Treaty 1725). In the 1700s the social balance began to shift again, as European numbers mounted and their interests changed. The Acadian farmers, who tended to ally with Indians, were expelled from the colony in 1756. English immigration quickened after the French withdrawal with the Treaty of Paris in 1763. Following their defeat in the American War of Independence, tens of thousands of British “loyalists” fled to the colony of Nova Scotia. The newcomers sought to locate in the same areas occupied traditionally by Mi’kmaq: in the coastal margins, at river

2 2   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s mouths and estuaries, and in the lower valleys where soils were best. To settlers ignorant of Aboriginal culture, the land might seem to be empty, a state of nature that begged for occupation and improvement. Colonial authorities encouraged this point of view, and confrontations over land proliferated. In the eyes of newly arrived deed holders, Mi’kmaq camping parties were unwanted “trespassers.” This was exacerbated as English colonial authorities expanded the offer of private land titles to immigrants. The prospect of free 100-acre plots lured massive immigration from the British Isles in the early 1800s. Forty thousand Scots alone arrived in Nova Scotia between 1815 and 1838 and a similar number of Irish entered New Brunswick between 1840 and 1860. As the alluvial river plains were exhausted, late arrivals took up land in less favourable river uplands, where soil was poorer, growing seasons shorter, and trips to market longer. Subject to neglect and hostility, the Mi’kmaq population declined to only a fraction of its precontact numbers. By the 1830s, colonial governments were bent on the pursuit of material exports and local commerce. Treaties were ignored and traditional Aboriginal land use was dismissed, at both the official and the popular levels. As Harald Prins puts it, “Outnumbered by hordes of poor immigrants running from cruel exploitation and squalor in Europe, Mi’kmaqs found themselves pressured into misery. Ranging through their former domains they saw gangs of white loggers destroying the woods and felt the pain of hunger when the game was gone. Great was their anger when aggressive newcomers refused them access to their ancient fishing sites or chased them from their favourite camping grounds. Even firewood was denied them” (Prins 1996, 165). By the end of the 1800s, Indians were confined to small tracts of federal “reserved” lands. For many, fishing was one of the few remaining lifelines. Then even access to the fishery was challenged by white society. Bill Parenteau has captured the complex processes by which Mi’kmaq fishing came under assault, in the Miramichi and other Atlantic salmon watersheds, in the closing decades of the nineteenth century (Parenteau 1998). This arose in part from white recreational fishers whose sense of  “sport” and “chase” was offended by Mi’kmaq techniques including river nettings and torch fishing by night. It was as much a distributional conflict as a cultural one, since the anglers and tourist operators aimed to secure long-term stocks by excluding a rival harvest. They found willing allies in the federal fisheries department and, over time, statutory measures were comprehensively framed to curb or even outlaw the Aboriginal fishery. Whether by land court or fisheries act enforcement, the prevailing patterns of authority were arraigned against the interests of the Aboriginal minority. In the face of this combined displacement from terrestrial and aquatic resources, Mi’kmaq were not passive. Chiefs made representations to government officials and appealed for respect of treaty provisions. Some Indian agents also sought to soften the rough treatment by settler governments, and church figures sometimes intervened with government on the Indians’ behalf. While none of these forces was able to blunt the predominant political vectors, they could at

2 P o w er a nd F r es hwa ter   23 times dampen the local impacts. In short, these mediating elements could exercise occasional influence without altering the entrenched power relations. In 1919 the government of Nova Scotia extended its jurisdiction dramatically with the passage of the Water Act. Inland water was declared a crown resource. Previous riparian rights were expropriated and authority to license water use, diversion, and appropriation was vested in the province. This was a response to mounting disputes around the construction of power dams and the success of nonindustrial landowners in winning compensation claims. In the face of common law judgments that put private property rights (and compensation) first, the province legislated to win control of water licensing for productive uses, principally water power (Nedelsky 1990). Given the government’s predilection for commercial hydro projects, the new provincial crown water jurisdiction served to further separate Mi’kmaq peoples from the freshwater resource. It is important to note that, despite the treaty guarantees mentioned earlier, the law provided no support for an Aboriginal right of water use at that time. Bartlett (1988) argues, however, that for reserves established before 1919 water rights should be legally retained, and Phare (2009) argues that the time is ripe for a judicial clarification in Canada.

Knowledge as Power Another perspective that offers significant insights to freshwater politics examines the power of organized knowledge. The sociologist Michel Foucault makes key contributions to this field by asking penetrating questions about how knowledge is organized, who defines what is important in a knowledge domain, and how knowledge is codified and transmitted in modern life. Foucault published case studies about prisons, medicine, psychiatry, and sexuality as institutional embodiments of knowledge (Foucault 1980). Central to each domain is a form of discourse—a way of arranging ideas to make sense of the world. While rival discourses may compete for influence in a field, a particular discourse that permeates social institutions can be dominant. Here we will ask similar questions about the way knowledge is organized in relation to freshwater. There is a long tradition here, stretching back to the Greek, Roman, and Islamic empires. Highly sophisticated works were devised to store, transport, and distribute water. However, it could be argued that hydraulic engineering began to emerge as a master domain in Europe in the 1600s. The Dutch were early leaders in this field, and their skills were sought across the continent and in Britain. Through personal contacts, training, and field experience, the knowledge was diffused. At its base lay a vision and a confidence about the purposive control of riverine nature. Frederick the Great was a patron of rural reclamation throughout his reign, and over the eighteenth century many marsh clearance and river valley defence schemes were launched across Prussia. Although far from the first, the towering figure in German hydraulic engineering is probably Johann Gottfried Tulla in the German state of Baden. Tulla is most famously described as “the man who tamed the wild Rhine” (Blackbourn 2006). In the 1700s much of the North German plain was marsh and fenland,

2 4   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s unsuitable for either cultivation or grazing. The rivers had multiple channels, the tributary structures were complex, seasonal pulses of water were intense, and flooding and waterlogging were endemic. The challenge was to drain the marshes, channelize the rivers, reduce the meanders, and reinforce the banks against flooding. In the terminology of engineering, the goal was to “regulate” or “rectify” what were hitherto wild rivers. Having studied engineering, surveying, and hydraulics and put them to work in a variety of practical projects, Johann Tulla submitted to Baden a proposal in 1812 to redesign the upper Rhine watershed. It is significant that no political decision was possible on this matter without the consent of the German principalities as well as the French state that held sway on the west bank of the river. The territorial expansion of some of the more “progressive” German states, such as Baden and Bavaria, advanced the prospect as well. Following a year of intense flooding, a treaty was signed in 1817 and Tulla was appointed director of the military command of water and road construction that same year. In this way he presided over both the planning and the initial decade of work to regulate the upper Rhine. The scope of the project was extraordinary. It called for carefully planned cuts, excavations, removal of islands, consolidation of channels, and construction of dikes along riverbanks. Overall, the goal was for the Rhine to be “directed into a single bed with gentle curves adapted to nature or … where it is practicable, a straight line” (Blackbourn 2006, 85). The result was dramatic. In the stretch of the upper river from Basle to Worms, the length was reduced from 355 km to 275 km. Overall, the Rhine project was so extensive that it continued for 45 years after Tulla died in 1828. It put German engineers in the forefront of hydraulic research, training, and practice, in Europe and beyond. It also reflected a new confidence by state authorities that nature could be conquered. In his study of  Tulla and the Rhine, historian David Blackbourn poses some penetrating analytic questions that go to the heart of understanding political power: “why were these measures taken, who decided on them, and what were their consequences” (Blackbourn 2006, 3). The political authorities of the German states that negotiated a complex agreement for “Rhine rectification” saw river regulation as a necessary step in the economic development of the region. In setting this project in motion, they took explicitly political choices. The fact is that every hydraulic change to a river sets interests against one another. Forces in favour are weighed with forces against. The fishers and hunters who thrived in marshlands and fenlands were set against the prospective estate owners and farmers of newly drained lands. The interests of agriculture could clash with those of industry. River transporters regarded the rivers differently from water power operators. Local interests were often arrayed against regional or national priorities when it came to the timing, design, and finance of river works. But the process of river regulation, once formalized in treaty and funded by sponsoring states, acquired a superior standing as a power mandate. As a result, decision outcomes and nondecision patterns were structurally shaped.

2 P o w er a nd F r es hwa ter   25 In the spirit of Foucault, we might say that hydraulic engineering posits rivers as natural flow systems, subject to scientific principles, that can be planned and modified for increased social and economic efficiency. Among his achievements, Tulla founded an engineering school at Karlsruhe, where advanced techniques were taught to generations of aspiring watershed architects. Tulla also helped make the uniformed engineers a force for nation-building. The role of a militarized engineering service in hydraulic design was not unique to Germany. It had a surprising parallel in the New World. In the United States, the Army Corps of Engineers was established in the early 1800s. Initially charged with the design of military installations and frontier surveys to chart rail and wagon routes through unknown terrain, the Corps’s mandate was repointed toward river works in 1824 when it was assigned responsibility for river surveys and improvements on the Ohio and Mississippi Rivers. As it consolidated and expanded in scale, the Corps adopted institutional philosophies and mandate preferences (Shallat 1994). For example, when the Corps accepted the 1861 Humphreys-Abbott survey, with its “levees only” strategy for flood control on the Mississippi, a new organizational philosophy took hold that would last for 60 years. Politically, the Corps solidified its place in the Washington hierarchy by cultivating intricate clientele relations with key Congressmen and with business sectors that were sensitive to river improvements (Reuss 1985). The particular discourse embedded in the Corps is highlighted more clearly when new government agencies appear. By 1920 these included the Bureau of Reclamation, the Inland Waterways Commission (IWC), and the Soil Conservation Service. The BurRec was charged with rehabilitating degraded resources, often by means of watering arid regions. The IWC was charged with multiple-use water management that went beyond the conventional single-use approach. The Soil Conservation Service sought to improve dryland farming, particularly through irrigation works. Each of these was founded in a characteristic worldview, and conflicts among them, as well as between them and outside social orders, were common (Clarke and McCool 1996; Reisner 1986). Once again, Foucault can point the way. By linking ideas and institutions through the concept of discourse, he offers some compelling insights into the power equation. While power can be exercised through the mobilization and clash of interests, it can also be reflected in formal organizations. Discourse can help explain the origins of institutions, the discipline and continuity that institutions display, the underlying interests that are embedded within them, and the means by which challenges and displacements occur. This includes a toolbox of watershed techniques that favour certain solutions and discourage others. The combined insights of decision-making frameworks, power and authority relationships, and discourse analysis provide a range of analytic tools for the study of freshwater politics. In the section below, we consider a little-known yet highly expressive case study of power relationships, to which all three models are relevant.

26

fre shwate r p ol i t i c s

CASE STUDY: POWER RELATIONS AT BOAT HARBOUR, NOVA SCOTIA The themes of the previous two sections converge in the politics of pulp mill pollution at Boat Harbour. For the Pictou Landing First Nation (PLFN), the encounter with corporate forestry can be seen as the most recent example of colonization, this time by a partnership of government and industrial interests. Over more than half a century, this small Nova Scotia Aboriginal community has been repeatedly exploited by institutions invoking expertise to legitimate what were highly contentious choices. In the early 1960s, a small sub-watershed in eastern Nova Scotia was destroyed as part of a deliberate scheme for industrial development.Virtually overnight, the aquatic life of a vibrant local basin disappeared, with profound effects on the adjacent human communities. Just how this was allowed to occur is an important story that speaks not only to local power relations but, with variations, to the hundreds of watersheds where pulp and paper or mining companies predominated in the time before modern plant effluent regulations arrived in the 1970s. Equally revealing is the series of political responses from regional community interests. This too anticipates the more complex and contentious politics that swept across the country when industrial “pollution” became recognized as a generic threat to the integrity of freshwater systems. While the story of Boat Harbour is not entirely unknown, it deserves closer attention and wider circulation as a contribution to the study of power in the water domain. In Pictou County, the largest watershed involves the East, Middle, and West Rivers that drain into different arms of Pictou Harbour and that empty, in turn, into the sea at the Northumberland Strait. The combined drainage area is almost 1,200 km2. Prior to European settlement, the area was occupied by Mi’kmaq people who pursued migratory livelihoods based on wildlife and fisheries. This included a tidal estuary known to the Mi’kmaq as A’Se’K or “the other room” (i.e., an extension of the house, outdoors). Mi’kmaq had signed a treaty in 1760 and their descendants also remembered Governor Belcher’s Proclamation of the following year, which held that “the laws will be like a great Hedge about your rights and properties” (Pictou Landing First Nation 2010). The Boat Harbour locale is illustrated in Map 2.1. Scottish settlement began in this rich natural environment in the 1770s, when immigrants from the Highland clearances arrived by boat, with a promise of free farm land. The colonial government issued grants to settlers of these Indian lands, and although the Mi’kmaq continued to live along the coast, they were viewed as trespassers in the eyes of the law and the settlers. Not until 1864 did the colony of Nova Scotia procure 20 hectares for the band between the Strait and the A’Se’K. Several other small parcels totalling about 500 hectares (5 km2) were later added. At Confederation, responsibility for “Indian lands” passed to the government of Canada. In 1960, Ottawa formally designated the Pictou Landing

2 P o w er a nd F r es hwa ter   27 Map 2.1  Boat Harbour and Pictou Watersheds, Nova Scotia

0

1

NORTHUMBERLAND STRAIT Lighthouse Beach

2 km

Pictou Harbour Causeway

Pictou Landing IR24 Stabilization Basin Settling Boat Harbour Basin

Dam

IR24G IR3

Pipeline Middle River

7

Pulpmill Ea

st

Riv

Disposal Cell

er

TRENTON

NEW GLASGOW

Indian Band as a band under the Indian Act. Today the band numbers about 560 members, three-quarters of whom live on the reserve. Boat Harbour is a particular form of sub-watershed. It is fed by several freshwater streams, and drains a surface area that is heavily forested with second- or third-growth spruce (the Pictou Landing First Nation have certified their lands as a sustainably managed forest by the terms of the Forest Stewardship Council). Until 1967 a defining geophysical feature was the connection of Boat Harbour to the ocean as a tidal pool. In assessing the subsequent impacts, it is important to keep this baseline in mind.

2 8   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s As with many Mik’maq communities, members pursued a variety of jobs in the urban and rural area. The Pictou Landing site had definite advantages. There was a clear spring for freshwater. Lighthouse Beach was a prime recreational area with its sheltered sandspit and a significant economic development opportunity for the band (a canteen was already in place). Jobs were also available at a nearby coal loading dock, and several band families maintained vessels in Boat Harbour and fished in the waters of Northumberland Strait. In the early 1960s this was about to change. The new power dynamics are explored in four stages below.

Part 1: Watershed Degradation at Boat Harbour—1965 to 1977 The provincial government led by Robert Stanfield was committed to attracting pulp and paper mills as tools of regional development. One of these was a sulphite pulp mill built on Cape Breton Island by the Swedish firm Stora Kopparberg and opened in 1962. It was followed five years later by the Scott Paper Company of Philadelphia, which opened a sulphate kraft pulp mill at Abercrombie Point, on the opposite bank of the East River from Pictou Landing. In both cases the government of Nova Scotia was prepared to offer major incentives to lure new international capital. This included concessionary stumpage rates for cutting crown timber as well as public infrastructure in support of mill operations (Sandberg and Clancy 2001). In the Scott case, the Stanfield government was prepared to virtually re-engineer Pictou Harbour to accommodate the mill at the desired site. To provide the necessary freshwater supply, it constructed a causeway across the harbour to contain the flows of the Middle and West Rivers. Furthermore, to relieve Scott of any effluent disposal costs or liabilities, the government agreed to take ownership of the effluent at the plant gate and to assume all downstream treatment and disposal obligations. These were sweeping government concessions; a fascinating series of original documents in this case can now be accessed and examined online (King’s College n.d.). The government of Nova Scotia then faced the problem of how to handle these new water use responsibilities. Of the two transactions (freshwater supply and effluent disposal), the 100 million litres (22 million gallons) per day effluent load was by far the more difficult. The Stora approach in Cape Breton, which initially relied on Atlantic ocean tidal flushing to disperse mill wastes, was not feasible in the shallower and marine-rich waters of Pictou Harbour and Northumberland Strait. Statutory authority for the water intake and outflow components of the Scott “package” fell to the Nova Scotia Water Commission as the licensing authority. Here, provincial officials identified Boat Harbour as the preferred site for a natural effluent settling pond. In an effort to secure their consent, the Band chief and a councillor were taken on a visit to Saint John, NB, and shown a sewage treatment plant with two open aeration tanks. Despite the stark differences between the Saint John facility and the proposed pulp effluent treatment set-up, this was presented to the Band leaders as an example of what could be expected at Boat Harbour. The Mi’kmaq were sufficiently convinced to

2 P o w er a nd F r es hwa ter   29 initial a handwritten consent with senior provincial officials over coffee, immediately following the site visit. As part of the deal, the province agreed to pay the Band the sum of $65,000 as compensation for lost fishing opportunities and for future use of the Harbour (Land and Sea 1988). There was also a commitment to build a skidding ramp to move boats around the soon to be dammed outlet of Boat Harbour. When the Scott Maritime mill commenced production in 1967, a gravity flow pipe carried the chemical effluent across the bed of the East River to Indian Cross Point. There it was released into an open ditch that fed into Boat Harbour proper. On the first day, a ribbon of dark brown odiferous water laced with sludge and foam arrived at the harbour, which instantly became a septic lagoon by the blocking of its mouth at the outlet to Northumberland Strait. The chemical inflow killed all aquatic life, and dead fish littered the shoreline while the water level rose 2-3 metres to encroach on shore lands. The water entered the lagoon at 33°C (91°F), which was too warm to allow outboard motors but warm enough to prevent freezing in winter. In a short time the paint on some of the community houses turned black. It was hardly surprising that local people stopped visiting Lighthouse Beach the day after the effluent began to flow. In the context of the power relations outlined earlier in this chapter, several comments can be made. Note first the stark contrasts in allocating benefits and costs. Hundreds of high-wage mill jobs, an enhanced rural timber supply economy, and an expanded municipal tax base benefited the dominant Euro-Canadian society at the cost of the physical destruction of an Aboriginal band territory and a gross defilement of its living environment. Second and equally striking is the default by the government of Canada of its fiduciary obligation to the Band under the Indian Act, given that reserve lands are held “in trust” by the federal crown. The nondecision entailed in Ottawa’s abandonment of the Pictou Landing chief and council, in the face of the evidently compromised intent of the provincial water engineers, was a key step in facilitating the outcome. Furthermore, the virtually fraudulent representations made by provincial officials in their presentation of the scheme in Saint John was a further abuse of public trust. In 1971 several “upgrades” to the sewage scheme were launched. Two settling ponds were constructed where the ditch ended, and beyond that point an aerated stabilization basin was built with a controlled outlet to the larger Boat Harbour stabilization lagoon. The effluent would spend 12 hours in the first phase, 8 days in the second, and 20–30 days in the lagoon before flowing into Northumberland Strait. At this final point it was required to comply with new federal pulp and paper effluent regulations. In 1974 a pipeline was built to replace the open ditch flow of effluent as far as the settlement ponds, thereby removing the crown liability for persons harmed while crossing Indian lands. During this first phase, the mill operating system was embedded in the Pictou Harbour watershed, with the plant on one peninsula and the treatment facilities on another. In addition, a politically negotiated bargain dictated the legal

30   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s responsibilities of company and provincial government, with little reference to third-party interests. Key allocative choices often occur early in a decision process and become impossible to challenge thereafter. Mi’kmaq and non-native residents of Pictou Landing were marginalized and left disorganized and without allies for decades.

Part 2: The Band Challenges for Damage Done—1977 to 1995 After years of living with the bleak effects of the Boat Harbour chemical lagoon, the Pictou Landing Band began to review its legal options. Despite the extraordinary despoliation, the situation was far from straightforward. Should the challenge be directed at the federal crown (heavily compromised in the initial arrangement and in possible breach of its fiduciary responsibilities), the provincial crown (the agent of the Boat Harbour lagoon initiative and legal owner of the waste as well as potential perpetrator of fraud), or the Scott Paper Corporation? When the band approached the Scott mill, it was told that the effluent was provincial property. When it turned to the provincial government of Gerald Regan, departmental officials suggested a “political” approach. After two meetings with Attorney-General Harry How, the Band was told that any action would have to come from the federal crown and that the minister would not be meeting with them again. Perhaps it is not surprising, given the initial alignments, that the Band felt its greatest affinity with the federal department of Indian Affairs and Northern Development (DIAND). The department, in turn, advised the Band to take action against the province and the company. After some delay in gaining the attention of federal lawyers, the Band convinced DIAND to enter a “partnership” to engage outside legal counsel. Although Indian Affairs was the client of record, the terms of the action called for the Band to be copied on all correspondence related to the case. In 1983, however, some inadvertent disclosures of federal correspondence (advising the law firm to hold back certain sensitive documents from the Band, and to exercise “discretion” in characterizing the federal position) led to a rupture. The Band engaged its own lawyer, E.A. Tony Ross, whose advice was to tackle the federal government first. An action was filed against Ottawa in Federal Court in 1986. Mi’kmaq prospects were strengthened by the Supreme Court of Canada’s 1984 decision in Guerin v. Queen. The case confirmed the federal fiduciary responsibility to status Indians and awarded damages to British Columbia’s Musqueam Band for breach of the federal trust responsibility in a valuable real estate deal. After years of preliminaries and postponements, Ottawa opted for an outof-court settlement in 1993, and agreed to pay $35 million. The proceeds were partly distributed to Band members as monthly back-compensation fees and partly paid into a trust fund, against the possibility that the Band would ever have to relocate its community. A section of the agreement covered joint health and environmental monitoring in the future. This resulted in a groundwater

2 P o w er a nd F r es hwa ter   31 monitoring system with piezometer installations around the community and ongoing testing since 1993. It has been suggested that the Boat Harbour aquifer may be the most intensively studied formation in all of Canada. In any event, this became increasingly essential as the Band community grew in size and water needs. The Pictou Landing Band’s settlement with Ottawa marked a series of political turning points. For the first time, it altered the terms of legal and political advantage in favour of the Indians. Note that this was achieved by shifting the point of pressure from the bureaucracy to the courtroom. Not only did the settlement put significant new financial resources into the Band’s control, it also enabled the Band to orchestrate positive and necessary resource management measures to begin containing the damage that had accumulated over almost a generation. Finally, it pointed the way toward continued political action.

Part 3: A New Vision for Boat Harbour Restoration—1995 to 2003 The government of Nova Scotia was not involved in the 1993 settlement, but as time progressed it became increasingly concerned for its potential liability. The province was, after all, the agent of both aquatic and terrestrial damage in the Boat Harbour drainage (solid waste from the settling facility had been deposited in volume on Band land adjacent to the aeration tanks). In addition, the province’s effluent treatment contract with Scott was nearing expiry after 30 years, an uncertainty that might threaten the future of the mill. Finally, there were suggestions that Ottawa was considering a suit against the province to recover its $35 million outlay. The Band attempted to discourage Ottawa in this course and offered its good offices to seek a negotiated solution. The shift in political leverage was confirmed in 1995 when the Pictou Landing Band reached an agreement with the province. With the Band’s consent, the government of Nova Scotia renewed its treatment contract with Scott for an additional decade, to 2005. In turn, the province transferred the balance of the crown land around Boat Harbour to the Band (except for the polluted footprint of the treatment facility). Furthermore, the province agreed to stop the flow of any effluent into the harbour in 2005 and to remediate the harbour bed with the intent of restoring it to a tidal estuary accessible to boats. This commitment opened the prospect for wholesale habitat change. In the interim, the province agreed to construct an on-site landfill for solid wastes and to improve aeration in the harbour, while also lowering the water level to the mean high tide mark. Land thus recovered would also be cleaned up. With this agreement the Band opted for landscape remediation rather than continued litigation. It skillfully used the political leverage that became available, as the original pollution “bargain” evolved, to enlist the province in this aim. This also opened the way for an accommodation with the third main pro­ tagonist, Scott Paper (acquired by Kimberly Clark Inc. in 1997). Looking beyond

32   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s the 2005 deadline, the company faced options ranging from a new effluent facility, at an estimated $60–80 million capital cost, to mill sale, or closure and withdrawal. When approached by Kimberly Clark about possible terms of continuance, the Band once again moved to the bargaining table. The resulting 2003 agreement, the third major negotiated settlement, set out the terms for extended treatment operations following 2005. The company offered the Band a series of cash payments for 25 years as well as 1,600 hectares (4,000 acres) of timberland in Cumberland County. The legal point of discharge was shifted from the mouth of Boat Harbour to the aerated settling basin, with water effluent volumes reduced from 118 million litres to 72 million litres (26 million to 16 million gallons) per day. Finally, a pipeline would be constructed to carry the treated effluent (which already met federal standards) from the settling basin under Boat Harbour to the shoreline of Northumberland Strait, for release on the receding tide. All of this was compatible with the Band’s goal, agreed on a best-efforts basis with Nova Scotia, to restore Boat Harbour to a tidal state (Nova Scotia 2003; Pictou Landing First Nation 2002). Over the course of four decades, the power status of the First Nation had changed dramatically—from unwilling victims of pulp mill construction to independent actors with extensive political leverage. However, bargaining is a fluid process and the terms of advantage and disadvantage can shift rapidly.

Part 4: The Bargain Unravels—2003 to Present The context for political negotiation can change quickly if any of the major parties alters course. In the period following the 2003 deal, only the First Nation adhered to a consistent line. At the mill there were successive shifts of ownership as Neenah Paper bought out Kimberly Clark late in 2004 and was supplanted in turn by Northern Pulp in 2008. The new owners inherited the bargain described above and showed little commitment to its terms, resisting major capital outlays on treatment facilities at a time of weak pulp markets. On the government side, concerns arose when the direct pipeline/restoration plan was being prepared for federal and provincial environmental reviews. The federal Department of Fisheries and Oceans voiced reservations about the effects of removing settled toxic sediments from the Harbour and concerns about future eutrophication in Boat Harbour. In 2005 the province and Neenah Paper advised the First Nation that the pipeline installation was not a feasible option (Pictou Landing First Nation 2010). This left open the question of what would happen after 2008 when the licence to discharge pollutants expired. Not coincidentally, Neenah had put the mill up for sale and the pollution treatment terms would figure large to any prospective buyer. In May 2008 the province decided, in confidence, that it would extend the discharge licence on a month-by-month basis. The following month the mill was purchased by a private equity firm based in New England and renamed Northern Pulp. Caught by surprise, the PLFN informed the province

2 P o w er a nd F r es hwa ter   33 that it had a duty to consult on any discharge licence extensions. In December 2008, three provincial ministers met the Pictou Landing Chief and made a written pledge to close the Boat Harbour facility and build a replacement facility. Negotiations began in the spring of 2009 but ended abruptly after the New Democratic Party defeated the Conservatives in the June election. While the NDP minister of transport seemed to endorse the replacement strategy, no formal meetings were held for the balance of the year, as monthly licence extensions continued. Another NDP minister suggested that his government was not bound by their predecessor’s commitment. Events came to a head in March 2010 when the province announced more than $90 million in financial assistance to Northern Pulp, to purchase timberlands and upgrade air treatment systems. The First Nation considered this to be a double repudiation: the funds for alternate water treatment facilities, apparently deemed too great a burden for public support, could nevertheless be granted to the pulp mill to enhance its continued operations. In addition, the 1995 and 2003 deals were effectively nullified. The First Nation requested the province to terminate the pollution discharge licence by the end of June. When this did not occur, a court action was filed in September. In it, the Pictou Landing First Nation sought a declaration on continuing Aboriginal and treaty rights to traditional lands, riparian and littoral rights, the binding nature of the wastewater agreements, and the failure of the province to meet its constitutional duty to consult with and accommodate Pictou Landing (Pictou Landing First Nation 2010). This action is still ongoing at time of writing.

Power Relations at Boat Harbour: Yesterday and Today Capturing the multiple dimensions of power relations is always a challenge. Here we approach it by contrasting the situation in the formative stages of the Boat Harbour degradation after 1967 and the situation in the more recent phases when designs for improvement and restoration were both offered and rescinded. It is useful to think of the power equation at any point in time as a multisided geometric shape whose complexity varies by the number of core interests and the substance of their ties. Each “side” connects a pair of these. In the 1960s, for example, one side involved the government of Nova Scotia deal with Scott Paper that made possible the original capital investment. This was a solidly entrenched relationship, rooted in the province’s development agenda. Another side highlights the connection between the government of Canada and the Pictou Landing Band as a statutory trust relationship. Despite its constitutional foundation, this relationship was never championed by Ottawa. A third side links the government of Nova Scotia with the Band, in the form of the contractual release and compensation letter that were signed in the Saint John coffee shop. As seen above, some serious questions can be asked about the legitimacy of this deal. Notably, there was no formal instrument connecting the company and the Band. The final side links the two governments, provincial and federal. Once again

34   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s there was no formal understanding, though the absence of federal advocacy on the Band’s behalf underlines how a decision not to act can facilitate a power relationship as much as positive action can. Because power is relational, it must be reinforced to be perpetuated and it can be modified in the face of new developments. The modern period takes shape in a series of steps beginning with the Band’s legal challenge and the Government of Canada compensation agreement in 1993. This set in train a sequence of moves leading to the Government of Nova Scotia (GNS) agreement of 1995 and the commitment to restore the Boat Harbour tidal system. It continued with the Kimberly Clark agreement of 2003 on the terms of continued effluent treatment operations at Boat Harbour. Here the First Nation significantly enhanced its status by resort to the courts and the pollution discourse was redefined, with Mi’kmaq interests in restoration at the very centre. The province and the company were both obliged to make major concessions to maintain the mill. Here the decision instruments were negotiated agreements whose terms reflect the evolving power structure. However, this new political bargain began to erode almost as soon as the terms were set. Declining pulp market conditions and shifting ownership gave leverage to the mill in its relations with the province. Evidence on the engineering and environmental options for alternative effluent disposal raised questions about negative impacts and raised questions of whether environmental impact licences could be secured. This led first to delays and, after the election of a new Nova Scotia NDP government, the abandonment of the 1995 and 2003 agreements by both government and company. This repudiation, coupled with the 2010 financial deal between the GNS and Northern Pulp, confirmed the extent of the power shift. The First Nation sought a new judicial remedy, grounded for the first time in Aboriginal and treaty right violations and failures of governments in their duties to consult.

Conclusion In this chapter the concept of power has been elucidated and applied to several freshwater settings. Power is relational and social. It can be exercised in a variety of ways ranging from physical force to legitimate authority. In some cases it emerges from open contests among competing interests seeking to resolve an issue in their favour, in other cases it is manifest in nondecisions. In Canada, Aboriginal interests have suffered particular failures in the political system, evident in several centuries of continued disempowerment. The Boat Harbour story is one example of a far wider set of aquatic pollution incidents in the pulp and paper and mining sectors. These cases began to accumulate in the nineteenth century and continue into the twenty-first. There seems to be a generic politics here, involving industrialists whose plants generate chemical effluents, federal and provincial crown authorities with legal jurisdiction

2 P o w er a nd F r es hwa ter   35 over land and water use, and host communities. Key policy decisions reflect the power relationships among the key interests. Allocative decisions confer both benefits and costs on stakeholders. In any case, decisions may be visible or invisible, and interests may be organized or unorganized. Consistent patterns of policy decision imply structured power while mixed patterns of decision-making suggest shifting power. In this way, decision analysis offers a prism through which aquatic politics can be interpreted. At Boat Harbour, we can see a range of power mechanisms at work. These are reflected in the occupancy and ownership of basin lands and waters. They are also evident in the relations between resident interests and outside interests. No watershed is politically self-contained, and the impacts of wider forces, both market-driven and governmental, can create profound impacts on local conditions. Political resources are unequally distributed. Contrast the capital possessed by Scott Paper, and the legal authority held by provincial and federal authorities, with the limited capacities of the Pictou Landing Band in the formative phase. Note also the impacts of changing judicial doctrine and emerging environmental science in reversing the initial bias and empowering the Band to a degree. Viewed politically, Boat Harbour demonstrates that power relations are integral to watersheds, large and small. These lessons carry over to future chapters.

3

Group Politics and Water

T

organized interests in water politics. It begins by introducing some influential perspectives on group interests. This helps to clarify what we should be looking for to understand conflicts and policy choice, what is involved in getting organized, and what shapes and sizes collective interests can assume. Then the chapter turns to the case of Alberta’s Athabasca River watershed. It is undoubtedly one of the most intensely contested waterways in Canada today (and it will reappear in chapter 10). The concepts presented here can be applied, in principle, to any freshwater issue or watershed. It is the mix of actors, the shape of issues, and the resulting power relations that will vary. his chapter explores the role of

Group Interests and Policy Networks The power of the individual should never be underestimated in politics. But neither should the power of the group. In political science, the 1960s was a decade when organized groups were rediscovered. At Yale University, researchers led by Robert Dahl asked the question “Who governs?” A series of case studies suggested that, in the city of New Haven at least, power was dispersed among a “plurality” of interests and that the particular cluster of engaged interests varied by policy or issue area (Dahl 1961).Viewed in this way, America seems a nation of organized groups. Not only did groups enhance democracy, by voicing public concerns and holding government accountable between elections, but, according to Dahl, the diversity of group voices and the crosscutting nature of group membership also served to moderate the intensity of political demands and to keep political agendas open to public debate. A theory of “pluralist democracy,” bearing markedly optimistic expectations for democratic accountability, was extrapolated from this and subsequent work. At the same time as the Yale studies took place, an experiment in watershed citizenship was unfolding in the Hudson River valley. This is a massive watershed in eastern New York state, with headwaters in the Allegheny Mountains and an industrialized lower section between Albany and New York City. At the time, the lower Hudson River was little more than an open sewer, with very little state regulation or private party responsibility. A focal event was the 1962 proposal by Consolidated Edison to build a massive power plant at Storm King, about 65 km upstream from Manhattan. The Scenic Hudson Preservation Council challenged the project’s environmental impacts (including mass releases of thermal waters) and won. In 1966, fisherman and journalist Robert Boyle was instrumental in founding the Hudson River Fishermen’s Association (HRFA) as a continuing voice for river defence. The group was able to take advantage of provisions in two longstanding federal statutes, the Rivers and Harbours Act of 1883

3 Gr o u p P o l i ti c s a nd Wa ter   37 and the Refuse Act of 1899, that allowed private citizens to act as enforcement agents, collecting evidence and filing lawsuits against polluters (Boyle 1969). Seventeen years later, the HRFA hired its first full-time river patroller. John Cronin was a former fisherman with political experience in Washington as a congressional aide. Organizationally, the concept of Riverkeeper was born—a privately funded watershed stewardship group with its own field presence on the river. Alongside this came an in-house legal capability through a link with the Pace University Environmental Litigation Clinic, where a dozen students and professors were engaged full time. Among the early actors here was Robert F. Kennedy Jr., who later became the chief prosecuting attorney for Riverkeeper. A third element in this advocacy model was the development of a popular network—of watershed residents, fishers, outdoorspeople, and community environmental groups—to serve as Riverkeeper’s eyes and ears throughout the vast watershed. This network greatly enhanced the monitoring activity and triggered a rapid response capability (Cronin 1999). Underlying the Riverkeeper philosophy of watershed defence was the understanding that polluters were enabled by the complexities of the legal process. This includes the near-prohibitive costs of legal challenges when mounted by individual citizens and the duration of commitment, measured in years rather than months, required to see a case from trial to appeal. However, an interest group with the expertise and capacity to stay the course could overcome these engrained disadvantages. Beyond the courtroom, Riverkeeper outlined a powerful political program for watershed improvement: end fish kills and pollution to restore a damaged ecosystem, protect the key source of New York City drinking water, and broaden public access to the Hudson River through riparian improvements and public amenities. This remains an influential model of freshwater activism and pluralist politics. Today there are more than 120 Riverkeeper or Waterkeeper Alliance groups in the US and another 10 in Canada, along with a growing presence in the developing world (Waterkeeper Alliance n.d.). By the 1970s, however, the theory of group politics was in flux and a revisionist critique was challenging the pluralist orthodoxy. Critics questioned many of the optimistic overtones of earlier studies. For example, how significant were the organizational barriers to group formation? Initially it seemed that the threshold costs were low: interest holders would come together, gather informational and financial resources, and join the policy debates that mattered most. Yet how, the critics asked, might the model change if interests were differentially endowed? Are capitalized business interests such as construction companies, power generators, and irrigation farmers better able to mobilize for politics than recreational users, neighbourhood residents, and naturalists? On another point, how prevalent were the diverse constituencies of rivalrous groups forecast by pluralism? Might it also be possible that more restricted sets of organized interests were engaged in lopsided contests that yielded consistently biased patterns of winners and losers? As E.E. Schattschneider famously remarked, “the flaw in the

38  fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s pluralist heaven is that the heavenly chorus sings with a strong upper class accent” (Schattschneider 1960, 35). Despite the innovative features of the Riverkeeper model on the Hudson, how many thousands of hinterland watersheds still await their conservationist champion? Furthermore, might there be alternative channels of power-holding that bypass the interest group universe to deal with fundamental questions too significant for public airing? One particularly intriguing insight emerges from the ­notion of the “nondecision.” Recall that the pluralist model stresses the importance of measuring power in terms of decision processes and their outcomes. Because every political decision is a sequence with a history, a set of participants, and a result, we can focus on the analysis of observable conflict on an issue-byissue basis. In a hypothetical watershed, decisions might be taken on a variety of questions. These include whether to license the construction of a water supply reservoir; whether upstream commerce in logging or farming requires riparian regulation; whether fish habitat demands restorative measures; and whether factory effluent requires treatment before release. The pluralist approach will examine each such issue and establish patterns of power by mapping group preferences against decision results. As mentioned in the previous chapter, Bachrach and Baratz argue that the observable interest group universe represents only one dimension of power. In the world of the nondecision, power is exercised by controlling what is admitted and what is excluded from the policy agenda. If threatening issues can be suppressed in advance, then the outcomes that pluralists highlight on the visible agenda tell only part of the story. Moreover, the capacity for issue suppression enables dominant interests to shape the political group landscape as well. Embryonic interests can be nipped in the bud if the issues around which they might mobilize do not see the light of day. Another premise of pluralist theory that became increasingly shaky over time was that of the neutral or disinterested state authority. In the original models, groups initiated and governments responded. Moreover, the nature of the response was largely a function of the pressure vectors asserted by groups, as political leaders sought consensus by fashioning a path of least resistance among the most organized blocks. State officials, it was said, functioned like umpires or even weather vanes, measuring and then reacting to aggregate group claims. The plausibility of this assumption came under challenge as decision-making case studies accumulated. Just as the size and shape of the interest group community varied according to issue-area, so too did the state institutions with which they engaged. The recognition of “interests of state”—forged and pursued by departments and agencies as part of their organizational mandates—forced a profound conceptual change. If a minister, a department, or an agency came to an issue arena with prior vested interests, then the game was entirely different. State decision-makers were no longer simply reactive umpires but rather active players with agendas of their own. If so, group interventions would be screened in a different fashion, through the filter of agency interests. Analytically, allowance

3 Gr o u p P o l i ti c s a nd Wa ter   39 needed to be made for group-state solidarities expressed not simply as advocacy but as clientelism or reciprocity or state dominance as well. In US water politics studies this was recognized at a relatively early date. Arthur Maass (1951) highlighted the importance of the Army Corps of Engineers as the core administrative agency for river and harbour improvements. Helen Ingram (1969, 1990) established the central role of the US Congress in both legislating and budgeting for river flow activities. Daniel McCool (1994) explored the concept of  “iron triangle” clientelism to western water issues, where the alignments among legislative, administrative, and corporate interests are assessed. Despite these seminal studies, much remains to be done to establish the patterns and variations of politics in the freshwater domain. While Canada lacks a water agency with the sweep of the Corps of Engineers, there is evidence of iron triangle-type dependencies in the irrigation and hydro-power sectors. More generally, a wider generation of post-pluralist thinking absorbed these many insights, providing in the process more realistic political accounts. Interest groups and state authorities were conceptualized as joined together in “policy networks” (Pross 1992). The search for patterned relationships yielded new typologies of such networks. For example, a configuration of diverse and rivalrous groups, seeking to shape state decisions by means of policy advocacy, was described as “pressure pluralism.” This recalled the classic formulation of multiple groups voicing their preferences from an orbit around the ultimate state decisionmakers. Alternatively, in situations where the agendas of select groups converged with the agendas of decision-makers, a closer form of working relationship could be discerned as a type of  “clientele pluralism.” Here certain interest groups earn trust and confidence (put another way, privileged access) to the councils of state. Information can be exchanged, closed consultations made, and nondecisions executed. In some cases, state actors can even promote the establishment of new interest groups to champion desired interests.Yet another possibility involves issue areas where group organization is anemic and there is far less societal restraint on decision-makers. In such cases of  “state autonomy” there is greater likelihood that the inner interests of institutions will define policy outcomes. This suggests that a more accurate mapping of water policy networks rests on several propositions. First, we should recognize the possibility that interest groups are arrayed around state institutions in layered “orbits” of inner, middle, and outer proximity. The client groups are close partners while advocacy groups operate at greater distance. Some potential interests are not present at all, and their absence may be regarded as phantom interests with a political significance of their own. It may be that authority, as defined in the previous chapter, is exercised principally in the inner layers. Influence, on the other hand, may emanate from the outer orbits. Second, the vectors of power and influence flow not just from groups to state but also from state to groups. In the United States, the Army Corps of Engineers has anchored policy networks for river public works for more than a century—dredging waterways, installing flood levees, and building lock and

4 0   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s dam structures. In Canada, provincial departments of agriculture anchor policy networks for irrigated farming, departments of environment anchor networks for groundwater use, and state-owned electricity corporations anchor hydro-power networks. In sum, public authorities can sometimes choose which (if any) interests to recognize and to collaborate with. Governments can enhance the status of favoured groups while marginalizing others through ignorance or neglect. It is also possible to promote new groups and new group alignments to alter the political dynamics in an issue area.

Life Histories of Freshwater Interest Groups Another insight into group politics follows from the recognition that not all groups are created equal. In seeking to explain variations in influence, we should also consider “institutional” differences. Paul Pross remarks that “institutionalization has the effect of linking a group’s capacity to hear and respond to the demands of its members with its ability to carry those demands to the state” (Pross 1992, 95). It is useful to envisage a scale or continuum of organizational types. At one end are single-issue groups that spring up in response to a newly discovered concern. Sometime described as “embryonic” or “nascent” groups, these are often locally grounded and begin when concerned citizens gather to discuss an issue of mutual interest. In Sackville, Nova Scotia, in 1988, some members of a residential neighbourhood grew frustrated with the dumping of abandoned autos into the Sackville River. Their first group action was to enlist a tow truck and haul 50 submerged cars away to the wrecking yard! If a satisfactory response is readily forthcoming, an issue may fade away and the group disperses. If, however, the struggle proves more difficult, then an interest group will find its commitment tested, as many prominent adversaries know that inertia can be a valued political tool in the face of unexpected challenge. Alternatively a single-issue group may, through its initial experience, redefine the objects of concern. Organizations that make this transition and show signs of longevity are sometime described as “fledgling” groups. Once the streambed was cleared of refuse, the Sackville Rivers Association (SRA) discovered that the federal Department of Fisheries and Oceans had declared it a legally dead waterway. Refusing to accept this outcome, the next challenge was to tackle the river’s deeply degraded condition. The SRA moved forward with initiatives to promote habitat restoration, tree planting, and fish ladders. Twenty years later it is recognized as one of the leading citizen action groups in Atlantic Canada, and the Sackville River has made a significant recovery (Sackville Rivers Association n.d.). Yet another organizational stage is marked by the arrival of a paid staff person and possibly also a permanent office establishment. This implies a quantum leap in the level of financial resources and functional capabilities and is sometimes denoted by the term “mature.” Deployed effectively, even a single staff member can energize a dedicated network of volunteers. For the Hudson Riverkeepers, this moment came in the early 1980s when they recruited the first river patroller. For many advocacy-oriented NGOs, the move to a full-time presence is a

3 Gr o u p P o l i ti c s a nd Wa ter   41 challenging step. The single-staff office is a complicated operation—demanding a variety of skills ranging from fund-raising to publicity to planning to operations. It requires networking and lobbying and mobilizing members, spending more time in the field than at the desk. A basic level of “core funding” may be gained through government outreach programs or private sector or foundation sponsorship. For example, in 1991 Environment Canada decided to promote a network of local watershed public interest groups, throughout the four Atlantic provinces, which became known as the Atlantic Coastal Action Program (ACAP n.d.). There are presently 15 such groups along with three “ecosystem initiatives.” While continued affiliation is to some extent performance-based, the initial conferral of ACAP support serves to elevate the chosen groups to new operational levels. It finances a full-time director and provides project funding. At the same time, the ACAP guidelines require that an affiliate function as a stakeholder forum with ties to a variety of regional water groups. In many cases, ACAP was a vehicle to raise local groups from fledgling to institutional status, and the Sackville Rivers Association was one of these. Sometimes the transition from a purely voluntary structure to a more formal one is accomplished when several local or community groups come together to form an umbrella association. Consider the case of the Nova Scotia Salmon Association (NSSA). It was established in 1963 by a group of avid anglers who were concerned about the damage that a proposed hydro dam would inflict on Gold River salmon stocks. Further local (river-based) affiliates gradually joined, for a total of 25 today. In 1985 the NSSA became a regional council of the Atlantic Salmon Federation, whose membership stretches across New England and Atlantic Canada. Over time several programs have emerged. First and foremost is salmon conservation work, which can occur at all levels. In addition, the NSSA engages in policy advocacy. There are also field programs ranging from Adopt-a-Stream restoration efforts to remedial work in acidified habitats to River Watch monitoring and the Fish Friends school education efforts. While the NSSA is still largely driven by its volunteer board and activists and raises funds internally, government agencies also play a critical role. Adopt-a-Stream, for example, is underwritten by a $200,000 annual allotment from the provincial government’s Inland Fisheries Branch, based on a portion of the provincial licensing fee (Nova Scotia Salmon Association, n.d.). From an organizational point of view, the “fully institutionalized” interest group represents the most fully elaborated category. It combines independently generated financial resources with significant pools of technical and policy expert staff. Business interest groups are classic examples here, in the shape of large corporations or the trade associations that speak for groups of firms in particular industries. For example, the Canadian Dam Association speaks for operators of large dams and promotes responsible practices and management as well as representing the “dam community” in policy circles (Canadian Dam Association n.d.). The Canadian Bottled Water Association was established in

4 2   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s 1992 to advance the collective interests of bottlers, equipment suppliers, and distributors in the field. Members account for 85 per cent of the product sold in Canada today. Institutionalized groups need not be “for profit” corporations. The Canadian Water Resources Association is a professional and public lobby for conservation and sound management. However, it originated, in a very different context, as the Western Canada Irrigation Association that was established in the 1890s to promote farm water supply in southern Alberta. Part and parcel of this was the application of engineering science to irrigation systems. In the post-World War II period, the group recognized the limits of the original mandate and opened itself to public and professional membership committed to conservation of freshwater in general (Mitchell and de Loe 1997). The “types” of interest groups described above can be arranged on a continuum of organizational development. Table 3.1 suggests some defining features for each type, together with examples. It includes some of the actors described above, as well as references to how one organization, the Hudson Riverkeepers, evolved through time. Finally, the table identifies some of the groups that will appear in the Athabasca watershed case study below. Despite the underlying theme of organizational advancement, I do not mean to suggest that all groups follow a linear pathway from nascent to fully institutional. Many groups find a level that “fits” with their situation and remain there. Other groups flame out and disappear. Pross (1992, 99) cautions that “groups may develop along the continuum but it is quite possible that they could regress as group characteristics change, policy capacity diminishes or even institutionalization dissipates.” As seen in the examples above, the road to institutional maturity is neither inevitable nor desirable for all interest groups.

The Stakeholder Conundrum In the 1980s, the perceived problems of a flawed water pluralism collided with the emerging social sustainability debate and delivered a new discourse of interest-based participation in terms of stakeholder democracy. There were several causes for this. First, new currents of environmental policy called for disciplined impact assessments of major commercial projects ranging from mines and mills to dams and pipelines. Explicit in this was the need to address not simply the project design but also its external impacts on third-party actors, a community that had been largely ignored in the past. The formal processes of impact assessment became, in effect, political subsystems that combined technical fact finding and adversarial representation, a volatile new combination. Second, the rise to prominence of integrated watershed management (IWM) practices placed a premium on enabling the full range of drainage interests to participate. In effect, IWM grapples with multiple uses and involves prioritizing needs and apportioning shares. Here, too, it was an article of faith that broad stakeholder involvement (as the new terminology put it) was a prerequisite. Accordingly, the new sites of political adjudication were the planning processes, advisory forums,

Table 3.1  Continuum of Interest Groups

Nascent

Fledgling

Mature

Fully Institutionalized

Defining features

Triggered by issue or controversy No prior organizational framework for politics Charismatic leadership and dedicated volunteers

Recognizes need to coordinate policies on multiple issues Addresses need for organizational continuity Still short-term and issuebased focus

Achieves ongoing capacity for policy interventions Greater organizational complexity including expanding professional staff role

Highly differentiated organization and hierarchy Creates a “normative order” with values inscribed in organizational structure Greatest potential to secure access, exert expert influence, and acquire administrative roles

Examples

Antigonish Harbour Watershed Association

Sackville Rivers Association Ottawa Riverkeeper

Nova Scotia Salmon ­Association Ecology Action Centre

Canadian Water Resources Association Canadian Dam Association Atlantic Salmon Federation

Group: Riverkeeper

Scenic Hudson Preservation Council, 1962–

Hudson River Fishermen’s Association, 1966–

Riverkeeper, 1980s–

Riverkeeper, 1990s– Waterkeeper Alliance

Oil Sands Environmental Coalition Keepers of the Waters

Pembina Institute

Cumulative Environmental Management Association Suncor, Syncrude, Al-Pac

Watershed: Athabasca NE Wild Alberta Coalition Athabasca River Basin Coalition 16 local groups

Source: Adapted from A. Paul Pross, Group Politics and Public Policy, 2nd ed. Toronto: Oxford University Press, 1992.

4 4   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s and regulatory deliberations. During the 1970s, as water basins emerged as candidates for integrated resource management in Canada, some government agencies explored an “interest-based approach” to public participation and watersheds (Mitchell 1975). Out on the radical edge, discussions involved the prospects for stakeholder “co-management” of resources alongside state administrative agencies. Third, the United Nations social and environmental agencies strongly promoted an expanded role for nongovernmental interests in their deliberations. In part this took the form of screening and “accrediting” NGO actors to UN bodies. Perhaps more than any other source, the UN World Commission on Environment and Development (the Brundtland Commission) established the context for new “multi-stakeholder” governance structures. Later, the 1992 Rio Conference on Environment and Development endorsed Agenda 21, an environmental charter that went further by specifying “major groups” or “key stakeholder” categories. These included women, youth, Indigenous Peoples, NGOs, business and industry, workers and trade unions, science and technology industries, farmers, and local authorities (Hemmati 2002, 3). While such thinking was viewed generally as a progressive development, insofar as it broadened political debates, it also carried a potentially awkward problem of which stakeholders to sanction. The Agenda 21 list was indicative rather than binding, yet its presence in a United Nations instrument added a definite patina of prestige. Perhaps even more significant was the question of at what stage should stakeholder deliberations be inserted into a decision process? The conundrum arises from the prospect of a modified form of  “pluralism,” installed at the initiative of state authorities and convening a weighted forum of organized interests. Such an arrangement seems to fall somewhere between the unregulated advocacy of pressure pluralism and the more transactional solidarities of clientele pluralism. Of greatest concern, perhaps, is the danger that it reproduces, in a new guise, the flaws of its antecedents.

Water Politics at the “Netroots” The notion of grassroots politics is well known—it involves individuals getting active on the ground, close to the level where things begin to grow. Over the past decade, however, a new political dimension has emerged in the form of the “netroots.” Rather than face to face, discussion flows from keyboards and smartphones as strangers explore shared interests and differences through the World Wide Web, texting, and Twitter. Journalist Matt Bai was an early analyst of internet-driven movements in the United States, identifying such signal actors as moveon.org, America Coming Together, the Howard Dean primary campaign of 2004, social networks such as Facebook, and alternate (blog) media such as the Daily Kos (Bai 2007). This now applies equally to freshwater politics, where it is possible to orchestrate lobby campaigns, build issue coalitions, and raise funds with unprecedented speed. Virtual political communities are now a force to be reckoned with. The animators and idea factories are the online organizations themselves. For example,

3 Gr o u p P o l i ti c s a nd Wa ter

45

blueplanetproject.net describes itself as “an international civil society movement begun by the Council of Canadians to protect the world’s fresh water.” The central values and cognitive “frame” for this campaign are those of water democracy. As Vandana Shiva (2002, 34–36) puts it, water is “intrinsically different—it is nature’s gift and all species have a right to a share, on a sustainable basis.” This leads Blueplanetproject to campaign, among other initiatives, for a UN treaty on the right to water. Some additional examples help illustrate the potential range. In the United States, the Clear Water Network brings together more than 1,200 organizations at varying spatial scales to “keep the promise of the federal Clean Water Act.” In Canada, the Polaris Institute has built its water program around an “Inside the Bottle Campaign.” This opposes the commercial bottled water industry and seeks to revive and restore publicly owned infrastructure. It monitors local initiatives to ban disposable drinking water sales on a worldwide basis. While Internet advocacy has become a formidable element in contemporary water politics, it is important to remember that watersheds still play a significant role in defining community boundaries and shaping group relations. This does not mean that resident interests predominate, but it does provide them with legitimate claims to participate. This should be evident below, as we explore a politically contested watershed in northern Alberta.

CASE STUDY: GROUP POLITICS IN THE ATHABASCA RIVER WATERSHED To illustrate the patterns and variations of freshwater interest groups and policy communities, this section explores Alberta’s Athabasca River basin. The longest river in the province, it rises at a Rocky Mountain glacier and flows 1,231 km in a northeasterly direction before emptying into Lake Athabasca. The drainage takes in 95,300 km2, an area almost double the size of Nova Scotia. Along the way, the river flows through mountains and foothills, grazing and farm lands, and the forested north. It has been a fur trade route, a river highway, a factory feedstock, and the hydrologic foundation of a vast wilderness. The Athabasca is also a political conundrum—how can a river that rises at the Columbia Icefields in the Rockies be implicated in severe health problems of the Fort Chipewyan Aboriginal peoples, at the river’s mouth? The watershed is illustrated in Map 3.1. Beginning in the 1960s the lower (i.e., most northerly) half of the basin assumed new economic significance as a petroleum-producing region. The Athabasca oil sands represent a massive but unconventional petroleum source. Below the surface, in deposits of variable depths and hundreds of kilometres breadth, lies a world-scale bitumen resource. This has long been known to geologists but had little commercial significance until relatively recently. Alberta was already well endowed with more accessible conventional crude oil, the development of industrial technologies for separating sands and heavy oil proved complicated, and the production costs at the oil sands far exceeded world crude prices.

4 6   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s Map 3.1  Athabasca River Watershed, Alberta

Lake Athabasca

FORT CHIPEWYAN

ca R ive

r

FORT MCMURRAY

HINTON

as

WHITECOURT At h

ALBERTA

ab

0

100

SASKATCHEWAN

200 km

In 1967 the Great Canadian (now Suncor) oil sands plant opened at Fort McMurray. The second producer, Syncrude Canada, followed a decade later (Pratt 1975). The OPEC-led oil price shocks of the 1970s gave added impetus to oil sands prospects but this faded with the energy price slide after 1982. However, an unprecedented oil sands rush began in the late 1990s. In what Ian Urquhart has described as “the second coming,” dozens of energy consortia took up licences and announced investment plans for mines, upgraders, and refineries in the area around Fort McMurray (Urquhart 2006). This was driven, in good part, by the oil sands royalty incentives of 1996 provided by the provincial government of Premier Ralph Klein. In short order, Fort McMurray emerged as Canada’s leading frontier boomtown, and incoming investment fuelled not only provincial but national GDP gains. When Prime Minister Stephen Harper trumpeted Canada’s

3 Gr o u p P o l i ti c s a nd Wa ter   47 emergence as a “global energy superpower,” it was oil sands production (present and future) that he had principally in mind. In short, oil sands development became entrenched in both provincial and federal economic strategy for the 2000s. Not surprisingly, an extensive array of interests impinges on oil sands environmental policy. The earliest residents historically were the First Nations peoples of northeast Alberta whose use of the land has been acknowledged both in Treaty No. 8 and in modern Aboriginal rights law. Today the five bands in the basin (Athabascan Chipewyan, Fort McKay, Fort McMurray, Chipewyan Prairie, and Mikisew Cree) work together for political purposes as the Athabasca Tribal Council. First Nations assert interests in a variety of issues ranging from community health and welfare, business development, resource sector employment, and political advocacy. Since 2006, the Council has been a prime mover in the “Keepers of the Water” campaign to achieve public watershed governance in the Athabasca basin as part of a wider campaign in the Arctic drainage region as a whole (Keepers of the Water n.d.). Business capital has also played a prominent role in Athabasca politics ever since the arrival of the merchant traders in the 1700s. Indeed, most of today’s townsites began as trade posts at the mouths of key rivers. In the latter half of the twentieth century, however, it has been the modern resources of pulp and paper and petroleum that have predominated. Five major pulp mills operate in the upper half of the watershed, including facilities at Hinton (West Fraser), Whitecourt (Millar Western), and the town of Athabasca (Al-Pac). The Hinton pulp mill was the first to open in 1957 and Al-Pac was the most recent in 1993. An intense political debate surrounded the proposal for the Al-Pac mill—the largest in Canada at the time. The scale of the environmental impacts was intensely contested. The recommendations of a joint federal-provincial review panel were bypassed by the Alberta provincial government to speed mill construction (Pratt and Urquhart 1994). This episode, incidentally, saw the provincial cabinet overrule the recommendations of environment minister Ralph Klein, whose conversion into an all-out commercial booster can be charted from that time. In the lower basin the oil sands hold sway. The first generation of oil sands production involves open pit mines, whose giant excavators and trucks convey raw sands to the crushing and separating plants. In 2013 there were four producing oil sands mining complexes in the Fort McMurray region (Suncor, Syncrude, Albion Sands, and CNRL) with others under construction. A second technology is used for deeper-lying oil sand deposits. This is known as in situ extraction or steam-assisted gravity drainage (SAGD). Networks of underground pipes heat the sands and convey the viscous oil to the surface for processing. At the time of writing, oil sands mining still outproduces the in situ sector, though long-term projections point to in situ as the dominant extractive technology (Oil Sands Developers Group 2012). While each firm or consortium pursues its particular corporate interests in dealing with state agencies, they can also work through industry associations such as the Canadian Association of Petroleum Producers (CAPP) or the Forest Products Association of Canada (FPAC).

4 8   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s Another conduit of community interests is local government. The Regional Municipality of  Wood Buffalo encompasses the northeast corner of the province. Prior to the oil sands takeoff, it consisted of a half dozen small settlements. Then Fort McMurray emerged as an urban growth pole, whose population quadrupled to 31,000 in the decade to 1981 and has since more than doubled again. It is the fifth largest urban concentration in the province. In 1995 the city was folded into the new regional municipality, which enables the greater oil sands region to be administered as a common local government unit. Across the broader Athabasca watershed there are another 17 local authorities, both towns and rural municipalities, with water interests in the basin. The environmental advocacy sector for the Athabasca watershed combines several types of groups. An early voice was the Friends of the Athabasca, established in 1988 to demand a comprehensive environmental assessment of the Al-Pac proposal and to defend the Athabasca watershed. Given the northern and wilderness character of the region (including Wood Buffalo National Park), conservation voices ranging from the Alberta Wilderness Association to the Canadian Parks and Wilderness Society (C-PAWS) are active. Advocating from another perspective are the groups centred on oil sands matters. The Pembina Institute is a highly regarded energy policy centre that combines research, consulting, and advocacy on sustainable energy. The World Wildlife Fund–Canada (WWF-C) is a regular partner with Pembina on matters of oil sands pollution, including the recent Under-Mining the Environment: Oil Sands Report Card (Pembina Institute and World Wildlife Fund–Canada 2008). Pembina is a longstanding member of the Oil Sands Environmental Coalition, along with the Toxics Watch Society of Alberta and the Fort McMurray Environmental Association. EcoJustice (formerly Sierra Canada Legal Defence) and Environmental Defence are also heavily engaged in oil sands advocacy. There are also regional conservation groups based in different reaches of the Athabasca River and its tributaries. Take for example the Athabasca Bioregional Society based in the upper watershed at Hinton. The group was formed in 1997 following an acrimonious series of public hearings related to the Cheviot coal mine proposal. Founding activists sought to promote better watershed awareness and engagement in west Athabasca communities. In the early 2000s, the Hardisty Creek restoration project was launched, and a few years later the group drew attention to the threat posed to the Little Smoky Woodland Caribou herd by habitat loss through logging and pipelines. However, the struggle to list the herd as endangered and to set aside a protected area has been long and arduous. Regional or tributary watershed groups are not uncommon in large drainages like the Athabasca. The 2005 provincial directory of water stewardship groups listed 16 for the basin, and this is not exhaustive. An inventory of watershed interest groups reveals a striking range of players, but how do they interact as an ensemble? As seen earlier in the chapter, the policy network concept situates groups in relation to state authorities. In a recent study of oil sands interests, Hoberg and Phillips (2011) argue that, in the initial

3 Gr o u p P o l i ti c s a nd Wa ter   4 9 operating decades, the shape of the policy network was closed and bipartite. Corporate actors enjoyed privileged access to provincial state authorities on industry policy matters, and nonindustry interests struggled ineffectively from the periphery. Beginning in the 2000s, however, a wider range of groups gained access, particularly through multi-stakeholder forums. NGOs drew national and international attention to oil sands environmental issues ranging from greenhouse gas emissions to watershed contamination. This was captured in a “dirty oil” narrative that by 2010 was assuming international proportions. Traditional government tactics of denying problems and dismissing socio-environmental criticisms proved increasingly inadequate. Hoberg and Phillips note the resultant shift in political tone as “‘dominant actors play defence’ when closed systems face the threat of conflict expansion strategies” (2011, 508). Several multi-stakeholder bodies were created in the 2000s, though they fell well short of transformative impacts. Since 2010 there have been signs of more basic political reordering. The security of international bitumen markets has been called into question by the formidable environmental opposition to the Keystone XL and Northern Gateway export pipelines. The next section describes how such changes are reflected in Athabasca watershed politics.

Oil Sands Environmental Politics It was inevitable that an industrial transformation on the scale described above would impose extraordinary physical and social stresses on the lower half of the Athabasca river basin. The extent of the mining operations are difficult to fully convey, but it may capture the scale to note that the open pit mines and tailing ponds stand out clearly on satellite photos from space. Four dimensions deserve special note. One is the impact on the surface drainage as the mineable sand deposits are stripped of surface cover, excavated, and processed. A second is the volume of water withdrawn from the river to fuel steam separation of the bitumen, and the impact of these withdrawals on the flow regime. The third is the impact of stored mine wastes, which have been collecting in tailings “ponds” for more than 40 years and leaching chemical residues into both the groundwater and surface drainage at Fort McMurray. Finally there is the health impact of oil sands operations on downstream communities. Surface Drainage: Since the 1970s, environmental impact assessments (federal, provincial, or jointly sponsored) have been central tools supporting policy decisions on major resource extraction projects. An EIA is generally triggered by law where a government licence is required for the project to proceed. For example, the fish habitat damage entailed in TrueNorth Energy’s proposed Fort Hills oil sands mine sparked a federal Department of Fisheries and Oceans review. In this case DFO opted for a narrow technical assessment of the destruction of Fish Creek rather than a comprehensive assessment of the overall project. (This choice was challenged in federal court, unsuccessfully, by a coalition of environmental groups.) On another level, concern has been raised over the flaws of conducting project-by-project assessments as opposed to the cumulative impact of successive

5 0   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s projects. Following a 1997 suggestion by the Alberta Energy and Utilities Board (AEUB, the powerful provincial regulator), the oil sands firms joined together to establish the Cumulative Effects Monitoring Association (CEMA). This “industry-led multi-stakeholder group” includes governments, First Nations, and environmental NGOs, or ENGOs (Urquhart 2006). However, more than a decade elapsed before CEMA was able to advance criteria for cumulative assessment, a period in which multiple oil sands projects won approval and began construction. This period of delay, or nondecision, in gearing up the CEMA structure is politically telling. In part because of this, the CEMA was widely viewed as a corporate front in the wider public context. By 2012 a long list of oil sands projects had begun construction, with another list licensed but pending, and all without a disciplined analysis of their cumulative impacts on watersheds, airsheds, and terrestrial habitats (Oil Sands Developers Group 2012). Water Withdrawals: A second policy subsector involves water withdrawals from the Athabasca for industrial use. Bitumen production is water-intensive and production is ongoing. The oil sands mining sector accounted for four-fifths of water inputs in 2011. While both techniques recycle at least 40 per cent of industrial water, mining operations use a net 2–4 barrels (bbl) of water to extract and upgrade 1 barrel of bitumen while in situ operations use less than half that volume (Pembina Institute 2013). As the number of plants scales up, questions arise about the cumulative impacts of these withdrawals and their impacts on the seasonally variable watershed flow regime. One response was supply management, and the Athabasca River Water Management Framework was announced in 2007. Under pressure from science studies and ENGOs, Alberta Environment (in concert with federal Fisheries and Oceans) released an “interim” management framework aimed at regulating cumulative oil sands water withdrawals according to flow conditions in the river (Alberta Environment 2007). The first phase of this scheme declared that oil sands producers would be obliged to share a finite magnitude of water withdrawals and that the level would be geared to weekly flow conditions in the Athabasca. When flows met or exceeded historic levels (the green status), an apportionment of up to 15 per cent could be authorized. When conditions dropped to natural low flow levels (yellow), withdrawals would be limited, and when lows were severe, total withdrawal would be restricted. Waste Management: A third policy concern is the polluting impact of oil sands operations on both the flowing river and the groundwater. Here attention centres on the impacts of the extensive tailings ponds, at present covering 130 km2, that contain waterborne wastes from refining. The ENGO Environmental Defence estimated that more than 11 million litres leak from these “ponds” into the environment each day (Environmental Defence 2008). The most graphic of these is Suncor’s Tar Island Dyke, which stands 92 metres high immediately adjacent to the Athabasca River. Because oil sands companies self-monitor groundwater contamination and the provincial government treats the data as confidential, there are at present no comprehensive site-based data on levels of toxic pollution

3 Gr o u p P o l i ti c s a nd Wa ter   51 passing into groundwater and from there on to the river. At the time of writing, scientific opinion can be described as divided. Some preliminary academic studies (Schindeler et al. 2007; Kelly et al. 2009, 2010) found evidence of mounting contamination. Yet a 2010 review sponsored by the Royal Society of Canada judged the data insufficient for firm conclusions, on water pollution at least (enhanced monitoring was, however, called for). In the past, neither CEMA nor the Alberta government disclosed their water monitoring field data to the public. Late in 2010 an expert panel appointed by the province outlined a roadmap for enhanced water monitoring on the Athabasca (Oil Sands Advisory Panel 2010). After further review, Alberta accepted recommendations for an independent monitoring agency and was joined in this by Ottawa. Among the issues to be addressed in future is the safe storage of contaminated oil sand tailings. In 2012 CEMA submitted a proposal for long-term storage as part of restoration planning. The centrepiece is 30 “end pit lakes” that will be created in exhausted open pit mine sites. The tailings will be deposited on the bottom and will be “overtopped” by a freshwater cap, becoming a permanent feature of the landscape. Although this design is entirely untested in the oil sands and the first prototype is still under development, the industry has put it forward as a conceptual alternative to the current temporary tailing ponds (CEMA 2012). Community Health: One final political framing process can be seen in the health threat narrative involving toxicity in the Athabasca River and the illness levels detected downstream at Fort Chipewyan. A local physician in the community since 2001, Dr. John O’Connor began to raise concerns about the apparent high incidence of cancers among his patients. The profile of illness among his 1,200 local patients contrasted significantly with the 9,000 he had serviced in a prior practice at Fort McMurray. For years, Fort Chipewyan hunters and fishers had complained about fish deformities, oil films on water, foul-tasting meat, and muskrat and duck population losses (O’Connor 2009). Beginning in 2006, O’Connor’s efforts to persuade federal and Alberta health officials to launch studies was met with denial and delay. The following year, Health Canada officials launched a complaint against O’Connor with the Alberta College of Physicians and Surgeons. The allegation, consistently rejected in the community, was that O’Connor had created “undue alarm” by scaremongering among the public. In the meantime, field studies of water quality confirmed that the Athabasca carried abnormal concentrations of arsenic, mercury, persistent aromatic hydrocarbons (PAHs), and other toxins. Though no professional complaints were upheld, the continued harassment led O’Connor to relocate to Nova Scotia in 2009, though he continued to travel to northern Alberta to provide back-up service in Fort MacKay and Fort Chipewyan. Following years of punitive harassment and denial, government health officials agreed to launch studies in 2008, though the slow pace of action has been questioned. Furthermore, the Alberta Cancer Board found cancer rates 30 per cent above the norm and declared in 2008 that the health bureaucracy had been wrong to provide unsupported assurance to Fort Chipewyan in previous years (Nikiforuk 2008).

5 2   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s

From Laggard to Leader? In the past decade, the government of Alberta has overhauled its freshwater management system in dramatic ways. It shifted from a laggard (Premier Ralph Klein allowed staffing at the water management branch to atrophy in the 1990s) to a leader. The centrepieces here are the Waters for Life (Wf L) strategy unveiled in 2003 and the Land Stewardship Act of 2008. At the core of the Wf L vision is the system of Watershed Planning and Advisory Councils (WPACs) that were organized in major watersheds and subwatersheds (11 to date). Their mandate is to assess basin conditions and develop plans and actions for management (Brownsey 2008). For the Athabasca, several hundred potential stakeholders were identified and, following an initial conference, Alberta Environment recognized and began funding the new Council in 2010. The Council has a 15-member stakeholder board constructed on a sectoral basis, with three persons drawn from each of the Aboriginal, governmental, industry, NGO, and “other” sectors.WPACs are nonprofit organizations in which membership is open to any watershed resident sharing conservation goals. There are two designated tools for council action.To begin, a state of the watershed report—a detailed technical compilation of conditions across the watershed—must be prepared. This is intended as the foundation for an integrated watershed management plan to guide ongoing activities. In 2010 the Athabasca Watershed Council (AWC) began work on its state of the watershed report and this continues at time of writing. There is also a public involvement component in Wf L in the watershed stewardship groups. These are local volunteer groups that propose water improvement projects for provincial government funding by the Alberta Stewardship Network. Many of these local groups predated the Wf L announcement, but they can qualify as stewardship groups when they are awarded financial support (of up to $7,500 per project). Projects range from river restoration work to educational programs and water sampling. By the close of 2010 there were over 20 such groups identified within the Athabasca watershed. As Alberta’s flagship freshwater policy initiative, Wf  L outlined a new approach that aimed to address the management of water shortages, the growing threats to water quality, and the necessity of basin-level planning. Its implementation, however, raises another set of challenges. The fact is that Wf  L was not written on a blank page but rather imposed on top of already existing water use and management schemes. In each watershed there was a pre-existing power grid consisting of organized interests with embedded claims and benefits. Indeed most of these benefits were allocated on an ad hoc or incremental basis in the period before holistic watershed systems were recognized as relevant. Both the privileged interest holders and their marginalized counterparts face an opportunity and a challenge to reposition under the new regime. The dimensions of adjustment can be illustrated in two particular ways—the manner in which water interest groups respond to the Wf L structures, and the manner in which the broader provincial government adapts to those same structures.

3 Gr o u p P o l i ti c s a nd Wa ter   53 In a watershed such as the Athabasca, we have seen that the range of group interests is broad: local governments, business sectors, residents, First Nations communities, ENGO groups, and even the multiple government agencies delivering programs within the basin. Groups engage in political action by many avenues, and water management is only one of these. Furthermore, political agendas are fluid—priorities rise and fall according to the sequence of events: are water levels high or low, are new users demanding major shares of river waters, is there evidence of significant contamination, is community health at risk, what is the evidence on aquatic environmental quality? Furthermore, interests may operate at different scales, ranging from the local to the watershed to the province as a whole. In short, the constellation of interested actors in a watershed can be extremely complex. With the advent of any new political structure, such as the watershed councils after 2006, groups have a choice whether to participate or not. The multistakeholder structure of the councils, as seen above, can guarantee a seat at the table for some, and a representative voice for others. Furthermore consensus-based rules of decision-making confer potential leverage on all participants. However, the benefits of participation are limited by the functions and powers available to a council, and if political priorities fall outside of state-of-the-environment reporting, the battle must continue elsewhere. In short, a watershed council offers a parallel path for action but is only one among many available pathways. Consider a concrete example. In 2006 a grassroots initiative, the Keepers of the Water, emerged among First Nations communities across the Mackenzie drainage area, including the Athabasca but also neighbouring basins such as the Peace, the Cree, the Fond du Lac, and the downstream Mackenzie River. The first gathering was held at Liidli Kue (Fort Simpson) in the Northwest Territories, where the Deh-Cho peoples were increasingly concerned with water quality threats emanating from the downstream tributaries. Out of this, “Keeper” groups, including the Keepers of the Athabasca, were formed in each of the main drainage areas. At the second annual gathering, participants approved a goal for “a grassroots watershed plan for the Arctic Ocean drainage basin, bringing together First Nations, local citizens and community groups” (Keepers of the Athabasca 2008a). At the fifth Keepers gathering in 2011, at Lac Brochet, Manitoba, topics included regional watershed updates, Aboriginal rights to water, sturgeon as a species at risk, clean community water strategies, cooperative water management schemes, and adaptations to climate change. Not only does the Keepers movement predate the Athabasca Watershed Council but it functions as a nongovernmental alliance of Aboriginal peoples, environmental NGOs, and communities. Its annual gatherings discuss issues across the drainage, combining field reports and political discussions while deepening the web of contacts between civil society groups. Clearly the representative base of the Keepers movement contrasts with the Alberta watershed councils. The issue agenda for the former is broader than the latter. There are differences in

5 4   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s funding that favour the councils, though the Keepers have drawn effectively on support from national environmental NGOs. Furthermore there is evidence that the advocacy perspectives, the issue agendas, and the ultimate watershed management blueprints will differ in the two cases. One measure of the Keepers/Council dichotomy can be seen in their frames of reference. While the Athabasca Watershed Council is confined to the Alberta portion of the river, the Athabasca Keepers deal with the entire drainage area of the river and the lake, including the Saskatchewan portions. Another point of comparison is the difference in philosophical grounding. The Keepers’ statement of principles opens with the claim that “we are guided by both indigenous elders’ traditional knowledge and western science” and follows with the claim that “we recognize that significant negative cumulative impacts are compromising the health and integrity of the Athabasca River and Lake watersheds.” Their declared purpose is to “build capacity for informed and effective watershed stewardship and advocacy” (Keepers of the Athabasca 2008a). In other words, the Keepers fit into the advocacy group category outlined earlier in this chapter. For its mission, the Athabasca Watershed Council seeks to “provide, foster respect, and plan for an ecologically healthy watershed by demonstrating leadership and facilitating informed decision-making.” The ultimate goal is “an ecologically healthy watershed while ensuring environmental, economic, and social sustainability” (Athabasca Watershed Council 2011). This will be accomplished through the formulation of technical reports and management plans under the Wf L framework. The Council has been organized and funded in a top-down fashion by Alberta Environment, and may be classified as a clientele group. In terms of public reporting, the Keepers moved more quickly than the Council. In 2008 the State of the Athabasca Watershed report offered an overview of watershed conditions to spur awareness and discussion. Compiled by C-PAWS (Northern Alberta) for the Keepers of the Athabasca, it drew together “currently available sources” in a 73-page document (Keepers of the Athabasca 2008b). The AWC’s “State of the Watershed” report has unfolded in several stages with a geospatial overview in 2011 and a sub-watershed ecosystem pressure rating the following year. In 2011 the Keepers of the Athabasca launched a “Keepers Watch” initiative. Part of this involved a toll-free hotline to enable residents to report their observations of disturbances (initially in the Pembina River tributary area). Another element was the designation of a local keeper representative for each tributary and reach of the river, to extend the network for “watching, responding, and protecting” (Keepers of the Athabasca 2011). The Keepers also inaugurated an annual “Healing Walk” at Fort McMurray to observe the effects of oil sands exploitation. Just how the existence of the Keepers movement will affect the overall prospects of the Athabasca Watershed Council remains to be seen. In many respects they are parallel organizations that, despite nominally similar purposes, display contrasting institutional features.

3 Gr o u p P o l i ti c s a nd Wa ter   55 In the years following the Alberta Wf L launch, the momentum for management planning moved in a different direction. Proclaimed in 2009, the Alberta Land Stewardship Act sought to fill the gaps and tie together resource management programs by a series of regional land use plans that addressed cumulative environmental effects to land, water, and air. Reflecting the political urgency of oil sands issues, the Lower Athabasca River was selected as the initial pilot region. Three years in preparation, the Lower Athabasca Regional Plan began with government research and public consultations by yet another Regional Advisory Council. The government then prepared a draft plan that invited further public input before it was revised and then reviewed and approved by the Alberta cabinet in 2012 (Alberta 2012). The principal policy tools here are three “management frameworks” for surface water, groundwater, and air quality. These schemes explicitly acknowledge the need to take account of cumulative impacts and to tie regulatory decisions to warning triggers based on indicators. The Pembina Institute characterized the plan as a “promising start” though seriously incomplete. In a preliminary assessment, Pembina highlighted many of the key development levers yet to be grasped (Pembina Institute 2012). It can certainly be argued that, at present, the rigour of environmental regulation of oil sands business fails to meet the most basic criteria of the public interest. At the same time, ENGOs have not succeeded as advocates, despite efforts to pressure the courts and provincial and federal ministers and legislatures. Here the counterweight is oil sands capital and the critical role it has played in reshaping the Alberta petroleum industry in the new millennium. Earlier in the chapter it was suggested that certain kinds of fundamental policy decisions are of particular significance because they define the frameworks in which later decisions will be taken. Urquhart and others have suggested that just such a commitment to maximizing oil sands production predominates not only in Alberta energy management but also in Athabasca regional environmental issues (Urquhart 2006). It was affirmed by Premier Ralph Klein’s 1990s royalty and tax strategy, designed to catalyze oil sands investment on a global scale, and Alberta’s extraordinary campaign of opposition to ratifying the Kyoto protocol in 2002. This points to an implicit Alberta government compromise, accepting a significant level of environmental overload in one relatively isolated frontier river basin in return for a perpetual engine of macroeconomic prosperity. Nonetheless, there is considerable evidence since 2008 of revisionary thinking in Alberta government (and oil sands industry) circles. With the overall sustainability of both the resource and the watershed being questioned in the most fundamental ways, the environmental regulatory regime is being progressively redefined. For the foreseeable future, the Athabasca basin will be the epicentre of this ongoing battle.

Conclusion Group politics is an integral part of a vibrant water politics, and interest groups can assume a variety of forms. It is important to be sensitive to group capacities and developmental potentials. In all likelihood, a government jurisdiction or

56   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s watershed hosts groups at varying levels of institutionalization and these groups are poised on different trajectories. For political purposes, groups will focus their efforts on policy issues and will seek to bring a variety of resources to bear. The target of these advocacy and clientele efforts are state agencies with the legal and administrative power to make and implement decisions. The Athabasca watershed is a fascinating example. It hosts a variety of groups seeking to shape water decisions at multiple levels. These range from the corporate resource extractive actors that have been authorized to use and alter water quantity and quality, to the rival freshwater users in municipal and First Nations communities, to the recreational and conservationist advocates concerned with the integrity of the Athabasca system. In the case of the Athabasca, we also see a variety of watershed issues, ranging from surface water withdrawals to industrial effluent disposal to community health concerns. These issues are confronted and resolved by a combination of decision-making and nondecision processes. The regulatory issues of the upper Athabasca watershed contrast with those of the lower watershed. Where the pulp economy predominates in the former, the oil sands threaten to overwhelm the latter. The proliferation of NGOs and other civil society groups is a crucial feature of recent decades. In the 2000s, the government of Alberta was increasingly forced to acknowledge and respond to issues of watershed integrity. Part of this involved efforts to channel and co-opt civil society groups. Part of it was motivated by the need to defend the province’s dominant industry against its critics, on a global scale. The new watershed regime that is emerging on the Athabasca contains some potentially transformational elements. Whether this promise is fulfilled will depend, in part, on the direction of interest group politics going forward.

4

The Freshwater State

T

the role of state authorities in the freshwater sector. In some circles, “government” is regarded as a single actor with unified characteristics. Here, however, we suggest a different approach, where the state is a complex structure of many parts and functions. The key components are discussed below, with examples drawn from the freshwater field. It is one thing to identify the state structure but quite another to appreciate its impacts. The boundaries of state authority are constantly shifting. For example, since winning majority status in 2011, the Harper government has moved aggressively to curtail Ottawa’s statutory role in freshwater environmental regulation; this story is described in a section below. Finally, chapter 4 highlights the role of provincial state intervention, with a case study of the Souris River watershed in southern Saskatchewan. Not only does the case speak to the complexity of decision-making on the Rafferty and Alameda dam projects but also the interplay between provincial and federal state subsystems and organized interests. his chapter builds a perspective on

The State System To this point, our focus has been on politics, power, and the role of organized groups in animating freshwater governance. Such topics point to another question. On what fields and by what processes do freshwater politics play out? In large part, the answer can be found in the notion of the modern state. What, then, is the state and what does it do? There is no ready agreement on this but most analysts would concede that the state is distinguished by the attribute of sovereignty—the capacity to make binding decisions, backed by the threat of force, for social collectivities of varying scales. Thus we can speak about a national, regional, or local “state.” It is a prominent though not exclusive site where political interests converge and authoritative outputs are issued. As has already been noted, a state is also a source of political interests in its own right, and we can speak of  “interests of state” in this sense. If a state is a sovereign actor, it must be structured to exercise such authority. This includes a set of fundamental rules and procedures, agreed in advance of political engagement, to channel the process. Typically these rules are spelled out in a constitution—a foundational law of special significance—and in statute law. These rules of the political game are important for structuring the behaviour of the players. By nature the state is a hierarchical structure that weaves together the necessary elements for sovereign choice. But how can we conceptualize a state? One useful model was advanced by Ralph Miliband in The State in Capitalist Society. He describes a “state system” composed of multiple subsystems—executive, legislative, administrative, judicial, regional/local, and coercive. Each of these

58   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s requires particular institutions, with their own particular logics. Each offers potential points of access for organized interests. Varying by case, these institutions combine in distinctive ways. Thus a state constitutes a complex field of political relationships which extends well beyond the boundaries of government alone (Miliband 1973). The challenge here is to craft an interpretation of state institutions insofar as they govern the freshwater resource in modern Canada. We can begin by exploring each of Miliband’s state subsystems. This reveals a freshwater state that is predominantly bureaucratic and federal in character.

Executive To “execute” is to carry out or to make things happen. It implies leadership and top-down direction. In a Westminster-style parliamentary system (i.e., the one Canada inherited from nineteenth-century Britain) the power to decide major policy matters falls to the collective executive of prime minister or premier and cabinet. Following an election, the leader of the largest party in the legislature is invited to assume office as first minister and, together with appointed ministers, to advise the crown. So long as this executive retains the confidence of the legislature (gauged by successful passage of major policy proposals) it continues in office. Thus when we talk of the political executive, the group that provides senior leadership, it refers to an elite group of several dozen ministers. Cabinet is a collective executive in the sense that it acts and speaks as one, but not all ministers are equal. The first minister is pre-eminent, followed by ministers holding central coordinating responsibilities as in financial or foreign affairs. Then there are ministers in charge of  “line departments” that deliver more specialized programs in functional or clientele areas. Where the discussion turns to key freshwater departments, they tend to be middle-tier, clientele-oriented organizations such as agriculture, fisheries, natural resources, environment, and transport. As department leaders, cabinet ministers are expected to bring major new proposals forward to cabinet for collective decisions and to inject departmental concerns into cabinet-level discussions. In addition, each minister is empowered by existing statutes to take action within an assigned portfolio area. Consider the federal Fisheries Act, a powerful instrument that enables the minister (on civil service advice) to regulate fisheries and fish habitats in Canadian waters. This is achieved through a massive Fisheries and Oceans field bureaucracy, deployed across six regions with a variety of regulatory and scientific responsibilities. Which ministers matter most on water matters? The answer shifts over time. In Canada at the time of Confederation, the Department of Marine and Fisheries was prominent. Then in 1870, after Canada purchased Rupert’s Land from the Hudson’s Bay Company, the federal minister of the interior held responsibility for all resources in the northwest hinterland. Later, in 1882, the public right of navigation was assigned to the minister of transport through the Navigable Waters Protection Act. With industrialization, the dominion resources department (which included federal forests, mines, and lands) assumed a role. It has gone under many

4 T he F r es hwa ter S ta te   59 names, from the initial Department of Interior to the current Department of Natural Resources or NR Canada. The 1970 Canada Water Act opened a tension between the dual portfolios of Fisheries and Resources. This revolved around rival paradigms—fisheries conservation for the first and watershed management for the second. The former prevailed. Not long after, the federal Department of Environment was established and subsequently consolidated its position as a “lead” federal freshwater department. It is worth noting that the inland waters program was only one branch (alongside atmosphere and terrestrial sectors) in the new department, and that successive Environment ministers were seldom more than intermediate stars in the cabinet firmament. The situation in the provinces (the other major freshwater authority) will be discussed in a later section. Only occasionally do freshwater issues rise to the level of cabinet priority. However, each generation seems to have at least one prominent case. In the late nineteenth century it was fisheries and in the early twentieth it was hydro­electric power. In the 1930s it involved responses to the drought on the prairies and in the post-war period it was the St. Lawrence Seaway and strategies for flood control. Industrial pollution took centre stage in the 1970s, habitat protection in the 1980s, and environmental assessment in the 1990s. The provinces were also involved. Ontario promoted a system of watershed planning authorities in the 1940s and 1950s. British Columbia embarked on a hydro-electric building campaign in its interior in the 1950s while Quebec did the same in its northlands in the 1960s. Manitoba mounted a massive works program in the 1960s, to protect the city of Winnipeg from Red River floodwaters. Finally, a concern with unsafe drinking water exploded across Canada following the deaths from contaminated water at Walkerton, Ontario, in 2000. At most times, however, freshwater issues may fly below the cabinet radar. Existing laws offer ministers and bureaucrats significant scope for operational programming and for incremental policy adjustment, without the need to go to cabinet. Instead the key political bargaining takes place between ministers with overlapping concerns, between ministers and departmental officials, and within the policy networks linking departments and interest groups. We have already seen several cases of this, with pollution at Boat Harbour and Athabasca River monitoring in Alberta.

Legislature If the executive role is to provide leadership and direction, the legislative role is to enact laws. Under the Westminster model, the composition of Parliament divides into “government” and “opposition” parties. On the opposition side the contrast is between the “official opposition” (the second largest party) and other smaller parties. The logic of this system is that the governing party will propose policy initiatives and the opposition parties will critically react. Through debate and close study (sometimes including expert witnesses at the “committee” stage) Parliament can clarify and improve bills before passing them into laws. Thus it has been described as a policy refinery—able to make incremental improvements

6 0  fre shwate r p ol i t i c s to the initiatives already defined at executive levels. A legislature has at least one additional important role in democratic accountability—calling ministers to account for the conduct of their portfolios. Is freshwater susceptible to partisan treatment? Would we expect a conservative party strongly committed to private property, capitalist markets, personal liberty, and small government to have positions on freshwater resources that differ significantly from a centrist or a left-of-centre party that sees the need to regulate markets, redistribute wealth, and manage the utilization of resources? Historically, the answer is a qualified yes. Business-oriented parties of the right have often resisted the establishment of regulatory authorities and the infringement of private property rights in the name of resource conservation. Once established, however, these principles have been embedded in modern government and the debates often shift to matters of degree. Should fishing grounds be managed by private clubs or by a public bureaucracy? Should rights of water use be regulated on a first-in-time, first-in-right basis or should rights be allocated according to social priorities? Are water supply systems (or hydro-electric power generators) better run by private businesses or public utilities? The Parliament of Canada has been the source of key statutes that set the legal framework for water management. The Fisheries Act (1868) was the first of these, but others have followed, including the Navigable Waters Protection Act (1882), the Boundary Waters Treaty (1909), the Natural Resources Transfer Act (1930), the St. Lawrence Seaway Act (1949), the Canada Water Development Assistance Act (1953), and the Canada Water Act (1970). All of these will be explored in greater detail in the chapters that follow. The modern trend in Canadian politics is toward a decline of the legislature as a decision-making body, and stronger roles for the executive and the bureaucratic subsystems (Savoie 1999). In part this reflects the vastly greater complexity of modern policy problems and the need to rely on an expert civil service for advice. It also reflects the vast expansion of “subordinate legislation” in modern government. Most statutes include enabling clauses that empower the responsible minister to formulate more detailed rules and regulations to further the objectives of the act. For example, there are dozens of sets of regulations under the Fisheries Act making detailed provisions for catch limits, seasons, gear, and other fishing conduct; water pollution standards for polluting industry; and habitat protection rules. These are formulated by departmental officials and approved at cabinet by means of order-in-council. They can be altered by subsequent order without the need to return to Parliament for formal amendments to the act. Before entirely dismissing the role of legislatures and their members, however, it is important to make some important qualifications. First, although a majority party enjoys a dominant position as government, relying on the support of its MPs to carry the day, this does not apply in a minority situation. Instead, when the largest party holds fewer than half of the seats in a legislature, it must attract support from opposition MPs to pass bills and maintain the confidence of the House. This obliges the government to be more pragmatic and open to

4 The F r es hwa ter S ta te   61 compromise if it wishes to survive. Since half of the federal elections since 1957 have returned minority Parliaments (including those of 2004, 2006, and 2008), this is a familiar situation in Canadian national politics. A second qualifier involves the role of House of Commons committees. These specialize in designated policy fields, and their membership reflects the party proportions in the House of Commons. Committees can examine proposed government bills and have the capacity to call expert witnesses ranging from ministers and bureaucrats to interest group spokespersons. When conducted effectively, they can enrich the policy debate and improve the draft legislation. Committees can also identify policy issues for investigation and go to the field to hold hearings and issue reports. For example, the House of Commons Standing Committee on Fisheries has published notable reviews of that resource on all three coasts, as well as reports on fish farming or aquaculture. In 2005, the Senate Committee on Energy, Environment and Natural Resources flagged the emerging water crisis in western Canada and probed the scope of the problem (Canada 2005). The final qualifier involves the role of individual MPs as advocates and champions for local interests in their constituencies. This is sometimes described as an ombudsman role between citizens and governments. One ultimate test of policy is its impact on the ground at local levels. Here an elected member has the opportunity to assist in the resolution of local problems that will not otherwise reach the minister’s (or deputy minister’s) desk. This may involve winning funds for local works such as bridge repairs, water treatment or sewage facilities, or water monitoring or testing studies. It may involve grants to local water NGOs or getting administrative field staff to prioritize local concerns. While these are far from the high profile “big picture” projects preferred by ministers, they can be invaluable in community settings and can lead to tangible results.

Administration The German social theorist Max Weber was a founder in the study of bureaucracy. Writing in the early twentieth century, he outlined an “ideal type” of modern administrative organization. Weber cited attributes of hierarchical control, specialized roles, rule-governed activities, and impersonal operations as secrets of bureaucratic efficiency (Weber 1947). While bureaucracy has been part of many state forms, it assumed greater prominence in nations such as Canada following World War II, when commitments to new and complex social programming required larger and more capable civil services. As seen above, the federal administration of freshwater has been split among several functional departments. In 1971, however, the creation of the first federal Department of the Environment (DOE, now known as Environment Canada) opened the possibility of more systematic water programming. The department began with a merger of a half dozen “organizational orphans” assembled from various departments and dealing with air, fisheries, land and forest, water, and pollution (Doern and Conway 1994). Of these, the fisheries branch brought

6 2   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s the most powerful legislative tool in the form of the fish habitat provisions of the Fisheries Act and a field staff that spanned the nation. By contrast, the inland water branch arrived at DOE from the federal mines and resources department, heavily based in water science studies, with a headquarters’ focus and a mandate for federal-provincial collaboration under the Canada Water Act. The contrasting logics and cultures of these respective units was evident early on. The DOE sought to frame an approach to regulating pulp and paper effluent, which accounted for more than half of all industrial releases into inland waters. The fisheries branch pushed an approach based on best available treatment technologies at the end-of-pipe, with national minimum standards. By contrast, the inland waters branch favoured site-based regulations based on the assimilative capacities of receiving waters, to protect against biophysical damage (Parlour 1981). This was a “political” choice that shaped Ottawa’s approach to waterborne effluent for decades to come. Although such organizational differences may seem trivial at first glance, they are politically significant. Here they highlight the origins of the DOE as a balkanized agency that struggled to instill a uniform philosophy and organizational culture. Graham Allison and others have made such “bureaucratic politics” a central variable in policy studies. Built on the premise that program mandate and staff professional outlook will tightly shape the organizational interests of a department or agency, this theory can be summed up in the phrase “where you stand depends on where you sit” (Allison 1971, 176). Put slightly differently, how you define an issue depends on where your desk is located, in organizational terms. Some government agencies are, by design and recruitment and mandate, highly disciplined while others are fragmented and less coherent. Since the 1970s, the trend in Canada has been to vest the administration of crown water powers in departments of environment. This includes both instream flows and groundwater. However, it does not normally include all wateroriented impacts of terrestrial commerce ranging from forests to mines to farms. As a result, the wider picture for freshwater-related policy is more complicated. In 2006 for example, 22 federal departments and agencies were identified as having water responsibilities, including the big five of Environment Canada, Fisheries and Oceans, Natural Resources Canada, Agriculture, and Health Canada. The situation is similar in the provinces, where departments of the environment administer crown title, license rights of water use, and monitor water for quantity and quality. A stand-alone department for water is rare (the Manitoba Water Conservancy is an exception and the Saskatchewan Water Security Agency is a crown corporation). However, a water branch within a department of the environment (or natural resources) is common. The dilemma is that no single department controls the full range of water-related programs. While an environment department can play a lead role, effective management requires coordination on a larger scale. In Nova Scotia, for example, the Department of Environment chairs a provincial government water task force that includes nine additional departments, ranging from transportation, agriculture, and fisheries to

4 T he F r es hwa ter S ta te   63 municipal affairs, natural resources, energy, and health (Nova Scotia 2002). There is also the matter of provincially owned hydro-electric corporations. These massive firms are intimately tied to their parent governments, giving the companies significant political leverage on water policy issues. Each water management bureaucracy has its own institutional history. Consider Environment Canada. Following an initial surge of activity, the federal DOE slipped into a decade of quiescence beginning in 1976. This is explained in part by the political distractions posed by successive energy crises and the 1982 economic recession, when green concerns took a back seat. Prospects began to improve again during the first Mulroney government, the final phase of a 20-year syndrome that Doern and Conway (1994, 12) describe as “the rise and fall and rise of the DOE.”  To galvanize a water agenda, a Federal Water Policy Inquiry was announced in 1985 (Pearse et al. 1985). Its report, Currents of Change, outlined an ambitious program that was partly reflected in Ottawa’s 1987 Federal Water Policy. The 1987 policy declared freshwater to be a scarce resource that could only be properly managed if its commercial value was accurately determined. Freshwater programming would no longer be simply reactive—in response to problems. For the future, the overriding policy objective was to use the resource “in an economically efficient and equitable manner consistent with socio­economic-environmental needs of present and future generations” (Canada 1987). It pledged Ottawa to take the lead, albeit in cooperation with the provinces. Among the five broad “courses of action” for its achievement were water pricing, science leadership, integrated planning, legislation, and public awareness. For greater guidance, 25 statements of specific policies were included. This new approach could have put Canada on the forefront of global freshwater management. It has been described as “visionary for its time” (Corkal et al., 2007) and Pearse and Quinn (1996, 335) characterized it as “the high water mark” in federal water policy. However whatever political urgency propelled the 1987 policy was soon exhausted, and for this there may have been several reasons. First, the Mulroney Government’s Green Plan of 1990 was an all-encompassing program in which water policy had to vie with other priorities. Second, as the lead freshwater administrative authorities, the provinces had their own ideas about management priorities that did not include a renewed federal presence. In fact, several provinces were soon drawn into disputes with Ottawa over new dam and reservoir projects, as in the Souris River case discussed below. Third, efforts by the Chrétien government to eliminate a record budget deficit led to severe program cuts in Environment Canada after 1994. Staff were lost, field offices were closed, and water funding was slashed. The net result was that, by the end of the decade, Ottawa’s 1987 commitment was a dead letter, lacking both the political will and the program capacity for bold new action. Shadowing the travails of Environment Canada was the emerging regulatory domain of “environmental assessment.” This was a signature initiative of 1970s environmentalism, which called for systematic review of the environmental impacts of proposed new development projects—terrestrial or aquatic—before

64   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s licences or permits were granted by the responsible agencies. The goal was to ensure that proponents included environmental impacts in the planning of their projects, a matter often ignored in the past. In this way negative impacts could be detected and avoided or mitigated before construction and operations began. The logic of environmental assessment (EA) was to document baseline (i.e., pre-project) conditions and weigh the impacts of a project proposal to assess the degrees of negative impact. Water development projects were often at the forefront of environmental assessment (Houck 2006). In Canada this began in 1974 when Ottawa announced the Environmental Assessment Review Process, or EARP regime, with responsibilities vested in a new agency. Over the next decade or more, the provinces followed suit. In this parallel federal and provincial EA regime, the potential for conflict was high, as the Souris case illustrates below.

Federalism Federalism is usually defined as a situation where sovereign authority is divided between national and subnational governments. It is commonly found in nations made up of diverse social and spatial interests that, it is hoped, can be accommodated by assigning the more “local” responsibilities to the provinces while maintaining common responsibilities at the central level. In practical terms, a federal system multiplies the number of authorities with constitutional autonomy. It opens possibilities for tension and conflict and highlights the need for coordinating mechanisms. For freshwater politics, as in most policy domains, an overriding question involves the division of powers. Jurisdiction over freshwater resources—their ownership, use, and management—is split between the federal and the provincial authorities. Ottawa has a strong foothold by virtue of its jurisdictions over fisheries, international treaties, navigable waters, and interprovincial water flows. While this ensures a federal presence in several key dimensions of freshwater management, provincial governments have an even larger position, based on their ownership of public lands and resources, along with their jurisdictions for property and civil rights and local and private matters. The meaning of these provisions has evolved over time, shaped by judicial interpretation and by federal-provincial negotiation, and has also evolved with the changing roles of freshwater in Canadian society and economy. Still, if there is a basis for general water management, it tilts toward the provinces rather than Ottawa. As Saunders put it, there is today “de facto acceptance of the primacy of the provinces in most areas of water policy” (Saunders 2006). If the provinces occupy the central regulatory and management roles, the government of Canada has devised several mechanisms to remain influential in water federalism. Some of these are conveyed by statute, as with fish habitat protection under the Fisheries Act or river regulation under the Navigable Waters Protection Act. Another source that has been particularly significant since World War II is the federal spending power, which allows Ottawa to spend money in

4 The F r es hwa ter S ta te   65 areas extending beyond its jurisdictional competence. Under the Canada Water Conservation Assistance Act of 1953, Ottawa offered to share the capital costs of approved conservation works. It was under this program, for example, that the Winnipeg floodway was financed. In a similar vein in 1970, the Canada Water Act opened the way for a substantial federal effort in aquatic science as well as for joint spending programs such as the federal-provincial water resource management plans. The federal government also plays a crucial role in international water flows. The Canada-US Boundary Waters Treaty and the Boundary Waters Act of 1909 established the International Joint Commission as a continuing panel for the investigation of shared watersheds. Today there are many cross-border watershed councils operating under its auspices. Within Canada, the federal government played a key role in fashioning the Prairie Provinces Water Board in 1948 to deal with intensifying demands on the Saskatchewan River system. It later played a similar role in the Mackenzie River Basin Board in the 1990s (Saunders and Wenig 2007). Another mechanism for joint or coordinated federal-provincial action is through intergovernmental machinery. These are ongoing bodies for continuing consultation at the ministerial or officials’ level. The Continuing Committee of Ministers of Environment (CCME) is one such structure that includes freshwater in its mandate. The ministers meet occasionally to set working agendas and to receive policy recommendations. In the periods in between, committees of expert bureaucrats convene to advance the technical work of the CCME. Here also, the ebb and flow of policy priorities can be observed. In the early 1990s, the CCME’s Advisory Committee on Water was abolished—a stark signal of declining interest. However, the Walkerton crisis served to draw the CCME quickly back into drinking water protection after 2000. In 2010 the provincial and territorial premiers gave at least symbolic recognition to freshwater priorities. At the annual meeting of the Council of the Federation, meeting in Winnipeg that year, leaders approved a “Water Charter” that pledged all governments to a “best efforts” commitment to water conservation, efficiency, monitoring, technology innovation, and municipal planning. Whether this amounts to more than a motherhood gesture can be questioned. No concrete measures or projects were stipulated, no timetables were set, and no follow-up reviews were mandated. Rather, the leaders agreed “to take all timely measures in our respective jurisdictions and, when appropriate, work together” (Council of the Federation 2010).

Law and Judiciary Water law is a combined product of legislative output and judicial review. The courtroom can be viewed as a field of political engagement as well as a venue for dispute settlement. Thus it is important to factor the role of judges into water politics. There are a variety of potential disputes that can arise. Some are between persons and corporations, often involving property, contracts, commerce, or criminal law. Others are between citizens and the state, involving the delivery

6 6  fre shwate r p ol i t i c s of government programs and the application of legal regulations. Still others are between governments, involving questions of jurisdictional powers. All of these are areas where legal disputes are resolved by judges. There are several sources of law that contribute to water politics. Common law is often described as “judge-made law,” as it is derived from the reasons that judges enunciate for their decisions. In the English tradition, judges draw upon precedents from prior judgments—particularly those of senior courts of appeal— insofar as the case at hand shares similar characteristics. The common law of water emerged from disputes in England between landowners and commoners. For example, the 1830 case of Rex v. Inhabitants of Oxfordshire provided the legal definition of a natural watercourse as “water flowing in a channel between banks more or less defined.” Furthermore it was decided that water in free-flowing form cannot be owned or possessed, even though the beds below the flow can. In another example, riparian law spelled out certain terms of use by virtue of a property right of access from the bank. Persons with land rights adjacent to the flow enjoyed strong rights to use the watercourse for domestic purposes and also for secondary “reasonable” uses so long as flow and quality downstream are unaffected. Should an owner hold both banks, a structure can be erected provided that flow is not altered (Atlantic Development Board 1969). Through most of the nineteenth century, these common law rights guided Canadian judges as well as English. However, a rival source of law is found in statutes enacted by legislatures; in cases of direct conflict, statute law prevails and common law rights are subordinated. Thus when Canadian authorities began to assert crown title to flowing water around the turn of the twentieth century, it marked a significant political turn. In Nova Scotia, for example, the Water Act of 1919 vested title in the provincial crown. Until that point, small rural landowners suffering burdens from dams and impoundments enjoyed considerable success in gaining compensation under common law. However the 1919 statute created a new Water Commission with licensing authority over future dam and reservoir projects, by which the government intended to make hydro-projects more accessible. This worked to the advantage of industrial capital but at the expense of small riparian holders as it obliged judges to alter the calculus in settling disputes (Nedelsky 1990). Today most provinces assert crown title through some form of water act that confers crown title and licensing authority for flowing streams, lakes, and beds. It is important to note, however, that where statute law is silent, common law continues to apply. Constitutional law is another field in which water law is framed. This involves the interpretation of the meaning of constitutional texts and the settlement of disputes pertaining to them. While all terms of a constitution are potentially open to litigation, those affecting freshwater have centred on the federal-provincial division of powers. In other words they ask which level of government holds the power to act on particular activities. Only a few decades after Confederation, for example, some provinces challenged the national government’s fisheries power on the grounds that provincial crown title to river banks and beds should carry

4 The F r es hwa ter S ta te   67 over to the fish in the water column. The highest court of the day sided with this argument in 1898. An administrative solution was concluded, to delegate administrative control to consenting provinces. The 1982 Constitution Act served to dramatically expand the scope of judicial review by entrenching a series of citizen rights and freedoms. For example, section 35 affirmed constitutional recognition of all existing treaty rights and aboriginal rights in Canada. Within a few years the Supreme Court heard the case of R. v. Sparrow. Here Ronald Sparrow’s conviction for fishing with an illegal net was challenged on the basis that he enjoyed an Aboriginal right to fish that superceded the statutory Fisheries Act. Put another way, Sparrow argued before the Supreme Court of Canada that the Indian Food Fishery Regulations infringed on his right, exercised since time immemorial, to fish for domestic purposes. In its 1990 judgment the Court found in Sparrow’s favour, thereby triggering a historic revision of the federal fisheries policy toward Aboriginals (Sharma 1998). More generally, Aboriginal rights to water continue to be contested in judicial settings (Phare 2009). Examples such as these illustrate ways in which the courtroom can become a forum for resolving political conflicts. Rulings in the senior courts of appeal are authoritative and final. They can either uphold or invalidate statutes, regulations, and the programs that underlie them. At the same time, it is important to appreciate the defining characteristics of legal politics. The process can be expensive and slow. The Sparrow case took six years from initial charge to final decision on appeal. In addition, arguments must be framed not in declarative political terms but according to the vocabulary and the logic of the law. Furthermore, decisions are zero-sum in nature—a plaintiff or defendant either wins or loses—and there is little room for the compromising style that can characterize legislative or bureaucratic politics.

Regional and District State Structures While the “senior” levels of constitutional government enjoy the strongest legal foundation, no discussion of the freshwater state would be complete without mention of the many types of regional and district structures. Here we refer to institutions based on spatial or functional mandates related to water. They exist at the discretion of senior governments and can be modified or terminated by their sponsors. At the same time they should not be confused with well-established local or municipal institutions, though the latter may be important partners in area management. There are several rationales for regional and district units. One is to formulate and deliver a newly defined program. Another is to aggregate pre-existing authorities into larger units for joint action. Although they are not confined to natural resource management, such structures are familiar in this sector. They may be charged with planning or coordination or project management or research and education. They may be purely administrative in the sense of organizing and delivering public programs, or they may involve direct or indirect constituency representation. Outputs from district water governing bodies may

6 8  fre shwate r p ol i t i c s be incorporated into statutory programs, or statutory powers may be delegated in part to district units. A common property is that they are established to overcome the limitations of standard jurisdictions and bureaucracies and to establish closer contact to local conditions. The watershed scale is particularly suited for this level of government. As already seen, there is a coherence to drainage basin landscapes that can coincide with administrative mandates. In the 1930s the US government established the Tennessee Valley Authority with legal powers to promote economic growth in a hitherto degraded region. Following World War II the government of Ontario established a statutory system of conservation authorities by grouping municipalities into special-purpose planning bodies according to watershed boundaries. In recent decades, the prairie provinces have been leaders in establishing water councils or basin authorities to address licensing, monitoring, and ecosystem issues on tributary basins and main stem rivers. Since 2000, Prince Edward Island has declared a community watershed organizing program that seeks to have management plans for all significant streams. In addition to watershed-scale units, there are many schemes that established special-purpose bodies on a more localized basis. These include irrigation districts, where farmer-owned authorities build and operate water delivery works; flood control districts, where floodplain damage reduction plans are applied; groundwater management districts, in which withdrawal rights are geared to sustainable recharge; drinking water protection districts, where special regulations govern human activity in proximity to supply reservoirs; and drainage districts, where surface water collection schemes are implemented in a coordinated way. Note should also be taken of authorities established to oversee interjurisdictional watersheds between provinces and territories. The Mackenzie River Basin Board has responsibilities for the Peace-Athabasca-Mackenzie drainage while the Prairie Provinces Water Board covers the Saskatchewan and Churchill drainages. The Lake of the Woods Control Board covers northwestern Ontario and eastern Manitoba. These institutions tend to be technical and administrative in both design and decision-making, with far less popular grounding than the special districts mentioned earlier. Finally there are regional watershed boards that operate under the authority of the International Joint Commission to link Canadian and American portions of cross-border watersheds. Taken together, the sections above show that the Miliband’s state subsystems can highlight key structures of freshwater politics. In concrete disputes, it is common for these systems to interact in different ways. In part this explains why the outcomes of water conflicts can be unpredictable. Organized interests can select from an array of institutional venues in pressing their claims, or they can combine actions on multiple fronts. If one venue proves resistant, attention may shift to others. Alternatively, developments in one venue may alter the prevailing arrangements in others. It is important to appreciate the entire state configuration in tracing a freshwater controversy. Sometimes the state system itself is called into

4 T he F r es hwa ter S ta te   69 question and its boundaries are redefined. The next section describes Ottawa’s efforts to draw back the scale of environmental regulation in recent years.

Federal Restructuring of the Freshwater State: 2012 Earlier we noted that the boundaries of state authority are constantly changing. A dramatic example of this arose in 2012 when the Harper government redrew the shape of its freshwater mandate. Through the enactment of two key statutes, the federal Conservatives imposed the most significant transformation of Ottawa’s environmental role in a generation. Central to this was a retreat on legal protections for watercourses in the face of commercial development. It was accomplished by curtailing the application of key statutes and narrowing the scope of federal environmental review. In the spring of 2012, the Harper government launched a bold restructuring of federal regulatory regimes for natural resources and the environment. The timing was not by accident, coming less than a year after the Conservatives won their first majority electoral mandate. The mechanism was carefully chosen as well—a 420-page “omnibus” bill that began with implementation measures for the 2012 budget but added to it a sweeping set of amendments, repeals, and substitutions to more than 60 nonbudget statutes. Part 3 of the omnibus budget Bill C-38 was titled “Responsible Resource Development.” It was designed, in the words of Natural Resources Minister Joe Oliver, to install a “twenty-first century regulatory system.” The thrust of this legislation was to lighten regulatory burdens faced by resource developers. This could be achieved in three ways—by eliminating existing regulations, by redefining the requirements in more developer-friendly ways, and by federal withdrawal from regulatory activities by delegating authority to the provinces. Each of these played a major role in C-38. One of the most graphic examples involves the federal Fisheries Act, which we have seen has been a central management statute since the time of Confederation. It will be recalled that federal fisheries policy was expanded significantly by the habitat policy released in the 1980s. In particular, section 35 sets out what are known as the HADD provisions—making it illegal to harmfully alter, disrupt, or destroy fish habitat. This reflected the awareness that the health of fish populations turned, critically, on the health of host aquatic habitats. Section 35 equipped federal fisheries officers with strong powers to review development projects for potential HADDs and to require adaptations to secure the required permits. In addition, where the minister authorized a project involving a HADD, it came with an obligation to replace the lost habitat to ensure that there is “no net loss.” Part 3 Division 5 of Bill C-38 changed some key terms of the habitat provisions. The HADD section is replaced with a clause prohibiting “serious harm to fish that are part of a commercial, recreational or Aboriginal fishery, or to fish that support such an industry.” In addition, serious harm is defined as the “death of fish or any permanent alteration to, or destruction of, fish habitat.” Taken

7 0   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s together, these Harper government amendments have the effect of narrowing the definition of habitat damage (harmful “disruption” is eliminated), narrowing the definition of harm (to cover only “serious” cases, however they are defined), and narrowing the scope of habitat damage (to cover only “permanent” alterations). In addition, the narrower definition of fish as species in use (or fish that “support” useful fish) means that nonharvested species are no longer covered. Another significant effect of the exclusion of temporary habitat alteration or destruction from the serious harm test is to ignore incremental or cumulative impacts that might eventually have permanent effect. Finally, there is a provision for the cabinet to designate certain “Canadian Fisheries Waters” as exempt from the amended section 35. The federal government’s intentions here are clearly to redefine the environmental balance point between fish habitat damage and resource development impacts, in favour of the latter. The advocacy of petroleum, mining, pipeline, and hydro-power interests in favour of such changes is well documented (Galloway 2013). At the same time, the fish habitat amendments in the 2012 budget bill were also challenged from several angles. More than 600 scientists signed an open letter to Harper and Minister Keith Ashfield in March 2012, arguing the need to strengthen rather than weaken the habitat provisions in the Fisheries Act (Schindler et al. 2012). Two months later, an extraordinary public statement by four former fisheries ministers (two Conservative and two Liberal) conveyed “our serious concern regarding the content of Bill C-38 and the process being used to bring it into force.”  Tom Siddon, David Anderson, John Fraser, and Herb Dhaliwal called for full examination of the proposed amendments at a parliamentary committee, and greater clarification from ministers on the rationale for change and on the role of corporate lobbying in the process. The four former ministers declared that “a strong Fisheries Act, a competent science establishment and vigorous enforcement programs are essential to protect fish stocks and the habitat on which they depend” (Siddon et al. 2012). Ultimately, neither this nor other political criticism led to a single amendment, and C-38 received assent during the summer of 2012. Months later, in the autumn of 2012, the Harper government introduced a second omnibus bill, C-45. This time the Navigable Waters Protection Act was a prime target. Originally enacted in 1882, the NWPA ranked alongside the Fisheries Act as one of Ottawa’s most substantial regulatory statutes. At its core is the protection of a public right of navigation that was originally defined in common law. As Transport Canada put it, navigable waters are defined as “all bodies of water that are capable of being navigated by any type of floating vessel for transportation, recreation or commerce” (Transport Canada 2013). Because many of the most serious threats to navigation involved obstruction (such as dams, bridges, booms, and causeways) or pollution (such as debris or material dumping), the statute also took on an environmental dimension. No physical “work” could be located in a navigable water without ministerial approval (there was a “minor impact” power of ministerial exemption). When the Canadian

4 The F r es hwa ter S ta te   71 Environmental Assessment Act (CEAA) came into effect in the 1990s, its review terms encompassed the NWPA along with other designated federal legislation. As a result, ministerial approvals triggered CEAA assessments. Earlier, in 2009, the minority Harper government had made amendments to the NWPA to curb what were perceived to be excessive waterway regulations. A tiered classification of waterways was defined with only certain tiers subject to the NWPA. Also, by ministerial decision, certain classes of works could be exempted from statutory approval (and as a result would be exempt from CEAA processes). The public notification and consultation provisions for exempt projects were also eliminated. In short, the scope of the NWPA was narrowed by limiting the range of waters and of projects to which approval and assessment applied. In the Fall 2012 omnibus act, the NWPA was more radically amended. First, the name was changed to the Navigation Protection Act, to underline a retreat from environmental protection and a focus on navigable conditions alone. Second, application of the statute was confined to a designated list of waterways that included 3 oceans, 97 lakes, and portions of 62 rivers. The rationale here, according to Transport Canada, is “to focus TC resources on the country’s most significant waterways” (Ecojustice 2012). Third, for all other nonlisted waterways, there is no need for approval for “works,” no legal authority to remove obstructions, and no need for proponents to provide public notice. There is also provision for Ottawa to delegate its continuing navigation protection powers to other governments (i.e., provinces). It should be noted that six months earlier, Bill C-38 had exempted major pipelines and power lines from the NWPA and assigned navigational safety for these facilities to the National Energy Board. So far as nonlisted waterways were concerned, the amended act declared that common law rules would still apply. In other words, private parties could seek remedy for navigation injuries by launching court action against the agents of the injury. In political terms, however, this transformed the power relations from one of ministerial protection of a public interest under law, to one of private citizen initiatives through the courts. Where the NWPA process was proactive, the common law route is inherently reactive and post facto. Where the onus under the NWPA was to prove no damage, the onus under the common law of nuisance is to prove damage. In addition, the costs of compliance are shifted largely from navigational waterway modifiers to navigational waterway users. There are also significant implications for Aboriginal rights. The crown duty to consult on actions that may affect Aboriginal rights or title does not extend to private interests such as corporations, so the scope of the crown duty is radically narrowed to the listed waterways. As one critic put it, “this is the ultimate in ‘privatization’ of Canada’s navigation regulatory regime” (Ecojustice 2012). In a similar spirit, the Harper program also carried major amendments to the Canadian Environmental Assessment Act and the Species at Risk Act. In sum, the 2012 package has the effect of narrowing and lessening certain standards of legal review, increasing ministerial responsibility in triggering

72

fre shwate r p ol i t i c s

reviews, and redefining key terms, while increasing the prospects for Ottawa to delegate decisions to the provinces. The Harper government policy of 2012 reflects the interconnected elements of the modern freshwater state. Cabinet decisions were translated into legislative format and attached to the budget bills. On the strength of the Conservative majority, key statutes were amended to curtail their scope and bureaucratic application. Future court challenges will be weighed against the 2012 statutory terms. And a potential shift of initiative, from Ottawa to the provinces, has been set in play.

CASE STUDY: THE SOURIS RIVER WATERSHED AND THE RAFFERTY-ALAMEDA DAM DISPUTES A classic example of the freshwater state acting on multiple levels is the dispute surrounding the proposed construction of the Rafferty and Alameda dams in southeast Saskatchewan. Over more than a decade of conflict, all elements of the state were engaged before the projects were completed in the mid-1990s. The case illustrates the multiple complications that can arise when a major water development project is launched, as well as the many distinct political venues in which organized interests are expressed. Of particular note are the cross-border alliances and tensions, the strategies of legal challenge by citizen groups, and the federal-provincial dimensions of project approval. The Souris River features a surprising level of geopolitical complexity for an intermediate-sized watershed. The river rises near Weyburn and flows 700 km to its confluence with the Assiniboine River in Manitoba. Three of the source tributaries point in a southeast direction and join at Oxbow. As the Souris, it continues toward the US border and enters the state of North Dakota where it gains added flow. After passing the city of Minot, the river turns north and re-enters Canada, this time in Manitoba. Here the “lower” Souris basin (a separate southeast Saskatchewan watershed that flows directly into Manitoba) joins the main stem, which continues northeasterly to intersect with the Assiniboine River and flow onward to Winnipeg. Thus the Souris not only transects the Saskatchewan-Manitoba boundary but also twice crosses between Canada and the United States. It is a heavily engineered basin, including some 40 dams, 4 of them major. The entire watershed is illustrated on Map 4.1. The Souris River watershed depends completely upon seasonal precipitation. This means that its flow patterns vary sharply from the spring melt to midsummer drought, punctuated by random seasonal cloudbursts. In an arid part of the prairies, where dryland farming is the rule, water is a key limiting factor and water “management” assumes a different cultural form than elsewhere. Marc Reisner’s comment on the United States applies equally to Canada—as he puts it, “in the east, to ‘waste’ water is to consume it needlessly or excessively. In the west to waste water is not to consume it, to let it flow unimpeded or undiverted down rivers” (Reisner 1986, 12). In this sense, dam-building is perfectly

4 T he F r es hwa ter S ta te   73 Map 4.1  Souris River Watershed, Saskatchewan REGINA

SASKATCHEWAN

MANITOBA

BRANDON M

oo se

Mt

ng

Cr

ee

k

n.

C re

ek

Alameda Dam and Reservoir ESTEVAN

is ur S o ver Ri

OXBOW

r

Lo

Ra erty Dam and Reservoir

S o uris R i v e

CANADA UNITED STATES

Boundary Lake Dam and Reservoir Lake Darling

MINOT

Proposed Burlington Dam

So u i s Ri r

ve

r

NORTH DAKOTA

in keeping with water conservation. Yet on the Souris, water scarcity combines with water excess. The North Dakota city of Minot has been the victim of major floods, repeatedly in the 1970s and most acutely in 2011. In effect the Souris is defined by both water shortage and overabundance, which complicates any regulatory efforts. Farm residents of southeastern Saskatchewan have long sought a form of river management but this has been frustrated by physical and political factors. As early as 1940 the province of Saskatchewan pressed for a formal agreement on apportioning water between the three jurisdictions in the Souris basin. The International Joint Commission (IJC) concluded that insufficient data existed at that time—a decision that, by perpetuating the status quo, implicitly favoured North Dakota, where the Army Corps of Engineers had already built multiple dams. The issue was revisited in 1959 when it was agreed that Saskatchewan could retain 50 per cent of the flow and the International Souris River Board of Control was established under the IJC. This Saskatchewan share was never fully used. The Boundary reservoir was built to cool a local coal-fired power plant that supplied half of the provincial base electrical load at the time. However, the push for hydraulic works was stronger on the American side. In response to the Minot floods in the 1970s, the US Army Corps of Engineers proposed the Burlington dam as a “dry dam” that would fill in the spring and empty as summer progressed. This American proposal

74  fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s was killed when a political deadlock developed between anti-dam farmers and pro-dam Minot residents. This opened the way for a different approach in the 1980s, when new political leadership took control in both the province and the state. The concept was to regulate the Souris by means of two new Saskatchewan dams, with tie-ins to electricity generation in the province and water supply in North Dakota. In 1985 the Saskatchewan Power Corporation proposed the Shand coal-fired power plant with the Rafferty dam and reservoir as its water source. With Minot increasingly anxious about flood protection, the Alameda dam was added as an upper-basin floodwater storage structure, with the hope that US authorities would co-finance the project. The Rafferty dam site is on the Souris River main stem upstream of Estevan, where the Shand coal-fired power plant is located. An earth-filled dam of 20 m height, it creates a reservoir 57 km long that stores 440,000 m3 when full. A 10-km diversion was also proposed to enable excess water at the Boundary Reservoir to be diverted to Rafferty. Further east, the Alameda dam is sited on the Moose Mountain Creek tributary. Located just above Oxbow, the Alameda is a higher (38 m) earth-filled structure that impounds a 25 km reservoir storing 105,000 m3 when full. The Alameda dam was completed in 1994 while the Rafferty followed in 1995. Given the transboundary watershed, a binational agreement was required to set out the details of the intended flow regime. It is telling that the detailed terms were hammered out by technocrats from Saskatchewan Power and the US Army Corps of Engineers, and then approved by Ottawa and Washington in a 1989 agreement (Redekop 2012). This century-long deal spelled out the allocative terms, with specific obligations for Saskatchewan not only to hold back spring flows but also to guarantee levels in Lake Darling on the American side (Canada and USA 1989). For Minot, the flood protection scheme was geared for a 1-in-100-year flood, whereas the earlier Burlington design was for 1-in-500 years. It was decided, at political levels, that the IJC and the Souris River Board would play no role in the design or negotiating process, thus sidelining the most authoritative sources of watershed expertise. The Saskatchewan party system of the time was polarized between the New Democrats (who governed until 1982 and again after 1991) and the Conservatives (in power from 1982 to 1991). The NDP was unsympathetic to the Souris River proposal during the opening phase, but Conservative leader Grant Devine (an agricultural scientist whose constituency included Estevan) was its champion (Hood 1994). In the run-up to an election in February 1986, Devine announced that the twin dams would be built, subject to environmental impact approval and a US contribution to the capital costs. A new crown agency known as the Souris Basin Development Authority (SBDA) was put in charge of project design and construction, including the job of navigating its pathway through some 25 licence and permit processes.

4 The F r es hwa ter S ta te   75 As we have seen, the premier (or prime minister) heads the cabinet and the executive subsystem. But Premier Devine’s enthusiasm for the Rafferty-Alameda project was not shared by all elements of the provincial, and federal, states. In Saskatchewan, various line departments resisted. At cabinet, other ministers harboured doubts that later hardened into silent opposition. So long as Environment Minister Eric Berntson was at the table, the SBDA enjoyed strong political support, but after his departure in 1989, other ministers and senior departmental officials became bolder and more openly hostile. This intensified as the environmental court battles (detailed below) intensified in the 1989–93 period. The federal government was also a significant player by virtue of the crossborder waters dimension. Not only did federal officials co-chair the International Souris River Board of Control (under the IJC), but the federal minister of the environment also held responsibilities under the International Rivers Improvement Act, requiring a federal licence for a major work within Canada on any boundary river. This proved to be a key political pressure point for anti-Rafferty forces, which successfully challenged the adequacy of the environmental assessments undertaken by Environment Canada. On the Saskatchewan side of the Souris watershed there was skepticism about how project costs matched up with benefits. The Alameda dam came in for particular criticism, as local farmland stood to replace the Burlington project and protect Minot against floods. Indeed the Alameda reservoir was often described by critics as “America’s Lake” (Redekop 2012). Such concerns were dismissed impatiently by Conservative politicians and SBDA officials. Nevertheless, concerned citizens came together early in 1988 to form SCRAP: Stop Construction of the Rafferty-Alameda Project. The Rafferty-Alameda project appeared at a moment when environmental assessment law was still at a formative stage in Canada. The principle of compulsory assessment of major project impacts was widely accepted, but the procedures and techniques were still germinal. The federal government published its first “Guideline” in 1974 (revised in 1984), obliging departments and agencies to perform assessments before licensing decisions. However this “regime” was not specified in fine detail, leaving officials considerable discretion of execution (Hood 1994). In Saskatchewan the NDP enacted the province’s first Environmental Assessment Act in 1980, though few regulations had been finalized under it by the time that the Rafferty-Alameda project was referred to an assessment board in 1987. In some respects, state agencies were still in the process of occupying this potentially massive new field of regulatory politics. In any case, development agencies tended to regard EAs as formalities. The initial Saskatchewan review was completed in little more than a month. The initial federal review, when it was judicially compelled, took less than a month (Houck 2006). In all, six judicial actions were launched on behalf of comprehensive environmental review. A citizen challenge to inadequate provincial public consultation failed; a SCRAP challenge to the adequacy of the provincial review also failed;

7 6   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s an action by the Canadian Wildlife Federation to force Ottawa to undertake a federal review was successful (and sustained on appeal); another CWF action to require a comprehensive panel review was also successful; an action by Ottawa for a judicial order to stop construction during the panel review failed; and a citizen action to force a federal review of the Alameda project after the site was shifted succeeded (though the project was completed while the review was underway). Through repeated litigation, project opponents successfully exploited a series of legal ambiguities and procedural irregularities, delaying project completion by half a decade (Stolte and Sadar 1993). At the same time, these challenges led Canadian courts to strengthen the status of federal environmental assessment policies. The legal vagaries of the federal EARP Guidelines Order cried out for judicial challenge by environmental advocates, and the Rafferty-Alameda project provided the spark (Tingley 1991). The 1989 action by the Canadian Wildlife Federation, at the Trial Division of the Federal Court of Canada, succeeded in quashing the initial licence under the International Rivers Improvement Act (IRIA) and ordered the federal minister of environment to fully comply with the EARP guidelines. Where the courts hesitated was in their willingness to halt the project until adequate reviews were completed. By the time the EARP hearings were finished, the major engineering works were largely in place. There followed a complicated series of steps and countersteps over several years, requiring repeated court challenges and policy miscues (Tingley 1991). Following EARP hearings in 1989, construction resumed and the Rafferty dam was largely complete by November. Then federal court Justice Muldoon quashed the “second” IRIA license on the grounds that full EARP compliance still required a panel inquiry. Saskatchewan sought financial compensation from Ottawa for the ensuing delay, and it was only in 1992 that the way was cleared for final construction (Canada 1991). It should be evident that the Rafferty-Alameda project became a lightning rod for a variety of political issues. Provincial officials argued that a provincial development scheme was being held hostage by central Canadian environmentalists and by design defects in a federal policy that had little to do with the project. Critics of the scheme questioned the coherence of the two-dam design, the credibility of the capital cost estimates, and the apparent contradictions in combining water supply, flood storage, and recreational purposes in the manner proposed. In addition, both federal and provincial authorities were willing to exaggerate the perfidy of the other to the point that water project particulars were sometimes lost from sight. Ultimately the Souris River controversy and the dam/reservoir debates serve as an intriguing example of the complexity of project politics and the capacity for them to permeate all avenues of the modern freshwater state. The legacy of the twin dam/reservoir projects can be found in the ongoing functioning of the watershed, as detailed in annual reports by the International Souris River Board. The ultimate capital cost exceeded the original estimate

4 The F r es hwa ter S ta te   77 of $80 million by several orders. As a result, the American contribution of $40 million dropped to less than 20 per cent of the total. It is estimated that flood management actions saved Minot from flooding in 1999, 2001, 2005, and 2009. But events in June 2012 overshadowed these successes. Heavy rains the previous fall left soils saturated within the watershed and winter snows in 2011–12 were double normal levels. These factors combined with acute spring rain events to send a 1-in-500-year flood into North Dakota, inflicting unprecedented damage on Minot. This prompted a binational review of the 1989 Canada-US operating plan, which continues at the time of writing.

Conclusion It is evident that freshwater policy issues permeate the modern Canadian state. At any point in time, significant questions are under consideration at multiple levels. Authority over these matters is dispersed and lines of accountability are far from clear. Indeed, a challenge for interest groups is how to accurately “read” the state structure and deal strategically with it. The questions are many: when to lobby a government minister (and if so, at which level); when to mobilize opposition party efforts in a legislature, or appear at committee deliberations; when to press concerns with bureaucratic officials and with which bureaucracy; whether a court challenge offers prospects for policy influence? In later chapters we will encounter these questions in a variety of freshwater settings. What are some of the lessons to be drawn from the Rafferty dam experience? The importance of ministerial leadership and cabinet solidarity is amply evident, if policy intent is to be realized over time. Also the long duration of a dam and reservoir project can be seen in the sequence of stages from proposal to formal acceptance to design and construction. When a watershed flows between jurisdictions (much less countries), the political process will involve multiple sovereign authorities and be more complex for that fact. In recent decades, the growing importance of water conservation and ecological interest groups has also become clear. Finally, the courts offer an important avenue for NGOs and other interests seeking to overturn an unfavourable decision by blocking it.

This page intentionally left blank

5

Fisheries and Pollution

W

“host” environment for living organisms, attention usually turns to fish. This chapter explores some of the leading political dimensions of freshwater fishing and fishery management. Among the significant variables are the interests of fishers and the conflicts that may arise among them, the status of fish stocks and the challenges of conservation and restoration, the allocation of jurisdictional authority between federal and provincial levels, and the ongoing threats from the pollution of aquatic environments. The chapter continues with a case study of the Miramichi watershed in New Brunswick and the status of wild Atlantic salmon in particular. The politics of salmon has been prominent in this watershed since first contact. Today, salmon management offers a classic illustration of the challenges facing fisheries more generally. In Canada, the freshwater fish resource is distributed across five drainage basins that encompass tens of thousands of rivers and lakes. Each is a potential host for one or more fish populations. Despite this massive freshwater estate, the range of fish species is surprisingly narrow. From a fisheries point of view, fewer than 30 species figure in terms of major catch importance. Heading the list on both the Atlantic and Pacific coasts is salmon, long regarded as the king of the game fishes, an anadromous species whose life cycle combines freshwater and saltwater habitats. Regionally prominent are pickerel, perch, trout, whitefish, char, and others. But in a comparative context the natural range is not diverse. Canada holds only one per cent of the 20,000 global freshwater species (Pearse 1988, 23). Each province has its own particular profile. In Nova Scotia for example, 17 native species have been present since the last ice age. This is not the whole story, however, as another 26 fish species have been introduced over the past three centuries of settlement. Further variations are found at the spatial level, where the size and mixture of populations varies by body of water and drainage basin. Even the same species can face markedly different conditions from one watershed to another, as the Atlantic salmon will attest. This underlines the fundamental challenge in understanding, much less managing, the fisheries resource. Overall, the endowment and the value of Canadian fisheries are substantial. But individually, the stocks found in particular lakes and rivers range from abundant to scarce, from commercially valuable to negligible, and from ecologically sensitive to resilient. The dilemma of freshwater fisheries programming stems in large part from its character as a localized resource on a national scale, with occasional international dimensions. Under these circumstances it has been very difficult to undertake sufficient surveys, at the appropriate scale, to fully understand the resource. Commercial value has normally dictated hen freshwater is considered as a

8 2   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s research priorities. But even with prominent species such as salmon, knowledge has been elusive and management has been of questionable effectiveness. On the Atlantic coast the salmon stocks that were so abundant in pioneer times hit rock bottom in the early 1980s. On the Pacific, salmon have been in crisis for the better part of the last generation.

The Politics The politics of the fisheries begins, however, with the interests that arise from the social appropriation of the wild resource. To put it another way, differences begin when rival claims are made on the access, capture, and utilization of different sorts of fish. It is not simply a question of  “who” but also of  “what” and “how.” In Canada, Aboriginal cultures have relied traditionally on fish to support their domestic economies. Fish were speared and netted, smoked and dried, consumed and exchanged as part of precontact life. Fishing sites were frequented by particular band and tribal groups, and fishing seasons were often the occasion for social gatherings. Later, with European settlement, opportunities arose to trade or sell fish commercially as well. During these times, a premise of permanent abundance prevailed. However, by the nineteenth century this premise was already being challenged and distributional conflicts broke out in many directions (Newell 1993). Some of this was culturally driven, as white colonists resented and resisted the efforts of Native fishers to maintain traditional access. It took the form of settler landowners invoking private land rights to exclude Indians from riparian access. It also involved denying or dismissing treaty rights. Finally it took the form of attacking Aboriginal fishing practices. For example, in Maritime Canada, white anglers took strong exception to Mi’kmaq night fishing with flambeaux—blazing torches fixed to the ends of canoes to draw fish to the surface where they could be speared. In the eyes of colonial gentlemen and military men, this was deemed unsporting (Parenteau 1998). As a result, the angling lobby pressed the federal Fisheries Department to outlaw Native practices. Another form of conflict arose between fishers located at different sites along a river system. Upstream residents saw their fisheries restricted by intensive harvesting by downstream rivals. The use of nets and weirs at river mouths interrupted fish movement upstream and jeopardized the return of spawning salmon stock. Inland communities regularly petitioned the authorities for protection. Colonial authorities responded by the mid-nineteenth century with regulations to prohibit spearing and netting on spawning beds. Another tool for fisheries administration, still used widely in Quebec and New Brunswick, involved the crown leasing reaches of river to sports associations for their exclusive use, maintenance, and—it was thought—fish protection (La Forest 1960). As time progressed, the cleavage between two sets of white fishers— commercial and sport anglers—deepened. The philosophy of angler responsibility for conservation underwrote not only river leases but private guardianship arrangements against “poaching,” and elite tourism became a profitable seasonal

5 F is h er i es a nd P o l l uti o n   83 industry. In the rural areas of upper river systems, the practices of spearing, netting, and torching were adopted by whites. For the Maritimes, Parenteau reports that “the annual Atlantic salmon run produced a series of confrontations each season between anglers, private guardians, government wardens, and local fishing populations from 1867 to 1914” (Parenteau 2004). In the twentieth century commercial fisheries expanded on major water bodies like the Great Lakes and Lake Winnipeg. Catch levels were enhanced by technological adaptations such as freezers, steam power, and larger and better nets. Ten thousand people were employed in the Great Lakes commercial fishery by 1900 (Bocking 1997). The decades following World War II saw the dramatic rise of angling as a recreational pursuit. This generated new tensions over shares of the fishery, particularly where stocks were depleted and habitats fouled. A third sector, the Aboriginal subsistence fishery, remained important in some regions and for some species, such as salmon. After decades on the defensive, this sector received a dramatic boost as a result of the 1982 constitutional recognition of “treaty and aboriginal rights,” a provision that the Supreme Court of Canada later applied to fishing rights. By the mid-1980s, the “allocation question,” as it came to be known, was being fought politically in watersheds from the Fraser to the Miramichi, from commercial fisher lobby groups to sport fishing conferences to tribal councils and in federal and provincial management offices (Tuomi 1985). Much of this conflict was concentrated on shaping the legal regime for fisheries and particularly on securing an entrenched advantage within it. In his 1988 review of freshwater fisheries policy in Canada, Pearse points out that fisheries “management” can be directed at three distinct targets: managing the fishing, managing the habitat, and managing the stock (Pearse 1988, 109). The first is where disputes among fishers predominate: how many fish of various species will be taken, who in particular will take which share, at what time of year and in what location, and with what gear will the fishing take place? Fisheries legislation can be quite detailed in nature, setting out open and closed seasons, bag limits, numbers of licensed participants, permissible instruments, and other terms. The federal Fisheries Act and regulations were used in the late nineteenth century to restrict Aboriginal fishing. A century later, they were used to phase down commercial fishing in maritime river estuaries. Not that state interventions were always effective—poaching has always been a major issue and conflicts between rival fishers were often pursued and resolved outside of the law. Managing the habitat involves protecting and restoring water quality in rivers and lakes so that fish stocks have the best chance of survival. The process of industrial manufacture involves the production of wastes and the alteration of waterflows. Dams and holding ponds will block stream flow and, unless ameliorated by fishways, will prevent fish migration to and from spawning grounds. Mill wastes disposed into streams and rivers can degrade water quality and river bank and river bed conditions. Chemical pollutants from land runoff or direct disposal can be toxic to aquatic species across food chains and cause dramatic fish kills (Ross and Amter 2010).

8 4   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s Prior to the 1970s, untreated effluents were routinely discharged from factories and waste facilities with little concern for the damages. A glib slogan of that time summed it up: “The solution to pollution is dilution.” The pulp and paper industry, Canada’s largest manufacturing sector for decades, accounted for half of all aquatic pollution (Sinclair 1990). The industrial chemical industry and municipal sewage disposal accounted for much of the rest. It was only with the dawning of the age of environmentalism that the government of Canada squarely confronted the problem. Under the authority of the Fisheries Act, the federal government issued the Pulp and Paper Effluent Regulations of 1972. They set new standards for effluent loadings but, significantly, excluded plants already operating before that date (a practice known as “grandfathering”). In effect this was a compromise approach that required new installations to treat industrial effluent to a high standard, while allowing older facilities a longer period for adjustment (Clancy 2004). An alternative approach to pollution protection is to focus on a watercourse as a habitat for aquatic life. In 1986 the Department of Fisheries and Oceans took a significant step into this form of regulation, by announcing the federal fish habitat protection policy. In many ways this reflected the growing impact of conservation biology and ecological science. The new policy sought to change the policy framework by asserting the essential value and continuing need to defend host environments in the round. Central to the fish habitat regime was the principle of “no net loss” of habitat due to development impacts. Damaged habitat required restoration or substitution of similar quality (Canada Department of Fisheries and Oceans 1986). This habitat regime was the target of legislative change in 2012, as detailed in the previous chapter. Managing fish stocks is the third and in some ways most challenging goal. An indispensable tool for understanding population dynamics is fisheries science, and even here the task is daunting. For each body of water there are complicated relationships between biophysical capacities and species characteristics to take into account. In addition are the trophic relations of energy that run between species. Natural reproduction can be augmented by hatchery cultures, but the effects of these can be uncertain. Also, naturally occurring stocks can be jeopardized by the introduction of exotic species capable of disrupting prior patterns. A contemporary policy tool that reflects an appreciation of the value of species per se is the species at risk regime. In cases where a population has been severely diminished or even extinguished in a host environment, there are technical and legal instruments available for designation and remediation. This will be explored below in greater length in relation to salmon.

Fisheries Law and Management In Canada’s federal form of state, “sea coast and inland fisheries” were assigned to the national government by section 91(12) of the British North America Act of 1867. The first dominion Fisheries Act was passed the following year, drawing heavily upon the prior statute in the Colony of Canada. The act remains one of the most powerful federal statutes, vesting extensive authority in the

5 F is h er i es a nd P o l l uti o n   85 federal fisheries minister. However, this policy field is anything but straightforward. Pearse remarks that “the inland fisheries may be one of our most complex cases of divided jurisdiction” (Pearse 1988, 37). Fish are a wild resource inhabiting a body of water. In terms of property ownership and constitutional authority, the living fish can be distinguished from the water column and from the riparian banks and beds that enclose water. Wild fish may not become property until they have been caught, but those wild fish may still be an object of public policy by those with responsibilities for the water resource. Furthermore, the right to fish may be determined by the riparian rights holder or the water title holder. Toward the end of the nineteenth century, several provinces mounted judicial challenges to the federal jurisdiction over inland fisheries. The provinces argued that their jurisdiction over property and civil rights (including riparian rights) and public lands (vested in the provincial crown) necessitated provincial jurisdiction over modes of fishing and the allocation of fishing privileges. The appeal courts found for the provinces in several cases, and this led in 1899 to a negotiated arrangement by which Ottawa delegated the administration of inland fisheries to Ontario and Quebec (Parisien 1972). As a result, the licensing of fishers and the enforcement of harvest regulations are normally handled by provincial authorities, while Ottawa retains its roles in freshwater fish science and habitat protection. This modern arrangement has been described as “a complex patchwork of freshwater fisheries jurisdiction, ranging from full federal delivery to delegation in whole or part” (Canada Department of Fisheries and Oceans 2010). What was the state of freshwater fisheries policy by the 1970s? The signals were not positive. Great Lakes stocks had suffered severe declines. Pulp and paper and other toxic industrial pollutants imposed extensive damage on river and lake habitats. One of the most infamous impacts involved the English and Wabigoon Rivers of northern Ontario, where facilities associated with the Reed Paper plant released mercury into the water. As it bioaccumulated in the downstream fishery food chain, it poisoned many Ojibwa peoples who contracted the debilitating Minimata disease (Troyer 1977). By the 1990s, the damaging impact of persistent chemicals, and their intergenerational legacies, was recognized more generally (Colborn, Dumanoski, and Myers 1996). The urgent need for a freshwater fisheries policy modernization was set out by Peter Pearse in his 1986 report to the Canadian Wildlife Federation, Rising to the Challenge. He described the freshwater fisheries decline as a “creeping crisis,” reflected in the slow but insidious decline of fish stocks for decades (11). This went unnoticed because of its localized incidence—individual stocks in particular water bodies were collapsing and declining year by year. Pearse highlighted overfishing and habitat damage as twin causes. He also offered a glimpse into the relative shares of the three fisher categories in 1985, where the Aboriginal sector accounted for 5 per cent of the total catch by weight, the (declining) commercial sector 28 per cent, and the (fast growing) recreational sector 66 per cent.

8 6   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s This relative ordering was about to change in another direction, as the meaning of the 1982 amendment on Aboriginal treaty rights was worked out in the courts. Previously there was little governmental affinity for Aboriginal fishers, at either federal or provincial levels. The prevailing stance was that treaty guarantees had either lapsed or been superceded by post-Confederation laws of general application (such as the Fisheries Act). This view also found expression in the lower courts in the pre-charter era. In 1990, however, the Supreme Court of Canada reversed this in R. v. Sparrow, which confirmed an Aboriginal right to fish for food. This forced a reworking of federal regulations to accord allocative priority to Aboriginal fisheries (Sharma 1998). Seven years later, R. v. Marshall opened the same prospects for Mi’kmaq treaty right holders in Maritime Canada (Wicken 2002).

Threads of Fisheries Science Louis Agassis is often considered the father of ichthyology—the zoology of fishes. After pioneering work on Amazon fish and a coordinating role in zoological classification, Agassis moved to Harvard University in 1848 where he spent more than 20 years teaching and writing for the next generation of fisheries specialists. It was not until the 1870s, however, that the US Fish Commission became the first federal government research agency (Pisani 1984). Despite the fact that science and management are closely interwoven today, field science came relatively late to the management field. Laws, licensing, and enforcement systems were well established by the time science made its appearance in the late nineteenth century. This was the case in Canada as well. A fisheries Board of Management was established in 1898, and the first two field stations, staffed by summer university researchers, opened at St. Andrews, NB, and Nanaimo, BC, in 1908. Full-time scientific staff were taken on in the 1920s, but their policy impact remained limited. It seems fair to say that the practical (commercial and political) and the scientific (method-driven research) perspectives on fisheries moved on separate tracks that occasionally intersected. For example, when fish hatcheries were first advanced as a solution to declining wild stocks such as salmon, the bureaucratic promoters invoked scientific authority. Controlled breeding could provide stock that would compensate for natural decline. Over time, however, scientific opinion began to question the universal efficacy of artificial stocking (Taylor 1998). This hints at some more basic dilemmas of state involvement in fisheries science. Should the priority be foundational (i.e., “pure”) science or applied science? Can the latter be achieved without the former? Are the universities the appropriate place for basic fisheries inquiry? Is contract research the preferred tool for management support? As mentioned, the federal government established a Board of Management in 1898 for a new Marine Biological Station, a floating research barge that could be moved among sites on the Atlantic coast. Several fixed stations followed at Georgian Bay, St. Andrews, and Nanaimo. The early research output tilted toward pure fisheries science. In 1912 it was reorganized as the Biological Board of Canada, with greater financial and policy autonomy

5 F is h er i es a nd P o l l uti o n   87 from the Department of Marine and Fisheries. Following the war, the Board was redirected toward more applied and technical problems (  Johnstone 1977). More generally, turn-of-the-century fisheries administration was driven by concrete material interests. These included the domestic and commercial demand for fish products, the rival claimants for fisheries access, and the potential revenues to be extracted from licences, fines, and business spinoffs. In the government sector, this was an era of licences and rules. Parenteau’s fascinating accounts of New Brunswick salmon policy during this time contain virtually no mention of science inputs. Distinct from the study of particular fish species is the study of aquatic systems. The late nineteenth century saw the rise of limnology as an integrated study of inland waters (lakes and rivers). This embraced physical conditions as well as food chains. Here a pivotal figure was Francois-Alfonse Forel, whose pioneering fieldwork took place at Lake Geneva. In 1922, the International Limnological Society (SIL) was founded to link scientists worldwide. Provincial governments inherited the federal administrative focus on licensing fishers and seem to have felt less need of science inputs unless pushed by crisis. In 1920, the Ontario Department of Game and Fisheries (Lands and Forests after 1946) began supporting inland fisheries work by biologists at the University of Toronto. The Ontario Fisheries Research Laboratory was the instrument here. There was a defining angle, for, as Bocking notes, “researchers generally focused on the dynamics of fish species of importance to commercial or sportfishers” in their studies of population sizes and dynamics and fishing impacts (Bocking 1997, 157–58). By the 1960s the provincial fisheries science staff began to grow but academic limnologists continued to play a key role. One of the milestones of government-supported freshwater science in Canada was the creation of the Experimental Lakes Area (ELA) in 1966. It speaks to the importance of state sponsorship in establishing unique research settings and in paving the way for new research paradigms. Equally, the ELA’s recent demise as a federal science centre is revealing about the politics of government-hosted science. The origins of Experimental Lakes lay in pressing public policy needs. In 1964, the International Joint Commission was directed to examine Great Lakes pollution. Out of this came the establishment of the Freshwater Institute (FWI) in Winnipeg. It was the FWI that launched a new permanent facility for “whole lake” or “whole ecosystem” studies. The FWI secured federal financial support, and the government of Ontario agreed to set aside the lands and waters and take back the timber licences then in effect. The site, in northwestern Ontario, included 17 small watersheds and 46 lakes. The first research program, covering the years 1968–75, centred on lake eutrophication. This responded to concerns about blue-green algae blooms in Lake Erie. In policy terms it led to recommendations that made Canada the first country to ban phosphates from laundry detergents (which accounted for more than half the phosphorus supply in many lakes) and the compulsory removal of phosphates from municipal sewage discharges into lakes. The next major ELA program, extending from 1972 to 1992, explored the

88  fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s processes of lake acidification. Beginning in the 1990s, an initiative was launched on the effects of reservoir creation and flooding. The 1980s and 1990s saw continuing debates over ELA mandates and outputs, but new operating agreements were negotiated in 1983, 1993, and 2000. The founding generation of scientific leaders moved into new careers in the public service and the universities, and federal budget constraints also posed difficulties. One ELA scientist referred to the 1990s as a decade of  “troubles” for the ELA. Despite its past distinctions, there were as many as five attempts to phase out the program in recent decades. The 2012 budget by the Harper majority government included a broadside of cuts to environmental science. This included scientific staff in departments ranging from DFO to Environment Canada and Parks. In early May, ELA employees were notified that Ottawa was terminating support for whole lake ecosystem research, effective in March 2013 (Smith 2013). This prompted a letter-writing campaign by scientific and ENGO groups in Canada and abroad, protesting the loss of a unique experimental setting for applied environmental research. It also triggered the formation of a protest campaign by the newly formed Coalition to Save the ELA, which succeeded in keeping the issue in the news during the transitional nine months (Saveela n.d.). The Harper government’s contention that whole lake ecology no longer fit with expressed federal research priorities was fiercely challenged in many scientific quarters. In 2013, newly selected Ontario Liberal Premier Kathleen Wynne announced that the province would provide funding to maintain the ELA. In sum, over the course of half a century the Experimental Lakes Area figured in a variety of policy narratives. It began as a bold environmental field venture and evolved successively into a confirmed contributor of frontline policy-relevant science, a questionable science infrastructure expense at a time of tight budgets, and finally an obsolete federal facility. In different eras, it has been caught up in a variety of scientific, administrative, and partisan debates. Most recently, it has become part of the debate about whether the Harper government has declared war not only on environmental advocacy groups, but on publicly supported science in the public interest. Clearly there are many science dimensions of fisheries and aquatic habitats. But if there is one fisheries issue that exemplifies both the influence and the limits of limnologists in public policy, it is the documentation and explanation of acid precipitation that so gravely damaged the lakes and rivers of eastern Canada. This is the subject of the following section.

Acid Rain One of the most profound threats to freshwater fisheries in eastern Canada comes from the chemical transformations of lakes and rivers due to acid rain. The story of its origins, impacts, and eventual policy responses is very revealing of fisheries politics.

5 F is h er i es a nd P o l l uti o n   89 The scientific building blocks are not new. As early as 1727 there was awareness that precipitation could wash acidic (particularly sulphuric) particles from polluted air. A century and a half later, Robert Smith coined the term “acid rain” in the British midlands, where coal fuelled the industrial revolution. However, given coal’s indispensability for manufacturing growth, the pollution was seldom questioned seriously. As recently as 1952 London experienced a dense five-day smog that caused over 4,000 deaths, as people inhaled acidic water droplets. This was a powerful catalyst for the UK’s 1956 Clean Air Act. There were parallel European findings of acidifying lakes, particularly in Scandinavia where prevailing winds carried UK emissions from high towers. In Ontario the work of University of Toronto biologist Harold Harvey revealed the acidity of lakes in Killarney Provincial Park near Sudbury. This raised questions about the link to smelter emissions by the copper-nickel industry. By the 1970s acid rain was recognized as a complex four-step phenomenon. First of all, sulphur- and nitrous-oxides (SOx and NOx) were produced from coal plant combustion and nonferrous smelters. These were then transported over long distances by prevailing winds, especially from superstacks (almost 400 metres high at Sudbury) that released emissions at altitude. Third, these pollutants were transformed by precipitation into particles of sulphuric or nitric acid—H2SO4 or HNO3. Finally they were deposited as rain or snow and altered the chemistry of soils, forests, and waters according to the “buffering” capacities on the surface. The key variables were the volumes of emissions, measured in millions of annual tons of SOx and NOx, and the nature of receiving environments such as vegetation, soils, rocks, and waters. Where acid reduction capacities are low (especially on the rock shield), river and lake acidity can increase quickly and heavy metals can leach from soils (Howard and Perley 1980). In waterways the key measurement is the pH level of surface waters. The pH scale measures the concentration of hydrogen ions, with 0 representing maximum acidity and 14 representing maximum alkalinity. On this scale, 7 is seen as a neutral solution and 5.6 is considered clean water in equilibrium with atmospheric CO2. In the northern hemisphere a range of 4 to 7 is normally found, with the 4s downwind of major industrial emitters and the 7s and above in alkaline prairie soils. It is important to bear in mind that since the pH scale is logarithmic, a reading of 5.5 is 10 times more acidic than a 6.5 figure. For fish scientists, waters with a level in the low 6s can be considered a point of prospective damage, with some species starting to die at pH 6.2. Under 5.2 the natural buffering potential is exhausted and waters will be very slow to recover. For Atlantic salmon, pH 5.0–4.7 can kill half the salmon eggs and up to a third of fry. The spring acid reading on Nova Scotia’s Mersey River centres in this range. By the late 1970s, there was general agreement on the nature and scope of the problem. However, scientists were chagrined by the political positions reflected by the emitting industries in North America. This involved varying degrees of evasion. Initially the predominant expression was to deny that there was

9 0  fre shwate r p ol i t i c s a problem, suggesting that certain lakes are naturally acidic. Later as the scientific evidence mounted, the argument shifted. Polluters conceded that there was a problem but denied that industry was chiefly responsible, since there were multiple contributors including duck droppings and forests. Finally, as the evidence became overwhelming, business accepted a causal responsibility while contending that it was too late to make meaningful change (Smol 2002). Acid rain policy would never be determined by industry alone. Beginning in 1970, governments began confronting the problem. Initially they acted in isolation, though a level of coordination emerged in later stages. The 1970 UN Conference on the Environment in Stockholm identified acid rain as an emerging priority, and environmental advocacy groups in Canada took up the cause. That same year, the province of Ontario issued an executive order for INCO’s massive mine complex at Sudbury to cut its SO2 emissions from 6,000 tons/day to 750 tons/day by 1978 (a deadline later extended to 1984). The goal here was to reduce acid pollution at the source. Recognizing that the Great Lakes region was an acid polluting region on both sides of the border, the government of Canada developed contacts in Washington. This began with research consultation in 1978. Two years later came a Memorandum of Intent to work on a trans-boundary pollution agreement. The election of the Reagan Republicans killed this initiative, with the businessfriendly White House declaring that more research was needed. Working groups were formed in 1981 but little progress was made during the Reagan years. It was not until 1990 that the first President George Bush signed Clean Air Act amendments for a 50 per cent SO2 cut by 2000. Meanwhile, there were federal-provincial collaborations of some substance in Canada. Environment Canada took the lead in proposing a maximum 20 kg per hectare per year maximum load for “moderately sensitive” ecosystems. Federal and provincial environment ministers agreed on 50 per cent reductions from 1980 levels by 1990. In 1984 this target was decoupled from American pledges and made unilateral by 1994 (MacDonald 1991). Over 30 years, then, acid rain reduction policies became a rare but legitimate success story in North America. But what impact did it have on the freshwater fish stocks of affected regions? For Atlantic Canada the total SO2 emissions at source dropped by 32 per cent by 1995. The deposition of acidic sulphate also declined in this period. However, data to 1998 (Beattie and Ro 1998) indicated that most of the region still received deposition greater than the critical load (that which maintained a pH above 6). Nova Scotia watersheds were the hardest hit. The most dramatic impact has been in Maritime salmon rivers. In Nova Scotia, the highest depositions of acid rain have been in the western region and in the Atlantic shore drainages. On the Atlantic shore, pH levels range from 5.3 to 4.6, the latter making natural reproduction impossible. Of particular damage is the “plug” of acid accompanying the annual spring melt. Salmon have disappeared completely from 14 Nova Scotia rivers and declined by 90 per cent in 20 others. Thirty more are classified as threatened. The Atlantic Salmon Federation calls for a further reduction of SO2 emissions by 75 per cent (Atlantic Salmon Federation n.d.).

5 F is h er i es a nd P o l l uti o n

91

A 2006 appraisal concluded that while precipitation acid loadings will return to balance over the next three decades, the cation loadings will take more than a century to disperse. An experimental project to lime sections of the West River in Halifax County in 2002 has shown positive results, but the prospects for broad-scale liming of the dozens of most damaged rivers has yet to be seriously considered (Atlantic Salmon Federation and Environment Canada 2007). Acid rain may be the best known environmental threat to Atlantic Canadian rivers and fishes but it is far from the only one. In this chapter’s case study, Canada’s most famous salmon angling watershed—the Miramichi River—is explored.

CASE STUDY: SALMON IN THE MIRAMICHI WATERSHED The Miramichi in New Brunswick remains one of the great wild rivers of eastern Canada. It has an axial length of some 250 km from source to mouth and drains almost one-quarter of the provincial area. Its complex system of tributaries creates 13 sub-watersheds and covers more than 14,000 km2 of forested land (Chadwick 1995). The two main branches are the Northwest Miramichi and the Southwest Miramichi, each flowing in an easterly direction before converging at Wilson’s Corner for the final 20 km flow to the estuary in the inner portion of Miramichi Bay. This watershed is the second largest in the province, half the size of the Saint John but twice that of the Restigouche. The dispersal of sub-basins in the upper reaches also contributes to the resilience of the overall watershed. In addition, most of the terrestrial drainage is heavily forested, a physical feature that has closely shaped relations between humans and nature.The second dominant natural resource is salmon. The Miramichi is a spectacular salmon habitat, fished continually for centuries and the most important Atlantic salmon spawning ground on the east coast today. Among the sub-basins, the Northwest, Southwest, Renous, and Little Southwest provide the most extensive and important spawning grounds. Considering its area, the Miramichi drainage is only sparsely inhabited. The population of about 45,000 is divided between Miramichi City near the estuary, a series of lumber towns located along the Southwest Miramichi, and rural residents scattered throughout the basin. Map 5.1 sets out the main tributaries and settlements. Prior to the 1760s, European interests had little presence on the Miramichi, and Mi’kmaq fished a variety of species including bass, trout, eels, smelts, and sturgeon as well as salmon. The standard techniques included weirs, spears, traps, and nets, depending on species and season. A decisive change was marked by the 150 mi2 land grant to William Davidson and John Cort in 1765, upstream of the confluence of the Northwest and Southwest Miramichi. This resulted in a fixed net salmon fishery and export business as well as the sale of riparian land to settlers. When the Davidson grant was revoked some 20 years later, colonial authorities transferred much of the best land to settlers. As a result, Mi’kmaq peoples found themselves under pressure at their village sites of Metepenagiag (Red Bank) and Natoaganeg (Eel Ground). Despite a Mi’kmaq river land licence

9 2   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s Map 5.1  Miramichi River Watershed, New Brunswick Heath Steele mine

e

Nor t hw S a v o g i e R i ve s t M i ram r

iv i chi R

er

Lit

bo

ve r g Ri

MIRAMICHI BAY

wes

BLACKVILLE Du

n g a r von

Ri

ver

Vi n

Riv

e

RENOUS

ve

Ba

y

u

r

o us R i v e r en

d

t R iv e r

Ri

uth

r

RED BANK FIRST NATION

r

R

t hwe

r ti

B a r n a by

tle

ve

So

Sou

Ba

MIRAMICHI CITY Ri

JUNIPER

BURNT CHURCH FIRST NATION

EEL GROUND FIRST NATION

st River

Mi

ram

ich

iv iR

er

DOAKTOWN Ca

in

sR

iv e r

0

10

20

30 km

FREDERICTON

from Governor Parr on the Northwest above Red Bank and several reserves being established below that point, the nineteenth century saw sustained campaigns to open Indian lands and squatter actions on those same lands (Hamilton 1984). Ultimately three Mi’kmaq reserves were confirmed on the lower Miramichi at Red Bank, Eel Ground, and Esgenoôpetitj (Burnt Church), amounting collectively to less than one-third of the original Davidson grant. Not surprisingly, given its forested hinterland, the Miramichi has also figured strongly in the province’s industrial history. In many ways the history of northeast New Brunswick is the history of the Miramichi. In early colonial times, two towns grew up near the mouth of the river. Newcastle was established as the shire town for Northumberland County in 1786. Located near the confluence of the two main branches, the Northwest and Southwest Miramichi, it began as a commercial centre for the masting, shipbuilding, and lumbering industries as well as a key port of export. Part of this trade was a thriving business in catching, pickling, and exporting barrelled salmon. Slightly downstream on the opposite bank was Chatham, a parallel town most prominently associated in the nineteenth century with the shipbuilding and lumbering interests of the Cunard family. In 1825 the Great Fire burned a quarter of the province’s forest cover while decimating Newcastle. It was one of the epic natural disasters of the century.

5 F is h er i es a nd P o l l uti o n   93 By the mid-nineteenth century the cumulative impact of the commercial fishing and export trade registered in the first historic salmon stock decline. Although the long distance fish trade never recovered, local communities still relied heavily on salmon as part of the regional economy, and a massive system of shore net fishing continued. By the 1850s a third sector began to expand as sport fishers discovered Maritime salmon rivers. While angling was pursued across the Maritimes, the Miramichi was understandably famous and attracted seasonal sport fishers from all over the continent and beyond. The rise of the timber economy affected the salmon resource in many respects. Early logging began at the riverbanks and advanced upstream. Not only did the loss of riparian forest cover tend to raise water temperatures (to which salmon were sensitive), it could also encourage soil erosion and siltation. Even more severe was the impact of spring log drives to transport logs downstream, scouring riverbeds and destroying spawning habitat in the process. Add to this the impact of local sawmills. Their dams and mill ponds blocked the fish runs, and although fish ladders were often mandated by law, these were often ignored. Solid wood wastes were also disposed into streams in the forms of wood chips and sawdust. The Atlantic salmon run in the Miramichi was historically the greatest on the east coast. Even with its relative decline in modern times, this watershed remains the most important in eastern North America. The riverbeds of the many tributaries offer massive spawning grounds and rich habitats for juvenile fish. The young fish hatch out in May or June. During the first few years in local waters, adequate forest cover and supply of leaf detritus are keys to health. After an initial two to six years of life in the river, the surviving smolts leave their freshwater nurseries and head downstream to the sea.Their internal organs adapt to salt water and they spend one or more years in the ocean growing rapidly in size.The subsequent return of grilse (one year at sea) or adult salmon (two or more years) to their native rivers for autumn spawning involves a reverse adaptation.The demographics of salmon survival are stark. By one estimate, for every 7,000 salmon eggs laid, 70 smolts reach the sea and of these, four return to their original river where three spawn successfully (MREAC and ACAP 2007, 52). Although numbers of return spawners are vastly diminished with each cycle, Atlantic salmon can spawn as many as six times. It is the upstream and downstream migrations that afforded extraordinary opportunities for the subsistence, commercial, and recreational salmon fisheries. The regulation of salmon fishing is a complex and many-sided story. The federal government was pressed on several fronts to favour the interests of rival harvesters. Commercial operators concentrated on the lower river and estuary while local residents defended their domestic fisheries wherever they lived. Aboriginal fishers continued traditional practices on the river while the increasingly lucrative tourist anglers and lodge owners pushed for a sport-dominated harvest. Despite the guarantees for traditional harvesting pursuits that were central to the eighteenth-century Mi’kmaq treaties, the colonial and Canadian courts tended to subordinate Indian hunting and fishing rights to the authority of provincial crown land, forest, and water title (Wicken 2002). As seen earlier with

9 4   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s Boat Harbour, the federal government had a strong jurisdictional claim after 1867 through its mandate for Indian Affairs. In practice, however, the federal fisheries power became the fulcrum of government intervention. In the decades following World War II, the sport salmon sector became more formally organized, with several angling groups at both the watershed and the regional level. The result, discussed later in this section, was a far stronger voice for salmon conservation. A key factor shaping politics among rival harvester interests was the licensing system. Beginning in the mid-1800s, when spearing and netting were first prohibited in spawning grounds, the colonial crown in New Brunswick and Quebec began leasing salmon fishing rights on designated river passages to private individuals and angling clubs (Parenteau 2004). In return for exclusive rights, lessees were obliged to install private guardians to monitor and protect their holdings. This system was carried over to the federal freshwater regime and was later transferred to provincial administration. By the 1890s more than 100 prime salmon stretches had been disposed in this way, with affluent foreigners joining Canadians as angling lease holders. Not surprisingly, the private lease system provoked widespread tensions with rural residents who held to customary local use rules. Parenteau describes the history of legal and cultural conflicts around fisheries patrolling, subsistence fishing, net fishing bans, and poaching on salmon watersheds like the Miramichi. It was notoriously difficult to secure and uphold convictions among rural magistrates and juries, even for violent crimes such as arson and assault. Such community tensions are what James Scott (1990) refers to as everyday forms of local resistance, of which only a portion rises to the level of visible politics. One activity that fell beyond the grasp of salmon conservation, however, was the commercial forest industry. New Brunswick hosted one of Canada’s premier lumber industries, and the pulp and paper sector came to rival it in the twentieth century. Both, however, lay under provincial government jurisdiction and Fredericton was tightly committed to the logging and milling economy. One of the most spectacular instances of this involved the chemical spray campaigns that covered the province for 40 years after 1953 (Sandberg and Clancy 2002). Maritime Canadian forests were prone to cyclical (20–40 year) infestations of the spruce budworm, which killed massive swathes of softwood stands. During the 1920s outbreak, the budworm damage was treated as a natural and inevitable process that would end when the insects ran out of food. By the time of the next cycle in the 1950s, neither government nor industry contemplated widespread timber losses with equanimity. An unprecedented joint enterprise was organized for the comprehensive, multiyear aerial spray of insecticides across the New Brunswick forests. Beginning in 1953, the chemical DDT was applied by a private air force assembled by Forest Protection Inc. (FPI) and millions of hectares were covered in peak years. This was not without ecological cost. Almost immediately, ground evidence pointed to the damaging impact to fish and birds, with much of it also documented by field studies at the federal fish research station at St. Andrews (Keenleyside 1959). The Atlantic Salmon Association publicly opposed the spray campaign as early as 1956. It also figured, dramatically,

5 F is her i es a nd P o l l uti o n   95 in Rachel Carson’s 1962 bestseller, Silent Spring. Juvenile salmon populations declined sharply in the late 1950s and early 1960s. What makes the DDT spray program so significant ecologically was its breadth and duration. For 15 years, FPI applied an industrial chemical to New Brunswick watersheds such as the Miramichi, with virtually no officially expressed concern for its collateral effects on wildlife or humans. The absence of integrated resource programming is politically revealing. Crown forest agencies dealt with the budworm as a forest management matter, while crown wildlife and fisheries agencies had very little influence on the key decisions, despite the ecological implications for birds and fishes. While one federal agency (the Canadian Forestry Service) was a partner in New Brunswick’s spray campaign, another agency (the Fisheries Research Board) was documenting the environmental degradation. It is a telling comment on political priorities that the Miramichi fisheries research program was discontinued in 1968 by federal government decision. Dramatic as the forest spray campaigns have been, it would be wrong to ignore other industrial impacts. In the postwar period, a promising base metal find was made near the Temogonops River, a tributary of the Northwest Miramichi. The Heath Steele mine, a copper-lead-zinc operation, was opened in 1956 by a joint venture of American Metals Inc. and INCO. By one account, during the spring that followed the first dumping of untreated waste water into the stream, returning salmon tried to reverse their course to the spawning grounds and exit the fish box at the entrance to the Northwest (Weeks 1968). While the mine property changed hands several times and was periodically closed when markets slumped, production continued until 1999. Over a 30-year operating life it released heavy metal and acid contaminants into the river and depressed pH levels to the point of eliminating native fish from the Temogonops tributary. Remedial work has continued at the site since 2000. The sulphate pulp mill near Chatham was an added source of organic pollutants for decades until its closure in 2005. Similarly a wood treatment plant in Newcastle accounted for persistent aromatic hydrocarbons (PAHs) before its closure in the 1990s. Sewage treatment systems in Newcastle and Chatham added bacterial pollution to the lower river before their recent upgrades, as did Canadian Forces Base Chatham before its closure. It is not an exaggeration to state that, by eliminating the major effluent contaminants, the de-industrialization of the Miramichi watershed over the past two decades has brought significant improvements to water quality. Even in the estuary, where contaminated sediments have been deposited for over half a century or more, the government of Canada’s decision to cease dredging a shipping channel has prevented the release of accumulated toxins. As a whole, this has led to a local assessment that while stresses remain, “the state of the Miramichi River is generally good” (MREAC and ACAP, 2007, ii). Returning to the salmon resource, the 1970s and 1980s were decades of concern, characterized by the continued decline of spawning numbers. Several conservation measures followed. In 1984, commercial net fishing was closed across the Maritime region including the Miramichi. That left recreational and

9 6   fre sh wate r p ol i t i c s Aboriginal fishing. In another wild salmon conservation measure, the sport fishing regulations were altered in favour of catch and release (as distinct from catch and retain) fishing. Today on the Miramichi, this occurs through a combination of licence conditions and bag limits, delineated by stretches of the river. Large adult salmon (>63 cm) can be fished on a catch and release basis only. Small adults (