An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000–1500 9780521880367, 9780521706537, 2009005515

252 136 16MB

English Pages [308] Year 2009

Report DMCA / Copyright

DOWNLOAD FILE

Polecaj historie

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000–1500
 9780521880367, 9780521706537, 2009005515

Citation preview

Short Loan Collection

AN ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL HISTORY OF LATER MEDIEVAL EUROPE,

1000-1500

This book examines the most important themes in European social and economic history from the beginning of growth around the year 1000 to the first wave of global exchange in the 1490s. These five hundred years witnessed the rise of economic systems, such as capitalism, and the social theories that would have a profound influence on the rest of the world over the next five centuries. The basic story, the human search for food, clothing, and shelter in a world of violence and scarcity, is a familiar one, and the work and daily routines of ordinary women and men are the focus of this volume. Surveying the full extent of Europe, from east to west and north to south, Steven A. Epstein illuminates family life, economic and social thought, war, technologies, and other major themes while giving equal attention to developments in trade, crafts, and agriculture. The great waves of famine and then plague in the fourteenth century provide the centerpiece of a book that seeks to explain the causes of Europe's uneven prosperity and its response to catastrophic levels of death. Epstein also sets social and economic developments within the context of the Christian culture and values that were common across Europe and that were the cause of constant tension with Muslims, Jews, and dissidents within its boundaries and the great Islamic and Tartar states on its frontier.

Steven A. Epstein is Ahmanson-Murphy Distinguished Professor of Medieval History at the University of Kansas. He is the author of numerous articles and five books on aspects of medieval social and economic history, including Genoa and the Genoese, 958-1528 and Purity Lost: Transgressing Boundaries in the Eastern Mediterranean, 1000—1400.

ee aoa

sa

oS

ae ss he, erie “* eran oleae red 7 m sth eel wd

Oe ea

:

a



ya acon oy eee tt : :

)ie

fh:

aE

,

eet i

8 0

7

fate

a:

ue

?

7

‘i

-

wy os ot

nd

eT ‘eda

ie ,



iene ae Dr



on ante

4

oqo} SeloWOT

wid

beet o kc hak ooo

are

ae ih

irik nh Hits ew parila! 1shaver. Manuianice bane cat ; iadsbas

Tiwi 0 ee wave yan T duns vimelyt frat afthbrs sanvebinsoll painictsiw

ig sibsii \ahndipshant bork vaadil ydembty nennenmenst ite emote AUDTSR

gtiikalars

edd

do vert

onke et

ab

natal te

sf vesbaiet ahaesn cars bers Tei stem bean Ty nee

cit he ep

a”.ee

sy

ane

a

Uideeetaerns Tea.) yh wTDri and} aby sexawnd)

(Kips WOW Paoat

A N ECONOMIC

AND SOCIAL

HISTORY OF LATER MEDIEVAL

EUROPE, 1000-1500 STEVEN A. EPSTEIN University of Kansas

A] CAMBRIDGE Nate

UNIVERSITY

PRESS

CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS

Cambridge, New York, Melbourne, Madrid, Cape Town, Singapore, Sao Paulo, Delhi Cambridge University Press 32 Avenue of the Americas, New York, NY 10013-2473, USA www.cambridge.org Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/978052 1706537 © Cambridge University Press 2009 This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements, no reproduction of any part may take place without the written permission of Cambridge University Press. First published 2009

Printed in the United States of America

A catalogrecordfor this publication is available from the British Library. Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Epstein, Steven, 1952— An economic and social history of later medieval Europe, 1000-1500 / Steven A. Epstein. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-0-521-88036-7 (hardback) — ISBN 978-0-521-70653-7 (pbk.)

1. Europe — History — 476-1492. 2. Europe — Social conditions — To 1492. 3. Europe — Economic conditions — To 1492. 4. Economic history — Medieval, 500-1500. 5. Social history — Medieval, 500-1500. 6. Middle Ages. I. Title. D117.E67

940.1’7—de22

2009

2009005515

ISBN

978-0-521-88036-7 hardback

ISBN

978-0-521-70653-7 paperback

Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of URLs for external or third-party Internet Web sites referred to in this publication and does not guarantee that any content on such Web sites is, or will remain, accurate or appropriate. Information regarding prices, travel timetables, and other factyal information given in this work are correct at the time of first vince ees University Press does not guarantee the accuracy of such information: thereafter.

i

DB,

CONTENTS

List of Illustrations Acknowledgments

page vii XI

Introduction 1

Europe at the Millennium

10

2

Agriculture and Rural Life

40

3

Trade 1000—1350

70

4

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

100

5

Economic and Social Thought

129

6

The Great Hunger and the Big Death: The Calamitous Fourteenth Century

159

7

Technology and Consumerism

190

s

War and Social Unrest

223

9

Fifteenth-Century Portraits

250

Index

283

-

ne ut saul 4

inet g



a ings eat |

'

i eae

|ae ae ret | ~~

Lae

oi

She. :

ty Sa

-

eb





Kee

a »@

vai,

Ry,

weer

ieee

cases

qmail

(ge ov

e

ig

Behetags

ne

. ”

small Isisoe bas We stumtod yutnaD-theesttd

b=

acre

s% !

OND)!

~.

tne eae ' Pw ies

_—

oF

3

;

£

deed

Ws

Speen

na

‘oes

LAeinade ,

Pe AD.

niet

oe

“ig

vce

ter

»

a

a« Mes ;

rompsiamit ena

ree

Sw ibe een

Wels a

it

tee pebecrend ine oe

w+

oe a

ober

bh Wied hay 44,

7

phim, peel

.4 Wo = woe we 3 prs Prey | wage!aster wh ; : ’

i

: a i

a iy

ILLUSTRATIONS

INTRODUCTION

Figure I.1 Big Map of Europe, Listing Frequently Mentioned Places CHAPTER

page 2

1

Figure 1.1 Charlemagne's Empire in 814

14

Figure 1.2 Early Medieval Slave Trade

26

Figure 1.3 Tenth-Century Invasions

30

Table 1.1 Church Property on the Continent Data

27,

CHAPTER 2

Figure 2.1 Types of Plows

43

Figure 2.2 European Vegetation

44

Figure 2.3 Medieval Manor

46

Figure 2.4 Malthusian Population and Incomes

65

CHAPTER

3

Figure 3.1 Fairs of Champagne

82

Table 3.1 High Estimates of English Currency Data

94

Figure 3.2 Thirteenth-Century Silver Movements

oD) Vii

viii

Illustrations

CHAPTER

4

Figure 4.1 Bruges

104

Table 4.1 Women Workers, Paris, 1292

119

CHAPTER

5

Figure 5.1 Virtuous Cycle

133

Figure 5.2 Usury Cycle

133

Figure 5.3 Licit Profits within Rules of Justice

37

Figure 5.4 Sexual Decision-Making Process

147

CHAPTER

6

Figure 6.1 Big Death

169

Figure 6.2 Humoral System of Galen

to

Figure 6.3 St. Roch

181

CHAPTER

7

Figure 7.1 Spinning Wheel

194

Figure 7.2 Horizontal Loom

195

Figure 7.3 Grist Mill

199

Figure 7.4 Tappet Camshaft

202

Figure 7.5 Verge and Foliot

209

Figure 7.6 Consumption Preferences Ideas

216

Figure 7.7 Arnolfini Wedding

218

Figure 7.8 Apothecary Shop

22

CHAPTER 8

Table 8.1 Venetian Monte Shares 1380-1474

236

Illustrations

CHAPTER 9

Table 9.1 Distribution of Wealth in Florence in 1427

25

Figure 9.1 Datini Check

257

Figure 9.2 Genoa Women Slaves 1400-1453

259

Figure 9.3 Genoa Women Slaves 1453-1500

29

Figure 9.4 Palace of Jacques Coeur, Bourges

261

Figure 9.5 Netherlands around 1500

267

Figure 9.6 Luca Pacioli

272

a tell cies mr

/

vee nse

Fagns i) Sr Gel &

ab

ad

ae

ere? 29

:

eae

S

Pagers

s

P"9

~ bin 1 a

Whew +e

:

nie SF weet oe

Ty

=

bor

ow

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

A book like this one depends on the accumulated research and insights of many

scholars, some of whom are noted in the chapter bibliographies. | am deeply grateful to all these people whose work | have borrowed, and from whom | have learned so much over the last three decades. Beatrice Rehl suggested this

project to me, and | thank her for setting me on this interesting path. William Caferro and Ann Carlos read the entire manuscript and made many excellent suggestions for improvements. Pam LeRow and Paula Courtney provided

invaluable help with the tables and illustrations. Ellen Tirpak expertly copyedited the manuscript, and Ken Karpinski skillfully managed its production. | am also grateful to the many students whose good questions have made this a better book.

xi

‘elie ade capa

5 eaengtiae na! aean aan autStyne ibscaintest eobacotssnc tantasververlowenca bon se rasta efiy gainer wh scorgre whwahdad. be. a 3

in

sds

ranch ven> a

ae

Wobiocn einenin'S pliant ee oAls.T ma einen variqa al

auc? vinogie anguT vol? snciteswult Inés ealelntstirtea

t nockabornat boggeucte nl iti nlm wx hin 28 AL aber nivitisesh &

sedate

tiem wach

rae S

|

INTRODUCTION

OU

HAVE

OPENED

THIS BOOK

ON THE

ECONOMIC

AND

SOCIAL

history of later medieval Europe, so you are entitled to know its

limits and biases. This is a big Europe of open horizons, especially shaped by Mediterranean and Asian influences that draw our story to North Africa and the Middle East (see Figure I.1). The year 1000 is an arbitrary beginning so, in Chapter 1, we must take a step back to examine the social and economic history of early medieval Europe. The year 1500 is not, in some respects, a good ending, but we can worry about that later. By 1000, the Europeans were basically at home, although there would still be some migrations within Europe. These Europeans were far from being the most comfortable or prosperous people on the planet. Two other peoples, the Turks and Mongols, came into Europe during our five-hundred-year period. By 1500, the Europeans, equipped with good weapons, institutions, and reasonable numbers, were on the verge of bringing their distinctive society and economy to the rest of the world. The entire story of this remarkable change is not contained within these five centuries, and the causes of change are not limited to social and economic history. Nevertheless, these vital subjects — economic and social history — warrant opening this book.

Economic history is easier to define. Its subject is human choices about consumption and is generally limited to the material circumstances of life. “Human” means women and men, always. Yet, men and women make choices about how to choose, and some reject materialism while others thrive in the world of making, buying, and selling. Here, we must study those who are trying to survive by satisfying their own basic needs — food, clothing, and shelter — while also, in some way, satisfying the needs of others. In other words, we are examining rational maximizers of self-interest, operating under the constraints of the real

2.

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

adoga e Novgorod _§ volea e

Mediterranean Sea

Moscow

CYPRUS

C

} Jerusalem

\ Alexandria

2,000 Kilometers 1,000 Miles

Figure I.1. Big Map of Europe, listing frequently mentioned places (map by Keith A. French and Darin Grauberger, University of Kansas Cartographic Services).

world, its rules, resources, climate, and all of the rest. As Gregory Clark has recently pointed out, wealth alone is the most important factor that enables lifestyles and therefore social history. This is the inevitable bias of economic historians — the privileging of the search for wealth as the activity motivating

Introduction

most people most of the time. Such an assumption does not make economic historians crude materialists. What they tend to hate is the absence of wealth — poverty. They see wealth and poverty as two sides of the same coin. Much of economic history is the search for an antidote to poverty and the ways that poverty hurts people. Social history, a vast subject, considers how people live together in society as members of groups. How they survive is the story of the constraints — how climate or clean air, or personal traits, such as health and religious opinions, come together with personal capabilities to affect survival. The emphasis here will be on how people live in families and how they work together, or do not. Because social history takes in almost all of human experience, in practice we must limit our focus here to those aspects of society most connected to choices about work, comfort, and the economy. This social history has little to do with past politics and is no substitute for a textbook on medieval history. Material culture matters here, so, for example, tools are discussed. Cultural history is discussed occasionally when values or luxuries emerge as topics. The approach taken to social history excludes most of cultural history, a regrettable

but necessary decision if the book is to be short.

One of the subjects that unifies social history and economic history is the standard of living, that is, the level of comfort a person enjoys. In our

time

period of study, many people had no choice about these matters, especially

those who were born and died as slaves. In practice, comparatively few people had any sort of standard of living that we might envy. Only at the end of our period of study does any sort of consumer society emerge that shared its products with any substantial amount of people — still perhaps the top percent in terms of wealth. It is practically impossible to measure the standard

of living in the Middle Ages, but sometimes, at least, we have a sense of what direction it was going. Precise numbers are lacking on topics, such as gross

domestic product, wages, literacy, caloric intake, and other factors that shape how people live and die. Whether or not the average person was experiencing any real improvement depends on how we

measure or estimate what they

valued. The privilege of praying in a great cathedral like Chartres has to be weighed against a grumbling stomach or cold feet. Free lands in Iceland or in the Ukraine experienced a burst of productivity, but it would not last. Clark's perspective on this problem was so wide that he contended that the average person was really no better off in 1800 than he or she was in 100,000 BCE. What he means must be taken seriously, even if he is wrong.

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

We must resist the temptation in social and economic history to focus on

elites, lords, and great merchants. The great mass of people, poor with very little or nothing, subsisted in a standard of living that their distant huntergatherer ancestors may very well not have envied. Our later Middle Ages were in the middle of the Malthusian world in which economic success equaled reproductive failure. In this environment, the stern message was that, for most people, the only ways to raise the standard of living were to decrease the birth rate and/or to increase the death rate. A pie of a stable size gave bigger slices to fewer people. The rich had more children because they could afford to, but if they had too many they would end up poorer. Yet, those factors we might assume improved the lives of people — peace, hygiene, freedom from epidemic disease — reduced the standard of living because they lowered the death rate! This way of looking at the world made economics, at first, seem to be truly the dismal science of death. Most medieval people viewed this world as a brief stop on the way to either a pleasant or hellish eternity. But they thought that what they did here mattered, not only to their salvation, but also to their choices about how to live. Their institutions, the sets of rules or norms by which they regulated social and economic life, are perhaps their most durable legacy to the modern world. This textbook is a summary of vast scholarly literatures which are growing exponentially every year in a variety of languages. Even at this moment, it becomes slowly out-of-date. This is the normal fate of textbooks. This introduction and each chapter mention the most important works for the topics discussed. Some major studies influenced every chapter and are not listed again. The bibliographies of these works, in turn, become a guide for the huge literature that you may wish to consult on any special subject that seems neglected or omitted. Wherever possible, | have emphasized readings in English, but I have tried to keep a proper perspective on the social and economic history of later medieval England. This vast and intensively studied subject cannot be allowed to overwhelm a text that must illuminate Europe as a whole. This textbook is a filter standing between you and the known facts and opinions about medieval social and economic history. I have selected some themes and not others, and | have chosen one example over another. My biases and ignorance will become apparent as you read. For now, | want to make it clear that this is not the first textbook on this subject. I will briefly set out the major influences on the ways I have shaped this book, so that you can think about these limits in advance.

Introduction

Let us consider a few old and great books for what they have the current wisdom on medieval social and economic history. will make immediate sense to you, but down the road it will ring now it explains the biases of this textbook. Henri Pirenne's Economic and Social History of Medieval Europe

contributed to Not all of this bells, and even

(1937) rightly commanded the field for most of the twentieth century. This book stood the test of time because of its big ideas. Pirenne claimed to be guided by the facts rather than theories. In practice, this means that he was in the grip of theories that he did not understand or had suppressed. Yet, his judgment was excellent and where the book fails is in the lack of up-to-date information. In the last seventy years, more research has rendered obsolete most of what Pirenne

wrote about credit, customs duties, employers, and entrepreneurial landlords,

among other topics. He knew well northern Europe, commercial fairs, banking, manors as social institutions, trade, in general, and many other things. Pirenne

saw Europe from the perspective of what he knew best — his native Flanders, its leading medieval city, Bruges, and another city he seemed to admire above all others, Venice.

Pirenne's book is filled with bons mots, really striking points revealing his biases, partly inherited by me. He thought that the merchant improvised at the will of his circumstances. This means he focused on entrepreneurs, opportunities, and accidents. The rise of a merchant class struck him as a fundamental issue in this period. Jewish merchants seemed to be accessories, and when they were largely excluded from commerce Pirenne thought society had lost nothing essential. He was the first, but by no means the last, historian to pon-

der the exact role Jews played in economic development, as their social fate became dominated by discrimination and even expulsion from parts of Europe. Feudal society hovered over the world Pirenne studied, and he thought that the few common people who preserved their liberties were of no consequence. Piracy struck him as the first stage or indeed the root of commerce (he had the Vikings in mind), validating Balzac's view that behind every fortune there is a crime. Commerce was contagious according to Pirenne, so being neighbors to

more prosperous trading civilizations was a stroke of good luck. His characteristic open-mindedness inclined Pirenne to value the contributions of Islamic practices to medieval economic life. Yet, he saw the one important result of the Crusades (not a subject that much interested him) as the ways Italians, Provencals, and Catalans came to dominate the Mediterranean at the expense

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

of the world of Islam. Usury laws on the interest rate on loans struck Pirenne as a hindrance rather than a barrier to economic development.

Above all, Pirenne was convinced that the later Middle Ages witnessed the rise of commercial capitalism and that anyone who failed to see this was blinded by theory or bias. He surely had in mind Max Weber, Karl Marx, and others who, for one theoretical reason or another, denied the existence of a medieval capitalism. Europeans did not have to wait for Protestantism or the end of the feudal mode of production to invent capitalism. Pirenne claimed that capitalism required an entrepreneurial class of rational maximizers who owned private property, who produced fora market, and who employed people to work for them. These basic hallmarks of a market economy, commercial capitalism, appeared together in Western Europe precociously in twelfth-century Flanders and northern Italy. Elements of a market economy had been long present in the Muslim and Greek East, legacies of the ancient world. Nevertheless, some people, be they peasants or nuns, continued to exploit some lands in common ways. One economic system does not automatically drive out others. The search for food, clothing, and shelter can be an individual, familial, or collective endeavor. Most economic historians have joined with Pirenne in locating the rise of free markets in the Middle Ages. Disagreements still exist about the degree to which the market's rise, which was admittedly impressive, had become the dominant engine of the European economy by 1500. This textbook tries to

avoid abstractions like "the market" or “capitalism.” | put forward here a view of economic development entirely consistent with a clear market economy in some regions by the end of this book. This does not mean that markets prevailed everywhere or overcame more traditional means of organizing production — for example, durable forms of peasant servitude. Pirenne also understood this inevitable mixing of styles of production and degrees of personal and material freedom. Pirenne was not infallible. For some reason, he was convinced that no one had economic policies in the Middle Ages, but as we will see, there were many policies. Marc Bloch's Feudal Society (1961) was conceived in the 1930s and reflects the

French Annales school approach to medieval social history. This school aimed to fuse economic, social, and cultural history into a total synthesis, enriching the previous emphasis on past politics and the Church. Bloch rooted his understanding of society deep in the soil worked by generations of peasants or serfs — both farmers under duress. A lordly class of professional warriors and landlords

Introduction

subjected this peasantry and lived off of their labors, Whatever surpluses the feudal regime generated sustained early markets and noble consumption. Bloch understood that feudal society did not prevail everywhere and was not even present all parts of medieval Europe. Nevertheless, we owe to him an abiding interest in medieval agriculture — its farming and pastoral regions that sustained cities. The role of the warrior in medieval society, and the social value placed on contracts among people, became distinctive medieval social legacies to the subsequent development of Europe. Some later historians have turned a skeptical eye toward “feudalism” as an anachronistic and useless legalistic construct imposed on the rich variety of local medieval experiments in self-help and

farming. Bloch’s social insights suffuse this text and its assumptions.

John Hicks, A Theory of Economic History (1969) synthesized the lessons of nearly a century concerning how to write economic history, a subject hard to

disentangle from all the other types of histories. Hicks wondered about how exactly history benefits from quantitative analysis, but he concluded that it did.

Economic theory was relevant to general phenomena, but not the stories that remain the staple of the historical narrative. Hicks was interested mainly in markets, which he saw as rising from custom and command in a society. The rise of the market is not a good or dramatic story; it is a general phenomenon.

Yet, most people eventually work for a market. Like Pirenne, Hicks loved city-states, such as Venice and Florence, because they revealed how merchants

ruled and specialized. It is natural for economic historians to have a fondness for merchants. So the things that engage merchants tend to absorb economic historians, because these things leave behind records and numbers to ponder. Hicks drew attention to risk — the merchant was above all in the business of reducing risk and enduring uncertainty. Yet, we must be careful to ask exactly what risk entailed in specific contexts. Law and money were the great Roman the medieval economy. Medieval merchants had to reinvent credit. the real point to disputes about usury was the morality of interest on loans. He saw feudal society as primarily a military system, and

legacies to For Hicks, unsecured economic

historians cannot forget about the costs of war. Finally, according to Hicks,

everyone understood that the theoretical benefits of free trade did not always work out, in practice, to enrich everyone. Economic historians tend to take free trade as an obvious good thing, as almost a religion. Social historians tend to worry about how the powerful rig trade to their private gain at public cost. Carlo M. Cipolla published the first edition of his fundamental Before the Industrial Revolution: European Society and Economy 1000-1700 in 1973, and its third edition

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

appeared in 1994. The title and dates reveal his most important premise — the later medieval world was a prequel to what really mattered — the Industrial Revolution. Cipolla’s interests and statistics thickened as he came to the end of this story. Yet, he accepted the basic connectivity of economic and social history. One of the common themes was scarcity — the basic constraint operating to shape and to distinguish needs from wants. Choice was always necessary, because there were always more wants, let alone needs, than resources. Basic choices concerned food, clothing, and shelter. Cipolla always had an eye out for those whose choices were most constrained: the many beggars in medieval society and the foundlings left on church porches. Charity was a prime example of a voluntary transfer of wealth. Cipolla saw the important distinction about savings: before 1000 — hoarding and dishoarding, and after 1000, the rise of investment. An important question to ask about any society is: who can save and invest? He too rightly observed that the public debt was unknown in the ancient world and was thus a great medieval invention. The very high percentage of the medieval work force in agriculture was proof of its low productivity. Some medieval work, such as weaving, saw considerable increases in productivity while others, such as domestic service or building, saw virtually none. Fixed capital was mainly in livestock, tools, and weapons. Cipolla had no doubts that warfare was negative economic production and a social waste. He also wondered if free trade was always a good thing and if protectionism was sometimes wise policy. Finally, Cipolla was a close student of the rise of the professional in later medieval Europe, and he gave pride of place not to the banker but to the physician. Cities were death traps but frequently hired doctors to serve the public. This was an amazingly astute and caring public health policy. These thoughts on the current status of medieval economic and social history prepare us to enter this complex world. Medieval people had no reason to believe that what we know as their social and economic history affected their own values, or history in general. We are imposing these categories of analysis

on the medieval world. Important themes take us to the calamity of the Big Death in the fourteenth century. This world did not end. Europe contained enough grounds for optimism so that its people chose to continue making choices to live. Without their endurance, many of us would not be here. From the perspective of the rest of the world, with its own stresses, the arrival of the prosperous and well-armed Europeans, with their new institutions and diseases, was far from ablessing.

Introduction

Nevertheless, we may see these five hundred years as an interval between the great migrations of Europeans during the early Middle Ages, and their subsequent adventures after 1500 across the planet. During our period of study, some Europeans (and not others) began to triumph over poverty and backwardness. Of course, any competitive society produces losers as well as winners. The grim side to the expansion of Europe remains a persecuting culture rightly credited with the origins of modern racism and slavery. Yet, on the other side of the argument, a judicious mix of property rights, reliable ways to resolve disputes, and useful mediating institutions, such as guilds, and policies such as protectionism, among other causes, helped Europeans to astonish their near

and distant neighbors.

SELECT BIBLIOGRAPHY

Janet L. Abu-Lughod, Before European Hegemony: The World System A.D. 1250-1350. Oxford, 1989.

Daron Acemoglu and J. A. Robinson, Economic Origins ofDictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge, MA, 2005. Robert C. Allen, Tommy Bengtsson, and Martin Drake, editors. Living Standards in the Past: New Perspectives on Well-Being in Asia and Europe. Oxford, 2005. Nothing before the seventeenth century — the modernist stance on medieval economic history. Marc Bloch, Feudal Society. Translated by L. A. Manyon. Chicago, 1961. Carlo M. Cipolla, Before the Industrial Revolution: European Society and Economy 1000— 1700. 3rd ed. New York, 1994. Gregory Clark, A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World. Princeton, 2007.

Christopher Dyer, An Age of Transition? Economy and Society in England in the Later Middle Ages. Oxford, 2005. If only such a book existed for every place in Europe... John Hicks, A Theory of Economic History. Oxford, 1969. Henri Pirenne, Economic and Social History of Medieval Europe. Translated by I. E. Clegg. New York, 1937.

EUROPE AT THE MiLLENNIUM

O

START

OUR

ECONOMIC

AND

SOCIAL

HISTORY

OF

EUROPE

with the Tenth-Century Crisis, we must take a step or two back in order to make a good beginning. First, the ancient economy ended in the early medieval West but continued on in some fashion in the Byzantine

Empire in the East. Great movements of peoples occurred across early medieval Europe. Vast migrations brought Germanic- and Slavic-speaking people into new lands that they claimed as their own. Second, the rise of Islam affected the entire Mediterranean economy and society. Third, the Carolingian state experienced an economic revival whose strengths and problems define the

Tenth-Century Crisis. Let us start with the legacies of the ancient economy as they are currently understood in light of the latest research. In the Barbarian kingdoms of the early medieval West, the imperial economy, with its sophisticated tax structures, collapsed by 700. Nearly everywhere in Europe, kings were increasingly unable to draw on local resources for military purposes in the ways that the most effective late-Roman emperors were able

to do. This fact suggests that the survival of the Byzantine state depended on some continuity in fiscal structures and public income in the eastern Mediterranean. Later, Muslim caliphates would be able to draw on these legacies. In the period from 400 to 800, aristocracies became weaker everywhere except in Francia and in the Greek East. In most places, the ruling elites were poorer and less comfortable in their material circumstances than they had been in the fourth century. Peasants, who were farmers working under some form of duress, became more autonomous, and those who had originated as rural slaves in many places found servile status to be less well defined and more onerous. Weaker aristocracies changed their cultures and identities as Christianity set

Europe at the Millennium

down deeper roots and ethnic and linguistic differences became more pronounced after the universal empire's fall in the West. The Roman state's policies had concealed the regional differences that became more obvious in early medieval Europe as tribal kingdoms that were in a diverse patchwork replaced the old imperial provinces. As regionalism began to matter more, the pace of

the important social and economic changes varied. In some places, such as Britain, the collapse of the Roman Empire was so complete that it wiped out many aspects of the old regime, while in Italy, and especially in the Byzantine south, some of the fiscal and urban traditions endured. The end of the Roman Empire in the West was the beginning of an early medieval Europe. Increasingly defined by its church as Christendom, it was a fragile spiritual home surrounded by formidable pagans in northern Europe and Eastern Europe, and sophisticated Muslim societies and economies to the south and to the

east. The end of Roman imperial unity in the West and its partial survival in

the East had long-term consequences for population levels, styles of government, tax policies, coinage, and many other aspects of daily life. Although the collapse of the empire was a catastrophe for its emperors, their armies, and urban societies, for most people life continued largely unchanged. Christian-

ity's triumph over classical paganism endured, and its rules on marriage would gradually percolate through Barbarian society. Still, the Barbarians wrecked much of the empire's infrastructure and manufacturing or allowed it to decay. Lead, copper, and silver mining, which were common across Roman Europe, collapsed to prehistoric levels and did not surpass these levels until the early modern period. Comforts, such as good ceramics and roofing tiles, gradually disappeared, as did international trade in staples, such as_ olive oil and wine. Patterns of shipwrecks across time in the Mediterranean suggest that Roman levels of trade have not been reached again until comparatively modern times. Mass production and consumption, a feature of the Roman economy, did not

survive the barbarians. Their invasions were violent, and many people suffered and died, as in the Vandal sack of Rome in 455. Justinian’s efforts to reestablish Roman authority in the West in the 530s and 540s resulted in further destruction and waste of resources, which included his subjects. A great plague in 541-542 devastated large portions of the Greek East and Italy, compounding the social and economic problems arising from the empire's difficulties. A more-prosperous and better-nourished society might have withstood this new

12

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

epidemic more easily, but that argument was little comfort to the nearly half of the population that succumbed. Although the exact nature of this illness

remains unknown, its effects were severe, not to be repeated in Europe until the Big Death of the fourteenth century. Evidence for a sudden global climatic change beginning in the 530s is mounting. This period of cooling for Europe,

known as the Vandal Minimum, occurred from about 400 to 850, with the coldest temperatures around the year 700. Cold climates probably spelled harder

times for agriculture across Europe and, in some places, may be responsible for the low crop yields that seem typical in this period. The general picture of economy and society before the Carolingian period suggests that the material complexity and comfort levels for both ordinary people and aristocrats plummeted in the West. Nearly everywhere, both slavery and literacy rates declined, but these legacies of the ancient world continued to endure. New barbarian groups continued to arrive in Europe. The sixth century witnessed the arrival of the Lombards in Italy, and in 582 the Avars and the Slavs penetrated the Balkans and sacked Athens. In the Byzantine lands, economic decline also occurred, but a relatively strong government kept alive such necessities as manufactures for the army, a supply of small change for the market, and ships for trade. The best-documented early medieval society, Roman Egypt, seems to have experienced the fewest problems, and its economy survived intact the Arab conquest of 639-642. The first Arab siege of Constantinople in 674-678 shows how quickly Islam affected the geographer's Europe, but we, like the Byzantines, must not forget about the Roman, now Arabic, East and its continuing prosperity. At the other extreme end of the early medieval world, Ireland, never Romanized, came over to its faith and escaped the waves of invasions that Britain experienced. Ireland's prosperous kingdoms preserved classical and early Christian learning. Historians have written for centuries about the fall of Rome, and more recent labels, such as “The End of Ancient Civilization," “The Transformation of the Roman World," "The Rise of Christendom," or even "The Birth of Europe," have become sound bites summarizing big arguments about this period. By 700, in a barbarized West, land and booty remained the principal forms of wealth for those emerging aristocracies and peasantries that the Carolingian kings forged into a temporarily cohesive state. What Georges Duby called “an economy of gift and pillage” partially explains a system of exchange where status and violence had at least as much to do with the ways goods circulated as did markets and local bartering.

Europe at the Millennium

CAROLINGIAN ECONOMY AND SOCIETY A quick survey of European society and economy in 800 in the heyday of Charlemagne's reign helps establish a baseline from which to measure the crises his successors faced at the end of the ninth century and through the tenth century. This highly selective summary can only skim the surface of a big subject, but let us begin with Figure 1.1 and some large generalizations. The vast extent of forests nearly everywhere except the drier Mediterranean south, where tracts of scrub prevailed, suggests that as the amount of land under cultivation had contracted. In what was once Roman Europe, rural population levels were certainly lower. Cities had shrunk, and some had virtually disappeared. The largest city in Western Europe, Rome, was perhaps at 5 percent of its population at its ancient height, while the greatest city in Europe by far remained Constantinople, which was a bit smaller than the Roman city but was still a giant compared to the settlements to the west. Surveying the regions from west to east, we first find the great exception

to decay in the west, a prosperous, urbanized Muslim Spain still connected by

North African trade routes to the heartlands of Islam in the eastern Mediterranean. A few small Christian kingdoms in northern Iberia looked north to the Carolingian Empire for support. The most important non-Carolingian sphere in the West was the British isles — Anglo-Saxon kingdoms connected byastill

relatively peaceful and vibrant trading network in the northern Atlantic and in the North and Baltic Seas, where pagan Norwegians, Danes, and Swedes traded

and occasionally raided their neighbors. Italy was fractured into a northern area incorporated into Charlemagne’s empire while, in the south, independent Lombard and Byzantine areas existed. The central fact here is the absolute decline

of Italy, which was now cut off from North African and above all Egyptian grain and other items of trade. Even so, Italy still was, apart from Muslim Spain, the most urbanized place in the west. Between those areas of Europe controlled by the Carolingians and the Byzantines, various largely pagan tribal groups

of Germanic- and Slavic-speaking peoples, along with the Avars from Central Asia, controlled the trade routes through their territories along the Danube and points east. Whatever unity Rome had once imposed on parts of Europe

had clearly disappeared. In those areas that were never Romanized, such as Denmark, there is no reason to assume that the population had declined or

that such comforts that had existed were gone. The movement of peoples from northern to southern Europe instead suggests that depopulation and riches in

14

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

Figure 1.1. Charlemagne’s empire in 814 (from Rosamond McKitterick, Charlemagne: The Formation of a European Identity. Cambridge 2008, p. 101).

Europe at the Millennium

the south had opened up niches for the wandering tribes and settlers to inhabit. A sophisticated market economy existed in Muslim Spain and in the Byzantine East, with some intrepid merchants, pilgrims, and travelers connecting these two systems. In Francia, as we will see, the land was the primary source of wealth. In less-organized areas of Europe, goods circulated in an economy of gift and pillage that was at least as important as the fragile worlds of buying

and selling. The monotheists (the Christians and Muslims) were clearly prevailing, and therefore, certain features of these faiths were becoming more pervasive. In the Christian lands, which were really a federation of regional faiths tied together by the Latin language and Mass, the Benedictine rule for monks and nuns, and the activities of missionaries, some basic social rules were emerging. The teachings of the faith were slowly establishing a nondivorcing, monogamous family life as the rule. Charlemagne reinforced this basic unit of society by requiring that everyone he controlled have godparents, which augmented the family when it proved unable, for whatever reason, to protect its children. He also tried to require paying a tithe to the church, and this custom as well as a constant stream of donations in exchange for prayers and the hope of salvation increasingly made the Church the greatest landowner across Europe. Christian teachings required that a proper burial should take place in consecrated ground, so cremation was disappearing and grave goods were an increasingly rare relic

of pagan values. In Muslim Europe, Arabic provided a linguistic commonality for what was

still a federation as these Muslims stood apart from the caliphate in Baghdad. As much of Spain became increasingly Muslim in faith, burial practices shifted to simpler and speedier burials. Some wealthy men, who were able to support up to four wives, practiced polygamy. But the similarities in social practices

among the monotheists, including the Jews, who were the most numerous in the south and above all in Muslim Spain (but still a tiny minority even there), are striking. In matters of diet, the Jews and Muslims denied themselves, for example, the pig herds that were such a common feature in Christian Europe, while the Christians needed fish on certain days and times of the year. Different specifics mask a common

belief that rules about food help define a people.

Monotheistic, literate societies have obvious common features, such as making wills, something that is not shared by the world evoked in the poem Beowulf or the by great ship tombs of northern Europe. Women

remained socially

subordinate among these monotheists because both of these faiths sanctioned

16

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

such treatment, admittedly in slightly different styles. Christians had convents of religious women living outside secular society; Muslim women might initiate divorce. This is not to say that the polytheists in the north created paradises for women, but in a world like Sweden, with goddesses and a gender division

of labor that left high-status tasks, such as brewing. in the hands of women, a rougher equality between the sexes may have prevailed. Both polytheists and monotheists had strong ideas about honor, and much of their literature concerned admirable defenses of it in the face of monsters, infidels, and other threats in the world. No group had a monopoly on honor; for what society would claim not to value a reputation for valor and integrity? All of the societies in Europe cherished honor. The lords, or the aristocracy,

were the warrior classes who controlled the land, usually claimed to have the

most honor because their style of life was in itself the definition of honor — was not their sword mightier and more dignified than the hoe of the peasant? Men claimed the right to define female honor and defend or violate it at their whim. The vast majority of the population, who were the tillers of the soil and the herders, found their honor invested in family life, village traditions, and the minute gradations with which the Carolingians in particular defined personal liberty. Slaves were by definition both without honor and debased items of commerce, who were either captured or born into their lowest status. Slavery was the great common theme — asocial and economic fact of life in all parts of Europe, and a major staple of the commerce that still existed among the regions. In most spoken languages, slave hunting in the southern Slavic lands gave an ethnic label to human chattel — the slave. Trafficking in people was one of the important links between Europe, North Africa, and the Middle East, and no society had any scruples or sense of guilt about dealing in captives and

born slaves who were more valuable than wood or even fur. One of the most distinctive features to emerge from the Carolingian documents is the manor. This form of agricultural estate stands at the end of a long tradition of organizing rural society to benefit the aristocratic or ecclesiastical landowners. What is new about the Carolingian manor, so far as we can tell, is that a few sources, the polyptychs, served individual lords, in the surviving sources usually abbots, as catalogs of their estates, broken for convenience into manors. An individual manor was a big farm that was usually divided into two parts. The lord, a monastery or Charlemagne himself, reserved part of the land, the demesne, and the local productive assets for his own benefit and use, to be run by a steward or estate manager. Records survive because absentee landlords,

Europe at the Millennium

such as the king ora bishop or a religious community, needed produce — grains, meat, vegetables, cloth, wine, whatever the particular estate could provide — in order to move these supplies to where they were needed. Or, a peripatetic ruler might move from estate to estate and live off the surpluses generated by his part of the enterprise. The other part of the manor consisted of tenants — peasant laborers who held land and other assets on a bewildering array of terms ranging from true rents paid by people who were personally free to work the servile lands clearly assigned to people originating as slaves and who, in some cases, were still called slaves. Other tenants, the lidi, or half-free, occupied a nebulous

status between the slaves and the free peasants and may have originated from mixed marriages between these groups.

The main source for this rural world was the polyptych — the most famous is the one prepared for Abbot Irminon between 825-829 for the estates of the great abbey of St. Germain des Prés near Paris. Three other documents of this type survive from other church estates, and a few scraps of information from Italian lands are also available. In addition, we have a famous capitulary or royal edict, De Villis, which Charlemagne issued to his estate managers about 800. This document presents an ideal portrait of what a utopian manor might have supplied to its owner, from the horses and fishponds to fruits and nuts, in addition to the staples in grains and firewood that the tenants were obligated to cart to wherever the ruler or religious community needed them.

Archaeology has also helped illuminate village buildings and the ways fields were laid out and cultivated. The study of place names has enabled scholars to determine types of rural settlements and even speculate about the ethnicities of their original inhabitants. On these slender sources, historians have been trying for more than a century to establish the basic features of the Carolingian rural economy, the engine upon which everything else, from war to trade, depended. The main debate has always centered on the manor — how pervasive was this institution, and how reliable are the statistics that can be extracted from the polyptychs? In brief, such numbers are worth scrutinizing for what they reveal and what they hide. Also, it would be an immense error to assume that all of Europe was an orderly patchwork of manors, even if Charlemagne and the

great landowners may have dreamed of such a world and the steady stream of wealth it would have provided. In the real world of violence and oral testimony that depended on village memories and traditions, much farming land remained outside this system and, in some places, peasants were comparatively free and

worked their lands mainly for their own benefit. In vast tracts of Europe outside

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

Charlemagne’s realms, the forests and the coastlines offered livings to many

people who probably thought the manors were traps. Without records like polyptychs, we can only guess about the rural scene in most places, but the biggest mistake would be to assume that manors were everywhere. Whatever

surpluses the Carolingian economy was able to generate flowed to the powerful from the manors they possessed rather than to the taxes that were so hard to collect.

POPULATION The bipartite structure of the classic Carolingian manor reveals a domain (demesne) reserved for the landowner to exploit and other lands held by family units. These tenants originally occupied an amount of land sufficient to support the family — a recognizable group of parents and children. Usually delineated sometime in the past, this tenancy or farm, referred to by the continental

sources most often as a mansus or, when the reference is found in England, as a hide, originally sufficed to keep the family alive and busy but produced enough surplus to pay rents and other services owed to the landlords. Some of these landholding patterns date back to late antiquity. Even in the ninth century, memories of the ancient Roman colonate (a system of rural settlement)

endured as the relatively free status of the coloni and their lands testify. When the polyptychs are scrutinized, they can yield some statistics about the families occupying lands on the big manors. Once again, the sources are not good and the results are not necessarily applicable across Europe, but again the numbers are worth considering for what they reveal about rural life.

The survey of the tenants on the manors of St. German des Prés showed, after correcting for various problems, a sex ratio of 119 men for every 100 women, and the wealth of the household did not change this rough relationship. In fact, the numbers of men became more pronounced in the lower status households where women seemed to be in even shorter supply. This sex ratio for the dependant peasants has puzzled social historians, and several hypotheses have

been suggested to explain it. Some technical problems about the sources, which do not always note the sex of children, may undercount women. The cloth workshops on the manor, especially those controlled by powerful lords interested in collecting women to put to work at this trade, may have absorbed many workers and removed these women from the pool of ordinary tenants. There is no evidence that infanticide of baby girls accounts for the sex ratio,

Europe at the Millennium

or indeed any reason to believe that any such practice would have males over the females anyway. In addition to speculating about women, it is also useful to ask about the extra men, many of sources tell us, were slaves. This type of source captures the male

favored the the missing whom, the slaves who

outnumbered the women who may have been living and working elsewhere. At the top of society, the households of the great collected women as economic assets, workers, and objects of prestige, and this admittedly demeaning practice would also skew the sex ratios in the countryside. The average household size was 5.76 persons, and the median was 6. As usual across time and distance in medieval Europe, the richer households, those that controlled more land, contained more people. These households were generally flat in generational terms because grandparents were rare, which indicated comparatively low life expectancies or a delayed age at first marriage. These competing explanations will require a closer look because they will result in two quite different views of the Carolingian economy's vibrancy. Households frequently contained a brother or sister of one of the spouses as well as other hard-to-classify members, so this view of the household argues that

the number of children present would barely suffice to replace the parents. All scholars assume high levels of infant and childhood mortality, as a rude index, perhaps at a mortality level of 50 percent by about age ten. After that point, the survivors had better chances for longer lives. Households replenished their ranks by people transferring in as other families collapsed from death or illness. Hence, the Carolingian family appears relatively flat in age but is extended laterally to the nearest kin of the spouses. Records from the estates of the monastery of St. Victor in Marseilles have been used to generate credible figures suggesting that families in Provence

contained between 2.9 and 3.1 children. This snapshot of the population, already reflecting the course of childhood deaths, could provide a reasonable basis for long-term demographic growth of perhaps 1 percent a year, which led to the population doubling every century — but this was not an example of Malthusian steady-state population. Lands available for clearing would have been able to sustain this growth, and pollen evidence from this period shows changes in plant species that are typical of farming and forest clearing activities. No widespread epidemics or famines would have provided the kind of external, positive Malthusian check on this type of population growth. It certainly makes sense that in an economy driven by agriculture, more farmers and lands under cultivation could have fostered economic growth. The overall

20

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

ambitious programs of early Carolingian rulers, as well as their successful wars of conquest, argue for the idea that their economic base was growing. The kind of productive manorial enterprise the capitulary De Villis describes also presumes patient increases in both the scale and scope of farming in new crops and more diverse products. The most plausible Malthusian preventative check on population growth was to delay the age of first marriage. Child bearing in this society reflected familial notions of honor, and Christian values frowned on illegitimacy except among slaves and ruling elites. The dowry system, which required that the parents of daughters to transfer wealth to their prospective sons-in-law, may have accounted for a drifting up of the age of first marriage for men who needed to compete and establish themselves before seeming worthy of a bride and a dowry. Often, this marriage pattern resulted in lower ages of first marriage for women who were married off as early and as cheaply as possible. In fact, the evidence from the polyptychs shows, from the relatively high and equal numbers of bachelor men and women (and widowers and widows), that spouses were roughly similar in ages and that they were marrying in the later rather than in their early twenties. This early medieval marriage pattern, which was characteristic of a peasant society and was caused by the dowry system or some other factors, would have acted as a break on rapid population growth. In turn, this preventive check worked to increase per capita wealth — a temptation to have more children and reverse the improvements! Much of the good land across Europe, from Ireland to the forests where the Slavic peoples of the East lived, escaped the manorial regime. Older patterns of individual farmsteads prevailed in northwest Europe. Migratory patterns of slash-and-burn agriculture were typical in the thinly populated areas along the Danube and Dniester rivers. But in the largest empire in the Christian West, manors supported the emperor, many of his soldiers, and much of his reformed Church.

TECHNOLOGY Connections among technologies and social forms and economic changes have been investigated for early medieval Europe. The task here is to summarize briefly the Carolingian technological platform from which subsequent advancements took off, if we accept this approach to innovation. Two issues deserve notice. First, European societies had open horizons from the beginning with respect to borrowing technologies from neighboring cultures or invaders and

Europe at the Millennium

quickly adapting them for local uses. At first, drawing on classical technologies that admittedly were stagnant whether asa result of slavery, limited education, or some other factors, Europe became an adept second adapter of other peoples’ inventions. Second, written sources alone are poor witnesses to technology, so we must keep before our eyes the evidence from art and archeology throughout the Middle Ages.

Whatever its origin, the stirrup, by the ninth century, had spread across Europe and had made possible the heavy cavalry so characteristic of medieval culture, what Lynn White succinctly called the “union of man and horse." Supporting these mounted warriors became essential for anyone wishing to

exercise military power. Because land and its uses remained the basic form of wealth, we will not be surprised to see that the needs of the man on horseback profoundly shaped rural society. Again, in rough terms, the ninth century also witnessed the widespread adoption of the nailed horseshoe, vital for keeping

the horse on its hooves. At the same time the horse collar, which probably came west with the Turks, enabled another union, this one more humble but even more significant, between horse and plough. The heavy plough, usually wheeled, made possible the cultivation of dense clay soil in northern Europe. Slavic tribes perhaps brought this innovation to the west, and they may have borrowed it from some peoples farther east. A scratch plough, ancient technology suited to the dry Mediterranean lands, still served well there. Vast tracts of arable from England to Russia required a better tool, that is, one capable of digging a deeper furrow and turning over the soil. This deeper plowing helped to bring nutrients back up to crop roots and also made draining fields easier in the rainy north. Teams of horses or oxen efficiently harnessed to heavy plows made agriculture possible in areas where the Mediterranean plough was ineffective. Plow teams and peasants were another combination that affected social forms. Peasants often needed to share animals to put together teams.

Long strips of land, for example, as shown in the origin of the furlong at 220 yards in England, made more sense because it was as long as these animals could pull together in one direction, and such plough teams were not as easily turned around as the simpler scratch plough was. Of course, the slower but steady oxen were still an important way to apply animal power to the need to feed people from the land. Horses and oxen also needed to eat. The availability of pasture and oats affected which animal would predominate in farming. Feeding these animals through the winter was always a problem and in parts of northern Europe they could not endure the bitter cold so they needed to be stalled.

Dil

22

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

Making coins and dies, the métier of the minter, is another ancient technological legacy of the Middle Ages. The big changes before Charlemagne had affected money and its uses. In the West, indigenous gold coinage had virtually disappeared, and the money supply consisted of silver pennies or deniers that were minted in vast numbers at mining sites or trading emporia, such as Frisian Dorestad and Flemish Quentovic. Enough silver pennies, in the millions, existed to sustain exchanges and tended to collect where they were needed along the trade routes and where they were hoarded and buried, as in the Viking north. Frisian silver ended up in England, parts of Scandinavia, and Rus long before any local coins were made. Francia was the main source for

silver in the West. A basic standard had developed by which 240 pennies were struck per pound of silver. This standard naturally moved around according to silver supplies and the desire of those making the coins to stretch those supplies and their profits by making baser coins. A multiple of the penny by a factor of twelve, the shilling, also called the “sou" or “solidus,” was a useful money of account — not yet a coin — but a way to keep track of all these pennies, as was

the pound, livre, and lira. Charlemagne's reforms resulted in identical penny coins throughout his empire. This made possible by having the dies cut at a central point and distributed to the many mints across his realms. The Carolingian penny became a standard of exchange. This penny was a broad and thin hammered flan, a fragile and, at the beginning, a high-value coin that did not solve the problem of small change unless it was cut into pieces, as it apparently was.

By 800 in the Byzantine East, the gold nomismata had replaced the late Roman gold solidus and the empire also had an abundant supply of copper coins to facilitate market purchases. The Arabs had basically maintained the monetary systems they found in place. They had adopted the Persian silver dirham (a broad, thin coin probably serving as a model for the western penny) in the extreme eastern and western reaches of their conquests, where silver supplies in Iran and Spain, for example, made this possible. In the Arab heartlands, Spain, and Egypt, close to African gold supplies, the gold dinar was standard, but silver dirhams and even copper small change also circulated. Hence, the

monetary map of Europe and the Middle East has a golden core stretching from the southern Balkans and Anatolia south through Syria and Egypt, with silver coinages prevailing in the Persian East and the Anglo-Saxon and Frankish West. Even in these places the occasional gold coin was minted, perhaps as a prestige item that imitated the more common Byzantine and Arab money.

Europe at the Millennium

The social function of coins is a much more complex subject to be addressed shortly in our look at trade. Monetary sums measured compensation for crimes in the form of wergild. Whether actual coins changed hands remains unclear, because bartering and payments in kind often replaced cash. Even on the estates of St. Germain des Prés, in the Carolingian heartland and one of the most moneterized areas of Europe, three-quarters of rents were paid in kind, we assume for the convenience of tenants and the monks. During the ninth century, as silver and gold coins moved about Europe in the hands of raiders, traders, refugees, and pilgrims, a rough ratio developed between gold and silver in the monetary regions. In the Carolingian and Anglo-Saxon West, where gold was not mined and hence was rare and most precious, the ratio between gold and silver was 12:1. Among the Byzantines, who still controlled some mines and

preferred gold to silver, the ratio was 7:1. For the Arabs, the elite traders from Spain to the Indian Ocean, dinars and dirhams coined from readily available gold and silver were usually about 10:1 in value. Silver and gold came out of the ground where they were, but they flowed in the direction of trade balances and cultural preferences. Astute traders understood enough about arbitrage to send metals where they enjoyed the greatest purchasing power.

TRADE Under eighth Rome. power

an effective ruler like Charlemagne, the Carolingian state from the late century experienced levels of economic prosperity not seen since late The agrarian regime, better technologies for farming and harnessing the of animals and moving water, a sound coinage, and successful warfare all

worked together, in a favorable climate to produce the modest food surpluses sustaining demographic increases. Charlemagne extended Frankish authority deep into Italy and east of the Rhine, connecting Francia via roads and the sea with its prosperous neighbors. For sea power, the Franks could now depend on Frisian ships in the north and Venetian and Pisan ships in the south to augment and sustain their communications, trade, and travel across the great sailing trunk routes to the north and south. The map Figure 1.1 shows how the

Carolingians might use their rivers and roads to facilitate trade between these two great regions and profit by these exchanges. What we now need to explore is the difficult subject of trade from the late eighth to the early tenth century. A brief word on economic theory is relevant here, because in the absence of reliable statistics, all we have to analyze are impressions and theory, which is

3

24

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000—1500

often a misleading combination. The classic factors of production are capital and labor. In the Western world, the main capital asset was good agricultural lands, partly mobilized by the manorial regime. Peasants extracted from the soils of Europe the food and products necessary to sustain Carolingian economy and society. This enclosed system seems a physiocrat's paradise — a productive, growing agricultural society that benefits from bursts of productivity resulting from bringing fresh, fertile land under better plows. Lay and church landlords at the top of the system envisioned a maximum of self-sufficiency, where manors would produce what they were best at: producing in some regions wine or cloth, and elsewhere wheat or horses. A modest internal trade would smooth out these comparative advantages and lead toa better life for all. Charlemagne would not have expressed his goals in these terms, but reading his legislation certainly leaves the impression that self-sufficiency at all levels was the goal. Even his armies were to draw on the manorial surpluses to wage successful wars and bring more resources under his control, just as the monks and nuns would pray more efficiently as they specialized in the work of God and left farming to the tenants. Ideally this world could thrive on its internal resources, needing nothing from elsewhere. As nearby as Constantinople or Muslim Spain, fine things like steel swords, silk, spices, and drugs hinted at a world of comfort far superior to what even the emperor enjoyed in Aachen. Hence, trade was possible and in theory would extend the system of comparative advantage across the wider horizons of the world beyond the Carolingian frontiers. Transaction costs mattered in a world where being a merchant was dangerous, and all travel was difficult and expensive. Traders needed something to sell, and people remained the most profitable and easiest to transport item of commerce in Europe. Economic theory argues for the rise of trade and the enjoyment of its inevitable benefits, but it does not explain why trade will begin to matter more in a particular place in a moment of time. Trade’s enduring appeal as both a panacea and a topic for study have made it a kind of proxy for all of economic history, which at times becomes simply the story of trade and complex maps with a lot of arrows. Far from privileging trade, let us remember how well this society was doing without it, how social values predisposed people to believe that trade was perhaps sinful, and what other moral issues might arise from dealings with the Byzantines and Muslims. In the Frankish world, trade appears to recover in the period 750-775 and remains good until the end of the ninth century, when, as we will see, the long Tenth-Century Crisis begins. Sometimes trade with the Muslim lands was

Europe at the Millennium

more important while at other times the land and sea routes to Byzantium displayed the most activity. These assumptions about trade accord well with the evidence on agricultural productivity and favorable climate — the main point is that the beginning of the European economy's long-term boom is in the ninth century rather than in the eleventh or twelfth centuries. Michael McCormick has made this argument by compiling a great deal of information about travel and communications in this period by arguing that evidence for these activities is also a reasonable proxy for commercial relations. After all, pilgrims, ambassadors, and even relics could not cross vast distances unless regular trade routes enabled goods as well as people to move. One of the most famous travelers was the elephant Abu Abbas, who made the long journey from

the realm of Haroun al-Rashid across North Africa, and then by sea to Pisa and then over the Alps to Charlemagne’s court at Aachen. This much-traveled Indian marvel ended his days at Haithabu in Denmark in about 806 while campaigning against the pagan Danes. The ability to move this elephant by ship presumes the existence of ports, shipping facilities, experienced mariners, and ways of communicating that our meager sources do not always illuminate. In similar ways, lost coins along trading routes and the little tags documenting the origins of relics can help demonstrate that both old and new sea and land routes of communication were open in the ninth century.

A few areas seem particularly vital to this trading system — for the Franks the

Frisian coast, elsewhere the Tyrrhenian Sea stretching down from Liguria and Pisa to Campania and Amalfi, and Venice with its commanding position at the head of the Adriatic and close ties to Byzantium. Byzantine trading networks centered on the Aegean and its route to the Black Sea and retained a good knowledge of the sea lanes and ship building. Muslim trading dominated the southern shores of the Mediterranean, and their slow conquest of Sicily (827— 902) and Crete (823-828) strengthened their grip on these sea lanes. Traders remain the most elusive travelers, not leaving specific records like those of the pilgrims and ambassadors. Still, Syrians and Jews remained specialists whose knowledge of languages, routes, and products gave them an edge over more recent entrants into the trading networks. The narrative sources may well exaggerate their significance in the West, because as strangers they were more likely to be noticed, mentioned, and occasionally despoiled. McCormick has argued that the slave trade drove Carolingian commerce, and that Christian Europe was unable to keep up with the demand for slaves in the Muslim and Byzantine lands (see Figure 1.2). Charlemagne’s conquests in Saxony and down the upper Danube yielded fresh supplies of slaves.

Oy

sunsiy ] “7

Apiey

[PAIIpow PARIS

apes] dew) Aq

ued

‘Jasiaqnesy AjISIoAIUT) Jo sesuey

D1Yyde1so71e7) SIDIAIIS

‘(

26

Europe at the Millennium

Thousands of slaves traveled as captive goods south and east along the sea and the Dniester and Volga rivers, toward Muslim Spain and markets in distant Cairo and Baghdad. The eastern shore of the Adriatic was indeed becoming a “slave coast’ where the capturing of people into slavery was a lucrative business for all concerned. Documents of practice, contracts, recording the activities of merchants do not exist. Archaeology for this period has not yielded the kinds of finds in ceramics than can sustain an argument about trade in commodities, such as oil or wine. The narrative sources tend to preserve notices of slaves, sometimes in the thousands, because the movements of slaves struck witnesses

as memorable. Certainly no society — Carolingian, Byzantine, or Muslim — tried to stop the slave trade in the name of morality. The demand for slaves in the more prosperous Eastern economies does seem to have exceeded supply. What

has not been demonstrated is that the income from this trade benefited the Carolingian economy or was put to any practical use. Much of the income disappeared into luxuries for a few, coin hoards, or the rapacious hands of raiders, such as the Vikings. Charlemagne's own income from booty seems to

have been ploughed back into provisioning his war machine or his modest building program. The point here, as seems to be usually the case in societies

that supply human capital to invested but rather consumed. like silks, spices, and steel for monasteries simply signaled to

other economies, is that the income was not Gathering of cash and valuable commodities weapons (not plows) in nascent emporia and the pillagers where they might find the richest

takings. Carolingian and Anglo-Saxon societies did invest in the first round of stone parish churches scattered across the countryside in villages where people lived and where their numbers where increasing. Technologies for building in stone

were not on a par with Roman accomplishments. None of the technological advances associated with this period affected in any discernible way craft manufacturing — which remained at low ebb. What cities as existed in the Christian West, apart from the interesting and poorly documented trading centers, such as Quentovic and Pisa, remained tiny and were not notable for artisan manufactures in easily tracked staples, such as pottery. Scriptoria were busy transferring what remained of the classical inheritance from paper to parchment, but we have no way of knowing what effect, if any, this accomplishment had on literacy rates. Taking into account all the pluses and minuses to the Carolingian economy, most observers now conclude that Charlemagne and his successors presided over a period of growth that began in the late eighth century. A

Die

28

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

general crisis in the Tenth Century certainly challenged this economic and

social progress. This problem is the beginning of our more intense study of the economic and social history of medieval Europe.

THE TENTH-CENTURY CRISIS One key fact about this crisis is that it concerned Western Europe while its

neighbors were either flourishing or preying on the West. Despite a Muslim sack of Thessalonike in 904 and problems with the Bulgars at the beginning and end of the tenth century, this was a good century for Byzantium. The empire was expanding in the Balkans and Asia Minor, Crete was retaken in 961, and missionaries converted the Bulgarians (864), Serbs (867-874), and the peoples of Rus (989) to Orthodox Christianity. These impressive accomplishments rested on the fiscal ability of the empire to raise taxes for armies and fleets, and these taxes largely came from hard-working peasants on the land. Even when under pressure, this remnant of the ancient world preserved enough ofa state to marshal resources for defense. Slavic peoples from the Baltic to the Black Seas, joined by Scandinavian raiders and traders, also established trading networks along the Volga and other river systems of Eastern Europe. Merchants from Rus brought furs and other goods south to Constantinople. Trading posts like Staraia Lagoda near modern St. Petersburg facilitated these exchanges, which initially relied for

exchange on Muslim silver, and were replaced by German pennies during the later tenth century. By the end of the tenth century, the rulers of Bohemia were minting their own coins. Elsewhere in the Slavic East, pieces of iron, so valuable for tools and weapons, also served as a medium of exchange. Without cities or monasteries to’be destroyed, and with much of Eastern Europe still cultivated by migrating peasants farming new lands until they were exhausted, the crisis was less severe here. Also, social fusion among Scandinavians and Russians and Ukrainians, and the Bulgars and southern Slavs, created some collaboration rather than simple mayhem.

For the Muslim world the crisis was not the result of external invasions and meant the political decay of the Abbasid caliphate in Baghdad and the subsequent fragmenting of the world of Islam. The emergence of a strong Fatimid dynasty in Tunis that conquered Egypt (969-1 171) meant that all of the southern Mediterranean was united under a powerful Shi'te rule of amajority Sunni population. In turn, this aggressive state in the southern Mediterranean

Europe at the Millennium

fostered, as we will see, a renewed wave of attacks above all on Italy. The other consequence of the conquest of Egypt is the famous Geniza records, a burst of information about the economy and society of the Muslim Mediterranean world in the tenth and eleventh centuries. These documents, that also illuminate trade with Europe and in the Indian Ocean, provide a wealth of details unavailable elsewhere. The activities of the Jewish Maghrebi traders from North Africa

have become an important touchstone for understanding the different paths to economic development in the region. For the moment, all of this is in the future, but for Egypt the Tenth-Century Crisis was an unusual conquest from the West that incorporated the most populous and probably wealthiest part of the Mediterranean into the Fatimid Empire challenging for control of the sea. For the Carolingian state, the crisis had internal and external causes. Charlemagne was lucky to be survived by one legitimate son, Louis, who became emperor in 814. The Frankish custom of partible inheritance meant that his three sons expected shares of the empire, and the political story of the ninth and tenth centuries is the gradual decay of the dynasty's power. Even though occasionally an able ruler, such as Charles the Bald, reassembled nearly all of the inheritance, the empire eventually fractured into an eastern German kingdom and a western Frankish/French one, with other kingdoms in Italy and Provence also surfacing. The relics of the famous Middle Kingdom stretching from Frisia on the North Sea down the Rhine into the Alps and beyond to the East and South became places where a state or empire ceased to have

any real meaning. The complicated political story here can be reduced to a few important economic consequences.

Once again the right to coin money

slipped away from a central authority and numerous mints, producing debased silver pennies, appeared wherever anyone, lord or bishop, took the initiative. The public authority the effective Carolingian rulers had exercised through

the counts was frequently usurped by these people or other strong men on the local scene. The great manors that had taken the place of direct taxes as a way for kings and emperors to fund war slipped out of royal control and were an increasing anachronism in an era of localism and violence. All these

problems were more serious on the continent than in Anglo-Saxon England, where stronger monarchs were still able to raise revenues and men for defense, but there the external problems were, if anything, even more severe. The renewed wave of attacks from all directions defines the crisis of the long tenth century (see Figure 1.3). The raiders must have found something

29

30

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

—> Viking invasions => *2*3 Yije 7401

Hungarian invasions Muslim invasions Niking settlements Viking lands

&@

Hungarian lands Muslim states

Figure 1.3. Tenth-Century Invasions (map by Keith A. French Grauberger, University of Kansas Cartographic Services),

and Darin

Europe at the Millennium

attractive about this world and its goods — the external threats are evidence of an increasing level of prosperity from at least the ninth century. Apart from a few tiny cities and wealthy monasteries and churches, the wealth that these lands contained consisted of what the peasants had assembled through decades of hard work. Raiders passing through could sweep up livestock and captives and seize food supplies and whatever modest possessions came their way. Literate monks, of course, saw the threat to their institutions as paramount and so they might have decided to flee into the interior with their treasures in search of safety. Peasants stayed where they were, suffered, and endured. Raiders could not take their lands with them and only posed a permanent problem, when as in the case of the Danes in England, Scandinavians in Rus, and the Vikings in Normandy, they decided to stay and occupy land for themselves. Even this settlement substituted one warrior/farmer for another. The story the map tells looks

terrible but this wave of invasions only challenged an agrarian society rather than destroying a sophisticated urban-fiscal network like the Roman Empire. These movements and migrations of peoples were the penultimate touches to

making a Europe of recognizable peoples. After 1000, only a few new arrivals, the Tartars and Turks, changed the basic medieval ethnography of Europe. To be in the path of the Magyars, Vikings, or Muslim raiders cannot have been a pleasant experience, and occasional chaos on the local level was bad for farming and hence the economy as a whole. These disturbances doubtless drove up the death rates for peasants living on the margins of subsistence. Western Europe, with its long sea coasts, many navigable rivers, and expansive plains open to the East, was difficult to defend and ideal to raid. The Magyars (later called Hungarians) were originally an Asiatic steppe people, the latest arrivals from Central Asia drifting west in search of pasture and opportunities. After helping the Byzantines defeat the Bulgarians, the Magyars found themselves to be unwelcome and pushed to the west, so they found a base in their permanent home, the Hungarian plain. Arriving there around 899, they quickly launched raiding expeditions of amazing distances, deep into Italy and the Carolingian heartland — as far south as Otranto, capturing Pavia and repeatedly threatening

Rome, and by 917 they were across the Rhine. The Magyars killed many people, sold the survivors into slavery, and sacked monasteries. Otto the Great king of

Germany defeated them at the Lech in 955 and by 1000 they were confined to their own kingdom and converted to Christianity. In this case, as awful as the

raids were, we will be looking to how a king in Germany was able to mobilize resources to defeat and contain them. These Hungarians must have caused

Si

32

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

terrible problems for the Slavic peoples in the East, but the contemporary sources are not clear on the effects on these poorer societies. The new people now effectively occupied the great fertile plain of the Middle Danube, which separated the Poles and other Slavs in the north from their linguistic cousins, the southern Slavs. Muslims from their bases on Sicily and in Iberia renewed attacks on Christian

states. In Italy, the challenge was on the mainland, the Byzantines lost Bari in 840, Rome was sacked in 846, and the great Benedictine abbey at Monte Cassino was destroyed in 881. The surviving monks fled with their books to Rome. Raiders from Muslim Spain established a permanent base at Freinet (near

modern Cannes) around 890 where they would remain until 973. Among their

spectacular feats was the capture of the abbot of Cluny in 972, whom they held for ransom. Perched on the coast, generations of these robbers interrupted the cabotage trade (for a short distance) along the Riviera and controlled the main road south to Rome and the Alpine passes to their rear. Supplied by sea, these Muslims prospered because there was no credible Christian navy in the region and this area of the Mediterranean was too far from Byzantine areas for the Greeks to make a difference here. Muslim raiders from North Africa so thoroughly sacked Genoa in 934/935 that this little port took decades to recover. They repeatedly devastated other parts of the Mediterranean coast from the Pyrenees to Naples, as well as Sardinia and Corsica. In Iberia where a frontier of sorts existed between the Christian lands, such as Catalonia and the Muslim kingdoms to the south, a more regular form of warfare protected Europe north of the mountains from raids by land. But the sea routes remained open, and into the eleventh century Muslim sea power from Balearic Islands and Tortosa held the upper hand. Above all, the threat from the Northmen began in the early ninth century and continued on past the pacification of the Magyars and the eventual taking of the offensive against the Muslims in the eleventh century. The story of the northern raids is a vast one as the Norwegians, Swedes, and Danes swept south in every direction, pillaging Ireland, England, the coast of Francia, and down the river systems of Rus into the Black Sea to trouble the Byzantines. Vikings, expert sea travelers, entered the Mediterranean from both ends during the ninth century. In some places, such as Normandy in Francia and the Danelaw in England, the raiders settled down and occupied lands. Elsewhere, the raiders remained a seasonal menace, appearing along the coasts or up rivers deep into Muslim, Christian, and Byzantine territories. Surely the ability of Scandinavia

Europe at the Millennium

to sustain such raids and export so many people, even to distant Iceland, testifies to demographic growth, shipbuilding skills, and an ethos for adventure that brought them as far as Greenland, Seville, and Constantinople. Their settlements changed the destinies of peoples in Francia and Rus. We must take all these troubles from the Magyars, Muslims, and Vikings as a given, and also leave aside the motives internal to these peoples that put them on the move. What we must focus on is their victims and their responses to these challenges,

for in these challenges many social and economic historians have found the origins of a feudal and commercial revolution and indeed the birth of Europe. The crisis had some lasting effects on the old and durable geographic regions of the Roman Empire. North Africa, Cyrenaica, and Egypt were under a Fatimid rule that contested the control of Syria and Palestine. The Byzantine heartland remained in control of Asia Minor and the southern Balkans, with toeholds still in Italy. Increasingly over the early tenth century the old Lombard and the Frankish kingdom of Italy meant nothing and local strongmen prevailed. Venice's unique geography and fleet spared it the waves of raiders, and this undoubtedly helped secure its trading center an even more important role in the aftermath of the crisis. Iberia remained divided with most of it under Muslim control and economic cooperation across the confessional frontier was minimal. Here too the ancient economy had thoroughly collapsed in the northern Christian kingdoms. Only in the Muslim and Byzantine lands did the late ancient fiscal motors still run bureaucracies and standing military forces. These accomplishments were far beyond the petty rulers in Francia where these things had collapsed now twice — in the different Roman and Carolingian models. Ireland, Denmark, and Iceland were places that had never fit into ancient

economic regionalism centered on the Mediterranean and Roman provincial boundaries, so their paths were new. England was drifting into a Scandinavian region unknown to the Romans. The repeated demands for tribute, the Danegeld, and the eventually Danish subjection of much of Britain may have provided the kind of fiscal demands that produced a more orderly exploitation and marshalling of rural resources. English agriculture, which was organized by the hundreds of farms and in a village structure that retained a sizeable numbers of slaves, fueled the ambitions of the Danish kings, such as Canute. East of the Rhine, the German kingdom faced the Hungarians as did their Slavic neighbors to the Byzantine frontier. This macropolitical picture of a big Europe now requires that we look beneath the surface to find the prosperity of the regions. Outside of the Byzantine and Muslim lands this will be peasant agriculture.

33

34

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

FARMING The Europe in this chapter had a very wide range of climates and environments

sustaining a broad number of farming, fishing, and pastoral systems. It would be a big mistake to impose an artificial and deceptive uniformity over these many forms suited to the microregions in which they existed, or to take one common type as symptomatic of all the rest. Once again, the nature of the surviving records causes distortions, because we are primarily informed about those peasant lands that fell into the control of the church through sale, exchange, or donation. These lands were already likely to be neighbors of whatever institution was eager to possess them, so they are already, in some sense, not typical.

Let us search for some common types. The peasant freeholder who had enough land to sustain his or her family was the backbone of the economy. After the big Carolingian manorial regimes collapsed, this type of farmer was the most common through the villages of tenth-century Europe. How much landa family needed, and what such a unit was called (e.g., hide, mansus, curtilage) varied according to soil types and regions. These farming families often contained other relatives, and the more prosperous among them might have still had a few slaves. Above the free peasant farmers were families controlling more land than they could directly farm themselves, and these people, the big men on the local scene, leased farming units to the landless and also put slaves to work where slaves were available — as a result, rural slavery persisted in wide area of England, Francia, and Catalonia. In fact wherever the documents survive we see more than vestiges of a rural slavery. Below the self-sufficient were a mass of ostensibly free but landless people, who lived by doing seasonal agricultural work for others. Such people were always necessary in an agricultural regime with bouts of heavy labor demands at harvests and other activities. The villages near tiny cities or on top of older ancient villas often had field structures like old Roman models — a mosaic of small, usually square holdings scattered around a village center. In the rural areas far from cities or wooden castles, the fields were larger. In some cases, by the tenth century individual plots were in long strips to facilitate plowing and perhaps to even out the risks of the microsoil qualities. Villages needed some sort of commons and wooded areas where peasants could gather firewood and pasture animals. These commons by old traditions remained a public right that free people used and needed. In Eastern European areas where peasants practiced slash-and-burn agriculture, the villages were very temporary settlements.

Europe at the Millennium

By the tenth century, in many regions, the surviving charters supply evidence of assarting — land clearing that usually takes the form of cutting down trees or draining wetlands to increase the amount of arable land. This movement made it possible to sustain population growth by bringing more land into cultivation,

especially outside of the densely settled, regions. This was the beginning of a major wave of internal colonization across Europe. Sometimes assarts nibbled away at the commons, and in other places it was not clear who controlled the wastes, as land not used was often called. Big proprietors, secular or religious, funded assarting by offering landless peasants a share of the new land, usually half, in exchange for the hard labor of clearing trees and rocks or draining water-logged areas. Masters could put their slaves to work on these projects and then settle them on the farms that were created. These low-profile patient activities would escape the worst of the raiding and continued on during the troubles, especially in those places farthest from the rivers, coasts, and roads the raiders might take. In mountainous regions, fields were always tiny and bringing new lands under cultivation often required back-breaking digging to construct terraces. Ina fishing village, rarely producing documents of any kind, we presume that increasing the scale of activities meant building more boats, extending a protective jetty by a few meters, or acquiring more salt to sell or to preserve more fish to trade. In a sense, these assarts went out into the sea, or mobilized the trees and salt pans. Soon the Dutch would begin the longterm process of literally assarting the sea. Several impulses guided assarting in general. New resources meant different things to different people — a free peasant with a few more acres had more to eat; a landless one might have a farm for the first time. A slave family on a new enterprise might hope for some event to turn them into tenants. Monks and nuns increased their income and supplies. Even where lords were still cultivating demesne lands with hired, traditional, or coerced labor, assarting improved their incomes as well. The bottom line here is that assarting only makes sense if an increasing population has some better

tools, like horse collars, to do the work. Other labor-saving technologies, such as the water- and wind-driven mills becoming widespread in this century, freed considerable labor from grinding flour that could be put to more profitable

ventures. Despite the breakdown of Carolingian order and the fresh wave of invasions, parts of Europe show signs of a durable prosperity and continued growth in population over the tenth century. The most important factor driving this trend, given a favoring climate for farming, was peasant labor. A chronology

35

36

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

of labor services, which brings the story down to about the year 1000, reveals that in some places, such as England, slavery remained an important rural fact, while in other areas like Catalonia and the Maconnais slaves were becoming tenants and joining the ranks of an increasingly subjected peasantry. Over the tenth century, a new discourse about society described a tripartite world in which some people farmed while others fought or prayed. First articulated by the bishops Gerard of Cambrai and Adelbero of Laon, this social theory, for that is what it was, inevitably privileged those who prayed, but sought in the warriors a group who could be motivated to defend the spiritual hierarchy in an increasingly dangerous world. The overwhelming majority of the population had the duty to work to sustain the clergy and a lordly class. When strong kings like Charlemagne had maintained order the world seemed divided into two orders, secular and clerical. But as kings multiplied and became ineffective in dealing with the externa] threats, a new vision of society made more sense. Public authority no longer prevailed. Private help on the local scene was required. Local lords eventually defeated the Muslims at Freinet, not some heroic king like Beowulf. In a prosperous but threatened rural Latium, these warriors built rural strongholds, primitive castles, from which to fight raiders and wage private wars. In the Midi (southern France), local violence among these warriors became so pronounced that movements known as the Truce and Peace of God began around 990 and continued on into the turbulent 1020s. Local clergy and small landowners initiated these desperate attempts to impose some rules on violence and those who claimed a monopoly over it. All of these trends constitute the beginnings of a feudal revolution and have three precursors that Marc Bloch noted sixty years ago — a subjected peasantry, a hereditary warrior class, and the collapse of public authority in the guise of effective kingship. As we will see in the next chapter, in some places none of this occurred, and free peasants or tribal systems or civic authority still counted for something. Signs of trade, travel, and communications in the late tenth century present a perplexing picture. In some places, raiding and trading went hand-in-hand and the Vikings dealt in slaves and booty wherever they went. Important but small cities continued to be sacked, as was Barcelona on July 6, 985. Some riches there attracted pillagers but documents that might have illuminated the activities producing this wealth were also destroyed. What contributions cities and trade made to a profoundly ruralized society and economy in the West remain very obscure. Cities were headquarters for bishops, drew on local

Europe at the Millennium

Table 1.1. Church property on the Continent Data (from David Herliby, “Church Property on the European Continent, 701-1200," Speculum 36 (1961): 81-105 data, table 3, pp. 103-105).

Property All of Percent

hinterlands for resources, and were frequently wrecked. Trading networks existed, and merchants from Amalfi and elsewhere, as pirates and adventur-

ers, were already making their way to Egypt and the East by 1000. This thin and elusive commerce is not self-explanatory — trade does not somehow mysteriously rise by itself and the supply of luxuries will not create a demand for them unless someone has accumulated the resources necessary to buy them. These processes only emerged slowly from the years of crisis, but we should be alert to the signs of rural prosperity and, above all, in whose pockets the

surpluses were accumulating. The later tenth century emerges from the shadows in particular regions or places where large numbers of written charters survive — Anglo-Saxon England, Catalonia, and the region around Cluny, Bavaria, and Lucca, for example. The great mass of these documents concern property transfers and, in a classic article from 1961, David Herlihy used a vast sample of them to discover the probably percentage of all lands that belonged to the Church (see Table 1.1). Because even those transfers between secular owners only survive because the property ended up belonging to a bishop or monastery, the sample may be slightly biased in favor of ecclesiastical landowners. Herlihy was well aware of this problem

37

38

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

and corrected for it by noting a special feature of nearly all charters, which scrupulously note property boundaries by naming, in the case of a square field, for example, the four neighbors. Counting all of these neighbors multiplies the number of property holders in the sample and captures many landowners who do not appear in any other records. Still, the great collections of charters, and monastic Cluny is the best example of this, show that church landowners pursued strategies of consolidating their holdings. Hence, the naming of the neighbors may be somewhat biased in favor of the very institutions collecting the records and lands. With all of these warnings in mind, we can still trust the general findings which have been ratified in many subsequent studies — that church property amounted to more than 30 percent of all of the lands in the Carolingian period, a time of enormous growth, and remained generally at more than 25 percent even during the troubled tenth century. (We will consider the post-1000 results in later chapters). Tithes and pious donations accounted for this great wealth. Waste, fraud, pillaging, and abuse kept the Church from owning everything. Studying these charters has provided a treasure trove of new insights that range from particular villages to the land-owning strategies of great monasteries and bishoprics. Most of the findings in this chapter rest on careful work on some collection of charters — from the work of Guy Bois on the village of Lournand near Cluny in the Maconnais to Michel Zimmerman’s vast study of nearly 10,000 charters from Catalonia before 1200. Except for the charters in England, where local traditions created a charter tradition with documents in the vernacular Anglo-Saxon, nearly all charters are in a Latin increasingly special to the region where it was written. Outsiders at first find these tenthcentury charters to be in a bizarre Latin that is annoying to anyone who learned his or her Latin from Caesar or Virgil. After setting aside prejudices about obtuse grammar and handwriting, students of charters ask: why there are so many of them? People required more and more charters over the course of the century. In a large number of cases, the parchment carries the marks or even the autograph signatures of the witnesses whose presence, along with the oaths of the parties, conferred validity on the business at hand. This evidence prompts even more good questions — why were so many people donating land to the Church? How many could read or sign their names? Why did they need writing to validate an oral oath? What was the connection between memory and writing? We know from the charters that a fear of Hell and a desire for intercessory prayers prompted many donatio ns to

Europe at the Millennium

the Church. The subscriptions to charters reveal that a number of people who made their marks by a cross on a document could also sign their name. Whether that meant that they could read or not is a separate issue, but even if they could not speak Latin, it was the language of record. Finally, the greater reliance on the written word to keep track of land reveals menaced societies in crisis

that needed to appeal to some authority outside of the parties literally to seal a deal. Recording speech was a new way of maximizing self-interest. Peasant memories in the countryside were one way to keep track of fields and rights and the folk memory remained a powerful repository. Anyone who could write or understand writing had access to a type of authority that could withstand the challenges of weak kingship, vague law, and even the raiders whose destructive ways meant that many charters were lost. But even more charters were kept,

especially by the powerful landowners who now hada new legal tool in addition to their long memories.

This brief look at the forces shaping Europe at the millennium suggests that

it would be best to begin looking at the next period by examining what most people did — farming.

SELECT BIBLIOGRAPHY

P. M. Barford, The Early Slavs. Ithaca, 2001. Guy Bois, The Transformation of the Year One Thousand. Manchester, 1992. Georges Duby, The Early Growth of the European Economy. Ithaca, NY, 1974. David Herlihy, Medieval Households. Cambridge, MA, 1985. Peregrine Horden and Nicholas Purcell, The Corrupting Sea. Oxford, 2000. Michael McCormick, The Origins of the European Economy. Cambridge, 2001. Joel Mokyr, The Lever ofRiches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. Oxford, 1990.

Julia M. H. Smith, Europe after Rome: A New Cultural History 500-1000. Oxford, 2005.

Adriaan Verhulst, The Carolingian Economy. Cambridge, 2002. Bryan Ward-Perkins, The Fall of Rome and the End of Civilization. Oxford, 2006. Lynn White, Jr., Medieval Technology and Social Change. Oxford, 1964. Chris Wickham, Framing the Early Middle Ages. Oxford, 2005. Michel Zimmermann, Ecrire et lire. Barcelona, 2003.

39

2 AGRICULTURE AND RURAL LIFE

HE MATERIAL

CIRCUMSTANCES

OF EUROPE

AROUND

1000 WERE

defined by the fact that the vast majority (at least 90 percent) of the population lived off of the land in the countryside. Over the next three centuries, the story of the land and its people was the fundamental model of the European society and economy and the basis on which every

other accomplishment rested. As Gary Holthaus writes, the issues that farmers faced included: “learning how to maintain the soil and water, animals, and crops; how to take care of the family, keep everyone healthy, and contribute to the community so that one can gain respect and create a meaningful life.” Some peasants skinned that sheep or calf whose skin provided the surface on which the most erudite scholastic treatise might be read.

It seems obvious but essential to note that the tiny number of people at the millennium who prayed, fought, or did something else for a living needed farmers to produce the food their own hands no longer supplied. We need not romanticize these people into some sort of organic, unadulterated Volk from whom everything honest and worthwhile about Europe is derived. Nor should we be content to have these largely inarticulate peoples’ stories be told by the literate classes who taxed, judged, and ordered the peasants to work. Most economic and social history has been written from the perspective of those who lived off of the peasants and who left behind the records and accomplishments that seem more important than the dull seasonal rhythms and proverbial idiocies of rural life. A crude environmental determinism is also an obstacle to understanding the people who pulled a living from the land or the seas. People and their needs were as much a part of nature as anything else. Climate and soil types are not destiny, any more than skin color, creed,

or ethnic stereotypes. 40

Agriculture and Rural Life

Even with these warnings in mind, we must pick up the story somewhere, moving from the general to the particular across three centuries or ten generations. Needless to say, a survey must be selective and still provide a sense of

the rich diversity of the microregions and microclimates of Europe. In a sense, every field and family would have a good story to tell, and historians have been trying to tell the story of an individual peasant or a particular village for a long time. Much of the warrior class also came from the countryside, and their hands rested heavily, in most places, on the backs of peasants. Summarizing all of this work into the blender of a survey risks a bland and even nauseating mixture; too many details will bore and bewilder. Let us then first look at climate, land, crops, and animals, and most importantly at the human settlements and the lives of peasants.

CLIMATE Weather is what happens in the expansive present. Climate is the long-term situation, usually changing so slowly, if at all, as to escape notice by peo-

ple living through climatic change. Hence, it is not surprising that medieval people did not notice the Little Climatic Optimum, a slow warming whose beginnings are vague. Usually defined as the period from 1000 to 1300, this optimum in northern Europe meant a slight warming (probably less than 1°C) bringing hotter summers, milder winters, and normal amounts of rainfall. The end of this period is sharper. Cooling began in the first decade of the fourteenth century. More severe winters did begin to strike contemporaries as

well. Too much rain in 1313/1314 and from 1317 to 1321 resulted in harvest failures and famines across much of northern Europe. For now, let us concentrate on favorable climate. Certainly occasional bad weather, droughts, and storms caused famines and starvation in parts of Europe — the contemporary sources note widespread hunger in 1005-1006, 1032-1035, and 1195-1197. Scarcity of food could drive up prices and encourage speculators. True harvest failures or diseases in livestock could cause absolute shortages at any price. But, in general, the circumstances were favorable to agriculture, and nearly all problems in feeding people can be attributed to transport breakdowns, market failures, and greed. In other words, across Europe there was always enough food, even as some people starved or went hungry because there was no food to buy where they were or because they were too poor to pay the higher prices.

41

42

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000—1500

People did not cause these climatic changes and could not control them. In northern Europe, across the line extending from the Pyrenees, the Alps, and the Carpathian mountains into the plains of Poland and Hungary, the warming meant a longer growing season. Also, more land could be farmed, especially up the mountainsides, and farther to the north in places, such as Russia in the east and even distant Greenland in the west, where imported cattle ate hay crops now possible where formerly ice prevailed. In southern Europe, in the Mediterranean lands, the slight warming did not have a big effect on the already hot and dry summers, which became just a bit warmer. Between these extremes, in the great bands of deciduous forests still stretching across the central parts of Europe in about 1000, the good weather favored the continuing patterns of clearances and assarting that began back in the Carolingian era. All things (technology, farming techniques, seed types, etc.) being equal (which they never are) a favoring climate by itself would have allowed for an accelerating population increase that resulted from better yields from more lands — in theory. What the evidence on demography actually reveals is more complicated.

LAND People had considerable power over the economics of land — how they valued, exchanged, and arranged it for their purposes. In Holland after 1000, the Dutch were adding to the stock of lands by raising it from the sea, but, in general, we should think of Europe's land as fixed in extent if not inuse and unlike population levels. Hence the basic factors of production were — land (capital) and people. They could also improve land, patiently, by burning the heath, marling with lime, draining the wetlands, or fertilizing with seaweed for example in Ireland where it was possible, or pasturing animals on it for manure, and in other ways. What varied enormously across Europe was the natural quality of the soils, about which people could do little. Across wide stretches of northern Europe, glaciated in the last Ice Age, good top soils were thin to nonexistent and grazing was a better idea than farming. South of these areas the glaciers had pushed before them big deposits of stony clays. In theory, these soils were fertile and ideal for planting, but in practice, they were difficult to plow, even with a heavy wheeled plow with iron plowshares pulled by teams of oxen (see Figure 2.1). In river bottoms, the lower reaches of the Thames, Seine, Rhine, Danube, and

Agriculture and Rural Life

Moldboard == Share = Covudter

Figure 2.1. Types of Plows (from Robert Friedel, A Culture ofImprovement. Cambridge, MA, 2007, p. 15).

Vistula, for example, where occasional flooding had piled up fertile deposits,

the lands were generally ideal. Across much of Europe stretching from pockets in northern France and the Low Countries and becoming more widespread in the great steppes of Ukraine and southern Russia were lighter soils called loess.

This windblown clay rested and easy to plow. Loess also peoples, such as the Huns, came west following these

on top of heavier soils and was rich in nutrients produced extensive grasslands ideal for migratory Avars, Magyars, and Mongols, who periodically grass “highways.” Mediterranean soils were thin

and often alkaline because they rested on vast tracts of limestone just beneath

the surface. The lighter scratch plow was well-suited to these lands, especially where keeping moisture in the soil was a priority. Many rivers entered the inland sea, and these delta and alluvial plains were important to prosperous agriculture in Catalonia (the Ebro), Provence (the Rhone), Lombardy (the Po), Tuscany (the Arno), and Latium (the Tiber). Many smaller rivers in parts of the

Balkans, for example, the Achelous River coming out of the Pindus mountains and entering the sea at the western end of the Gulf of Corinth, created similar microregions of good alluvial soils surrounded by poorer ones. Floods could be even more of a problem in the south as good soils were continuously washed away into the sea. Natural processes created and destroyed soils. As yet, humans had only marginal ways to affect these changes, probably less than goats and sheep!

Forests were important natural resources since much construction depended on timber. Heating and cooking required firewood and charcoal. The north seemed to have limitless reserves of coniferous forests even in the face of the

43

44

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

a

Coniferous Forest

1A

Deciduous Forest

UY

.

/

FAROE Is.

./ SHETLANQ gS

Black\Se@

Figure 2.2. European Vegetation (map by Keith A. French and Darin Grauberger, University of Kansas Cartographic Services).

great clearances and assarting (see Figure 2.2). In the fragile ecologies along the mountainous and drier northern shores of the Mediterranean, forests, once cut down, would not easily reestablish themselves. Also, in these regions fires could be devastating. Trading in wood was important, especially for ports, such as treeless Venice, which had to draw on timbers from the southern slopes of the Alps and the Dalmatian coast. It is very hard to say at what point the cutting down of Mediterranean forests had so degraded the environment that flooding and soil loss became problems in some regions. Certainly parts of the classical Mediterranean world had complained about disappearing forests and eroding soils, which were aggravated by overgrazing of sheep and goats. Lower population levels in the early Middle Ages presumably allowed nature time to correct these problems. We should be alert to signs of deforestation reoccurring in the period of growth after 1000. Surface coal seams were not present in the Mediterranean regions and therefore could not substitute for

charcoal and wood, as they slowly did in parts of the north, such as England, by the end of the Middle Ages.

Agriculture and Rural Life

CROPS AND ANIMALS The staple crops of Europe are familiar. In the north, the main spring crops were barley, often for brewing, and oats, for horses, and in poor areas, for people. Everywhere vegetables were spring crops. Peas and lentils were especially valuable because they could be dried and stored for long periods. The main fall crops were wheat and rye, for the staple bread, truly the staff of life, along with porridge, in these societies. Three-course crop rotation was common

in the

north by 1000 and by the thirteenth century had spread as far east as Poland. In

this system, the peasants sowed one-third of the field in a winter crop, one-third in a spring crop, and left one-third fallow, usually for animal pasture. Threecourse rotation generated a significant increase in productivity because now

two-thirds of the land was under cultivation, as opposed to 50 percent under a two-course system, where half was cropped and half was fallow. Peasants knew that the land needed to rest occasionally, and they also understood that wheat

crops cycle. yields living

grew better in soils that had peas or even clover on them in the previous So they rotated their fields and strips through this system, getting higher as a bonus, unknown in detail to them, from the nitrogen-fixing bacteria in the roots of some plants. In some bottom lands, the soil was so good

that it could be planted for years without fallow. Peasants were close students of their soils, and we should expect a lot of varieties in crops that depended on rainfall and soil qualities — which could vary over small distances. Soils in the south, the Mediterranean lands, were not suited to three-course rotation, and the general pattern there was the ancient practice of planting in the fall, allowing the wheat to germinate and get the benefit of seasonal rains, and then a harvest around early summer before the great heat set in. A standard pattern in the south would be one-half of the land ina fall crop and the other one-half fallow, of course allowing for the ordinary production of fruits and vegetables. Olive trees grew throughout most of the Mediterranean forest lands on Figure 2.3. Grapevine cultivation in this period, a little affected by climate change, appeared increasingly deeper into the river valleys of northern Europe, along the Moselle and Rhine, for example. Olive oil was an important food staple in the south, but it was also used for lighting because there was little tallow or beeswax available for candles, which, when available, were usually costly in the south. Olive groves and vineyards, once established, could remain productive for centuries, and raiders and warriors usually left them alone. (Destroying trees and vines was a sign of brutal warfare.) Wine, like

45

46

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000—1500

Medieval Manor

Lord's Fields

Peasant’s Fields yl

Common Pasture

Pasture

Figure 2.3. Medieval Manor (from Clifford R. Bachman, The Worlds of Medieval Europe. New York, 2009, p. 198).

beer and ale in the north, preserved itself and was a way to keep this pleasant carbohydrate, grape juice, available over the winters. Dried grapes in the form of currants and raisins were also appreciated. Wine was also essential for the Christian Mass, so it needed to be imported into those regions too cold to sustain viticulture — as far as distant Iceland and Greenland.

Specialized agriculture developed in some areas, in an almost infinite variety that is hard to catalog. Some new crops, for example, cotton and sugar, came from the east and were cultivated in the better watered areas of Cyprus, Sicily, and southern Spain. The Hospitaler Order of fighting monks obtained through gifts the initial capital to finance sugar production in Latin Syria in the

thirteenth century. Fields of crocuses in parts of Tuscany yielded precious saffron. Picardy in northeast France became prosperous from vast fields of woad, planted for its blue dyestuff. Plantations of mulberry trees in parts of Greece

Agriculture and Rural Life

and Italy supplied the only leaves that finicky silkworms would eat. These crops, and others, like hops for beer and flax for linen in the north, presumed a market in which some peasants could obtain their food supplies in exchange for marketable commodities. Some landlords, lay and ecclesiastical, also understood the benefits of cash crops. We will look more closely at some of these regional issues when we consider trade in Chapter 3. The pool of domesticated animals remained basically the same in medieval Europe. Horses, cattle, pigs, fowl (chickens, geese, and ducks), sheep, and goats were inherited from remote antiquity. Peasants understood how to produce sturdy mules by crossbreeding horses and donkeys. Mountainous or hilly areas, north and south, were ideal for pasturing goats and above all sheep, whose wool, milk for cheeses, pelts, and meat provided so much to the diet and to the economy. Sheep in their millions became a decisive factor in the economy. By the thirteenth century, sheep vastly outnumbered the people in Yorkshire or Castile. Hilly abundant pastures in the north, and the vast expanses of grass in the central Mesta of Spain provided grazing and made the landlords, nobles or monasteries, wealthy. The prized Merino wool from Spain, which came from sheep brought there by North African Berbers in the fourteenth century, began to feed the nascent weaving towns in the south just as English wool

came across the Channel to Flemish weavers and others in the north. The story of wool is but one example of the tight links between urban and rural economies.

Animals were ubiquitous — the warrior aristocracy fought on horses just as

peasants needed them for plowing in the north. Peasants lived closely with these animals, shared characteristic illnesses with them, and slowly built up slight immunities to diseases that would kill those people not in close proximity to these animals. People and animals in a sense evolved together, and illnesses, such as influenza and smallpox, were also shared. All of these domesticated animals were smaller, sleeker, and wilder than modern types. Peasants were not going to domesticate fish in the strictest sense, but fishponds in many areas allowed year round and easily obtained stocks of carp, trout, and salmon. Deepwater fishing for herring and cod required seaworthy craft not easy or cheap to build and maintain. Rabbit warrens too allowed

for access to their meat and skins. Dogs and cats worked for lords and small. Europe still abounded in wild formidable opponents. The warrior

Dovecotes were fixtures on big estates. peasants alike in hunting game large and animals, and the wolf and the bear were classes tried to monopolize hunting and

47

48

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

claimed rights to certain noble animals, such as stags and swans. One of St. Francis's most engaging acts of charity was his solution to the problem of the

wolf of Gubbio, whom the residents agreed to feed in exchange for being left alone. All these animals had an important part to play in the economic and indeed social histories of medieval people — lords, peasants, and townspeople alike.

PEASANT SETTLEMENT Rural people settled where the land could be plowed or might yield something

to eat, where they were safe, as on hilltops, where they had freshwater at a pond, spring, or creek, or at a place where roads or paths crossed. Sometimes villages were established outside of major fortifications or holy sites. Some of these places were ideal and had been settled for many centuries. Peasants rarely lived in isolated farmsteads, and the characteristic settlement was the village, or its smaller version, the hamlet. In these nucleated villages, the people lived together and walked out to their fields. Divisions are arbitrary here, but work usually defines the village — the vast majority of people were in farming of one sort or another — although, of course, there were mining or fishing villages too. A big village might contain three hundred people and begin to look like a small town; indeed, some evolved into towns. A hamlet (at least three families) might contain only five or six and were often satellites to the larger, nearby villages. These settlements had names, deriving from a bewildering array of traditions from old Roman, Greek, or Celtic place-names to the latest Newton or Neuburg. Villagers frequently moved small distances, often carrying along the old place names. A major distinction is between the planned and unplanned village. Since the time of the Romans and subsequent tribal settlements, many villages were planned as colonies for veterans or ventures of one type or another. These planned villages are an important feature of the settling of new lands across medieval Europe from 1000 to 1300, especially in Eastern Europe. The planned villages often have regular fields and houses set out along streets or around a central green or square. In other places, it seems that people had always been living there, and villages and field patterns evolved slowly over time in highly local and distinctive ways. Blocks or strips of land, depending on soil types and crops, coalesced or were divided according to the vagaries of inheritance. A village might easily come into existence over the ruins of a Roman villa as farmers

Agriculture and Rural Life

stayed on the land that they knew, just as newcomers settled down around a pioneer on some new land. The planned villages of the medieval colonization phase required a new profession, the locator. This person, working for a landlord, recruited peasants and set up villages on new lands — the Saxons moving

deep across the rivers of central Europe are an example of this phenomenon. These German villages in places, such as Transylvania, were interspersed with Slavic villages that might be planned or unplanned. Every village had an economic and social history —a reason for existing that responded to the historical geography of particular microregions. Villages and hamlets were flexible and durable features of European society; they existed long before the Middle Ages and in much of Europe they still endure. This flexibility meant that they changed over time. Hence, a snapshot of the village at any point in time fails to convey the dynamism of the village.

Yet, some people continued to live outside them. In some difficult areas, such as the highlands of Scotland, we cannot be sure what forms rural settlement took. On Iceland, single farmsteads prevailed, with the “Big Men" controlling enough people and occasional slaves for their farm to resemble a hamlet. But mountainous regions generally favored dispersed single farmsteads and hamlets. Often transhumance was afeature of these regions as people and animals moved vertically by season, following pasturage from lowlands to highlands or across the steppes as the weather changed. In the lowlands, peasants lived in small, timber, or wattle-and-daub one-story buildings with two or three rooms for

people and animals. This flexible structure allowed for expansion as family groups changed over time, and they could also be rebuilt or slightly moved with ease. This was beneficial because the land around the hut or cottage, called, in English, the toft, was greatly improved over time by human and animal wastes and might become the garden or a small field as the living space was moved. In mountainous regions or other glaciated areas with a lot of surface rubble,

peasants built stone dwellings, which were durable and warmer in the cold months. In parts of Spain and Italy where their labor was especially threatened and valuable, peasants were moved by landlords into fortified villages where they might be controlled and protected more easily. Even before 1300 there were a few deserted village sites across Europe because, for one reason or another (usually thoroughly exhausted soils), the peasants moved on. But, in general, the pattern was for the villages existing around 1000 to endure, with many new ones springing up, mostly planned, during the processes of internal and external colonization.

49

50

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

Documents, such as manorial court rolls and even handbooks for confessors,

reveal the social life of peasants inside these villages, and some things merit notice. Actual forms of tenure varied enormously. Much of the period from 1000 to 1300 witnessed efforts by peasants to regularize the ways they held land and might exchange, sell, or inherit it. We will look at these issues more closely when we bring the landlords into the picture. Throughout much of Western Europe the course and aftermath of the Tenth Century Crisis took the form of what some scholars have called “a feudal revolution” and others have stressed as its most distinctive feature — the rise of peasant servitude. In late tenth- and early eleventh-century Catalonia, the Maconnais, and England after the Norman Conquest, the landlords increasingly burdened formerly free peasants with material exactions that diminished their economic and social liberties. This complicated process turned much, but not all, of the peasantry into serfs, and it was more successful in some parts of Europe than others for reasons we will explore shortly. The fusion of a peasant village and a lordly estate, more common across continental northwestern Europe, became the classic manor (see Figure 2.3). The serfs on this manor practiced a three-course crop rotation. This idealized village had only one “Big House," and its ten huts sheltered perhaps fifty men, women, and children. No real place was exactly like this sketch. Not every manor had its own blacksmith or mill pond, but most did. The lord had first claim to the common pasture rights and was sure to locate his house upstream from the serfs. The surrounding forests were a valuable resource that could sustain increasing population, up to a point.

For the moment let us focus on the hallmarks of serfdom, what serfs owed the landlords — a compulsory labor service, a ground rent per unit of land, a death duty, some sort of payment or fine for marrying, and a head or poll tax. On the local level, there was almost an infinite variety of negotiated or coerced set of impositions that might not include all of these standard features. This seigneurial regime defined what the landlords collected from their serfs — a revenue stream, income, or what economists call "rents" because they derive from the power to demand them. Rents might include a bewildering array of other exactions concerning, for example, the obligation to cart the lord's wood or the duty to use the lord's mill or oven and to tithe to his church. The overall effect of this feudal regime was to alienate the serfs from the fruits of their labors, to humiliate them by controlling, for example, whom they married or where they lived. In practical terms, the landlords compelled

Agriculture and Rural Life

obedience to all these demands by running the local courts and when necessary fining or beating the serfs into submission. The role violence played in this regime should not be underestimated. Peasants were reduced into serfdom by force. Only a few slaves found promotion to this status as something of an improvement, and it did not end the beatings. Many words were coined or

adopted to describe these serfs — the most common was the old Latin word for slave, servus, but also villein (a villager, rustic, inevitably a base person) and in one revealing old French expression, homme de corps — a man or woman whose very body could be subjected to work or be punished as the landlord saw fit. This seigneurial regime flourished in those parts of Europe suited to large-scale agriculture and where the lords were strong enough to enforce it. We will return to the important question of regionalism when we look at the lordly class. Landlords owed protection to their tenants, serfs, and slaves. This security allowed farmers the time and incentives to study and improve their lands, animals, seeds, and tools. The great survey of manors in England ordered by

William I in 1086/1087, the famous Domesday Book, was itself an astonishing bureaucratic achievement. That it survives is also remarkable. The Domesday inquest missed London and Winchester, but provides a wealth of details on mills, animals, and above all the conditions of land tenure. The book and

inquest are two snapshots that intended to describe the kingdom on the eve of the Norman Conquest in 1066 and currently, and these records are descriptive rather than an effort to explain change and processes. Yet, its details by county clearly show that already by 1087 the king, the Church, and the warrior aristocracy owned the vast majority of the lands of England. Serfs (villeins) comprised about 40 percent of the population, small holders (cottars) about 32 percent, freemen 14 percent, and slaves still 10 percent of the population. These percentages varied according to the lands and their uses, as did the ratios of oxen to horses, the extent of forests, and other aspects of rural life. A few local examples will show the flexibility of the feudal regime and how it changed over time. The manor of Halesowen in the English Midlands first appears in Domesday Book in 1086 as a huge entity, perhaps 10,000 acres,

including a number of villages and hamlets. Slaves still existed at that time, but soon enough they all would join the mass of unfree tenants, serfs here called

villeins. When the manor belonged to the crown in the thirteenth century, the terms for the unfree peasants included a substantial annual rent for their lands, six days to plow and ten days to sow for the lord, and one day's boon work, and they also had to mow grass and fence the gardens. The customary tenants

al

52

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

also owed the lord a death duty or heriot (mainmorte) of their best beast, and their heirs had to pay entry fines, two years’ rent, to take up the holdings. They

also had to pay fines when their daughters married. The freeholder peasants, who comprised about one-third of the tenants, did not owe labor services but still had to turn up regularly at court. When the Premonstratensian Order of canons got this manor and built an abbey there in 1217, they doubled the entry fines and probably the rents as well. The canons also built a mill and required the tenants to use it, and they instituted some local tolls. All peasants owed suit at the manorial court, where petty fines regulated brewing, marriages, debts, trespasses, and a host of other customs. The labor services remained the same, and in 1327 these services were commuted to a money rent. These changes over time in one place reveal the chronology in which lords imposed on their peasants rules they thought benefited themselves. Elsewhere, local circumstances resulted in different outcomes. For example, the famous Statutes of Lorris, a model contract that shows the favorable terms that the kings of France used in the twelfth century to attract peasants to new villages. Here the process of assarting included new settlements on royal

lands, with the king as landlord looking for tenants. These new tenants came from somewhere — extra children from older villages, runaway serfs, or migrants looking for a better life. The king offered these peasants a simple modest money rent, a token part of the crop (rye) for lands, defined labor services amounting to gathering wood for the lord's kitchen, and carting his wine to Orleans — and this was required only of those people who had horses and wagons and who had been asked. The peasants owed suit at the king's local court, but they enjoyed defined rights there and were promised that there would be no new demands placed on them. The statutes reveal a pervasive sense of peasant liberties — they were free to travel locally without tolls, sell their possessions, and, if they wanted, to leave the village. The king granted new arrivals the year and a day privilege, that is, if they lived in Lorris for that time with no one claiming rights over them, they became free members of the village. These economic and personal liberties reflect a regime that preserves only the mildest forms of serfdom at the same time as other peasants found their circumstances becoming harsher. Here peasants owed almost no labor services, no death duties, were free in their personal movements and decisions, including choice of spouses, and promises of justice presume that the king's officials did not beat people in Lorris. There, the peasants were no longer serfs and were very nearly free although they were

Agriculture and Rural Life

landless at first. Whatever the king derived from places like Lorris was more than he received when the lands were vacant. It is important to keep in mind the kind of mosaic panorama of landholding systems in the countryside. Manors, such as Halesown, or peasants, such as some relatively fortunate tenants of the kings of France, were known but were by no means universal throughout most of Western Europe. In the south, near admittedly little cities, such as Barcelona, Montpellier, Genoa, and Lucca, for example, system of public law, based roughly on Roman models, still supported the notion of a private property right in land. Where this right existed, it was possible to sell land, even if the owner needed the permission of his kin or some lord to confirm the act because they too had some rights or expectations over the property. For example, a small archive of documents, beginning in 1065,

record the patient efforts of Ricard Guillem and his wife Ermessinda to buy vineyards, houses, arable land, and entire farms in the region around Barcelona. These charters reflect a solid legal context, a monetary system, and, above all, the clear right to own land and sell it without any lord's approval. Rights over land in the countryside were seldom absolute, and as we will see urban land had its own rules. Where land could be bought and sold, one might also lease it, under long terms set by Roman models, that is, twenty-nine years or even greater spans measured in lifetimes. These features, never absent in the north but more precocious in the south, are the hallmarks of a land market. Such a market can change the relationship between tenant and landlord or between buyer and seller. Markets could also be copied and exported.

The demeaning personal aspects of serfdom might be entirely absent where a market determined the ties between those who controlled the land and those hands were needed to work in the fields. Peasants in the valleys around Genoa saw nobles living in castles who usually controlled the best lands. The bishop

in town and some powerful local monasteries also owned land, which was often leased out on favorable long terms and fixed, customary and low rents were paid to the powerful, often their kin, who then turned around and bargained with local peasants. These tenants often had their own lands, and in the valleys it was rare for aman or woman to owe labor— this was more common in the fertile plains and river valleys. The common theme is that the lords, the powerful, had most of the best land, and ran the local courts or interpreted the old laws

and kept the best records of their rights. The thing to ask about the peasants in localities is: did they have to right to leave, to buy and sell tenancies, and to negotiate terms as individuals or a collective? If the peasants did not pay in

53

54

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

their own labor, they needed access to markets to sell their surpluses to obtain silver pennies to pay their taxes and rents.

These local rules presume some pressure from the peasants, who could indeed

negotiate their terms and in most places had a headman, some elder with respect who spoke for the villagers. Seigneurial regimes reflect a mix of coercion and bargaining — the same king of France eager to pursue his own runaway serfs was also in the business of attracting other tenants and looking the other way at their origins. Some villages in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries had communes, which were sworn associations of the members that stood in solidarity against the lords of the land. Rare notices of village chests survive and in these places the peasants kept modest amounts of cash and above all precious documents that secured their collective personal status and land tenures. Levels of literacy in these villages remained low, but there is no doubt the peasants understood the value of the written record over memory even if they could not read. Christianity imbued these settlements with some economic and social practices. Tithing was easy to observe and enforce in the countryside, where priests and monks could count the sheep and have special barns built for their share of the crops. In Denmark, for example, the new practice of tithing (and manorial farming) granted thirds to the local priest, church upkeep, and the bishop. In other places the poor received the bishop's portion, and often lay people owned the tithes. In the eleventh century, paganism was waning fast and increasingly confined to the northeastern and southeastern corners of Europe, for example, the Turkic Cuman and later Tartars of the south and the still-polytheistic Baltic peoples in the north. So with some important exceptions, the peasantries of Europe were Christian. Throughout much of Castile and Aragon, Muslim peasant villages were a fixture of rural life in these expanding kingdoms. On Sicily these Muslim villagers were fated to be harassed and pushed out in one way or another during the thirteenth century. Some Jewish peasants survived under Greek rule in the east and under the Venetians on Crete, but it was becoming increasingly difficult for Jews to own and work farmlands across much of Europe because they did not fit into the emerging feudal systems of land tenure, and they were not wanted by lords or their Christian neighbors. One story of this period concerns heretical peasants — those who rejected the teachings of the official Church. These people were virtually nonexistent at the millennium, but in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries, for example, the Cathar faith attracted some peasants, and in some places, such as Languedoc and the Pyrenees, the majority. This change of belief did not alter farming, but it did profoundly

Agriculture and Rural Life

affect the worldview of these peasants. Crusades and inquisitions destroyed these communities by the early fourteenth century, so force solved the problem of the heterodox peasant. What, in practice, did it mean then to say that these peasants were Christians, beyond the facts that their lay and spiritual rulers wanted them to belong to the official Church, follow its rules, and pay its tithes? Lists of male and female names, gathered from 1000 to 1300, reveal that the great and various collection

of Germanic, Celtic, and Romance names was shrinking down to a smaller set of familiar Christian names deriving from the set of prominent saints. So, many

more Johns and Peters and Catherines and Marys appeared everywhere, and this was especially significant for the peasants because very few had any other name.

What this meant in practice is harder to say, but we assume that the naming patterns reflect a general desire to internalize the values and good qualities of these saints and to seek their protection for the bearers. St. Francis (Francesco)

of Assisi bore a new name, practically invented by his father apparently as a tribute to his prosperous trade in cloth with France. (Indeed, today children bearing the names China and India, for example, are not unknown.) So there were some new names, and in this spectacular case, the name Francis and all its

variants appeared quickly in the vernacular languages across Europe. One Dominican priest, Stephen of Bourbon, while hearing confessions in the thirteenth century diocese of Lyon learned of a mysterious St. Guinefort,

previously unknown to him. He found out that peasant women preserved a story of this holy martyr who came to have special powers for healing sick children. Occasionally women left babies in a sacred wood overnight and later discovered that a healthy baby had been substituted for theirs, or indeed that no changeling or infant was there to be found. These practices scandalized Stephen who became even more stunned when he figured out that this saint was in fact a dog, a holy greyhound. Old and deep beliefs about the spirits in the woods and the powers of creatures remained deep in a peasantry ostensibly Christian for centuries. Stephen claims he had the dead dog dug up and its bodied burned — what can the peasants have made of this warning?

What did Christianity have to do with peasants and their lands? The subject is vast but here are a few highlights. The biblical injunction “to be fruitful and multiply’ embodied an entire worldview about the natural world that encouraged procreation and an attitude toward land and its creatures that positively mandated exploitation of nature. This world was designed for people, and it contained everything they needed. Peasants, closest to the land, were

a2

56

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

an integral part of this system. They truly earned their bread by the sweat of their brows and were supposed to feed their so-called betters. They also tamed

pockets of nature as they cut down forests, drained swamps, and experimented with grafting fruit trees and crossbreeding types of sheep. The Church also taught the peasants a family structure resting on the familiar nuclear type, and it encouraged marriage and procreation of legitimate children. Church rules about infanticide, inheritance, godparenthood, work on Sundays, baptizing children, and tithes increasingly prevailed. A substantial minority of peasants everywhere knew the Church as a landlord with meticulous records and a need for income. Not all peasant culture derived from Christian teaching, and on some matters older or secular habits prevailed. For example, a gender division of labor in village society stereotyped some jobs, such as plowing, for men and left women in charge of small animals, brewing, and other tasks. Yet, when harvesting the crops, delousing the children, or weeding the fields, all able hands pitched in, and there was almost no work that any peasant, man or women, indeed girl or boy, could not handle in a pinch. Peasant culture, as well as sermons, frowned on idleness, because it was a cause and symptom of poverty that left the Devil many opportunities.

FEUDAL SOCIETY Feudal society hovers over the Middle Ages as the characteristic feature that most people remember. Social and economic historians have a long tradition of looking at this great time span as one when social ties among lords and peasants, as they evolved, shaped the typical and memorable features of a world standing between the classical past and early modern globalizing capitalism. Critics have maintained that this vision of feudal society is a mirage that is doing more harm than good and is an outdated mode of analysis invented by lawyers who made their living in the intricacies of feudal law. A concession to these critics is to

speak about feudal society as opposed to feudalism, a confusing generalization unknown to the people in our period of study. “Feudalism,” like all “isms,” is an empty box into which people drop all their ideas and examples in order to generalize about the practices they study. Our path here is to focus, on the one hand, on relationships, and, on the other hand, on property. A feudal society presumes that relationships among people start from the premise of something we can call feudal, in fact, the fief. A fief was a piece of property held in exchange for some service we will consider later in the chapter. The holding

Agriculture and Rural Life

of a fief creates an obligation and is hence social and more enduring than if it was simply the momentary tie between a buyer and aseller. Confusingly, scholars sometimes refer to this obligation as afeudal rent — military and other services from the warriors, cash rents, and labor services from the peasants to the warrior. For our purposes, a rent is a stream of income in-kind or in cash, agreed on or imposed by local custom. These feudal rents are not strictly market rents

because the peasants had little bargaining rights and often no formal contracts. Force and the market determined their rent. Some peasants lived on lands that were parts of fiefs, but they did not possess fiefs — they lived in a lower class that did not hold property in this way. A class of powerful people controlled the land as in some wayafief, or as personal property, the allod, for which they may have owed some public obligation, usually a tax, sometimes military service. By the eleventh century, the Latinized Germanic word fevum had supplied the Latin word feudum, which was a grant of land called afief. Over this century, a vocabulary emerged that described the people who were involved in this relationship. The vassal held the fief. He was typically a miles, a warrior most effective on horseback, a knight, from a Germanic word for a type of servant,

but not a humiliated one because he served in arms. This vassal received the fief from a lord, a dominus, who might himself be the vassal of someone more powerful. Only kings and emperors might claim to have no earthly lord. Often a ritual of homage served to symbolize and ratify the act by which the vassal became the man (homme) of another man, his lord. Homage might involve getting down on one's knees before a lord, or kissing his hand, or for a lucky vassal to be raised up and exchange a kiss on the cheeks or mouth with a lord. In a society that valued oaths, it is not surprising that soon enough in the eleventh century, an oath of fealty became common as well, by which the

vassal swore to be faithful to his lord, who in turn swore to fulfill his part of the contract to his vassal. The fief was the cement of the system and what tied the fighting men together in a contract based on mutual military and other

support in exchange for land. The more powerful the lord, the more vassals he had because his power rested on his mounted retinue, the men who would turn up to fight when he needed them. The vassal of a powerful lord could, in turn, count on a good lord to protect him when he needed protection. Mutual protection, by contract strengthened with an oath, to hold property and to fight — these were the hallmarks of feudal society from the perspective of the warrior class. In economic terms the warrior class was rent seeking, using their skills in violence to compel an income, a feudal rent, from the peasantry.

SY.

58

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

In exchange, the fighters offered to protect the peasants from even worse people. Most scholars approve of the idea of a first and second feudal age, usually shifting sometime around 1050. This chronology is tentative and vague, but it does stress the dynamism of the eleventh century. In the first feudal age, beginning during the Tenth-Century Crisis, the characteristics of the regime slowly emerged in its heartland, in the north between the Loire and Rhine rivers. This regime required a class of professional warriors, increasingly defining

themselves as noble, who in the first feudal age emerged on the local scene from very diverse backgrounds — some Carolingian counts, some local toughs, indeed some peasants with a sword and a horse and the will to dominate others.

These people spent good money in the second feudal age having family trees drawn up to demonstrate their proud genealogies. But the crisis of the tenth

century threw these men into prominence, and the order and military strength they created were the most important factor in resolving the crises of the invasions. Mounted warriors stopped the Magyars and Muslim raiders. Some Vikings who settled own in Normandy became lords and vassals, and their chief claimed to be a duke. Church lands often became fiefs because bishops and abbots too needed vassals. Kings used these fighting men on the church lands by demanding military service from the clergy. The first feudal age witnessed the growing hegemony of a social idea, articulated by clerics, that the world was divided into three orders: the fighting class of warriors, the professionals who prayed, and the peasants who farmed. From the beginning gender, roles were distinctive in the division of labor in the orders. These three “natural orders" replaced an older vision of a Christendom divided into a clergy who prayed and dispensed the sacraments and a heterogeneous laity that had the duty to support and protect the clergy. Even at its inception in the tenth century, the idea of three orders was inadequate to the task of describing a real world in which women prayed and farmed. Merchants and small cities always mattered. From the view of the lordly class, they were the order that counted for the most. Although few in numbers, their extra children staffed the church and filled the best spots in the most prestigious nunneries and monasteries. Noble women cemented family alliances and passed down noble blood to their children. Lordly donations and swords protected the Church and led crusades in this world. For these services, warriors expected prayers and sacraments that eased their own violent selves into Paradise.

Agriculture and Rural Life

The first feudal age also witnessed the drawing together of some old social facts, such as the mounted warrior, the manor, and a subjected peasantry, into a system devised to maintain a warrior class. Kings, even heroic ones, had retinues too small to fight the Magyars, and so local strongmen drew together vassals who fought for them. Kings might have been individually weak, and they no longer had a fisc or any sort of reliable tax base to fund an army. Kings too needed vassals or the money to hire fighters. Even the army that William Duke of Normandy used to conquer England in 1066 consisted of both vassals who owed him service and would share in the booty, and men, true mercenaries, who wielded their lances for pay. Even now, at the cusp of the two feudal ages, silver also mattered, and William's wealth came from

many lay and clerical hands from the peasants working the productive soils of Normandy, its counties and bishoprics — one of whom, the duke's uncle Odo bishop of Bayeux, fought at Hastings. The feudal revolution of the eleventh century is the rise of a seigneurial

regime throughout much of the countryside of Western Europe. The landlord exercised, through some local or manorial court, rights of justice, over a subjected peasantry that included free and unfree peasants. A chief (who may be the king),or as in Italy, a nascent commune, a free association of townspeople granted self-government, were the effective lords of the countryside. Just as these processes were taking shape, contradictory trends surfaced, which made all generalizations about feudal society perilous. For example, in one of the first known instances of this innovation, in 1058 the abbey of Nonantola in Italy began the process of ending serfdom by abolishing one of its most demeaning aspects — its serfs were not to be beaten. By the thirteenth century cities, such as Bologna in 1257, abolished all forms of serfdom — in the latter the names of the lucky 5,855 people were recorded in the Liber Paradisus. Elsewhere, as in fertile Tuscany, over the course of the twelfth century many landlords commuted old money rents and services into rents-in-kind, usually in grain, over long terms. Rents in wheat, for example, protected landlords

from inflationary pressures on fixed customary cash rents and provided a steady stream of a highly marketable commodity sensitive to market pressures. Oaths of loyalty still bound these peasants to the landowners, who in the thirteenth century began to experiment with the mezzadria (sharecropping). Under this system, the landlord leased a farm to a peasant family and often supplied the

house, tools, and animals. The peasants worked and paid over to the lordafixed

59

60

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

share, usually one-half, of all of the produce the farm generated. This system

spread the risk of crop failure between worker and owner, but it guaranteed the landowner food supplies and marketable commodities, such as grains and wine, that could be turned into cash. The peasants had the use of a farm that they would never be able to buy. They were at the mercy of the market for their produce and labor. Under fixed money or grain rents the peasants bore most of the risk; as sharecroppers they had different incentives and the opportunity to prosper. They were piece-rate agricultural laborers working for one-half of everything that they produced. In commercialized areas, such as northern Italy and Flanders, where increasing numbers of urban people needed to purchase their food, entrepreneurial landlords were wise to secure their incomes in kind rather than in increasingly debased fixed sums of cash. In these places, market forces were transforming serfdom even as in parts of eastern Europe, for example, serfdom was being imposed for the first time. This dynamic to feudal society requires a patient attention to the issues of regionalism and chronology. In northwest Europe, the classic west and its frontiers, two systems of land use predominated: (1) the open fields plowed in strips and on the Atlantic coasts a bocage or (2) hedgerow style of farming enclosed fields called crofts. The Pyrenees and the Alps separated these methods from a general Mediterranean style of farming and village life (described below) showing elements of similarity throughout this vast region. More sparsely populated regions, such as the Slavic lands and Scandinavia (excluding Denmark), exhibited small village and dispersed farming and pastoralism. A good way to open up traditional Europe's horizons is to compare its rural scene to that of the Byzantine Empire. This great state still controlled most of the Balkans and varying parts of Anatolia down to 1204, when the Fourth Crusade wrecked the empire, sacked Constantinople, and created a Frankish or Latin feudal empire in parts of this region. This Frankish state ended in 1261 and the Byzantines recaptured their capital, but parts of the Peloponnesus remained in French hands for a long time, and valuable islands, such as Crete and Negroponte, were lost to Venice for good. In these areas colonial practices imported into

the East, as in Latin Syria, created some feudal regimes in the countryside and reduced parts of the indigenous population to serfdom. The brief comparisons here to Byzantine agriculture concern the empire's prosperous centuries, which began earlier than the West's, and witnessed its heyday in the twelfth century, before the catastrophe of 1204.

Agriculture and Rural Life

What tenth-century crisis the Byzantines endured was quickly resolved by successes against the Slavs and Turks, and the empire entered its golden age under the dynasty of the Comneni. In the countryside, polyculture, the raising of a wide variety of crops, and pastoralism were the mainstays of rural life. This was the world of the olive and vine. Water mills were common and also used to irrigate land. Storing and distributing water were necessary in these relatively dry climates that received seasonal rains. In general terms, peasant villages and great estates were the norm. These estates were collections of rent-paying tenancies and seldom practiced demesne farming, though in some places by the fourteenth century peasants owed public labor services called a corvée. Managing these estates was a common theme in East and West. Specialized officials with manuals and records understood that land was capital producing after-tax

income for its owners. The bishops and monasteries were great landowners as well, and we are especially well informed about the holdings of the great houses near Mount Athos in Thrace. Another interesting similarity between the east and west is that monastic records are a valuable window on agriculture. Small, peasant holdings predominated, and slavery in the countryside was waning in the twelfth century, as it was in the West. The size of farms naturally varied and depended on the local soils. The basic pattern of Mediterranean agriculture with its square open fields prevailed, where suitable, for cultivating the basic cereal crops: wheat, barley, millet, oats, and rye — all spring plantings. Notable special

crops were fruit trees, the olive trees planted near the sea at low elevations where it did not freeze, and mulberry trees for the silkworms. Peasants understood that vines exhausted the soil, were very labor intensive, and required frequent replanting. Greece and Anatolia still had great forests, some owned by the

state. Rural peoples supplemented their incomes by working at a variety of crafts including cloth, ceramics, and metal working. A pool of wage earners stood in reserve to help fill seasonal demands for labor. The great mass of peasants called the paroikoi were tenant farmers who might have owned a few vines and other personal property but were renters and not

serfs. They owed rents that were traditionally higher than the taxes paid by proprietors of the land. Only a minority of peasants owned their land outright.

Irrigated and intensely cultivated patches of gardens (now called buertas after the Spanish model) produced good yields of vegetables, a major part of the diet. Another big distinction among the peasants was who owned animals.

The more-prosperous ones had their own ox and could join together with a

61

62

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

neighbor to form a plow team. On these light soils, two oxen were enough to plow, and this source of power made a difference in the lives of some peasants. One important feature of Byzantine land taxes is that they varied according to the quality of the soils. On the large estates where the owners also had the rights to the peasant taxes, this bonus amounted to one-half of heir incomes. These peasants had village communes, and in the eleventh century the local taxes were conceded to powerful landowners. The empire was itself a great landowner and in the twelfth century the rulers adopted the pronoia system by which peasants living on imperial, fiscal lands paid their obligations directly to soldiers for their lifetimes. This system allowed the emperors to pay their troops on the local level and saved the trouble of collecting and redistributing this income. At first, the pronoia grant was strictly for the lifetime of the soldier, and it created a personal, economic relationship between the state and its soldiers. In the thirteenth century, necessity compelled some emperors to grant pronoia for two generations. Clearly, however, this system was not a feudal society in Western terms because the Byzantine State had laws guaranteeing property rights and land markets, a regular land tax systematically collected, and it did not need social forms, such as homage and fealty to secure military service. In fact, the empire supported a powerful army and fleet that were testimonies to the enduring importance of using taxes to pay warriors. The heart of this system was not the fief but was instead the extensive

state lands that gave the emperors the income that they needed to pay for the military and the bureaucracy. Some estates, defined as military lands, also

directly supported fighters, and occasionally church lands were required, in lieu of part of their tax-exempt status, to pay money directly to the military. This system also required a monetary economy and the state had for centuries maintained a reliable and prestigious gold currency, now called the nomismata. The Byzantine agrarian economy was clearly part of the broader Mediterranean system that thrived despite a complex pattern of microregions and microclimates. Whatever economic and social problems the Byzantine Empire experienced did not result from its agricultural base, which seemed in good shape in these centuries and able to sustain a pattern of demographic growth similar to the West's. Byzantine agriculture achieved in these centuries improved yields, increased specialization, and rational ways or organizing and taxing land. Peasants were at the heart of this method of farming, and many of them also participated in a pastoral sector characterized by transhumance patterns common in the Mediterranean. As we will see when we consider trade and other

Agriculture and Rural Life

economic matters, the Byzantine State was exceptionally effective in developing and implementing economic policies and a legal system for making them work. The state also supplied a sound currency that made this region among the most monetarized in the Mediterranean. The challenges this state faced from the East and West, from crusaders, Turks, and others, wrecked many of these accomplishments in the fourteenth century, when this region experienced the common calamity of plague.

DEMOGRAPHY The survey of the agricultural base reveals a general pattern of increased scale and scope to farming that could have sustained an increase in the population. Analysis of skeletons from medieval Danish graveyards has yielded good evidence on individuals and their life expectancies — here a diverse and wholesome diet produced people about the same size as they are today. Studying people in groups and population movements, the science of demography, is difficult for the Middle Ages because the original sources are not good. Medieval people were aware of numbers and their uses, sex ratios, and ideas about multitudes, but they did not count themselves. Without a clear census of people, scholars

have to scrutinize other sources for clues on population growth. Some records reveal the number of households in a specific city or region, usually for tax or rental purposes. Other sources occasionally count the number of persons in a household, so estimates of population usually reflect some debate about the proper multipliers: the number of households and their size. Crude birth and death rates occasionally emerge from some types of records. Royal and noble genealogies can yield demographic data about the great lineages that kept track of births and deaths, but these families are hardly typical. Civil and canon law, as well as court records, supply different opinions on the age of majority, the role of consent in marriage, and other issues, such as informal marriages. Wills can provide a sense of the household over time as living and deceased members were recalled, but these sources do not survive everywhere and are more common in the notarial, urban south in this period. Other indicators also provide some sense of growth: new settlements and parishes, the size of fleets and armies, extensions of city walls. Some scholars argue that nineteenth- and early twentieth-century censuses from some rural, underdeveloped parts of Europe may be good indicators of

the carrying capacity of the land and hence provide clues about medieval

63

64

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

numbers of people. Considerable speculation and guesswork go into these estimates of populations and some scholars shy away from the enterprise and the mental effort required to imagine medieval societies’ benefits from even sketchy

estimates of population. For example, if England had more than two million people around 1087 and has more than fifty million today, even this rough ratio helps to provide some sense of how the landscape may have appeared in

the past. With these problems and warnings in mind, let us consider the rural demographic trends, saving most of the urban problems for Chapter 4. Good evidence from rural fourteenth-century Macedonia indicates that the population there was about thirty-four people per square kilometer. Conserva-

tively using one-half that figure to project back to 1025 and the height in area of the Byzantine State for Thrace, Macedonia, Bulgaria, and Asia Minor, and using the lower figure of nine people per square kilometer for the less populated parts of Greece, Angeliki Laiou has estimated the rural population of the empire at

eighteen million. In 1025, the largest city in Europe by a big margin was Constantinople at two hundred thousand, and allowing for other cities would put the empire's population at nineteen million. By the 1170s, when much of Anatolia had been lost to the Turks, the population was still probably about the same

because of demographic increases over the previous century and a half. Before 1204 Constantinople may have reached as many as four hundred thousand, its medieval height. This numbers help to demonstrate how important the eastern Mediterranean remained in terms of people and their economic activities. For the rest of Europe before the plague of 1348, the estimates of population vary considerably, but there seems to be a consensus about England's population, with two million at Domesday Book (1086/1087) and at its medieval height about 5.5 million in 1300, a near tripling of population. More reliable numbers from parts of France concern household size and these figures derive from patiently accumulating information from manorial, fiscal, and other sources. The best figure is the number of children per household with children — this excludes the single and childless who had to replaced if the population was to grow. (One-third of medieval couples had no surviving children, for complex reasons, including infertility, early death, and other factors.) Here are the French numbers on children per household: 1000-1050, 4.3, 1050-1 100)4:2— 9.7; 1100-1150, 4.6-5.3; 1150-1200, 4-5.2. These numbers indicate a range of 0.3—.6 percent population increase per year, by no means an explosion but in line with the demographic trends noted at the beginning of this chapter. Urban figures are less common, yet for Genoa 1150-1250 a sample of wills

Agriculture and Rural Life

Birth Rate

Higher

Births (Natural trend) Inverse Relation Births and Deaths

Death Rate

Malthusian Equilibrium At lower death rate Death Rate 2

constant birth date At lower death rate

Higher Inverse relation

population & income .. Higher Birth Rate

Population Number

income trend line

Lower Income

Income per Person

Figure 2.4. Malthusian Population and Incomes (adapted from Gregory Clark, A Farewell to Alms. Princeton, 2007, p. 27).

indicates 2.5 offspring for couples with children, far below the rural numbers. If reliable, this suggests, as most scholars assume, that medieval cities were not the engines of demographic growth and relied on rural migrants to sustain and increase their populations.

The reasons for this population growth are complicated. The standard

Malthusian model (more land~more food~more people) posits a strict relationship between the food supply and population levels in a traditional closed economy. At best, food supplies expand by incremental arithmetic growth if all

goes well, while uncontrolled population growth is geometric. Where the lines cross, the equilibrium means subsistence at this population level, but no more. The model suggests this grim paradox — raising the death rate increases the standard of living and that will eventually enable families to have more children — more pie, more people. Another way of looking at this dynamic is to assume a Malthusian equilibrium where life expectancy at birth is the inverse of the death rate. Hence, only by limiting births can life expectancy increase — here is another paradox: peace, good hygiene, and weather will reduce the standard of living and eventually the population as well. (See Figure 2.4) Gregory Clark,

an advocate of the Malthusian model, also assumes that wealth alone is the most important factor in the Malthusian model because changes in its levels,

65

66

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000—1500

the standard of living, influence everything else — consumption, lifestyles, and natality. This is true because the great mass of people, peasants, spent virtually all their income on food, clothing, and shelter, leaving to the tiny number of rich elites among the warriors and the clergy the opportunity to consume more. Yet, only the warriors put some of these resources into larger families, the clergy, monks, and nuns were officially celibate. Overall population trends depended on marriages and births among the peasants. Even a 0.5 percent annual growth rate over centuries can double and triple population figures and confound the dismal Malthusian predictions about the necessary link between births and deaths. The numbers suggest that an increase in births provided the impetus behind population increases. The injunction to be fruitful and multiply had not been repealed, and farming needs children. Avoiding offspring within marriage was considered an immoral act, even as the Church stressed the values of celibacy and virginity. A greater emphasis on the infant Jesus was part of an evolving

attitude toward childhood that cherished offspring and encouraged natality. Greater numbers of births appear likely. Without much data on death rates, we do not think that people were living much longer than they had before. Political stability (the benefit of feudal society?) and no lethal epidemics probably reduced death rates. General trends in agricultural productivity presumably led to dietary improvements for women as subtle as more amino acids from lentils and meat products became more widely available. Increases in the food supply and the teachings of the Church lessened the extent of infanticide, which in traditional pagan societies had fallen more heavily on women. One constant was that women, even healthy ones, continued to die from the complications of childbirth, though this leveled off at menopause and after that women lived a bit longer than men. European societies knew that attitudes about the proper age at first marriage were a means to control births provided that there were strong social sanctions against illegitimacy. In some parts of Europe, particularly in the Mediterranean, we see evidence that delaying marriage for women and men was indeed a way to conserve resources and in practice control the number of children. Every year that a teenage girl did not marry lessened the number of children she might bear. Every year that she waited to marry increased the dowry her father had to pay and at a certain point made it less likely that she would ever marry. Peasant men needed to control some land and establish themselves before they were ready to establish a new household or burden their parents with a

Agriculture and Rural Life

wife and new babies under the same roof. This matriage model, derived from southern sources, posits a relatively young age for women at first marriage, usually between fifteen and seventeen years of age, although the sources record plenty of younger wives. Men waited until their mid-twenties or even late twenties to marry. How common this marriage pattern was in northern Europe remains intensely disputed. Some evidence in the north suggests that women there married later but still younger than their husbands. But the demographic results from the models are interesting. The relatively young age of the women increased the child-bearing years and contributed to rural population growth in the twelfth and thirteen centuries. The age gap between spouses meant that this society would produce a number of widows, able to control property and serve as guardians and helpers to their children. Men were older fathers and may have identified with the carpenter St. Joseph, who was often portrayed as the elderly husband to a younger wife.

Many factors affected the age at first marriage besides a desire to control the size and shape of the households resulting from these unions. For example, higher rents and more crowded tenancies may have forced peasant men to spend more years acquiring the wherewithal to marry. Migrating to new lands made marriage easier. Maybe better diets were driving down the age of menarche (still a few years later than today’s 11.5 years) and enabling women to bear more children over their lifetimes, even as pregnancy remained arisk to their health. Women had the ability to limit pregnancy by using safe and effective means of contraception — pessaries containing compounds

acting as spermicides or

ones interfering with implanting fertilized eggs in the womb. To what extent peasant women used these practices or abortion is unknown, but more children were assets to peasant families. Family size argues that peasant women were enduring multiple pregnancies during their fertile years. Even allowing for the terrible levels of childhood mortality perhaps 50 percent between birth and age ten, better-nourished rural women saw more of their offspring into adulthood. Agriculture and rural life were the basis of a functioning European society and economy. Increased agricultural productivity fueled demographic growth and resulted from a rational exploitation of the land and its people. Entrepreneurship began in the countryside with people building up and rationalizing holdings. Landlords, warrior or monastic, should have encouraged these efforts, as the

Lorris statutes indicate. The warrior class assumed the duty of protecting society from bandits and predatory neighboring lords and coerced the peasants into supporting them. States still existed and were occasionally able to defend

67

68

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000—1500

peasants, whose own families were also a place of refuge and self-help. These behaviors formed, in the West, a complex, feudal milieu in which ties of obedience percolated through society. All theories advanced to explain economic development, which is sustained growth over a long period of time, can shed light on medieval increases in agricultural productivity. There is no reason to assume that this growth was evenly constant and occurred everywhere in Europe. A new model for England posits slower growth from about 1000 to the mid-twelfth century and then a transition to a more rapid period of growth extending to the fourteenth century. Studies of Danish resources suggest a moderate population growth rate in the twelfth and early thirteenth centuries, still checked by famines, and faster growth for the balance of the thirteenth century. A favorable climate and the absence of great disasters, such as massive epidemics, storms, volcanoes, or earthquakes, helped more people to raise bigger crops. European agriculture was no miracle but instead depended on more secure property rights and social status that gave peasants incentives to improve their circumstances, even

while supporting the lordly class living on their rents. Elites certainly had more luxuries and comforts during the twelfth and thirteenth centuries — all generated by hard work. European society had not escaped the Malthusian limits defined by the resource base on its numbers, but it had extended these limits by bringing more land under cultivation after the crisis years in the tenth century. We have no good way to measure whether the average peasant was better off in 1250 than in 950 — but there were certainly many more of them by the later date. Institutions as humble as a village commune served to improve the bargaining rights of peasants who were able to slowly erode the

harshest features of serfdom. The unfettered market was not the panacea for all economic and indeed social ills. Self-sufficiency was a hallowed ideal but people lived in the real world of buying and selling. Commercialization was a two-way street and affected family size in the rural and urban areas. It is time to draw the connections between the stories of lands, lords, and peasants, and the revival of another aspect of the market — trade.

SELECT BIBLIOGRAPHY

Peter Biller, The Measure of Multitude. Oxford, 2000. Thomas N. Bisson, The Crisis of the Twelfth Century: Power, Lordship, and the Origins of European Government. Princeton, 2008.

Agriculture and Rural Life

Marc Bloch, Feudal Society. Chicago, 1961. Pierre Bonnassie, From Slavery to Serfdom in South-Western Europe. Cambridge, 1991. Robin A. Butlin and Robert A. Dodgshon, editors, An Historical Geography of Europe. Oxford, 1998. Gregory Clark, A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World. Princeton, 2007.

Philippe Contamine et al., L’économie médiévale. Paris, 2003. José Enrique Ruiz-Doménec, Ricard Guillem: Un sogno per Barcellona. Naples, 1999. Georges Duby, The Three Orders: Feudal Society Imagined. Chicago, 1980. David Herlihy, editor, The History of Feudalism. New York, 1970. Rodney Hilton, Class Conflict and the Crisis of Feudalism. London, 1990. Gary Holthaus, From the Farm to the Table. Lexington, KY, 2006. Nils Hybel and Bjgrn Poulsen, The Danish Resources c. 1000-1500. Leiden, 2007. Angeliki E. Laiou, The Economic History of Byzantium. Washington DC, 2002. John Langdon and James Masschaele, “Commercial Activity and Population Growth in Medieval England," Past and Present 190 (2006):35—81.

N. J. G. Pounds, An Historical Geography of Europe. Cambridge, 1990. Zvi Razi, Life, Marriage and Death in a Medieval Parish: Economy, Society and Demography in Halesown 1270-1400. Cambridge, 1980. Susan Reynolds, Fiefs and Vassals. Oxford, 1994. Jean-Claude Schmitt, The Holy Greyhound. Cambridge, 1983.

y TRADE

1000-1350

HE

TOPIC

OF

TRADE

INCLUDES

EXCHANGES

RANGING

FROM

buying eggs or a field from a neighbor to the most exotic commodities crossing the Silk Road linking China and the West. Dazzling long-distance ventures, for example, the travels of the Polos of Venice, have too often obscured the local and regional trading networks and old markets for land that were the backbone of the economy. Erik the Red found Greenland just as our period began and Marco Polo had returned from China and dictated his adventures there by the late 1290s. Expanding horizons of Europeans and the vast profits from long-distance trade have masked the deep currents of humbler commerce in grain, salt, and wood. Still, an analysis of trade opens up Europe's frontiers and reminds us that this part of western Eurasia was not a closed system but rather increasingly depended on linkages to the wider worlds of the Middle East, East Asia, and Africa. The period from the tenth century to the plague witnessed the rise of the first world system of trading in which these disparate regions formed, to some extent, a common market that brought prosperity to its participants. Travelers, pilgrims, conquerors, scholars, and adventurers also frequented the routes that the merchants used and fostered communications among the big regions. Innovations and best practices spread quickly, from forms of contracts and systems of numbers, to gunpowder and the compass. Men and women on the roads and seas do not make a new economic system unless their contacts lead to changes of behavior and not just merely news from the wider world. Trade, as the Florentine businessman Francesco Pegolotti defined it in the early fourteenth century, was business: the work of buying and selling. Because most merchants did not sell the fruits of their own handicraft, trade involved travel as merchants and goods circulated in local, regional, and international 70

Trade 1000-1350

markets. A market is a place where business takes place in a protected setting. Markets are also places where people allocated resources based on supply and demand, which they studied closely. Pegolotti, whose own business experiences as an agent took him across much of Europe, knew that in his native Tuscany the market was mercato, and in other related dialects the piazza, the open setting where merchants displayed their wares. He credited the Genoese with bringing the Persian bazarra (bazaar) to Europe, and in other Eastern contexts the word

fondaco, on Cyprus afonda (as it was also known in Spain), denoted a protected place for businessmen to lodge. Another Arabic word, sugo (suk) also meant market from Andalusia across North Africa into the Middle East. In Greek, the

Italianized panichiero was also a hostelry for merchants, and in Flemish alla (hall) was the same thing, a familiar word in all the Germanic-speaking lands. Great merchants and humble local retailers frequented these markets, and we will examine their urban spaces in Chapter 4. Here our main goal is to understand the rise and significance of long-distance trade. A standard story about the rise of trade has for centuries dominated accounts

of European economic development, and it goes something like this. Land, labor, and capital are the basic factors of production. A school of economic

thought taught by the physiocrats contended that land was the basis of any productive economy, and we have put agriculture first partly as a result of that traditional privileging of farming. Land cannot move, however, and those

observers struck by mobility as a powerful economic force have focused on labor — people and capital — a surplus in the form of goods or money that can also travel. Mercantilists believed that a society's wealth derived from a favorable balance of trade, and so they charted movements

of labor and

commodities, finding prosperity where surpluses accumulated. Because gold

and silver surpluses testified to successful trading, this school of economic thought is also known as “bullionist." This approach also assumed that there was something about the human character that relished buying and selling, negotiating, and bartering, that thrived on the ambitions, relationships, and experience of business as well as the goods acquired in the process. Mercantilism as a state policy found its name in early modern Europe, but its assumptions stretch back deep into the Middle Ages. For if a favorable balance of trade was the main way to explain the wealth and poverty of nations, then

the monarch or ruling group's job was to negotiate or compel favorable trading terms with neighbors. Adam Smith (1723-1790) did not view trade as a zero-

sum game in which some grew rich and others poor but the mass of wealth

Vl

Te.

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

remained the same. Instead, he stressed comparative advantages by which each society or economy developed its market strengths and strongest products and

traded for equally improved items from others. According to this theory, each society would use its resources in the most profitable way to excel at some production that would command market share. Advantages to consumers were derived from the great range of excellent goods that would become available to them, provided that trade was free and governments or interest groups did not succeed in rigging the terms of trade to benefit themselves and not consumers. Smith's understanding of the benefits of free markets and rational choices by consumers to maximize their own comfort has become central to the standard story of how trade played the dominant role in the ways the European economy developed from the ninth century to the plague of 1348. If this theory is true, then any innovations that foster the smooth and fair functioning of a market economy will benefit trade and hence prosperity for the greatest number of people. Modern theorists have focused attention on institutions that secure property rights and reliable legal systems that bring the benefits of trade to those taking the risks on land and sea. Institutions, as defined by Avner Greif, are simply “systems of social factors that conjointly generate a regularity of behavior.” In other words, we need to explore collections of motives, rules, and beliefs that shape how people behave and make choices about how they work, consume, and trade. Examples of these institutions range from merchant guilds and trading companies to treaties and merchant law and courts. The purpose of these institutions is to make behavior predictable, in order to minimize risk and allow rational people the chance to make plans or investments that will pay off in a future that they can envision. Merchants were not yet able to use mathematics to calculate risk, and they understood that uncertainties in the form of sickness or natural disasters might strike at any moment. Game theory, really the study of human behavior in making choices, stresses how one's optimal behavior depends on the ways other people act. At equilibrium the results are best for all, which is exactly how Smith saw the benefits of free trade. But game theory is a bit more subtle and stresses how this equilibrium is not a unique solution but instead evolves over time and depends on

the concrete historical context in which people make these choices. Economics is after all simply the science by which we study human choices about consumption. Society is the surrounding context in which people live and make choices. To find the roots of increased medieval trade and prosperity resulting from it, we will want to focus on how, where, and why some people changed

Trade 1000-1350

their behaviors. Farming, praying, and fighting no longer constitute the entire set of choices. Current models for understanding trade view it as a transaction — a socioeconomic behavior that changes over time as the rules people make improve the outcomes. A consensus on transparency holds that these transactions benefit all parties when they occur in an environment that encourages honesty and predictability in making contracts. As we will see, medieval people spent a lot of time worrying about the language of contracts, the reliability and standards of weights and measures, the soundness of the currency, and other matters. These

positive circumstances — enforceable contracts, clear numbers and quantities, and sound money — reduced transaction costs and hence made trade more

efficient and profitable. They were especially important when traders ventured beyond their own group to trade with peoples who spoke different languages and believed in other creeds. In these long-distance trades, where trust was harder to maintain, self-interest could still drive very different people to strike deals. Game theory assumes that different cultures share the same rational self-interest that has been part of economic thinking for centuries. Institutions themselves are also actors that affect the behaviors of people inside and outside of the institutions. The guild of butchers made rules for their own labors. Their customs influenced consumers, young people hoping to enter the trade, and governments trying to protect the common good by securing safe supplies of meat, which was a task not always safely left to the guild. Institutions are not human beings, but the rules and rational people share one trait — predictable

behavior. This aspect of culture will help explain, for example, why the guild of Christian butchers excluded Jews. Consumers looking for the best products and prices stimulated tensions between groups of butchers separated by their faiths.

MERCHANTS The history of trade is the story of how medieval people exchanged commodi-

ties and profited by moving them from places where they were plentiful and cheap to where they were scarcer and hence more expensive. We have already looked at how peasants produced some agricultural products, and in Chapter 4 we will look at manufacturing and handicraft production. For the moment, we will be focusing on local and international markets for exchanging goods and the institutions and techniques that facilitated trade. We will enter these

#3

74

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

markets as medieval merchants and travelers did, as people behaving in certain new ways. There is a venerable tradition in medieval economic and social history that seeks out the first traders and tries to explain why the traditions appeared where and when they did. These heroic entrepreneurs have become

staples in economic models seeking to explain the process of commercialization or the rise of markets and trade. Hence, we begin with people. This method of proceeding, however, cannot be separated from the problems of the primary sources.

A fortuitous survival of a mass of miscellaneous records in a storeroom of the Maghrebi synagogue in Cairo has provided amazing details on the networks linking Jewish traders from Andalusia (Muslim Spain) across Sicily and North Africa through Cairo to points east bordering on the Indian Ocean. Without the details provided by a few contracts and letters, we would have to depend on sketchy narrative sources to show that this trade even existed. What little we know about the dominant majority of Muslim traders and merchants from Rum in Christian Europe comes from these same Egyptian sources until Italian records begin to appear in sufficient quantities in the twelfth century in Genoa and Venice. Tantalizing references to merchants from Amalfi, as early as the tenth century, suggest that these intrepid southern Italians led the way in opening up northern Mediterranean trade in Egypt in the tenth and eleventh centuries. The loss of local records and the triumph of Amalfi's rivals makes this trade very hard to document. Still, we know that the Amalfitans were great merchants and travelers who made their way to Jerusalem in sufficient numbers

as pilgrims before the first crusade of 1095 to justify having their own hospice there. Hints and fragments of information before regular runs of documents were kept suggest a revival of long-distance trade in the Mediterranean, North, and Baltic seas. Later, better sources illuminate this trade. Because we are starting with the merchants, the inevitable question is: who were they? Both the items that they traded and the methods by which they could trust one another mattered. Their identities are worth considering first. The search for a nascent merchant class within the feudal milieu has inevitably focused on a few entrepreneurial lords and peasants. Some members of the lordly class made the not-always-sharp jump from raider or pirate to trader. Even some intrepid fishermen put to their boats to unexpected uses when the fishermen became merchants. These clues indicate that feudal society and those embodying its values were the obvious candidates to branch out into new activities. There was no innate hostility between feudal society and the rise of

Trade 1000-1350

trade or indeed capitalism. Even ports and cities, islands of ostensible refuge for peasants and even lords, were parts of the system of growth and exchange on which trade depended from its inception. The great Belgian economic historian Henri Pirenne argued almost a century ago that the career of St. Godric of Finchale was a marvelous vignette that explained how at least one merchant got his start from nothing. Godric began life in late eleventh-century English Lincolnshire as a poor peasant with no resources. However, his area of the coast, facing the North Sea, proved to be

fertile ground for beachcombing. Godric began to gather up what scraps he could find from Viking and Flemish wrecks and whatever else was washing up on the shore. (Often this jetsam belonged to the king, but he was not there to claim it.) A lucky find enabled Godric to become a peddler who slowly traded his wares into a larger stock of goods. He eventually became a merchant

with contacts and business across the North Sea. Now we know about Godric because he experienced a spiritual conversion that put him on to the path to poverty and sanctity and hence a saint's life from which these details come. His previous career, the proverbial rags-to-riches story, demonstrated how a canny sense of markets rewarded those with the ambition and luck to better themselves. Godric's story is unique. Behind every successful merchant family there was often some entrepreneurial founder of the family's fortune, and at least a few of them must have sprung from the most-populated social class — the peasantry. Of course, the story begs the question of origins — where did the Vikings get things to lose in a shipwreck? They might have been simple thieves but even that status presumes that that there must have been some wealthier victims in the vicinity to pillage. We naturally ask: where did they get their wealth? Hence, the seductive and generally pointless search for ultimate origins, but there is still some value in looking for the source of a merchant class, because they cannot all have been men like Godric. Yet, we can accept that the psychological makeup of some peasant farmers drove them to comb a beach rather than to plow afield. Some people, such as Jews, excluded from ordinary economic activities could become itinerant peddlers. Trading small plots of land taught peasants something about bargaining and value. Robert S. Lopez, in the 1930s, used good records for medieval Genoa that

enabled him to propose a hypothesis about how that city became an important trading center. These circumstances are not unique to Genoa but relate to all those places where feisty rural nobility looked for new opportunities. These nobles, a collection of people descending from the old Carolingian

Te)

76

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

aristocracy and some new men, controlled the countryside, the local church, and marshaled what wealth local agriculture produced. They also enjoyed a small stream of cash rents in the form of silver pennies. This money presup-

poses the existence of local markets and fairs. Local alliances among nobles and private wars at times, in the absence of a strong local power, led to anarchy. Troubled times and fragmented power in a small port like Genoa meant that opportunities for trade existed. These potential merchants needed to find markets. They needed customer and suppliers. Agriculture and some booty from piracy provided the capital, and local sailors and fishermen had sufficient knowledge and timber to make small ships that were capable of voyaging across the Mediterranean. This story so far fits the scraps of information we have about tenth-century Genoa. We also know that by the time of the First Crusade in 1098, Genoa and other ports had sufficient naval power to bring supplies to the armies besieging Antioch. In the interval, a merchant class had appeared and taken over the city from its bishop and count — this too happened elsewhere. Modified versions of the story also existed elsewhere — in Venice, the local nobles, from the beginning, drew their wealth from the fisheries and salt pans of the Po River estuary, not directly from peasants. Yet, some take-off had occurred. Trade cannot exist without markets, and no one thinks that there was enough local consumer demand or products in places, such as Amalfi, Pisa, or Barcelona, to account for the rise of commerce. We are postponing the discussion of commodities for the moment, but we need to consider right now questions of distance — where were these potential suppliers and customers if not in the ports? The initial items of trade found everywhere in the region consisted of mix of exotic high-price luxuries, such as pepper and silks, and humbler items of mass consumption, such as the salt necessary for the human diet and also the best preservative available. Our potential merchants were close students

of these matters, and they had the resources to invest in the first bags of salt or spices to move from where they were relatively cheap to where they could yield a profit. For every beachcomber turned peddler, there must have been hundreds of men, with resources or skills and knowledge that other men and women investors would trust with their resources, to engage in this trade. The search for markets made these merchants itinerant, indeed, great travelers moving goods from A to B. They sailed the Baltic, North, and Mediterranean seas and found their ways up rivers and over mountain passes with whatever goods that increased in value by moving across these distances.

Trade 1000-1350

Scholars have known that these first-generation entrepreneurial types in Europe had one other obvious advantage. They had more prosperous neighbors — in the Muslim world stretching from Andalusia in southern Iberia across all of North Africa into the East, and an old and well-integrated market system in the Byzantine Empire centered on the Aegean. Although partly in Europe, these richer and more-developed areas opened up from the beginning European horizons to Africa and Asia. The Geniza records, among other sources, reveal that these people already had well-established commerce before the first intrepid person from Rum entered their markets in the tenth century. The

nearest neighbors, of course, had advantages. Venice's links to Constantinople, forged in late antiquity, were never broken. Amalfi was close enough to what remained of Byzantine Italy to have similar benefits. But all distance is relative, and news of the wealth of Byzantium and the world of Islam perco-

lated across seas and rivers, along with the goods and cash, to find interested raiders and traders as far away as Novgorod. Swedish traders, for example, were farthest from their wealthy neighbors, but the great rivers of eastern Europe flowed south to the Black Sea and potential lessons. The important point here is the advantage of having wealthy neighbors to serve as suppliers, sources of information, and even booty to jump-start their poorer neighbors. Lopez's search for the origins of a merchant class led him to people who were as perfectly capable of pillaging Muslim shipping in search of capital as they were of squeezing the silver out of their peasants. At a certain point, the

interests of the potential merchants resemble the story of the goose laying the golden egg. Too frequently, resorting to violence was not a long-term solution to the problem of gaining wealth. Eventually Muslim targets would disappear or

become tougher to seize. Peasants might run away or fight back. Even bandits benefited from settling down and reaching agreements with local people. So these potential merchants were quasinoble pirates capable of envisioning a more regular future, in which taking a chance on peaceful trade was, in fact,

less risky that pillage or extortion. In the north, the Vikings had learned the same lessons as their large treasure hoards of Muslim and English silver testify. To look for the origins of the European commercial revolution on its prosperous fringes seems to beg the question about indigenous development on several levels. The explanations for the continued vitality of trade in the Muslim and

Byzantine worlds are off of the table, out of sight, and are simply a preexisting condition for Europe's growth. These exogenous factors cannot be discounted — nor can they be the entire story. Having prosperous neighbors can be a trap

77

78

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000—1500

to the economic development of the less-advanced region. If merchants and raiders simply prey on or colonize their unfortunate, poorer victims, then the latter cannot borrow or steal what they need to sustain endogenous growth. The Slavic and Albanian Adriatic coast is an example of this phenomenon —it became the early medieval “slave coast” because its most important resource, people, was pillaged for centuries by all its neighbors and then traded to the Muslim and Western and Eastern Christian worlds into this period and beyond. Some clues indicate how these commercial relationships actually developed. Muslim merchants were completely unwelcome in Christian ports in the eleventh and twelfth centuries. Any that turned up out of innocence or bad weather would find themselves captives and their goods seized. In theory, Byzantine traders would be safe but in practice very few ever appear outside their eastern sphere of influence in the western Mediterranean. Westerners traveled south and east, and those too far away from the Mediterranean to go themselves ended up trading with those that did through intermediary mechanisms, such as the Volga River system or the Fairs of Champagne (more below). For whatever complex and fortuitous reasons, Western Christian merchants generally found a safe welcome as customers in Muslim and Byzantine ports. From time to time bad relations caused Western merchants grief, and they and their goods were seized — this happened to the Genoese in Egypt around 1100 as a result of crusader conquests in the Holy Land. But, in general, Western merchants were welcomed in the East because they had a reputation for paying high prices for second-rate goods and were therefore a bonanza to local merchants. In reality, the foreign merchants brought rivalries and trouble with them. In 1171, the Venetians sacked the Genoese merchant quarter in Constantinople and also seized some ships and cargoes at sea. In faraway Acre, a rich terminus of the caravan trade across Asia, a vicious war broke out in 1257 between the Genoese and Catalans on the one hand and the Venetians, Pisans, and Provengals on the other. This War of St. Sabas involved other powers but was fundamentally a struggle over lucrative trading privileges in the East. In one disaster in 1258, the Genoese lost more than 1,700 men and many ships. Indigenous rulers in the East had to tolerate this violence and sometimes even compensate Western victims because force as well as self-interest determined the terms of this lucrative trade. At first Muslim, Byzantine, and crusader rulers tolerated Western merchants like geese that every year could be counted on to turn up in Constantinople, Acre, Tunis, Alexandria, and other places. This asymmetry in relations points to the important roles violence and the threat

Trade 1000-1350

of violence played in the actual ways commerce developed during these first centuries of the commercial revolution. Privileged trade opened the door to

concessions extorted at the point of a sword.

TECHNIQUES OF TRADE Trade happened when a merchant bought low and sold at a higher price. Trade flourished when merchants figured out many ways to make markets function more smoothly. At every step of the process of buying, transporting, and selling commodities, merchants invented or transformed institutions and methods of doing business. Those in the Mediterranean had the advantage of seeing and

borrowing whatever best practices they observed in the Muslim and Byzantine systems. Traders in the north, farther from these stimuli, devised many similar strategies, demonstrating that rational self-interest was capable of producing profitable trade in different settings. Starting once again with the people, we will follow these merchants along their trade routes in search of markets. Where traders stayed and how they made deals are central to understanding trade. Also, from the beginning merchants were concerned about their security and wanted privileges that provided optimum conditions for their businesses. Many of these privileges concerned customs duties and tolls — the easiest ways to tax trade. Rulers had an interest in siphoning off some of these profits, but too much skimmed would push trade toward more favorable places and terms. Where merchants ran their own affairs and decided tax questions, their policies reveal a nice understanding of the risks and benefits of ostensibly free trade. Trade required a venue, a market, open periodically. Traders must have a place to stay and store their goods, as well as a means to travel safely and to avoid as much as possible paying vexatious tolls. Where tolls were reasonable and predictable, they were no real barriers to trade. If tolls became predatory, merchants could choose to go elsewhere and did. They also needed ways to

learn these things — hence the value of guides and merchant lore. Merchants also required skills in numbers and written words that make records and contracts possible. Above all, they wanted a favorable climate that reduced as many risks as possible. Trade was a hard way to make a living, and crimes, such as theft, forgery, and piracy, could make things worse. Two inheritances from late antiquity in Byzantium, the xenodochium, a charitable hostelry, and the pandocheion, a proper inn for travelers, provided easy and open access for merchants, pilgrims, and other travelers. Muslim merchants

79

80

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

and rulers adapted these institutions into the versatile funduq, a secure place for merchants and their goods. These commercialized places catered to Muslim merchants and were fixtures in every city. By the eleventh century, the Byzantines were borrowing back ina sense these evolved institutions and establishing them for their own traders. At the very beginning of the revival of commerce, these funduq offered havens for Western traders as well. By 1000, Amalfitan

and Byzantine merchants were present in these places in the Muslim world. In the twelfth century, the original sources on these fundug thicken. Pisa secured privileges for its merchants to use one in Egypt in 1154 and joined Venice and Genoa in securing safe havens in recently conquered ports in Latin Syria. This type of place, grander than a simple inn and warehouse, became a true merchant quarter, known in Italian dialects as a fondaco. A fondaco had houses, a church, an oven, cemetery, baths, and whatever else the travelers need to feel at home. In Muslim territories, Western merchants usually had to be content with more modest arrangements. In Spain, rulers of Castile and Aragon acquired fundugs in conquered Muslim cities, such as Valencia, and found them to be useful institutions for attracting and taxing foreign merchants. In turn, Catalan merchants acquired North African fondacos overseas in Muslim Tunis in 1253 and Bougie in 1259. In 1228, Venice began building a great fondaco for the German merchants in order to encourage them to come to Venice and trade. The emerging patterns support the already established asymmetries in trade

arrangements. For whatever reasons, and we will explore them below in this chapter, Muslim states often found it prudent and profitable to grant these trading facilities to Western merchants. These Westerners also sought privileges in Constantinople and access to the Black Sea trade routes from the Byzantines. Christian states on the northern shores of the Mediterranean sometimes provided these facilities to other Western Christian traders, but never to Muslims or even Byzantines.

In the north, German merchants found a similar path to privileged trade and security. In the tenth and eleventh centuries, these Germans began to replace the Frisians as the most important continental traders. Two key events leading to this path are the founding of the port of Ltibeck in 1159 and the privileges Henry II of England gave the merchants of Cologne in 1157. Ltibeck became the model for a great trading town that served as the linchpin of the German Hanse, which began as an association of merchants. Cologne merchants active in the wine trade wanted a secure place, eventually called a guildball in London, elsewhere a kontor. The period 1150-1250 witnessed the rise of the Hanse and

Trade 1000-1350

German merchants as a great trading route developed connecting the arc of cities from London to Bruges, Hamburg, Liibeck, Reval (founded in 1219), and Novgorod — all connected by waterways to hinterlands. Outside the German lands these merchants depended on the protection of foreign rulers to sustain their trading in the face of rivals like the Flemings, Danes, and Norwegians. (The Dutch stayed out of the Hanse and were not yet an important factor in northern trade.) Danish export trade in cattle and horses relied on driving these animals over land routes and required markets but not big cities. Another axis of this trade stretched from the Swedish island of Gotland and its main port Visby south through the German cities and then west to the Fairs of Champagne where they linked up with Mediterranean networks or east to Riga (founded in 1201) and points south toward the Black Sea. The important development here is how the German merchants, who shared

a common language but were increasingly left to fend for themselves by fragmented states and weak rulers, reduced their risks by seeking common privileges for trade as well as securing merchant quarters. Their famous Steelyard in London isa tribute to their importance to the economic life of England's capital, and a clue to what commodities mattered in this trade. In the north, German merchants thrived by a judicious mix of new trading cities and kontore in established ports. Unlike the Italians in the Mediterranean with their proverbial fierce rivalries, the German Hanse was at first a great confederation of merchants from many cities. In the later Middle Ages, the league of cities became the predominant feature of the Hanse, but this development was in response to challenges after the plague, a problem with consequences in the Mediterranean as well. The Germans faced English, Flemish, and Norwegian rivals in the west and Russians in the east, but all these powers were Christian, unlike the circumstances the Italians faced in the south. Yet, the common theme remained: a search for regular, predictable trade conducted under set rules in a secure environment. In many places, local merchants resented the Germans, but their access to capital

and profits made them indispensable to local rulers and producers. Merchants required markets, places where buyers and sellers could find one another. Retailers in small towns could provide some items, but even they needed to be stocked. Medieval consumers and merchants relied on fairs, which were periodic markets that attracted travelers to a safe place to conduct business. One of the oldest regular fairs in Europe was held under the auspices of the royal abbey of St. Denis, which twice a year sponsored the Lendit Fair in

a field just outside Paris. Tracing its origins back to Carolingian times, this fair

81

82

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

~ Principal commerce routes “~~ Secondary commerce routes @ Principal fair O Secondary fair © City

Figure 3.1. Fairs of Champagne (map by Keith A. French and Darin Grauberger, University of Kansas Cartographic Services).

gave the monks a regular income from fees the traders paid to have the abbey’s reputation guarantee their peaceful trade. Nearby, perhaps in the late tenth but certainly over the course of the eleventh century, the counts of Champagne sponsored a series of fairs in the main towns of their region (see Figure 3.1). The four sites of these fairs became Troyes, the count's seat and an old Roman settlement, Provins, a castle and then a considerable weaving town, Bar-surAube, a major crossroads, and Lagny, a monastic center. Six fairs running in through the year in roughly two-month cycles made the region attractive to merchants coming from Flanders and above all the Italians from the south. From the Fair of the Holy Innocents in January through the famous Lenten, May,

Trade 1000-1350

St. Jean's, St. Ayoul, and finally the fair of St. Remi before Christmas, these

events gave merchants a schedule for traveling, arranging transport of goods, and setting up their stalls for selling. A series of astute counts, notable feudal lords, and ardent crusaders, fostered these fairs because they rivaled Paris and brought prosperity and income to the local nobility and their townspeople. The count provided laws of the fairs, guardians, safe roads and places to stay, speedy resolution of disputes, and predictability in exchange for moderate fees. In 1209, the king of France also

extended his protection to merchants traveling to the fairs. Many notaries, both local and traveling with the merchants, redacted contracts for the exchange, often on credit, of northern money and cloth for spices, eastern imports, and other luxuries that the Italians hauled north up the Rhone or over the Alpine passes. Lombards and later bankers from Cahors provided money-changing services and some credit while Jews were left with pawn-brokering services to lesser clients. The fairs became venues for settling international debts and

credits. A new contract, the bill of exchange, developed as a contract facilitating the transfer of money by contract rather than by hauling around bags of silver pennies. At these fairs, Latin remained the written international language of contracts. French speakers, regardless of their ethnic origins, enjoyed advantages, and interpreters earned good livings. The fairs thrived in the late twelfth and early thirteenth centuries, providing an important clearinghouse for goods and money between the Flemings in Bruges, the merchants of the Hanse, and the Italians from the south, sometimes organized, as in the case of Siena, into a corporate body that traveled together for safety. These successful fairs are another sign that feudal society was well suited to take advantage of geography and fairs to increase everyone's prosperity. This has all the hallmarks of policy. Two later developments made the fairs of Champagne less significant economic events. When the county fell to the French monarchy in 1285, the Flemings, long-term rivals of the French, were harassed and found trading there difficult. Also, the Italians, principally the Venetians and Genoese, were exploring the prospects for direct sea connections by galley service from the Mediterranean to a central place like Bruges. These sailings became regular by the 1290s. Also, merchant and banking companies found ways to establish permanent connections in the north through resident partners in places, such as London, and this made annual arduous travel less necessary. The fairs stopped mattering in the late thirteenth century and ended altogether in the aftermath of the Black Death. Other places, such as Lyon,

83

84

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

Avignon, Copenhagen, Augsburg, and Nuremberg, emerged at various times in the later Middle Ages as convenient entrepots for traders to meet. Local mar-

ket fairs and lesser regional fairs continued everywhere trade occurred across Europe. The services, information, and goods that these events provided were essential to integrating the European economy.

CONTRACTS AND NUMBERS A merchant class has appeared and traveled long and short distances to buy and sell goods. These traders also needed a system of law, and in Chapter 4 a look at town government and political economy will provide the best context for exploring the legal framework for commerce, work, and other economic activities. The focus here is to examine the art of the deal — how merchants made contracts and used these instruments to conduct their activities more efficiently. A vast amount of medieval business always occurred on a handshake and an oral agreement, depending on the reputation of the parties, to enforce the terms. Local business did not always benefit from elaborate written records. The deals that needed time to mature were the ones that could not rely on memory alone to enforce them. Some minority groups, such as the Jews, with no good recourse to wider legal enforcement mechanisms, always had to depend on their own relatives and coreligionists as the most reliable partners and traders. They had their own languages, notaries, and customs about commerce. Even among the majority groups, some business always occurred outside the formal and somewhat costly setting of written contracts. These documents, which become so ubiquitous over the course of the twelfth and thirteenth centuries, provide the main evidence for a revolution in the methods of commerce. The problem for economic historians is that we do not have a first example of any contract. Initial runs of documents, from the notarial cultures of the south and at first Genoa, reveal business practices already old before the first evidence that survives. Also, we know well that Muslim and Byzantine commerce also relied on written contracts that may have inspired their Western rivals to borrow these sensible practices. The classic contract is the commenda, a partnership between two traders — one who traveled and one who stayed home. In its starkest terms, the traveling merchant took some capital (cash or commodities) from an investor to put to work in a common enterprise that may have had many partners. A traveler,

off to Alexandria or the fairs of Champagne, promised to put this capital to

Trade 1000-1350

work in the venture in exchange for one-quarter of the profit. He bore all of the risks of the venture, expenses came out of the joint capital, and his investor was liable for nothing except his or her own contribution. From the very beginning, especially where old Roman legal ideas still prevailed, women, especially widows, had the right to make contracts, and they appear early as investors. The efficiencies, incentives, and results all flowed from this simple arrangement. Investors, by finding multiple partners, could spread risk across ventures even as they often took contracts from others and ventured into the wider world. The traveler might have at first been without capital and what he offered his potential partners was perhaps the reputation of his own family and the ambition to make a start as a merchant. His one-quarter of the profit was of course elastic and motivated him to trade as profitably as possible by looking for the best deals and keeping his expenses low. Sometimes the contract stipulated that the traveler was to invest in a specific commodity, such as pepper, but

more often the details were left to his best judgment of the market he found far from home. Upon his return, the merchant settled with his partners, who of course bore the risk that he might disappear in the sea or the Alpine snows, or abscond with their capital, or simply trade poorly and make little or no profit. Year after year, investors and travelers accumulated the knowledge necessary to invest wisely in the best travelers who went to the most profitable venues. In a Venetian variant of the commenda, called the colleganza (early examples date from the 1070s), both parties usually contributed capital and divided the eventual profits according to rewards for shares and the labor the traveler put into the enterprise. As with all these contracts, the deal was for one venture — a voyage from Venice to Thebes or Genoa to Alexandria. In a bilateral commenda, known in the original sources as a societas, both partners contributed capital, ideally in equal shares, but the traveler, working harder and bearing the main risk, took the greater share of the profit, which was typically two-thirds. This variant of the contract suited those partners who had capital and wanted to see it on the table. Across the Mediterranean world from Lisbon to Caffa in Crimea, the parties went to a notary, ascribe skilled in writing down contracts into his cartulary or

notebook. He knew how to frame the contract in the proper legal terminology, and his contract, suitably witnessed, was legally enforceable. Often the parties kept no copy for themselves and instead relied upon the notarial cartulary as the copy of record. Copies cost money, and the notary's formal record sufficed and was often deposited with some public authority after the notary retired or died. This explains why some early cartularies survive — the most famous is from

85

86

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

the pen of the aptly named Giovanni Scriba of Genoa, whose work dates from the 1150s. The 1,306 acts of business in all forms in this collection include 335 contracts

for overseas commerce,

the vast majority commenda or societas

agreements. Another type of contract, the sea loan, appears in this cartulary. The traveler, in an example from 1157, going on a trading venture to Sardinia, borrowed fifteen lire and promised to repay twenty lire one month after his safe return. This important condition made the loan legally acceptable in Genoa because of the risk involved — if the traveler never returned for whatever reason, his heirs did not have to pay. The lender received a specific sum for this service, regardless of how profitable the voyage was. In practice, Genoese and other merchants overwhelmingly preferred the first two types of contracts because they were true partnerships and did not raise any vexing moral questions about interest on loans — which is discussed in Chapter 5. These contracts are a burst of information about trade rivaling the Geniza records for Egypt. Giovanni Scriba’s cartulary contains evidence of a sophisticated method of making contracts that was already up and running for many years before the first surviving examples. No indigenous economic traditions in Genoa can account for this method of making contracts. Genoese traders did not learn about contracts from reading old Roman legal texts about them. What little we know about Byzantine partnerships suggests that joint liability always remained a feature of those contracts. Byzantine merchants pooled investments but continued to share liabilities for the original investments. Old Muslim legal sources confirm the pattern found in the first surviving dirad contracts from the Geniza records that this flexible form of partnership shared risks, profits, but not liability. Whether the Arabs found or invented this style of contract remains uncertain. It is likely that Western merchants learned by watching somewhere in the Mediterranean this method of raising capital, and it suited flexible entrepreneurs and those pioneering new businesses. The surviving records show merchants using unilateral and bilateral commenda contracts to make deals with peasants about investing in herds of goats or sheep. As commerce developed, best practices spread across the Mediterranean world. The earliest surviving notarial records from Barcelona, Montpellier, Marseilles, Palermo, and other places all contain the basic forms. Travelers to the fairs in the north brought these practices with them, but the rarity of surviving commercial contracts from the north makes it hard to state exactly what form they took. Merchant law and court records suggest that partnerships prevailed and joint liability was a feature of companies, not deals. From the beginning the

Trade 1000-1350

notarial cartularies contained notices of other types of contracts — straight sales of goods or land, quitclaims by which a party acknowledged receipt of what

was owed, simple loans with artfully concealed interest payments, and wills (a contract with the living heirs among other things) that provide a snapshot of a merchant's activities and investments. Keeping an eye on the fortunes of the commenda contract is the best way to note changes in the circumstances of trade.

Whenever the percentage of this form, as opposed to all other types of business, begins to decline, it is usually a sign that more investments were slipping into longer-term arrangements, such as companies, and that some investors were employing agents overseas rather than forming partnerships with itinerant merchants. Activities at the fairs of Champagne during the thirteenth century probably facilitated the development of a new form of contract: the bill of exchange whereby a person borrowed money in one place, say, Siena, and

promised to pay at a different time, six months, in another place, Troyes, and in the currency prevalent there — livres. Money changers, and their partners and agents, were in the best position to make and deliver on these contracts, which facilitated trade and removed some of the risks of transporting cash.

These bills also became a way to advance credit and charge interest for what was in effect a concealed loan. A bill written on a person's reputation, rather than secured by pledges or guarantors, was risky. The best way to share risk, the insurance contract, first appeared after the plague and will be examined later in

Chapter 6. These contracts presume the ability to calculate numbers, to add up the total capital and figure one-quarter of the profit. Merchants had old tools to aid their mental skills, including the abacus, whose base-ten system of beads gave a visual tally, as did tally sticks with their notches and even checkerboard patterns of piles of coins for those who needed to see their sums. Leonardo Fibonacci of Pisa (c. 1170—c. 1240) in the early thirteenth century wrote a book on numbers, the Liber Abaci. One of the few personal details he supplies is that as a boy he spent time in the Pisan customhouse in Bougie in North Africa. There he may have first seen or learned about the marvelous new Arabic numbers, borrowed from the Indians and including the mysterious zepber as the Arabs called zero. Around this time, Arabic numerals began to appear in commercial documents, and they were a vast improvement over Roman and Greek systems of alphabetic

numerals. Fibonacci’s work was a practical introduction to the world of numbers for merchants and traders. He explained the basics of mathematics, as well as the

87

88

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

proportional or fractional way of determining values and weights of merchandise in different systems of measurement. Because barter, in his view, depended on a mental notion of price, that is, a number of some kind, merchants needed to be able to think abstractly about values, sizes, and weights. Fibonacci was a mathematical genius, and his practical math problems evoke the world of buying and selling from Constantinople and the crusader East to what is modern Algeria. He managed elementary algebra without the modern notation and explained to whoever cared to know how to find the cubic roots of numbers. There may be more math problems here than the average merchant could ever solve, but the text is a tribute to the love of puzzle solving that was also central to the merchant's occupation. Besides knowing how to figure exchange rates between currencies, the merchant also needed to introduce time into his calculations. Markets rewarded the ability to mentally picture what something would be worth in six months, even to think of time as quantifiable, such as money. There could be no reward for risk without the curiosity and ambition to succeed. Numbers gave ambition a practical goal and rewarded problem solvers who understood the new system of Arabic numerals percolating westward along the trade routes. Both the honor-based cultures in the Mediterranean and the feudal ideals prevailing among the nobility and their imitators in parts of Europe stressed the literal sanctity of contract. Even in the cartulary the oath to fulfill the terms of a commenda was as serious as the vow between lord and vassal. Of course, both worlds had their embezzlers and traitors and forgers and liars. Laws and courts existed to enforce contracts but to resort to them was to lose time and money. Better by far to rely on reputation, good faith, and culture to make honoring contracts second nature to all. These qualities became proverbial tests of character.

THE DEAL Trade requires that buyers and sellers find one another, and cities and fairs were obvious places for these encounters to occur, where strangers might meet. As Luca Pacioli (c.1445—c.1514) later observed in his classic text on accounti ng, a merchant needed cash, a good accountant, and accurate records and ledgers. A good reputation also enabled a merchant to obtain credit, without which it was not easy to conduct business. This broader context, a place and the

financial wherewithal to be in business, made trade possible. Merchants faced

Trade 1000-1350

other obstacles to making a deal. If the parties did not speak the same language, which was likely far from home, they needed interpreters and multilingual notaries to make deals. Whether in the customhouse in crusader Acre or on the docks in Alexandria, Constantinople, or Visby, wise travelers knew languages or reliable interpreters. Common trading languages developed in big spheres of commerce — in the north because of the Hanse German was useful; in

the Mediterranean French, Greek, and Arabic all rivaled for the best lingua franca. Farther east, Persian and Mongol were assets and in the big arc around the northern parts of the Black Sea one Slavic tongue helped merchants and travelers communicate in the others. Simple manuals and word lists, which were primitive dictionaries, helped to teach literate merchants what commodities each region supplied and how to communicate with the locals. Young men also served apprenticeships with experienced merchants and learned trading firsthand. The lore of commerce, picked up in travels and ports, encouraged merchants to seize opportunities that came their way, and few specialized in particular items. But having invested the time to learn routes and languages, merchants built routines of business as they specialized in markets as far away as Famagusta on Cyprus or Bruges on the Flemish coast. Ship captains and pilots and muleteers and drovers knew the sea lanes and paths from one place to

the next. Merchants at first relied on notaries as specialists in contracts, which, for traditional reasons, remained in Latin everywhere in the Christian Mediterranean West through the thirteenth century and in most places long beyond. Notaries knew the rules, but as they listened over a career to thousands of negotiations and contracts, they also became a good source of information about the economy. Their professional reputations depended on preserving their customers’ privacy while at the same time recording their business in writing before witnesses. This was a neat balancing trick. Notaries went to where business occurred — the fair stall, the church porch, the covered market, or a warehouse or funduq. Death-bed testaments brought notaries into the home, but commerce was more public. Efficient notaries were in most places members of a guild with rules and charged according to a scale. This reduced transaction costs while making contracts valid and reasonably transparent. Money changers facilitated the exchange of different coins, and some of them eventually turned their benches (banca) into the first banks. For a long time, these companies were private banks deriving their capital from partners rather than depositors. Goldsmiths and jewelers could also provide a safe place for leaving valuables

89

90

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

and even arranging credit. Coins were a store of value and a means of exhange. Money as an abstraction helped people see a connection between the present and the future, between borrower and lender. Other professions contributed to the infrastructure for trade, or the institutions that made it more profitable. Innkeepers or the staffs of funduqs housed and fed traveling merchants. Transporters of all types moved their goods. Town criers shared the news and auctioneers helped to set prices in an extremely transparent setting. For those merchants who had a hard time finding the right customer or supplier, local brokers made it their business to bring such people together, usually charging about 1 percent of a transaction for such services, which could amount to very respectable incomes. Synergies developed among these professions. Innkeepers could point one in the direction of carters and muleteers. Brokers knew the interpreters; the notaries in the ports knew captains with space for cargo and crewmen. Some of these trades required a long apprenticeship — it took time and learning to become a notary. Others required capital, if, for instance, one wanted to buy an inn. A good talker with a nose for news might set up easily as a town crier, broker, or auctioneer. All of these activities provided entry into the merchant class and explain the great social mobility within the group. Many, of course, began to inherit their status through the great merchant families who dominated business and politics in

some towns. But the rags-to-riches stories, Godric, and many others, had more than an element of truth about them. The routines of trade left some widows and working women the chance to participate and use their minds to make money by investing in or running an inn.

COMMODITIES Having looked at the people involved in trade and some aspects of how they made deals, we can now consider the last subject of what goods they traded — the commodities that constituted the lifeblood of commerce. Anythi ng whose price might be increased by moving it in space could be an item of trade, from huge constructions, such as an entire ship, to the delicate and almost weightless crocus stigmas that yielded valuable saffron. The commodities by themselves could fill many books, and so we must pick and chose good exampl es of things and places that illuminate the broader picture. Europe's many microregions and microclimates contained a wide array of resources that might be traded, and its people had generic skills, such as turning hides into leather. Europeans also

Trade 1000-1350

wanted things from outside of their world, whether herring and cod from the nearby North Atlantic or cinnamon, cloves, and pepper from the East Indies. Natural products, mainly the results of farming and pastoralism, constituted the bulk of medieval trade in every sense. These goods range from cereals, to wood, minerals, wool, fur, and living creatures, such as horses and slaves. Considerable labor can go into the elaborate efforts to extract salt from seawater or take tin

from the ground. The result, a bag of salt or an ingot of metal might be directly consumed in the case of food or become part of a manufacturing process that mixed tin and copper to produce bronze, brewed beer from barley, or made

cloth from wool. Every step in the process of production added value — even the apple picked off of the ground was worth more simply by being collected. Nevertheless, there is some benefit to dividing all commodities into two big classes — more or less natural products, and those that result from skilled human labor being directly applied to raw materials. Merchants, of course, traded in all types of products, but there is a difference between selling timber or oars, and rules about selling them to friends or enemies. The value-added commodities provide one of the great purposes behind urban development and will be analyzed in more detail in Chapter 4. The story of commodities can become a bewildering map of arrows as things move around Europe — wools comes out of England, wine from southwestern France, silver from the Harz mountains of Saxony, finished wool cloth from the manufacturing towns in Flanders and northern Italy, and flax from Egypt — the

list is endless and ultimately baffling. A few admittedly extreme examples can clarify the basic issue of commodities. We must ask, as those who came to live in a specific place came to ask — what do we have here that can be traded for what we do not have or what we really want? Self-sufficiency was a delusion that even those monks and nuns claiming to be dead to the outside world never realized. Let us start with Iceland, virtually at the end of the known world, in the period of the Free State from about 1000 to the 1250s, when the island had been settled and its best lands taken. Iceland is a good case because it had no cities and its merchants tended to leave for other places, such as Norway. Merchants from Norway, in fact, dominated the island's external trade and indirectly connected it to the Hanseatic networks. On the island, farmsteads exchanged goods they needed, but there was a basic general need to import staples — barley, wheat, timber, and linen. The settlers had the money they

brought with them to the island — the silver was Viking plunder. But there was

91

OD

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

no silver to mine on Iceland, and gradually all the cash might flow out to pay for imports. In fact, Iceland remained a silver-poor society that frequently had to resort to barter or payments in-kind in a useful monetary equivalent, such as standard units of homespun wool cloth. What the Icelanders had to export above all was their wool and woolens, which were famous for their high lanolin content and hence somewhat waterproof quality. Iceland, like everywhere else, had some special valuable exports to send elsewhere: sulphur, white falcons, and walrus ivory. There would never be enough of this stuff — or narwhal tusks to be passed off as unicorn horns, to pay for what the Icelanders needed, so wool ruled for centuries. In the early fourteenth century, some amazing Icelandic entrepreneur found a way to make stockfish, the famous dried cod that soon became the island's most valuable export. This is what trade in commodities amounted to on Iceland — so much imported metals, spices, luxury cloths — all the many things imported in exchange for what Icelanders had — from pastoralism and fishing. Finally, Iceland is an unusual place because it is basically a last stop. To the west, there was more fishing and even more isolated Greenland, but that was it. Island economies and trade tend to force the places to become entrepots of a carrying trade, like the role Cyprus played in the eastern Mediterranean, or to have the economy drift into a kind of colonial emphasis on the most profitable extracted product — silver from Sardinia or wheat from Sicily, in this way, resemble the commercial function of stockfish on Iceland. Muslim Spain, gradually reduced to Andalusia in the south as a result of the conquests by Castile and Aragon in the thirteenth century, was not literally an island, but its circumstances are a useful counterpoint to Iceland. Andalusia was prosperous, had important cities, a sophisticated economy, and commercial links to the wider world of Muslim trading stretching from North Africa to Egypt and beyond. Andalusia had resources to export — olive oil, dried fruits, copper, mercury, ambergris, leather, and important to the Muslims, supplies of timber for their tree—poor parts of the southern Mediterranean. Silk was important in the earlier centuries but became less significant as an export in the thirteenth century as more competitors surfaced. Muslim Spain continue d to import Egyptian flax and began to take in more wool in the thirteenth century. Trade in foodstuffs everywhere existed on the local level, but in order to travel long distances, food had to be salted, smoked, pickled, or dried. So, like other regions, Andalusia occasionally sold or purchased rice and wheat and exported dried figs and raisins. The frontier between Muslim and Christian Spain was not

Trade 1000-1350

impermeable, and some trade continued across it, as merchants from Provence

and Italy also came to trade. Genoese traders helped foster the shift of trade from the southern to the northern shore of the Mediterranean. Iceland was a last stop in trade except for what trickled in from Greenland. Andalusia was a great crossroads attracting gold across the Sahara and then to eager northern markets, and pulling down furs, from as far away as Rus, that became highly prestigious and sought after luxuries for residents of the Sierra Nevada and Morocco. Sardinia was a poor island with little to offer the outside world except some wheat, mediocre cheese, and above all silver. Local squabbles prevented the indigenous population from benefiting from this resource, and more prosperous

foreigners, first the Pisans and Genoese in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries, and later the Aragonese merchants, used violence to seize the island and loot its resources. This impoverishment happens to some islands, even ones originally economically complex, such as Ireland and Sicily, that became the targets of wealthy merchants interested in cheap commodities. Silver is a useful example, however, because its value as a commodity was its function as money, a

well-respected medium of exchange by coin or weight. Mining silver directly increased the money supply and made some regions magnets for luxuries. More

silver helped keep the money supply in pace with population growth and prevented prices from increasing faster than they did from 1000 to 1300. As Table 3.1 shows for England, estimates of English money in circulation (mostly silver, gold negligible before 1331) kept pace with population increases. Also, the political power controlling supplies of silver could turn this cash into power through war or other means. Originally, in what became central Germany, first the area around the Harz mountains in the 960s, then Goslar around 1025, and then farther east to Freiberg from the 1160s and south to Bavaria and the Tirol (see Figure 3.2), repeated new discoveries of silver supplies fueled prosperity in Saxony and

a burst of fresh wealth from new mines soon ability to pull silver from ore. Nevertheless, of supply. The Tirol silver strike began to a bullion famine first appeared. But exactly when European trade began to flourish, from the mid-tenth century to the early fourteenth, German silver became an important basic commodity in this world's trade. This silver and coined money soon enriched merchants from Magdeburg and Cologne and sustained trade in every direction — east to Poland, north beyond. The cycle is interesting — exhausted medieval technology’s a boom followed the new source pan out after 1300, and signs of

93

94

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000—1500

Table 3.1. High Estimates of English Currency Data (from Martin Allen, “The Volume of English Currency, 1158-1470," Economic History Review 54 (2001): 595-644, at 607). 2.5

1.5

0.5

|

1158 1180 1210 1247 1279 1282 1290 1299 1310 1319 1331 1351 1422 1470 Pounds

to Scandinavia, and west to Frisia and England. This silver helped to finance the Hanse merchants and pay for their imports of wine, wool, and cloth, which in turn strengthened more distant markets. By connecting to the fairs of Champagne, this silver also linked northern and southern markets. Exploring for veins of silver itself became an important profession. The mines at Kutna Hora, discovered in 1298, eventually made the kings of Bohemia rich and powertul. This last great discovery in Europe's silver boom was capable of exporting 22-24 tons of silver annually in the 1320s and 1330s and helped to maintain silver supplies in the face of diminishing yields elsewhere, These silver boom towns and others, such as the aptly named Argentiera and Iglesias on Sardinia or Freiberg in Meissen and smaller ones in Tuscany, England, Scandinavia, and

elsewhere, became ideal places for merchants to peddle their luxury imports. Wealthy miners and mine owners eagerly purchased silks, spices, wine, fine woolens, and other expensive items.

Trade 1000-1350

hots.

_| HARZ

SE

~

Mining-areas

TUSCANY

Commercial areas

Cologne

Commercial towns

Pao AACologne__ MEISSEN aoe pre

x

Aw

pec

ee ir

Paris “CHAMPAGNE

FAIRS

orms

fe

M

SZ

yea

eae

ZIPS

lenna

STYRIA R

cA —

Danube

v,

Ae Pens

500 km

Figure 3.2. Thirteenth-Century Silver Movements (from Peter Spufford, Money and Its Use in Medieval Europe. Cambridge, 1988, p. 137).

Pepper is the classic spice butjust one of the 288 “spices” Francesco Pegolotti listed in his famous manual on commerce. A spice might be anything small and

valuable, such as the familiar pepper, cinnamon, ginger, cloves, to chemical like alum, dyes, such as indigo, drugs, such as hashish, and even items not springing to mind, such as incense, gemstones, and sugar. Even bulkier items, such as cotton, originally made this list because it was expensive, originally transported in small, valuable quantities. Sugar and cotton eventually became bulky items of commerce shipped east in bales and sacks from Egypt and Syria. Pepper came from so far away that by the time it reached Alexandria it had increased remarkably in price so that even when it got to twelfthcentury Genoa, or farther, it could substitute for money. Some expensive manufactured goods, such as soap and beaten silver, also counted as spices. Some spices, such as honey, wax, and hazelnuts originated in Europe, but the ones people wanted the most, such as pepper, were from far away. At a “zero boundary,” transportation costs might make a spice so expensive that no one could afford it, but this did not happen anywhere. Southerners made and lost fortunes selling spices in northern Europe, where few of them originated.

95

96

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

Wool is the classic natural product. Moving this fiber from the backs of sheep to the backs of people was a major trade everywhere. Clothing was a necessity. Silk and cotton were for long only for the rich, and linen, skins, and furs had their costs and disadvantages. Weaving cloth and cutting it to make clothing were major trades to be investigated later. Vast herds of sheep enriched lay and monastic landlords, but even peasants could keep enough sheep to make the venture profitable. The incomes of the great Cistercian abbeys in Yorkshire and elsewhere sustained consumption and building projects that benefited the local economies. Cistercian grange policies cleared off lands (from woods and people) to create vast grazing areas. In well-watered places the herds remained relatively fixed, but in the semi-arid conditions prevailing in Castile, moving the flocks and their herders was necessary — hence transhumance. Big herds first appeared there in the eleventh century and the flock owners needed the coastal ports to sell much of the crop overseas. In the late thirteenth century, Alfonso X formalized the Mesta Real, a national guild of livestock, primarily sheep owners. The big entrepreneurs needed secure pasturage and rights to move the flocks across private lands andjurisdictions. The king derived regular taxes from the privileges that he granted and the resulting trade. The pastoralists carefully crossbred local and imported stocks to produce the justly famous superfine wool of the Merino sheep, a new, hardy animal that was well suited to the environment.

Castilian wool supplied local weavers in cities, such as Barcelona, but was exported mainly to centers above all in northern Italy, though some made its way via Basque ports to Flanders. Likewise, highly prized English wool exported by Italian, Flemish, and German merchants kept weavers busy in Bruges and Florence. The opening up of the sea lanes from the north to the Mediterranean made an international trade in wool easier. English weavers, like the ones on Iceland, competed to export actual value-added cloth, and, of course, English merchants wanted to be in the lucrative business of exporting

their island's most valuable commodity. The interests of monastic producers and Italian merchants combined to use an old way of doing business, the forward contract, to make the wool trade more routine. Big producers had large building projects, taxes, and other expenses that benefited from a predictable and secure income years into the future. The Italians wanted to assure their customers on the continent adequate supplies of raw wool. The forward contract allowed the parties to make multiyear deals at fixed prices. Up-front payments in advance helped producers and were a kind of loan, and the prices sometimes include d

Trade 1000-1350

a discount that was in effect an interest payment. Only a small amount of finequality English wool was sold by forward contract. The complex international

market for wool brought the English Crown, producers, and customers into tighter relationships. This trade illustrates the issue of economic policy, in the sense that states looked to commerce as a source of revenue to pay for their characteristic activity — war. Trade wars also occurred — witness the classic rivalries among Pisa, Genoa, and Venice. Here merchants directly paid for

the ships and weapons involved in protecting their livelihoods. In fact, the merchant fleet was the war fleet, the city government the creation of the long distance trader, and the line between trade and piracy often a fine one. The main centers of the fur trade were Kiev, Novgorod, and Kazan. Kiev exported ermine, sable, and beaver furs down the Volga and Don trade routes to Byzantine and eventually Muslim customers who paid in silver but also in luxuries, such as spices and silk. In the eleventh century, Novgorod began to monopolize northern and eastern supplies of fur. Novgorod also became an entrepot for exporting massive quantities of gray squirrel pelts, in barrels of 5—10,000, eastward to Hanseatic customers. Its merchants obtained cloth, salt, wine, herring, and silver. (Kazan controlled the trade routes to the Muslim Tartars dominating land access to the Black Sea.) In the fourteenth century, Moscow, closer to Siberian supplies of luxury furs, especially sable, began to challenge Novgorod. The issue was who would serve as intermediary between hunters and peasants (in some places paying rents in squirrel skins) and the customers for royal ermine and humbler furs. River routes connected Siberian and Scandinavian supplies to the Black and Caspian Seas. Zones of influence and trade routes shifted— eventually a land route across Poland-Lithuania served Western Europe. Despite all of these changes, the fur trade persisted because

fur never went out of fashion. But let us return to wool as a prime example of the intimate connections between commodities, trade, state finance, and violence. In England, the crown in 1271 required a license for all who exported wool. The king needed the revenue and favored some traders, typically, at first, his foreign creditors. In 1275, Edward | started a customs duty (export tax) of 6s 8d per sack of wool, yielding him some £10,000 for wars and paying off his creditors, the Ricciardi of Lucca. The ability to impose this tax testifies to the strength of wool exports. Foreign merchants paid the duty on top of the prevailing price, but producers were confident that their product was still competitive in the international market for wool. In the 1290s, the king temporarily tripled the duty to

oF

98

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

£2 per sack to pay for his wars in France and Scotland. Beginning in 1313, he

established a royal monopoly or staple on wool exports, which required, in this instance, all wool to be exported to St. Omer to be sold from there and taxed accordingly. The later experiments with the wool staple need not detain us here — the point is the role of wool in what constitutes royal or public finances and indeed economic policy. Basic necessary commodities, such as wheat and wool, enabled states to squeeze peasant and merchant alike. The way to tax wheat was to burden the peasant proprietor — not to put unpopular duties on bread. Likewise, taxing clothing was impractical, but passing on the costs of war to foreigners was irresistible. International trade in commodities, such as wool and salt, made these policies possible. Urban society required a closer look at the old question — who benefited from the rise of trade? Rural producers supplied commodities and markets. Peddlers and fairs might have satisfied local needs for exchange. One of the great medieval social and economic transformations was the rise of substantial cities across much of Europe. Agriculture and trade provided the context for exploring this important development.

SELECT BIBLIOGRAPHY

Janet L. Abu-Lughod, Before European Hegemony: The World System A.D. 1250-1350. Oxford, 1989. Martin Allen, “The Volume of English Currency, 1158-1470," Economic History Review 54 (2001): 595-611.

Adrian Bell, Chris Brook, and Paul R. Dryburgh, The English Wool Market, C. 1230-1327. Cambridge, 2007. Jesse Byock, Viking Age Iceland. London, 2001. Olivia Remie Constable, Housing the Stranger in the Mediterranean World. Cambridge, 2003.

, Trade and Traders in Muslim Spain. Cambridge, 1996. Philippe Dollinger, The German Hansa. London, 1970. Steven A. Epstein, Genoa and the Genoese 958-1528. Chapel Hill, 1996. Paul Freedman, Out of the East: Spices and the European Imagination. New Haven, 2008.

Avner Greif, Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge, 2006. Robert S. Lopez, The Commercial Revolution ofthe Middle Ages, 950-1350. Cambridge, 1976.

Trade 1000-1350

T. H. Lloyd, England and the German Hanse, 1157-1611. Cambridge, 1991. Janet Martin, Treasure of the Land of Darkness: The Fur Trade and Its Significance for Medieval Russia. Cambridge, 1986. Francesco Balducci Pegolotti, La pratica della mercatura. Edited by Allan Evans. Cambridge, MA, 1936. John H. Pryor, Business Contracts of Medieval Provence. Toronto, 1981. Carla Rahn Phillips and William D. Phillips, Jr., Spain's Golden Fleece. Baltimore, ROi

Kathryn L. Reyerson, The Art of the Deal: Intermediaries of Trade in Medieval Montpellier. Leiden, 2002.

Peter Spufford, Power and Profit: The Merchant in Medieval Europe. New York, 2003.

99

4 CITIES, GUILDS, AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

HE GRADUAL

URBANIZATION

OF EUROPE

AFTER

1000 IS ONE

OF

the most important themes in medieval economic and social history. Yet, the rise of cities should not be overstated. Even by 1500 only a small percentage of Europeans, perhaps 15—20 percent, lived in them. Cities were always thoroughly imbedded in their regions and depended on networks of smaller towns and farmlands to sustain their livelihoods by producing a surplus. Cities are places where strangers are likely to meet because anonymity was possible there — unlike a hamlet. They are also places where people would starve without regional and long-distance trade. Merchants and artisans and lords and the Church, were the engines driving the prosperity of these cities. Their incomes and need for security provided the means and the reason to pay taxes. As centers of wealth, cities attracted the attention of others, kings, feudal lords, and church officials, who also needed money to pay for war and cathedrals and much else. “Political economy” is an old-fashioned name for the intersection ofpolitics and economy. In a late medieval context, the paramount issues were fiscal — taxes, customs duties, public debt, and the money supply. All governments faced these issues, but cities incubated the ideas and practices that made it possible to raise money for the common good, and to consider what economic and social circumstances were most likely to favor commerce and manufacturing. In other words, cities were places that needed economic policies, where people thought about markets not simply as naturally occurring phenomena, but as human institutions that wise people could manipulate to their own advantage. Cities reflect the human tendency to form groups, to band together for mutual support and protection. Guilds, and later companies and firms, show the same impulse to cooperate as a means to compete with others. Feudal 100

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

society, clans, and even big families accomplished these goals in parts of the countryside. Some lords founded cities as part of their efforts to control people and profit from them. No inevitable tension existed between subordinating the peasantry and favoring the rise of cities. These developments in practice worked well together. At a certain point, however, the townspeople wanted rights not granted to serfs, and then tensions occurred. Local movements succeeded (or

not) in establishing various systems of urban self-government — the commune. Inside the cities, groups also coalesced around individual trades and professions. In many places the bakers, for example, formed an association known as the guild, a self-help organization dedicated to fostering the trade and those masters, employers, who dominated it. These three topics — cities, guilds, and political economy — help illuminate an urban society where other new features, such as wage labor and a gender division of labor, were appearing.

CITIES There are many ways to define cities — by size, social, political, and spiritual functions or by legal status. In the simplest terms, we are looking at settlements where most people are not farmers, and where the population has reached a certain size. A town, conveniently a small city, might have as few as one thousand people at the beginning of urbanization. The most populous cities in Europe, Constantinople before the sack of 1204 and Paris before the Black Death, may have reached as many as two hundred thousand people, and the major cities, such as Florence, Venice, Naples, and Palermo, topped out in the early four-

teenth century at over one hundred thousand. Hundreds of places counted in the range from small towns to the urban giants. The general trend follows the demographic facts considered in previous chapters. Swelling numbers of people from rural birth rates fed the population growth in cites. Most observers conclude that the cities were unhealthy environments and unable to sustain their

own growth and instead depended on migration to grow. Migration from outside of Europe did not contribute to population growth — in this narrow sense, Europe remained a closed system. Yet, it was not immune to African and Asian economic and social trends. Medieval settlements required a certain amount of surrounding land to supply food and fuel. Intensively cultivated garden plots around some urban areas supplied townspeople with daily necessities. The practical limitations of trans-

porting wood and foodstuffs created zones between the central places and their

101

102

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

nearest neighbors. Naturally, the size of the rural zones varied depending on

the quality of local soils, the ease of water transport, and other issues. Some regions of Europe, the Low Countries and northern Italy, were able to sustain a larger number of cities than others because of their good lands. A few great cities, such as London, Paris, and Constantinople, drew on suchalarge hinterland that their sheer size suppressed the growth of other cities within the zone the central place needed for food and firewood. Calculating how far peasants and mules could travel in a day or two to sustain cities of certain sizes has produced an array of grids and maps showing the likely positions of central places across Europe. If we also note the prior existence of ancient cities and durable geographic features, such as ideal ports and good places to cross rivers, we can establish a logic to the size and number of Europe's cities. No historical geographer could have predicted the institutional factors that conferred permanent advantages on Rome or why some particular cities, such as Bruges, grew at the expense of less-lucky neighbors. European agriculture and fuel supplies could sustain an urban population that remained even by 1500 in many places less than 10 percent of the population, and even in the most urbanized regions less than 25 percent. As many cities, so many stories. Each urban society and its region merits study. Because we must generalize in order to make sense of so many particular places, it might seem best to set up types and examine the typical port, the standard industrial or university town, or royal capital. This model has merits, but no city was quite like another. For example, Ghent and Florence were wool cloth towns, but their institutions, culture, and much else were totally different. Guilds will pose similar problems — in no two places were their growth and roles really the same. So, we must proceed by learning enough about a few cities so that as you come across more examples through study or travel you will be able to fit them into an increasingly complicated pattern of urbanization in later medieval Europe. Two regions, the Low Countries and northern Italy, will dominate this analysis because they contain many large cities and became the most urbanized areas of Europe. They also led the way in Europe's most important industry — wool cloth production — but this business alone did not by itself drive urbanization — for Icelanders made plenty of cloth and had not a single town. One thing all cities had in common was that they had permanent markets. Many old cities had bishops because the church's organization reflected ancient patterns of settlement at desirable spots. Some cities coalesced around a castle,

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

bridge, good harbor, or some natural advantage that made the place safe.

Every city (except Venice) and even some villages built walls for self-defense. Those little places that had clung to existence during the early Middle Ages and survived to about 1000 were most likely to thrive and grow. A few new important

cities were purposefully created after that date, as was Lund, what became the city of Denmark's archbishop. In the ideal world where everyone prayed, fought, or farmed, people needed new words to describe urban people, and we will settle on the burgher, the bourgeoisie, and the cittadini. Very quickly, cities reflected older inequalities, and some men placed themselves above others. This

tendency required those who ran cities to distinguish between the inhabitants — anyone who happened to live there, and the true burghers — property owners and citizens with some material stake in the city’s life. Outside of the city walls, the growth of suburbs (faubourgs) help to chart the pace of urban growth and illustrate the need for new circuits of walls. City air made men free from serfdom. Where women and slaves would find their liberties remained unsettling questions.

Bruges (see Figure 4.1) in the 1120s was a small city of perhaps 1,000 people tucked up the Reie River close to the sandy coast of Flanders. This city thrived where roads and waterways intersected. Its substantial stone castle protected the inhabitants, who were mostly merchants, builders, traders, and boat people. The city had two big parishes but no bishop — it was not an ancient site though Roman ruins were in the area. At this time the North Sea was retreating but floods remained a menace and probably encouraged people to cooperate on vital matters like ditches and dikes. Bruges castle also functioned as a community headquarters for the region and an administrative center for the count of Flanders. Its location, a big open and covered market square just outside of the castle gate, was also a reason for its modest economic success. Houses and shops surrounded the commercial and administrative center. Bruges was a place of opportunity and provided employment to notaries who kept the count's financial accounts. The city did not fit well into the existing social rules of traditional, feudal society of lords and peasants, and so it was filled with flux and tensions. On March 2, 1127, some conspirators killed their count, Charles the Good, while he was praying. The ensuing crisis encouraged an able and temporarily unemployed notary Galbert to record the aftermath as local powers and groups struggled to assert authority over Bruges. His vivid story is one of the few contemporary accounts from anywhere in Europe that describes how

violence and local competition shaped urban development.

103

104

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

Figure 4.1. Bruges (map by Keith A. French and Darin Grauberger, University of Kansas Cartographic Services).

Charles died without immediate heirs, and the townsmen, the burghers, took advantage of a power vacuum and formed a sworn association whose first purpose was to choose their count. The kings of France and England had stakes in what happened to Flanders and were not likely to yield to common people. These burghers did not hope to name the next count by themselves, but they

did expect to be consulted about the issues that mattered most to them: security, the common good, and caring for the poor. These concerns constitute a sophisticated political, economic, and social program. Their neighbors in St. Omer

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

received a charter from the new count that together with Galbert's account makes clear exactly what the burghers wanted. Their leaders, the aldermen, (elders) were recognized as the town's officials and the count promised to protect them. Security issues extended to personal status — the townspeople were not serfs to anyone, although not all of them counted as burghers. As a sign of free personal status, no one paid a head tax. Landowners no longer owed dues on urban land, and these freeholds became everywhere the mark of urban status — the burghers — householders who owned their building and had at least a traditional right to the land under it. Finally, merchants wanted the right to have their customary laws — a way to settle commercial disputes that did not resort to trial

by combat or ordeal but instead rested on fairness and reason. This merchant

law could draw on the common legal past of Europe, containing the rudiments of a commercial law drawing on Roman and other traditions. What mattered

most were rules about enforcing contracts and arbitrating disputes among parties that did not expect to carry every problem to a court, with its expenses and uncertain outcomes. Merchant law became a common law across Europe.

How the burghers defined the common good focused on their desire to work and trade without being impeded by outside exactions. The St. Omer charter promised to free the members of the commune from all customary taxes and to exempt them from some vexatious tolls. The merchants wanted to travel

safely but also without having to pay whatever power set itself up on a bridge or road to skim off some of the benefits of trade. Lords and the church (which owned some traditional tolls) saw trade as a revenue stream to tap while the merchants saw these toll keepers as predators. Urban people became close

students of tax policies and were inclined to use tolls, customs duties, sales taxes, and monopoly income on necessities, such as salt, to pay a commune’s bills and provide for basic services, such as walls and courts. In order for local markets to function well, merchants needed sound money — a silver currency of reliable fineness not subject to the profit-making schemes of the count. Rulers understood that the right to mint coins was profitable because of the small traditional payment, a royalty, owed to coiners. Even more profits could be obtained from stretching out the available silver with

other metals literally to make more money. Some communes eventually manipulated their money supply, but they at least knew why and the commune profited. In St. Omer, the count conceded his mint to the commune in exchange for a substantial annual payment and the promise that the burghers would maintain good money for the common good. The right to mint money

105

106

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

everywhere remained a keenly contested privilege, and the most successful monarchs were, as in the case of England, able to impose a common and reliable coinage on their cities. Florence introduced its famous gold florin in 1252 as a deliberate policy to strengthen its bankers and their currency as an international means of exchange. Its commune also expected to profit from minting gold. Finally, the burghers in Bruges had claimed that they wanted to take care of the poor. They knew that the tithe that they were supposed to pay to the local churches was in theory intended to be divided into thirds to support the clergy, the material fabric of the buildings, and Christ's poor — the deserving widows and orphans. The burghers could reasonably claim that supporting the liberties of the church was in the interest of the poor. They also intended to focus their own charitable donations on these poor souls, using the church to administer these donations and grant spiritual benefits to the donors. Everyone understood that the best antidote to urban poverty was employment for those hands able to work at a trade. The burghers expected the “common good" to favor local prosperity that, in turn, allowed the able-bodied poor the chance to work for the burghers. Their guilds were partly intended to regulate competition among the members on thorny issues, such as training and wages. The issue across these emerging cities across Europe was the poor. The common teachings of the Church encouraged an ethos of charity often disbursed by lay religious confraternities. A wage economy, something that was fairly new, also operated in a moral framework in which the laborer was indeed worthy of his (and certainly her) hire. The communal conception of the common good, resting on an oath binding Christians, from the beginning excluded Jews from full participation in urban society. The circumstances ofJews were complicated and apparently none lived in Bruges. Elsewhere, in Castile, Aragon, and Muslim Spain where Jews were most numerous in Europe (still less than 5 percent of the population), their continued existence depended on the good will of sovereigns taking money from the Jews in exchange for protection. After 1000, as landholding became more difficult for Jews, they became, especially in Christian Europe, an increasingly urban population even as some towns, for example, Genoa and Venice, were hostile and permitted none to settle. No Jews had lived in England until some came over with the Normans after the conquest of 1066. The fates of Jews ands other minorities in medieval society will receive extended discussi on in

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

later chapters. For now, it is enough to observe that their small numbers play no apparent role in the communal movements, the rise of guilds, or indeed the economic development of Western Europe. Increasingly confined to economic

activities inside their own communities and unpopular trades, such as pawnbrokers, rag merchants, and tax collectors, Jews became (along with others) convenient scapegoats for those who questioned the rise of new institutions and a market economy. Older scholarship picked up on these medieval complaints and exaggerated the role Jews played in these developments, especially after 1000 when a Christian merchant class appeared to take charge of local and long-distance trade. In Byzantine and Muslim lands, the Jews certainly endured second class status, but they remained free to engage in some professions and

trades denied them in the Christian West. In the German Empire, that vast but ill-defined state stretching from the North Sea to the vicinity of Rome, imperial free cities, such as Cologne, Mayence, Worms, Speyer, Strasbourg, Basle, and Ratisbon, started as episcopal towns. The bishop provided a cloak of authority that spread over the burghers' claims to self-rule in the eleventh and twelfth centuries. (The well-intentioned bishops of Mainz and Speyer were not able to prevent massacres of local Jews during the crusading fervor of 1096.) Pisa was an ancient Roman port with a continuous existence since antiquity. Pisa’s commune, beginning in 1081, received from the emperors a series of charters allowing self-rule. Its system of government, revealed in exceptionally detailed records, in 1162 depended ona

board of five consuls (later between five and ten), chosen by the previous group, who appointed the other officials and judges and enforced the law. A council of forty senators assisted the consuls, and other groups made lists of citizens and their property in order to prepare galleys to protect the port, especially during the sailing season from April to October. Overseas trade was the lifeblood of Pisan prosperity, and it also served as the entrepot for Tuscany's commerce coming down the Arno River. These consuls and senators were not Roman survivals but instead took their venerable names in order to attach their new free status to traditional job titles with no current relevance. Pisa's consuls conducted a foreign policy and were generally loyal to the German emperors (hence Ghibellines) and expected to be supported in their colonial ambitions on Sardinia with its modest agricultural wealth and silver mines. The consuls as collective chief executives settled disputes, directed the constructing of city walls, and regulated the city's relations with its powerful

107

108

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

archbishop. Pisa also had a famous law code, the usages or customs of Pisa, in its oldest form dating from 1161 but reflecting centuries of practice as well as a deep understanding of even older common Roman law. This law code largely concerned shipping and contracts and above all stressed that equity should prevail in commerce. Pisa experienced a rather typical institutional progression. The old commune extended its authority over the nearby countryside but ran up against similar ambitions in its nearest neighbors Lucca and Florence. By the early thirteenth century, the city had a podesta, a professional city manager, always a foreigner, chosen for a one-year term who was supposed to ensure impartial courts and defend the city against its many enemies, especially the Genoese. In 1254 the Pisan popolo, the merchants and major employers in the guilds, took over the commune and established yet another authority, the captain of the people, as a remedy to the defects of a clear, experienced local executive. A great naval defeat in Pisa's port in 1284 led to Genoese naval supremacy in the Tyrrhenian Sea and the beginning of hard times for the commune, which began to fall into the hands of a series of local strongmen, the signori. The late thirteenth-century commune had a more ambitious political program than its predecessors. It supported with money the local hospitals, hermits, monks, and nuns, and helped to clothe the new orders of friars, the Franciscans and Dominicans, active in urban ministry. The commune even paid a bounty to eliminate the local wolves, offering 2 lire alive, 1 lira dead, and five solidi for cubs. All these decisions reflect local choices made by ruling groups, however defined, valuing their autonomy.

Bonvesin della Ripa, a member of a new religious order, the Humiliati, in 1288, wrote a short work on the marvels of Milan. His book, a pious panegyric on his hometown, described a city that had a podesta but in Matteo Visconti a noble captain of the people in the process of establishing a durable family dynasty over a free commune. This remarkable source situates the city clearly in

its region — populous Lombardy with its exceptionally fertile lands. Located at the confluence of two rivers, Milan had according to Bonvesin an ideal climate and plenty of freshwater from wells and springs. He was attuned to the local environment and understood natural resources and advantages. His choice to divide the book into eight chapters reflects his gaze and priorities. The contado, and Milan's housing, people, abundance of goods, power, fidelity, liberty, and dignity interested Bonvesin in that order. A close observer of Milan, Bonvesin supplies many numbers, some more credible than others. For example, he wrote that the famous hospital of Brolo could house 500 poor and sick people and

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

take in another 500 when necessary, and that it supported 350 babies out with wet nurses — this seems reasonable. He claimed that there were 200,000 men in

the city and Milan's large contado, which included many towns, some significant like Monza, and 150 villages with castles. He thought there were seven hundred thousand people in this region, and two hundred thousand in Milan proper. The problem is that he had no real basis for this guess, and was probably on the high side, as he was when estimating the one thousand five hundred notaries active in Milan. More believable is that there were seventy schoolteachers, and he must be right that there were precisely six trumpeters.

Good and bad numbers all serve Bonvesin's larger point that the markets and fairs, plus the region's natural abundance in crops, such as wheat and cherries, guaranteed that any healthy person could make a living suitable to his or her station. He thought Milan was at full employment but recognized that many could not work — hence the need for charity. Bonvesin was briefer on the other topics but they mattered as part of how he conceived Milan. Spiritual power made Milan rich in religious treasures from St. Ambrose's time in the fourth century. Political power partly derived from the large and prosperous trades practiced by blacksmiths and armorers — Milan made enough weapons for itself and for export. Milan, a Guelf town, had suffered for its loyalty to the papacy and had resisted tyrants — the German emperors. Bonvesin, as a good member

of the Humiliati, devoted to piety and cloth weaving, found the city's main

dignity to come from its Christian faith. He tried to be balanced and noted Milan's defects — it lacked civic peace (like many cities) and without a port it had no sea power — hence, its interest in Genoa just south over the maritime Alps. Having no university meant that Milan did not have many foreign inhabitants. Bonvesin saw this as a blessing because these foreign students probably would have corrupted the local people. Above all, his praise of Milan reveals a strong

sense of civic patriotism in an age when larger entities did not yet command this type of loyalty, when indeed Germany and Italy remained geographical expressions.

Cities provided a good environment for intellectual activities. Great university towns, such as Bologna and Paris, became centers where professors lectured and wrote books on theology, canon, and civil law. Salerno's medical school helped facilitate the transmission of Arabic and Greek science into western Europe. Not every city had or wanted a university, however, and the popes eventually asserted their authority to charter an official school whose degrees were recognized across Europe. Ambitious building projects like cathedrals

109

110

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

employed artists and architects as well as masons and carpenters. As kings

became less peripatetic and settled down, their courts became centers for

musicians and poets to make livings and enhance the intellectual climate. Schools in cities turned out increasing numbers who could read and write as their trades demanded. Notaries, for example, were literate and stimulated a market for books and literature in Latin as well as the vernacular languages. Urban culture rewarded the reasonable and literate members of society and attracted learned men to teach in its universities and take care of the legal and spiritual needs of the inhabitants. Jews were excluded from universities

and maintained their own Hebrew language, yet some of their scholars knew Latin. Also denied access to the universities and those professions inside and outside the Church that required degrees, some women nonetheless learned to read and write in cities, whether in the urban convents or in the family. Urban economic life granted some of these women, often widows, a chance to run

wool shops as opposed to merely spinning thread or weaving cloth. Communes emerged in the Low Countries and northern Italy, and found some

imitators in southern

France and Germany

as townspeople

banded

together to foster their self-interest. Home rule did not guarantee economic success and being the capital of a national monarchy with a close interest in its governance did not harm London and Paris. By the end of our period of study, Pisa had become a wrecked and malarial shadow of its former economic prominence, Bruges had yielded local supremacy to Antwerp, and the great age of Seville, Bristol, and Lisbon was just beginning for the Atlantic ports. In general, the long-distance traders, in position to earn the biggest profits and provide jobs for allied trades, were the first to see the benefits of ruling their own cities outside the models of monarchy and rural lordship. These people, however, soon divided along wealth and status lines into the big people, defined as the really rich and powerful, and the little people, the great mass of respectable middling folk. During the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries, many communes experienced civic strife as parties of the people, sometimes allied with an aristocracy or a king, fought for control of urban institutions that seemed to guarantee economic success or failure. A new institution, the medieval guild, provided yet another way for people to divide into groups defending the interests of the employers in a trade or profession. These guilds, often existing on uneasy terms with other centers of authority in urban society, helped to determine the roles people might play in the wider world.

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

GUILDS Guilds were usually spontaneous and local organizations devoted to fostering the welfare of the employers in a particular craft or business. As with any institutions, guilds had rules, beliefs, and norms, often codified in written statutes.

Sometimes these associations needed the sanction of a higher power. In other places city governments or other authorities encouraged the development of guilds in order to more closely regulate the members’ activities. In some cities, such as Bruges or Venice, the commune seems to have originated in effect as a merchant guild, a coalition of the long-distance traders who often ran local affairs for their own benefit. These institutions, which gradually developed rules and traditions, benefited the members in several ways. Above all, the guild was supposed to make the business or trade of its members more secure and profitable. As an institution the guild fostered what Sheilagh Ogilvie has called “cultural efficiency,” a social framework where human constraints affected the ways employment and production evolved. In other words, guilds were a way to settle disputes about resources, in this case, the buying and selling of raw materials, finished products, services, and labor. Religious confraternities permeated rural and urban medieval societies. A guild was also usually a confraternity in the sense that its members, bound by a common oath and faith, often had a patron saint, worshipped together in their

chapel, buried their members, and spiritually bonded as a group who happened to be in the same trade. (For these reasons, they excluded Muslims and Jews from membership.) People excluded from guilds are telling signs of broader economic trends. For example, we should be alert to changes in rules about membership that privileged relatives of current masters. Artisan and craft guilds usually included this spiritual purpose but also organized people according to their trades and professions, which often had patron saints, such as St. Joseph for the carpenters. Because membership in a guild carried benefits, the masters, who were full members, were interested in regulating entry into their business, maintaining standards of quality, and managing to some extent the competition among them for business. As employers, the masters were competing to train and recruit labor. The apprentice and journeymen and journeywomen system, by which young people obtained a technical education and learned to make candles or

wool cloth, could exist outside of a formal guild structure. The masters hence

ue

112

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

had a quasipaternal or maternal relationship with the student, who was supposed

to be educated and often fed and housed in sickness and in health. Often this relationship resulted ina lifelong tie that was sometimes buttressed by marriage to a master’s offspring. Hence, the guild was a spiritual and social club as well as means to recruit labor. An organized trade was in a better position to manage the delicate balance of not stealing one another's employees while at the same time expecting a solid level of training among the workers. Guilds fused social and economic functions into a comprehensive way of life for its members and subjects. Guilds first appeared in the Christian West along with the rise of cities in

the eleventh century and the evidence for this rise thickens in the twelfth century. Guilds were partly the result of a pervasive tendency for such groups to form among medieval people who valued solidarity and sought to reduce risks by cooperating. Two aspects of this impulse toward self-help must remain at

the center of our analysis. First, these guilds counted as full members only the employers or, at least, the self-employed. One needed his or her own shop or oven or tools to be an independent producer for customers and the markets. Those who worked for others for a daily or piece rate wage were subject to the guild's rules but were not among those who made the rules. In some parts of Europe, for example, Germany, the guild (Zunft) remained an important part of city life into modern times. These later associations played a role in inspiring the trade union movement among workers who often called their early (and illegal) bodies by the same names. But the medieval guild was in no sense a union devoted to fostering the well-being of the workers, and there is no line of descent between the medieval and modern ways managing employer-employee relations. In the later Middle Ages, journeymen and journeywomen (or compagnons) occasionally had their own shadowy and often illegal associations, but they were not able to bargain collectively with the employers. The second aspect of this impulse toward self-help is more complicated, but it puts the questions surrounding European economic development into their proper context. Ancient Roman cities had groups called collegia or corpora (literally bound by a common tule or oath, or a body of people) organized along professional, trade, or craft lines. Under the empire, these institutions functioned as charitable associations of the members and also provided a convenient way for the state to regulate vital activities, such as the grain trade. These ancient guilds perished along with other sophisticated parts of the Roman society and economy and so there is no line of continuity between these guilds

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

and the ones that appeared in the medieval West centuries later. This result is not surprising because the impulse to coalesce in such groups required only

suitable circumstances to occur again. Yet, when medieval people searched for a Latin legal vocabulary to describe the new guild (this a Germanic word),

they often went back to ancient labels and so the collegium, corpus, universitas, and scola all reappear, and some guilds will even have officials called consuls. This vocabulary also shows that the medieval university followed the guild model with its master educators in the same profession regulating the terms of their work and product — the qualifications of the students! Also, the examination to prove competency or approve a masterpiece became a guild tradition, and some apprentices obtained journeyman status this way. The type of people behind

the communes and guilds agreed on traditional titles, but they left behind a false trail that suggested continuities between ancient and medieval institutions where there were none. Any argument about the links between ancient and medieval institutions has to take into account what happened in the Byzantine and Muslim worlds. In the Byzantine parts of Europe and especially in Constantinople guilds continued to exist, uninterrupted since antiquity. These guilds were corporations or legal persons with the right to own property, have rules, and manage competition and relations with the government, particularly over taxes. These guilds also controlled training and remained social and charitable clubs. For the eleventh century, the original sources are not good, but these guilds continued to exist in a more competitive market as Western merchants began to appear in Byzantine ports to trade. The structure of the labor market remained complex and interesting with journeymen and women, apprentices, and slaves all at work, some in state monopolies and imperial workshops turning out high-quality luxury items, such as silk cloth and tapestries. A high level of technical skill

among the silk workers prompted the famous episode in 1147 when Roger II] of Sicily brought silk weavers and embroiderers from Thebes and Corinth to Sicily to start an advanced production there. Forced migration is one classic way to transfer technology. The fine details of how the imperial bureaucracy attempted to control the price of bread, and still allow for the expenses and a reasonable profit (4.2%) for the bakers, show that until at least 1100 the continuities between the ancient and Byzantine guilds seem tight. Training and traditions also account for the high reputation that Eastern handicrafts enjoyed throughout the Western as and Eastern trading networks. No evidence suggests, however, that guilds

113

114

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

far away as London and Paris needed these Eastern models for their own spontaneous institutions that served some similar needs. During the various crises, the Byzantine State experienced in the twelfth and subsequent centuries, the guilds seem to have withered away and were replaced by nothing indigenous. Instead, foreign merchant quarters and even artisan quarters appeared in the major cities and trade seems to have diminished local production in old staples, such as silk and ceramics. The larger story of how the emperors managed their political economy so poorly is not the issue here. Two basic conclusions remain — these Byzantine guilds were not the models for Western ones, and they did not survive, for whatever reason, to foster internationally competitive urban industries in the Greek-speaking East. About 1000, Muslim rulers still controlled most of Iberia and its important cities, Sicily and of course North Africa and nearly all of the Middle East. As inheritors of another region of the late Roman economy and society Muslim rulers seem to have preserved public authority, which suited their purposes. Market inspectors supervised the bazaars, collected taxes, and maintained the moral order by suppressing the many types of fraud. Trades had an identity and sense of common purpose and often coalesced in neighborhoods or along a certain street. But they lacked any formal organization, and no one has found in Arabic sources any traces of guilds in Muslim cities in the eleventh and twelfth centuries. For instance, no crafts had rules about formal training in apprenticeship. A Sufi fraternity of silk workers in thirteenth-century Damascus was apparently a purely religious club. In Muslim cities, the markets anda strong central authority regulated the trades and professions without guilds. This result suggests that Western merchants would not find anything in these Muslim cities to stimulate a desire to go home and form guilds. Just as every city had its unique history, so too did every guild have a particular path to development over the period 1000-1300. The story of a typical guild distorts these varieties in time and space so it is better to concentr ate

on

some general issues. A charter from 1149 granted some weavers in Cologne corporate status. These workers specialized in making mattresses and pillow covers, so this group represented a stage of an already evolving division of labor as weavers honed their particular skills. A division of labor indicates a more efficient operation and one that fostered a tight solidarity among people with a special skill. This charter shows no signs of a gender division of labor in this trade or in Cologne, but we cannot doubt that women worked at these trades, were excluded from being masters in a guild, and were paid low wages.

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

In Worms, the fishermen in 1106 obtained the corporate hereditary right

from the count and bishop to control the fish market. These authorities had the spiritual and secular power to sanction a guild, and the public responsibility to ensure the quality of fish. The fishermen wanted to limit their numbers in order to make sure each could make a living at this trade, and they also wanted

their sons to have a claim on a share of the market. In this sense, the guild was a monopoly. The members wanted a monopoly to exclude interlopers from entering the trade and presumably taking the fish the members saw as their own. At this stage, the fishermen were not a cartel — they had not agreed to fix prices or set quotas on the catch. Most of the time guild members in many trades continued to compete against one another on quality, freshness, or other

aspects of reputation that over time established a good position in the markets. In Pavia, where a commune existed since 1164, the consuls had to settle a dispute between the guild of fishermen and the monastery of Morimond over rights to fish. Rivers fell under public jurisdiction, but rights over fish could belong to other associations besides the guild. In 1152 in Toulouse, the consuls of the city government set the maximum profits of the millers and bakers. This was a pervasive trend across urban societies everywhere in Europe —a public authority's concern for the food supply and fair prices. Throughout England, Henry II began setting up local assizes of bread and beer. These courts were supposed to regulate the price and quality of beer and the weight of standard loaves of bread. In order to accomplish these goals, authorities also had to set prices for wheat, barley, and oats. These complex price controls were difficult to enforce but show the needs of consumers were in theory understood.

The common good of the trade was the business of the guild. Most observers concluded that when this narrow interest conflicted with the broader public good, people could not count on the guild to do the right thing. In the thirteenth century, however, the Church taught that guilds were not conspiracies against the public good, and so they had a right to exist. Vigilant city officials had to supervise trades involving bread to make sure there were adequate supplies at affordable prices. Producers and retailers of grain might not agree on what prices were fair. Very few people believed that the markets alone would guarantee this result, especially for the poor. In cities, such as Toulouse and Venice, the public authorities may have taken the lead in organizing some guilds in order to regulate their activities more efficiently. Certainly in Venice the commune, controlled by the old families engaged in overseas trade,

115

116

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

closely supervised all guilds and had a strong role in formulating the trade's rules. In the major royal capitals, such as Paris and London, the state also remained active in supervising the trades ostensibly in the name of the common good but in practical terms to keep the peace and prevent food riots and other disorders. As a sworn association of employers, guilds often had statutes, private laws, devised by the members, or sometimes imposed on them, that set the limits on who could enter the trade and how they should practice it. These statutes survive from across Europe and where city governments took a close interest in guild activities, for example, in Paris and Bologna in the thirteenth century, the statutes survive in important collections. In some communes, such as Florence, where membership in a guild gradually became necessary for participation in political life, guild statutes for the major and wealthy employers were serious matters. Later copies of rules tend to make older ones irrelevant and disposable. For example, the Florentine guild of money changers was already old and prestigious before its first surviving statutes of 1299 — which were speedily revised in 1300, 1313, and 1316. Guild members liked to tinker with their tules, especially with an eye toward how their sons could enter the trade and the circumstances under which their wives and daughters had rights to manage shops and do business. Another major concern of masters was apprenticeship — how long it needed to be, who was eligible, how many apprentices a master might have, and how the apprentice might prove his or her competence. Apprenticeship remained the most common form of technical and vocational education across medieval Europe. The daily routines of apprenticeship have left almost no traces in the surviving records. Most apprentices lived and worked with their masters, and received food, clothing, and shelter. The number of years required to learn trades was set by statute and custom and were often long. To learn to be a goldsmith in Paris took ten years, the same for a silversmith in Genoa. Normal terms of apprenticeship in both cities expected a student baker to serve five years. Did it really take so long to learn these trades, or were the rules intended to keep young people from competing with day laborers? Did masters simply want more work from apprentices at little or no pay? Apprenticeship contracts reveal a nuanced system of training in which the student often promised to perform all services inside and outside the house. In practice, this meant learning the trade as well as being a domestic servant. An apprentice learned about the hierarchy of labor in all its forms, that technical knowledge of a craft and going to the well for water were both work.

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

Nevertheless, the lore and technical expertise of some crafts took a long time to acquire. A spinner needed to understand the wheel, keep it repaired, and produce consistent thread. The apprentice repeated manual skills until the master's supervision was no longer necessary. Masters also passed down all the

knowledge of the trade, from testing the fineness of gold with touchstones to measuring the strength of thread. In these teen years, the apprentices also learned lessons on discipline and cooperation in the workplace. Some appren-

tices needed to learn rudimentary numerical and writing skills. In whose interest was it to make a goldsmith in just one year? The main obligation of the apprentice was to learn his or her trade and to

acquire good work habits and loyalty to employers. Occasional paternalistic rules prohibited apprentices from gambling, drinking, and sex. A training wage might contribute to the apprentice's family wage and allow the master some years of work at a low price. Journeymen and jouneywomen working fora daily

wage received less attention in statutes because employers were the bosses, period. Masters did not like the idea of competing against one another for

employees and were quick to raise objections to having their best workers lured away. Setting wages across a trade by statute was impractical and hard to enforce — because other issues, such as meal breaks, lodging, and holidays always intruded to make it complex to figure out exactly what counted as compensation.

The ordinances of the drapers’ guild in Chartres from 1268 reveal a nice mix of public and private concerns. This big guild included an alliance of trades in the cloth business including wool combers and carders, weavers, finishers, and dyers. In Chartres, anyone could join this guild upon paying a modest entry fee, and the rules compelled no one to join. Still, it would be hard to be in

the cloth business and remain apart from this guild. The drapers were mainly concerned about maintaining the quality of their local cloth — known by the town's name, not the name of an individual producer, and so they banned the sale of inferior cloth and investigated and fined anyone who made it. Trade marks for specific towns developed to signal customers about quality. Sales of

cloth took place at a public market so infractions were easy to spot. In Chartres, both men and women might rise to the status of master: In this town, the guild remained open to newcomers and unusually to a broad range of employees, but the common oath bound all to the high standards of quality and the dominance of the masters, whose monopoly was subtle but effective. The Livre des métiers is a collection of regulations for the guilds of Paris Eonipiled for the prévot or city manager Etienne Boileau in the 1260s. The 101 trades

117

118

An Economic and Social History of Later Medieval Europe, 1000-1500

included represent a wide cross-section of work in Paris and reflect a minute

division of labor — three separate guilds made buckles, divided according to the raw materials used. Most officials (preudbommes) of the guilds were appointed by the king's prévot or in some cases his appointee — for example, the king's baker had the right to name the officials of the bakers’ guild. The statutes set the terms of work: how many apprentices and valets (journeymen and women) a master might have; who could enter the trade — sons, daughters, strangers and at what fees. Strict rules determined whether or not the laborers could work at night — depending on if the trade was noisy or required good light. The statutes also set the length of apprenticeship, but the years varied depending on whether the apprentice paid for training. For example, the wool guild expected four years of apprenticeship and a payment of eighty sou (four livres) or seven years without payment. The calculations here included the costs to the master of feeding and housing unskilled labor in the early years versus the value of an unpaid and experienced apprentice at the end of his or her term. Women predominated in some guilds — they comprised the majority of the work force in many aspects of the silk trades and also had the status of masters capable of training apprentices. Even if the guild excluded women from actually running the trade, it was important that skilled women were able to pass down their knowledge to the next generation of women, and even in some cases train men. In a few guilds, such as the makers of silk caps, women served as officials (preudesfemmes). A handful of guilds, such as the lapidaries in crystal and stone, excluded women completely — the usual excuse was that the women did not know enough to carry on the profession, but this ignorance, if true, resulted from their exclusion. The 1292 taille in Paris, a tax assessed by hearth, gives a broader view of occupations outside the guild system. This source names 172 occupations and notes women working at many jobs — for example, copyist, artist, juggler, and dancer— for which there were no guilds. Women also worked as drapers, money changers, and in other professions that had guilds. Many women worked as domestic servants or as peddlers and wet-nurses, which were unregulated occupations. Women predominated in some jobs — most of the food trades, caring for the sick, and, as we would expect, in all phases of the silk business except actually running the main retail shops (see Table 4.1). Licensed professions, such as notaries and lawyers, excluded women, and women were absent from the ranks of porters and sailors, who performed heavy work and also toiled outside the guild system. The Livre des Metiers and taille records indicate that

Cities, Guilds, and Political Economy

Table 4.1. Women workers, Paris, 1292 (data from David Herlihy, Opera Muliebria: Women and Work in Medieval Europe. New York, 1990, p. 146).

Ml Servant Peddlar Dressmaker

Laundres

Silk Beguine Hairdresser